Sunteți pe pagina 1din 17

IMPACT OF FUEL SUBSIDY REMOVAL ON NIGERIAN ECONOMY

By

AKINDELE OLUSOLA AKINOLA

NOVEMBER, 2O11

INTRODUCTION The regulation and control of domestic prices of petroleum products by government is peculiar in developing nations of the world. Governments, in some cases focus their efforts on the direct control of import levels, domestic distribution, and domestic prices while some give the private sector the mandate to freely import and distribute petroleum products. However, the government sets the domestic price ceilings and compensate the private sector distributors to cover ensuing losses. Governments that directly control prices in most cases introduce price subsidies that keep domestic prices below border prices. This is particularly the case when international fuel prices increase sharply and governments are reluctant to pass these increases fully on to the domestic prices of petroleum products. Energy subsidies are found in virtually every country but its size varies; some are relatively high while some are low compared to that of other countries. The justifications for the use of subsidy vary from social welfare protection, job creation, the encouragement of new sources of energy supply, and economic development to energy security. However, large energy subsidies in countries also compete for limited resources that could otherwise be used to deliver other essential services for the developmental projects in the economy. Removing fuel subsidies is considered by many to be a win-win policy measure that would benefit both the global economy and the environment and therefore a no regret option for climate-change mitigation (Burniaux et al., 2009). In theory, eliminating fuel subsidies would result in higher fuel prices in countries that currently subsidize consumer prices, which would reduce consumption. At the same time, removing subsidies would remove a costly drain on the government budget. Consequently, eliminating subsidies on fuel may be one of the most cost-

effective and least distortionary options available to governments for reducing the strains on their budgets. On a basic level, if a subsidy that is keeping fuel prices artificially low is removed, the prices would rise. If producers were also receiving a subsidy, they will suffer a loss of their surplus and may raise prices. If prices rise, demand will likely fall, resulting in decrease in the level of consumption and loss of consumer welfare. If demand and producer surplus fall (in a closed economy), production may fall as a result of higher cost, resulting in a loss of employment and decrease in welfare. However, government expenditures on the subsidy will also fall, creating a net government surplus, which could then benefit society through reductions in government deficits and debts, or through improvements in government social programs. From the environmentalists point of view, declines in consumption will automatically lead to decline in emissions. The magnitudes of these changes will be determined by the price elasticities of supply and demand (Von Moltke et al., 2004). The primary focus of this paper is to evaluate and analyze the distribution of fuel subsidies, with special emphasis on the likely impacts of their removal on firms and households and to proffer alternative approaches to reduce the possible adverse effects.

LITERATURE REVIEW It is pertinent to understand the concept of subsidy. The World Trade Organisation Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (ACMS) provides a definition of subsidy. Article 1 of the Agreement states that a "subsidy" exists when there is a "financial contribution" by a government or public body that confers a benefit. A "financial contribution" arises where: a government practice involves a direct transfer of funds (e.g. grants, loans, and equity infusion), potential direct transfers of funds or liabilities (e.g. loan guarantees); government revenue that is otherwise due is foregone or not collected (e.g. fiscal incentives such as tax credits); a government provides goods or services other than general infrastructure, or purchases goods; or a government entrusts or directs a private body to carry out one or more of the above functions. A "benefit" is conferred when the "financial contribution" is provided to the recipient on terms that are more favorable than those that the recipient could have obtained from the market. Over the years, there has been divergent view on the removal of energy subsidy. Most authors believe that the removal of subsidy is healthy for economic growth and development. This is centered on their submission that paying actual cost reveals the true cost of consumption and leads to a greater level of efficiency in the economy. However, appropriate measures are considered necessary so as not to affect macroeconomic variables like inflation, unemployment, economic growth, etc. It is worth knowing that there are costs associated with subsidy removal, mostly in the short run.

According to Nwafor et al (2006), subsidy removal without spending of the associated savings would increase the national poverty level. This is due to the consequent rise in input costs which will be higher and a rise in selling prices of most firms and farms. The key sector that experience increased nominal output is the refined petroleum products sector which provide income for an extremely low number of households. The findings of Coady et al (2006) shows that energy subsidies are badly targeted in all the countries analyzed which are Bolivia, Ghana, Jordan, Mali, and Sri Lanka. This even holds true for kerosene, for which subsidies are often promoted as a way of protecting the poor. Reflecting this, the real income burden resulting from the withdrawal of energy subsidies is borne disproportionately by higher-income households. They said lower income households do suffer sizable real income decreases from subsidy removal, and any credible policy strategy therefore needs to address the mitigation of these adverse effects. ORyan et al (2003), analyzed the subject matter on Chile and concluded that removing oil subsidies could have economic and distributional effects on the economy. This is mainly because consumption of oil is relatively large compared to other forms of power. Also, the effects on the sectors concerned, namely oil refining and coal production are much bigger in each case. However, the environment clearly benefits from the removal of both coal and oil subsidies as the level of emissions are much lower in both cases. Ghana has been a small producer of oil, importing the bulk of its needs either in the form of petroleum products or as crude oil to be processed in its domestic refinery. In 2004, as the world oil price rose, the total cost of subsidies increased sharply. By 2005, fuel price increased by 50% as a result of subsidy removal but series of mitigation measures were also introduced that were transparent and easily monitorable. These included the immediate elimination of fees at

governmentrun primary and juniorsecondary schools, and a programmes to improve public transport. There was opposition to the increases but there was general acceptance of the policy (Bacon and Kojima 2006).

FUEL SUBSIDY IN NIGERIA In Nigeria, the government bears part of the production cost of fuel through subsidies basically to alleviate the high cost on the masses and to reduce production cost of goods and services. The local refineries in the country produce about 13 million liters of refined petroleum products daily. However, daily domestic consumption is about 30 million liters. The shortfall of 17 million liters is imported so as to meet daily demand. The imported products are not sold at their full landed cost as it is subsidized. In 2003, the government stated that for each liter of petroleum products, N12 is spent as subsidy. This implies an explicit subsidy of N74 billion or about 1.42% of GDP. Expenditure on fuel subsidy has increased over the years. It cost the government N1.3 trillion (about $8.38 billion) in the 2010 fiscal year, which accounts for about 25 per cent of the entire budget expenditure for the year under review. By the end of the year, the approved amended and supplementary budget amounted to N5.159 trillion (about $33.2 billion). Investigations revealed that fuel subsidy incurred by the Federal Government may have exceeded the N1 trillion mark by the end of the third quarter, with indications that payments to petroleum products marketers may surpass 2010 levels at the end of the year. Government regulates the sale of Premium Motor Spirit (PMS) and House Hold Kerosene (HHK), selling both at N55 and N40.90k per litre, respectively at the depots of the Petroleum Products Marketing Company (PPMC), a subsidiary of the state-owned Nigerian National

Petroleum Corporation

(NNPC). The Petroleum Products Pricing and Regulatory Agency

(PPPRA) allots quarterly imports quotas to the NNPC and petroleum products marketers and pay both parties the difference between the landed cost and the approved pump prices. Checks however revealed that the petroleum products marketers have turned the subsidy payment regime into a huge profiteering enterprise ripping the state of hundreds of billions each year under bogus subsidy claims for petroleum products they neither imported nor delivered to the pumps. Three quarters through 2011, independent checks revealed that outstanding subsidy payments amounts to over N1 trillion, while ongoing racketeering surrounding kerosene supply and distribution appears set to raise subsidy payment claims to an increase by the end of the year. According to the PPPRA pricing template, even though petrol is sold at N55.90k and N65 per litre, ex-depot and pump price respectively; if deregulated, consumers would have to pay N138.20k per litre. Essentially, the subsidy element on current petrol price is N82.30k per litre. Similarly, although ex-depot and pump prices of HHK is N40.90k and N50 per litre respectively; if deregulated, consumers would have to pay N151.15k per litre. Essentially, the subsidy element on current kerosene price is N110.25k per litre. It can be deduced from the literature that several countries were faced with the problem of removing fuel subsidies at different times and some succeeded as a result of the strategies that were adopted. If the proposed fuel subsidy removal is successful, prices of petroleum products would increase in the short run. In the medium to long term, investments in development of infrastructure would increase, jobs would be created, technology would be domiciled and under such circumstance, the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of the country will grow increasingly.

The success of this will however depend on the sincerity of the government and her ability to channel the funds back into the economy for developmental projects.

METHODOLOGY The events in an economy are shaped by the activities of the economic agents (government, firms and household) in such economy. The firm is the productive arm of the economy. Policies affecting the firm goes a long way in determine the behavior of the economy. Hence, the impact of fuel subsidy removal on the economy can be explained from the point of view of the firm. The model used for this purpose is an extension of the theory of firm. It is assumed that total output is a function of capital, labour and power. However, given the poor state of electricity in the country, it is assumed that firms power their plants through Premium Motor Spirit (PMS) (1) Where Q is total output K is capital AL is effective labour (labour driven by knowledge) P is PMS Assuming a Cobb-Douglas production function, the total output function becomes: (2) Where The quantity of total output that can be produced at a given time is determined by the budget constraint (cost function). Assuming a unit cost of capital to be r, per unit cost labour, w and a unit cost PMS to be z. The cost function becomes: (3)

However, z is not the consumer unit price of PMS as a result of subsidy. Demoting subsidy by s, the consumer unit price of PMS (z) can be defined as the difference between the actual price (u) and subsidy (s). z=us Therefore, the cost function becomes: (5) Firms seek to maximize total output subject to the cost constraint or minimize cost subject to the production constraint. Setting up a minimization problem for the firm using the Lagrangian multiplier, we have: (6) The first order condition yields the following equations: (7) (8) (9) (10) Solving for K, L and P in equations 7-10, yields the following: (4)

( ( (

) ( ) ) ( (

) ) )

(11)

....(12)

(13)

Substituting equations 11-13 into equation 5,

(
Note:

) (

( )

.. (14)

See appendix for full workings.

INTERPRETATION The effect of subsidy can be seen from equation 14 where s serves as a reducing value to the numerator as can be deduced from its negative sign. The removal of subsidy makes s to be zero. This implies that the numerator becomes relatively larger which consequently increases c (cost of production). However, it should be noted that the magnitude of the impact of subsidy removal on production cost will be determined (u-s), the difference between actual unit price of PMS and the amount consumers pay for a unit of PMS. The economic implication of the removal of subsidies can be analyzed through its impacts on the firm, as given above and consequently its effects on households. The removal of subsidies on fuel increases expenditures on power and transportation (movement of goods and people). This will however lead to increases in prices of goods and services which could cause cost-push inflation. This reduces purchasing power and increases the level of poverty.

SUMMARY Efforts has been made to study the impact of fuel subsidy removal on the Nigerian economy. The first section of the study dealt with the concept of subsidies and the rationale behind its application. Also, relevant literature was reviewed to establish the impacts subsidies has on economic growth and development, the consequences of removing fuel subsidy on the economy and ways of tackling the resulting crises posed by it.

Furthermore, the theory of the firm was adopted to study the impact on firms with the use of Cobb Douglas production function with capital, effective labour and power (PMS). The presence of subsidy on PMS was reflected in the firms cost function which was solved through optimization. Conclusions were drawn and policy recommendations were suggested on tackling the impending fuel subsidy removal in Nigeria.

CONCLUSION The removal of fuel subsidy will imply that consumers will be paying the actual price of the commodity. This will remove all forms of distortions and lead to an improved level of efficiency and effective operations in the economy. Literature has shown that subsidy removal is healthy for an economy. However, the removal of fuel subsidy removal will have a great impact on the Nigerian economy as fuel has no competing close substitute and its demand is inelastic in nature due to its importance in driving economic activities by households, firms and government. Considering the present state of Nigerias economy, removal of fuel subsidy will have a negative effect on the economy in the short run and possibly in the long run if adequate measure are not taken. In the short run, there is a likely effect of inflation, increase in poverty level, high level of social unrest, decrease in productivity level, unemployment, etc. The main reasons for these will be due to poor infrastructures; in terms of good roads, power (electricity), rail system of transportation; lack of political will and the high level of corruption. Another contributing factor will be the inability of local refineries to operate at full capacity to cover local consumption of refined crude oil.

If these shortfalls are met and the funds initially spent on subsidies are channeled back into productive activities in the economy, the effect of the removal of fuel subsidy in the short run will be minimal and will lead to considerable growth overtime.

POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS The following measures are suggested for the government to take before removing subsidy on fuel. Firstly, the power sector should be developed so as to ensure constant electricity supply. Secondly, efforts should be geared at restoring efficiency to the local refineries and building of new ones by private investors. Furthermore, the provision of basic infrastructures with the construction of electric rail systems. Also, government should initiate the development of cheaper alternative sources of power. For example, solar and gas. Lastly government needs to partner with the private sector to ensure the development of the real sectors of the economy. It must however be noted that economic growth and development in Nigeria can only be achieved if there is strong implementation of policies, political will and the reduction of corruption to the bearest minimum.

REFERENCES Adenikinju A. ( 2000). Analysis of Energy Pricing Policy in Nigeria: An Application of a CGE Model. Research for development. NISER Background Paper for the World Bank Group Energy Sector Strategy (2010). Subsidies in the Energy Sector: An Overview Bacon, R. and Kojima, M. (2006). Coping with Higher Oil Prices. Energy Sector Management Assistance Program, World Bank: Washington, DC. Burniaux, J., Chanteau, J., Dellink, R., Duval, R. and Jamet, S. (2009). The economics of climate change mitigation: How to build the necessary global action in a cost-effective manner. Economic Department Working Papers No. 701. Coady, D., El-Said, M., Gillingham, R., Kpodar, K., Medas, P. and Newhouse, D. (2006). The Magnitude and Distribution of Fuel Subsidies: Evidence from Bolivia, Ghana, Jordan, Mali and Sri Lanka. IMF Working Paper. Ellis J (2010). The Effects of Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform: A review of modeling and empirical studies. International Institute for Sustainable Development. Nwafor M., Ogujiuba K., Asogwa R. (2006) Does Subsidy Removal Hurt The Poor. Secretariat for Institutional Support for Economic Research in Africa (SISERA) Working Papers Series. ORyan R,. Miller S., Rogat J., Miguel C. Energy Subsidies: Lessons Learned in Assessing their Impact and Designing Policy Reforms in Chile. Von Moltke, A., McKee, C. and Morgan, T. (2004). Energy Subsidies: Lessons Learned in Assessing their Impact and Designing Policy Reforms. Sheffield: Greenleaf Publishing.

APPENDIX (1) Assuming a Cobb-Douglas production function, the total output function becomes: (2) Where (3) Where z = (u s); hence, (4) Setting up the lagrangian, we have: (5) The first order condition yields the following equation: (6) (7) (8) (9) From equation (6) and (7)

(10) From equation 6 & 8

(11) Substituting equation 10 & 11 in equation 9, we have: ( ) ( )

) (

( (

) ( ) ( )

) (12)

Substitute equation 12 into 10 ( )( ( ( ) ( ) ( ) ) ) ( ) (13)

Substituting equation 12 in equation 11

( ( ( ) ) (

) (

(14)

Inserting equation 12, 13 & 14 into the cost function, we are able to solve the cost function thus:

) (

) (

( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ) ) ) ( ) ( ) ( ) (

) ( ) ( ( ( ) ) ) ) ( ) ) ) )

) ( ( ( ( ( ) ( )

( ) )( )( ) ( ) ( )

) (

( ) ( ) ) ( ) )

) ( ( ( ) )(

) ( )

) (

(16)

S-ar putea să vă placă și