Sunteți pe pagina 1din 13

No.

390 Febuary 1, 2001

“Big Oil” at the Public Trough?


An Examination of Petroleum Subsidies
by Ronald J. Sutherland

Executive Summary

Critics of the oil industry allege that the oil revenues and far less generous than the pref-
industry receives large and unwarranted govern- erences and subsidies provided for rival business-
ment subsidies and that rival technologies, such es and technologies such as mass transit and
as those for ethanol, renewable energy, and ener- alternative fuels. Moreover, most energy subsi-
gy efficiency, deserve compensating government dies are wealth transfers that do not significant-
preferences. The evidence indicates that, on bal- ly distort energy prices or affect energy markets.
ance, the oil industry is not a net beneficiary of The contention that oil consumers do not pay
government subsidies. The facts point in the their fair share of the environmental and national
opposite direction. The oil industry is more defense costs they impose on society is dubious.
harmed than helped by government intervention There is little evidence to suggest that the envi-
in energy markets. ronmental externalities imposed by oil consump-
Special tax deductions, direct expenditures, tion exceed the taxes and regulatory costs paid by
net excise taxes, and research and development consumers. The contention that national defense
expenditures are constantly targeted by oil crit- costs would be lower if domestic oil consumption
ics. However, those subsidies are a small share of were taxed is also not supported by the evidence.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________

Ronald J. Sutherland is an energy economist who has worked at Argonne National Laboratory and the American
Petroleum Institute. He is currently with the Center for the Advancement of Energy Markets.
The classic defini- percent tax on oil. That tax would “get the
tion of “subsidy” Introduction prices right” and thereby solve the global
warming problem at no cost.4
is a government The contention that the oil industry Both the Greenpeace and the ASE calcula-
action that receives large government subsidies has a tions, however, ignore the many burdens
long history. The ethanol lobby justifies gov- placed on oil production and use. Those bur-
bestows an eco-
ernment preferences largely by decrying the dens include Superfund taxes, road fuel use
nomic benefit on market-distorting subsidies supposedly pro- taxes, and many environmental regulations.
a special-interest vided the oil industry. The environmental An honest accounting demands that burdens
community raises the issue in an effort to be given as much analytic attention as posi-
group with the justify increasing subsidies to “green” tech- tive subsidies.
objective of nologies. Oil’s competitors and their advo-
encouraging cer- cates justify government help by calling for a
“level playing field” between industries, a The Anatomy of
tain economic playing field that can supposedly be created Energy Subsidies
behavior. only by offsetting one set of subsidies with
another.1 Accounting data, such as government
The alleged oil subsidies at issue fall pri- budget data, are typically used to measure
marily into three categories. First, there are energy subsidies. Using those accounting
tax provisions: the depletion allowance and measures poses conceptual difficulties; a cau-
deductions for intangible drilling costs and tious interpretation of subsidies is in order.
enhanced oil recovery.2 Second, indirect sub-
sidies in the form of defense expenditures for A Definition of “Subsidy”
the Middle East, the Alaskan pipeline, and The classic definition of “subsidy” is a
the Strategic Petroleum Reserve are substan- government action that bestows an econom-
tial and not reflected in oil prices. Third, ic benefit on a special-interest group, or eco-
there are environmental costs to oil con- nomic sector, with the objective of encourag-
sumption (primarily air pollution and global ing certain economic behavior.5
warming) that are not fully reflected in the The first defining characteristic of a sub-
price consumers pay for petroleum-based sidy, then, is that it results from a govern-
products. Because it does not act to “inter- ment action. Such action can be triggered by
nalize” within oil prices the cost of the envi- virtually any piece of legislation or regulatory
ronmental externalities imposed by oil con- initiative.6
sumption, government is alleged to subsidize The next defining characteristic of a sub-
the oil industry indirectly. sidy is that it bestows an economic benefit on
Studies of energy market programs, the recipient. Subsidies, however, can include
including subsidies, focus on one of two programs other than direct monetary trans-
questions: (1) How large are the government fers from the government. For instance, an
subsidies to and charges on various forms of industry may receive favored tax treatment
energy? (2) Are those subsidies and charges at relative to comparable industries. The impact
the appropriate level? of such treatment is similar to that of a direct
Relatively recent studies by Greenpeace monetary transfer. Conversely, tax laws can
and the Alliance to Save Energy are typical of penalize an economic unit if that unit is sub-
the literature. According to Greenpeace, the ject to higher taxes than comparable eco-
oil industry received net government subsi- nomic units. The effect is a negative subsidy.
dies of from $15.7 billion to $35.2 billion, Regulation may also provide a subsidy.
including defense subsidies, in 1995.3 The For instance, the Price-Anderson Act encour-
ASE quantifies the environmental externality ages the development of nuclear power by
of oil consumption and recommends a 22.7 limiting the liability of a plant owner in case

2
of a large nuclear accident.7 This law is an Greenpeace; indeed, their definitions of “sub-
important subsidy to nuclear power, sidy” are representative of the larger public
although no monetary transfer occurs. policy literature. The point is simply that
Regulation may, on the other hand, impose a energy subsidies are difficult to define in
negative subsidy by requiring firms to terms of properties that are different from
expend additional resources. For example, those of other energy policy actions. As we
health, safety, and environmental regulations shall see, subsidies are even more difficult to
impose costs but may also produce benefits. measure.
Furthermore, a subsidy may affect a spe-
cific fuel or technology rather than energy Equity and Efficiency Implications of
markets in general. The impact on submar- Subsidies
kets could distinguish energy subsidies from Subsidies can have equity effects or effi-
other energy policies. However, the complica- ciency effects, or both. That is, subsidies may
tion is that all government actions have dis- affect the distribution of wealth within soci-
proportionate effects on some segments of ety and the efficiency of economic activity.
energy markets. Specific sectors receive bene- The effects may be positive or negative,
fits (or pay costs) even when the policy is not minor or major, direct or indirect, intended
intended to subsidize. or unintended. Policy analysts who wish to Subsidies may
In sum, subsidies may be direct or indi- inform the public debate must consider equi- affect the distrib-
rect, positive or negative. A subsidy for one ty and efficiency effects independently ution of wealth
technology discriminates against competing because each effect is important.
technologies. A subsidy may result in the Efficiency issues, however, are most preva- within society
favored technology’s being a “winner”; how- lent in the energy subsidy debate. Most criti- and the efficiency
ever, the technology locked out of the market cisms of subsidy heard today imply that pub-
might have been preferable. Accounting mea- lic policy produces an inefficient level and
of economic
sures of subsidies do not capture such mar- composition of energy use. activity.
ket distortions. Economic theory allows for conditions in
The last defining characteristic of a sub- which unregulated private markets provide
sidy is the intention to encourage specific too little or too much of some goods. If pri-
economic behavior. The underlying ratio- vate markets undervalue an economic activi-
nale for an energy subsidy is to encourage ty, then a government subsidy could enhance
the development of a fuel or technology that economic efficiency. Likewise, if private mar-
private markets neglect but that is in the kets overvalue an economic activity, then a tax
public interest. could enhance economic efficiency. However,
A subsidy is properly thought of as a kind if private markets correctly value an econom-
of government action. However, it is some- ic activity, then a government subsidy distorts
times defined to encompass all energy policy resource use and produces inefficiency. Such
interventions. For instance, the definition of inefficiencies are termed “nonmarket fail-
“subsidy” used by Greenpeace—“Subsidies ures” by Charles Wolf;10 others more bluntly
represent government policies that benefit term them “government failures.”
particular sectors of the economy”8—could The main economic question about subsi-
be used to describe any government interven- dies, then, is whether they reduce a market fail-
tion in energy markets. The definition used ure or impose a government failure.
by the Energy Information Administration— Addressing the question requires a complex
”government actions which had as their policy analysis. In the absence of such an analy-
function alteration of energy markets by ben- sis, we cannot determine whether subsidies are
efiting some group of producers or con- market distorting or market enhancing.
sumers”9—suffers from the same problem. “Equity” refers to the distribution of ben-
My intention is not to criticize the EIA or efits and costs. Virtually all government

3
actions produce equity effects, because gov- ment’s tax collector. Consumers respond to
ernment programs produce both winners the sales tax in part by paying it and in part
(the beneficiaries of the action) and losers. by attempting to avoid it. Avoidance mea-
The losers include those not benefited or sures include shopping in a no-tax region,
even those punished by government action as shopping on the Internet, shifting purchases
well as those who pay the taxes or regulatory to nontaxed goods, and perhaps reducing
costs to secure benefits for others. Judging consumption and increasing saving. Each of
whether equity effects are favorable or unfa- those avoidance efforts shifts part of the bur-
vorable is a separate issue. Equity effects are den back to the retailer in the form of dimin-
not unambiguously good or bad. One con- ished sales. Further, data on sales tax receipts
cern here is the extent to which energy pro- underestimate the cost to producers and
grams have equity effects without altering consumers because the data do not reflect
efficiency. the lost value of diminished purchases.11
While economists are concerned chiefly The distinction between the initial inci-
with the economic efficiency of government dence of a tax and its ultimate burden is par-
interventions, politicians and policy activists ticularly applicable to tax allowances for
are concerned chiefly with the equity effects energy. A tax allowance (termed a “tax expen-
of governmental interventions, especially diture” by economists) results in a reduced
when the issue is subsidy. For instance, the tax rate for certain goods and services vis-à-
moniker “corporate welfare” is often derisive- vis that paid by consumers of competing
ly marshaled by those who generally do not goods and services. Such disparities
oppose welfare in principle. They do, howev- inevitably trigger complex market adjust-
er, oppose welfare for the better off. The ments of the kind observed in consumer
argument is grounded in a concern about reaction to sales taxes.
equity. Moreover, the public appears to be Moreover, the benefits bestowed by subsi-
more concerned about the “fairness” of gov- dies are reduced by competition and cap-
ernmental policy (the equity effect) than tured, in part, by others, primarily con-
about its efficiency effects. sumers. If the initial subsidy lowers costs to
the producer, those lower costs may translate
Initial and Ultimate Effects of Subsidies into reduced market prices that benefit con-
Although promoters of subsidies may sumers. Most subsidy studies ignore the allo-
Market agents fre- intend one set of effects on production and cation of subsidies between producers and
consumption, market agents frequently consumers, because accounting data cannot
quently adjust to adjust to the existence of subsidies so as to make that distinction.12
the existence of shift the ultimate cost or benefit of the sub-
sidy from the intended to unintended par- Estimating Energy Industry Subsidies
subsidies so as to ties. In fact, subsidies generally have such A 1999 report by the EIA summarizes the
shift the ultimate complex effects on the economy that exami- direct and indirect federal subsidies for ener-
cost or benefit of nation of outlays provides only fragmentary gy using accounting data.13 The report pro-
and incomplete information. Because of this, vides a useful taxonomy of subsidies.
the subsidy from taxation analysts distinguish between the Table 1 summarizes the EIA estimates of
the intended to incidence of a tax and the ultimate burden of a federal energy subsidies. Total energy subsi-
unintended tax. That distinction is particularly impor- dies were $6.2 billion, about 1 percent of total
tant for measuring energy subsidies. energy expenditures, in 1999.14
parties. Consider a tax on retail sales. The initial Figure 1 shows the magnitude of energy
incidence falls on the retailer. However, the subsidies for each fuel source. The data in the
retailer typically adds the tax to the sales figure clearly show that the oil industry
price, and most of the burden shifts to cus- receives less real subsidy than any other fuel
tomers. The retailer becomes the govern- industry.

4
Table 1
Federal Energy Subsidies on a Budget Outlay Basis, Fiscal Year 1999 (millions of dollars)
Type of Subsidy

Direct Research &


Beneficiary Expenditures Income Excise Development Total

Oil 255 263 0 49 567


Gas 501 1,048 0 115 1,664
Coal 0 85 0 404 489
Misc. fossil fuelsa 0 205 0 0 205
Nuclear 0 0 0 640 640
Renewables 44 15 725 b 327 1,111
Conservation c 166 110 0 0 276
End use d 0 105 0 454 559
Electricitye 459 195 0 330 f 687
Total 1,425 2,026 725 2,022 6,198

Source: Energy Information Administration, “Federal Financial Interventions and Subsidies in Energy Markets
1999: Energy Transformation and End Use,” SR/OIAF/2000-02, Table ES1, p. x.

aThis category represents expenditures not allocated to any of the three individual fossil fuels.
bAlcohol fuels excise tax.
cConservation programs are directed primarily at consumers of energy and often are supported by grants.
dEnd-use programs are oriented to the development and introduction of new technologies for use in specific sectors.
eDoes not include support for the Tennessee Valley Authority, the power marketing administrations, or the Rural
Utilities Service.
fElectricity research and development in advanced turbine technology. Other generation technology research
and development subsidies are distributed by fuel.
Figure 1
Magnitude of Energy Subsidies, 1999
30

25.64
25

20

15.6
15

10

5
2.19 1.91
0.26 0.38
0
Oil Natural Gas Coal Nuclear Renewables End-Use
Electricity
Source: Energy Information Administration, “Federal Financial Interventions and Subsidies in Energy Markets 1999:
Energy Transformation and End Use,” SR/OIAF/2000-02, Table ES1, p. xiv.

5
Energy tax expen- Tax Expenditures tax expenditures by the GAO, for instance,
ditures in 1999 Federal tax law defines the tax deductions lists the 15 largest tax expenditures.17 The list
that businesses and individuals are entitled does not include tax deductions for the oil
totaled $2.75 bil- to in computing their federal income tax lia- industry. Instead, the list includes such things
lion, of which bility. The tax code provides numerous pref- as pension contributions, deductions for med-
erences for selected economic sectors and ical insurance premiums, deductions for state
$263 million interest groups. The tax deductions resulting and local taxes, deductions for charitable con-
accrued to the oil from those preferences are revenue losses to tributions, and other deductions. The GAO
industry. the government. The term “tax expenditures” estimates that in 1993 tax expenditures for all
is used to describe those revenue losses. As business programs were $61.5 billion.18
defined by the U.S. General Accounting
Office, Direct Expenditures
The sole direct expenditure subsidy for the
Tax expenditures are revenues fore- oil industry, according to the EIA, is the Low-
gone, or revenue losses, due to pref- Income Housing Energy Assistance Program.
erential provisions of federal tax Other direct expenditure subsidies that favor
laws, such as special exclusions, the fossil fuels industry (that is, the natural gas
exemptions, deductions, credits, and coal industries) include federal public
deferrals or tax rates.15 power undertakings and the various regulato-
ry agencies’ ongoing activities that qualify as
The subsidy literature considers tax direct subsidies to the industry.
expenditures as subsidies. The expenditures The LIHEAP, under the management of
are (supposedly) revenue the government the U.S. Department of Health and Human
would have received in the absence of the tax Services, provides block grants to states and
deduction. Tax expenditures enjoyed by one Indian tribes to administer assistance to low-
sector are comparable to government rev- income households in meeting their heating
enues used elsewhere. and cooling needs.19 According to the EIA,
Tax expenditures, however, offer advan- the LIHEAP spent $1.26 billion in 1999 to
tages (to the recipient) relative to direct mon- administer assistance to 4.5 million house-
etary transfers. Tax expenditures are not tax- holds. Of that amount, only $255 million
able, whereas direct monetary subsidies are was used for oil.20
subject to federal income tax. Tax expendi- Low-income households certainly benefit
tures, moreover, are part of the tax code and from this program,21 but energy producers
hence are not normally subject to an annual may not be significant beneficiaries. The EIA
review. In contrast, a direct monetary subsidy reports that the average LIHEAP household
must compete with other expenditures in the consumes about 10 percent more energy
annual review of the federal budget. (Given than does the average low-income house-
the vast inertia in budgeting, it is unclear hold22 and only about 0.4 percent less energy
how great an advantage this is in practice.) than the national average household uses for
The EIA estimates (Table 1) that energy heating.23 The data thus suggest that
tax expenditures in 1999 totaled $2.75 bil- LIHEAP recipients would have purchased
lion, of which $263 million accrued to the oil about 90 percent as much energy without the
industry. Thus, the oil industry received 0.96 subsidy. Thus, much of the LIHEAP subsidy
percent of the tax expenditures on the energy displaces existing energy expenses, enabling
industry. Most of that subsidy reflects an recipients to spend more of their incomes
enhanced oil recovery credit.16 elsewhere.
Compare this $263 million tax subsidy to Underscoring that conclusion is a survey
the oil industry with the tax subsidies enjoyed of household energy consumption conduct-
by other industries. A comprehensive study of ed by the EIA. That survey found that house-

6
holds in the lowest three income levels spent budget of $464 million in 2000 but had off-
33.2 percent, 38 percent, and 35.6 percent, setting receipts of $460 million.27 Hence, its
respectively, of their energy budgets on space net cost (the direct subsidy) was $4 million in
heating in 1993.24 Households eligible for 2000. Other energy regulatory agencies, such
federal assistance spent 34.7 percent of their as the Bureau of Land Management and the
energy budgets on space heating. Apparently, Minerals Management Service, have no off-
the LIHEAP does not encourage low-income setting revenues. Hence, many analysts count
households to substantially increase their their entire expenses as subsidies.
expenditures on space heating. Those regulatory expenditures do not
The distinction between the incidence appear in Table 1, however, because they are
and the ultimate burden of a tax applies to indirect rather than direct subsidies and thus
the LIHEAP subsidy. In its initial incidence, outside the scope of the latest EIA studies. In any
the LIHEAP subsidy is an energy subsidy case, their impact on the market is negligible.
because it subsidizes the consumption of
energy. However, LIHEAP recipients respond Trust Funds and Excise Taxes
to the subsidy by decreasing the amount of The government uses numerous trust
their discretionary income allocated to ener- funds to meet specific needs of various
gy. After market adjustments, LIHEAP industries. Trust funds allow firms in an After market
appears to be more of an income subsidy to industry to form a common pool of funds to adjustments,
the household than a subsidy for energy address an external cost. For instance, if an LIHEAP appears
businesses. industry imposes environmental costs, the
Another large federal subsidy of the government taxes the industry to obtain to be more of an
“direct expenditure” type is for energy ser- funds for environmental restoration. The income subsidy to
vices for electricity generation. This subsidy, EIA describes several environmental trust
which totals somewhere between $2.38 bil- funds. For instance, the Oil-Spill Liability
the household
lion and $5.1 billion (depending on how fed- Trust Fund, which finances federal oil-spill than a subsidy for
eral interest rate support and return on asset cleanup efforts, is financed by a tax on oil energy businesses.
support are calculated) is the largest single entering U.S. ports.28
energy subsidy.25 It reflects the taxpayer cost Presumably, the government does not
of supporting government power adminis- intend trust funds to be subsidies. The subsidy
trations such as the Tennessee Valley literature does not consider trust funds as sub-
Authority, the Rural Electrification sidies as long as industry-related expenses
Administration (currently Rural Utilities match industry-related receipts. If industry-
Service), and the power marketing adminis- related expenses exceed industry-related
trations (including most prominently the receipts and general revenues make up the dif-
Bonneville Power Administration). Those ference, the industry receives a subsidy.
providers operate at a financial loss that However, if industry-related trust fund
appears as a subsidy.26 Those subsidies are receipts supplement general revenues, the
not included in Table 1, given the uncertain- industry receives a negative subsidy. The EIA
ty of the calculations, but it should be noted reports that only the Black Lung Disability
that none of those subsidies is directed at the Trust Fund is running a deficit. On the whole,
oil industry. energy-related trust fund program receipts
Direct expenditures also include those for exceed costs by $13 billion annually.29
energy regulatory agencies. Those agencies’ Another dedicated energy fund that draws
activities are intended to provide a service to attention is the Highway Trust Fund, a feder-
the industry and its customers and, when al program that assists in the construction
funded by general revenues, are considered and maintenance of highways and is funded
by many to be subsidies. The Nuclear by a vehicular fuels tax. Although vehicular
Regulatory Commission, for instance, had a fuel taxes had traditionally been imposed as a

7
sort of “user fee” dedicated exclusively to this dealt exclusively with federal subsidies. State
fund, Congress levied an additional trans- and local governments levy many of the road
portation fuels tax in 1990 to support the taxes and use some of those tax receipts to
General Revenue Fund, and that tax, accord- support various other government services.
ing to the EIA, amounted to a “negative tax”
on the oil industry that was 10 times the size R&D Expenditures
of the direct and indirect subsidies to the The federal government has a long history
industry.30 During most of the 1990s, the oil of supporting R&D, particularly in defense-
industry was burdened by this negative sub- related technologies and basic research. The
sidy in the form of a 4.3 cent per gallon tax U.S. Department of Energy supports national
on motor fuels. Since October 1, 1997 (the defense (nuclear weapons), environmental
beginning of fiscal year 1998), the govern- restoration, basic research, and the develop-
ment has been depositing the funds in the ment of energy-related technologies.
Highway Trust Fund.31 The EIA reports that in 1999 the DOE
The Federal Highway Administration pro- budget for energy programs was $2.02 bil-
vides data on funding for highways and the lion, of which $49 million was allocated to
disposition of revenues at the federal and oil-related research. This apparent oil sub-
state-plus-local levels.32 The main point is sidy is 2.4 percent of the total R&D budget
that federal, state, and local taxes and fees for for energy programs. The largest share of
road funding were $89.1 billion in 1998, the DOE’s energy budget was used for elec-
while spending on roads was $69.2 billion tricity-related technologies, such as coal
and funds diverted for nonroad use were ($404 million), nuclear ($640 million), and
$19.9 billion. renewable energy and energy conservation
Numerous other taxes and fees are collect- ($327 million).
ed from motorists by various levels of gov- The DOE’s R&D budget for applied ener-
ernment. Conventional taxes include motor gy programs has declined over the last two
fuel taxes levied at the federal, state, and local decades. The largest declines are in the
levels. Additional taxes include registration nuclear and coal programs. The oil program
fees, drivers’ license fees, title fees, vehicular continues to be a small share of the energy
property taxes, and sales taxes. The Federal program R&D budget. The conclusion we
Highway Administration reports the amount can draw from these data is that federal R&D
of those “other taxes and fees” that is allocat- subsidies for energy technologies are relative-
ed to roads but does not report the amount ly small and on the decline. Furthermore,
An accounting of actually collected from motorists. A signifi- many energy R&D subsidies are primarily
cant portion of total taxes and fees collected wealth transfers that do not significantly dis-
indirect subsidies for roads, however, is redistributed away tort energy markets.34
to oil consumers from road use.33 Most of the funds diverted The accumulation of funding for energy
reveals a number from road use go to mass transit or to gener- R&D programs since the DOE was estab-
al revenues of state and local governments. lished in 1977 adds a qualification to this
of additional Consumers of vehicle transportation services conclusion. From 1978 through 1996, the
negative subsidies pay taxes that exceed government expendi- DOE spent (in 1996 dollars) $20.1 billion on
tures on those services by billions of dollars nuclear energy (excluding nuclear weapon
beyond that of
per year. research), $13.3 billion on energy conserva-
the motor In sum, an accounting of indirect subsi- tion, $13.2 billion on coal R&D, and $5.1 bil-
fuels tax. dies to oil consumers reveals a number of lion on solar energy. 35 Those amounts
additional negative subsidies beyond that of included the $4.5 billion spent for fast breed-
the motor fuels tax. The negative annual sub- er reactors from 1978 through 1987 and the
sidies from road and highway taxes were not $661.8 million spent on magnetohydrody-
highlighted by the EIA, because that report namics from 1978 through 1992.36 Neither

8
of the latter two programs attained commer- (those borne by entities other than the con- R&D programs
cial success. sumer). Economic efficiency thus requires by themselves
The R&D programs by themselves may that the price of oil include marginal private
not affect energy markets, but, in combina- cost plus marginal external cost. Environ- may not affect
tion with government tax and regulatory mentalists argue that the price of oil is not energy markets,
changes, those programs have significant high enough to reflect the marginal external
market effects. In 1995 nuclear power pro- cost and that a tax on oil would “get the prices
but, in combina-
duced 21.8 percent of the kilowatt-hours right.” Short of that, preferences and subsidies tion with govern-
generated by utilities in the United States.37 to oil competitors would “level the playing ment tax and reg-
This market share results from the enormous field” and help establish competitive neutrali-
R&D subsidy over time along with state reg- ty in the marketplace. ulatory changes,
ulations that encouraged the construction of those programs
nuclear plants.38 Other state and federal poli- National Security Costs as an Oil have significant
cies encouraged the adoption of energy con- Industry Subsidy
servation measures and the use of solar tech- The issue of defense expenditure subsidies market effects.
nologies. We can define the initial incidence to the oil industry revolves around two specif-
of those subsidies and infer that the govern- ic questions: First, does the national defense
ment research community was a beneficiary. budget subsidize the use of oil? Second,
We cannot determine whether energy con- should the government tax oil imports or con-
sumers were made better or worse off by sumers to pay the national defense costs of
those subsidies. protecting oil supplies in the Persian Gulf and
in other regions? The answer to the first ques-
tion is affirmative. The answer to the second
National Security and question is negative.
Environmental Costs The argument that the national defense
budget subsidizes oil was perhaps most clear-
For some time, critics of the oil industry ly made in a Greenpeace study, which con-
concentrated their fire on tax expenditure cluded that national defense costs directly
subsidies. The more recent critics emphasize attributable to Middle Eastern oil are in the
indirect subsidies in the form of the national range of $10.5 billion to $23.3 billion per
defense and environmental costs of using oil. year.40 The Greenpeace analysis begins by
A Greenpeace study, for instance, argues that reviewing other estimates of the military
the oil industry (and thus oil consumers) costs of defending oil in the Middle East, esti-
does not pay the military costs of defending mates that range from $79 billion per year to
oil in the Middle East. The ASE argues that $500 million per year. The enormous range
the producers and consumers of oil products in estimates reflects the use of different
do not pay sufficient environmental taxes, methodologies. The lower estimate is an esti-
especially taxes for global warming. On the mate of marginal defense costs. The higher
basis of those and other similar analyses, estimate is a total cost estimate. Because the
some observers peg the indirect subsidies to cost estimates depend critically on the
the oil industry at $84 billion annually.39 methodologies employed, a brief discussion
The argument for additional externality of each methodology is in order.
taxes derives from a simple economics frame- The total cost approach allocates the mil-
work. A textbook condition for the efficient itary budget to various regions around the
use of resources is that the marginal cost of a world, with a specific sum to the Middle East.
product must equal its price. This equality The oil security objective then receives some
implies an absence of externalities. However, share of that allocation. Considering that the
marginal cost includes private costs (those total national defense budget was $268.5 bil-
borne by the consumer) and external costs lion in 1998, the funds estimated as oil relat-

9
ed are necessarily large.41 Given the total size al vehicles produce environmental emissions
of the defense budget, the Greenpeace esti- that impose an external cost on nonusers, the
mate of the national defense costs of oil sup- argument that additional pollution taxes
plies ($10.5 billion to $23.3 billion for 1995) would promote efficiency is quite a different
is not surprising. assertion. The Environmental Protection
The marginal cost approach relates the Agency has promulgated regulations
change in military spending to the change in designed to achieve cost-effective environ-
the use of foreign oil, or perhaps to the mental quality. The EPA’s approach is to
change in world oil prices. In one application, favor environmental standards over pollu-
the marginal cost approach estimates the tion taxes. For motor vehicles, those stan-
decline in defense spending that results from dards include requirements for catalytic con-
subtracting the oil security objective from the verters, unleaded gasoline, reformulated
military budget. The Congressional Research fuels, and fuel efficiency standards.43 We can-
Service estimate of $500 million in defense not determine a priori whether those stan-
expenditures per year for oil is derived from dards impose costs at the margin that exceed
this analytic approach.42 An alternative environmental benefits or are less than envi-
application of the marginal cost approach ronmental benefits.
Government sub- estimates the potential savings in military In addition to environmental restrictions,
sidies to the oil expenses resulting from a marginal reduction there are federal, state, and local taxes on
industry do not in domestic oil use. If a large and permanent motor fuels. Those taxes are, in effect, mar-
tax were placed on oil, the use of oil products ginal externality taxes, although their pur-
appear to produce would certainly decline. With less dependence pose is to generate revenue. Those net tax
significant distor- on foreign oil, so the argument goes, a reduc- payments, which are in addition to the costs
tion in military expenditures would be feasi- of existing environmental regulations,
tions in energy ble. Once again, however, the Congressional should more than pay the marginal environ-
markets. Research Service study suggests that a mar- mental cost of using oil products. A recent
ginal reduction in oil use would not facilitate study by W. Kipp Viscusi and others used
reducing military expenditures. EPA data on the economic costs imposed by
In sum, reducing consumption of foreign the environmental damage associated with
oil would have little impact on defense energy use.44 Calculations were based on
expenditures, which suggests that the emissions contribution per unit of fuel con-
national security costs of oil imports are min- sumed and percentage of retail price. Those
imal and that they do not significantly affect calculations were then compared with the
energy markets. net current taxes paid by various energy
sources and considered under various tax
Environmental Costs as an Oil Industry approaches (consumption, Btu, ad valorem,
Subsidy and carbon). Although the authors acknowl-
A second externality cost of oil is the envi- edged a wide range of uncertainty in the
ronmental cost. The combustion of fossil assumptions, they found that the external
fuels results in the emission of several air pol- environmental costs of gasoline were “inter-
lutants that impose an environmental cost nalized” completely by regulatory action and
on nonusers. Air pollution is the classic overtaxation for other purposes.45
example of an environmental externality. The
ASE develops this argument and recom-
mends “getting the prices right” by imposing Conclusion
additional taxes on oil products. Such taxes
would reflect existing air pollution costs as The EIA estimate of energy subsidies for
well as global warming costs. 1999 provides the foundations for much of
While it is certainly true that convention- this study’s analysis. Total energy subsidies in

10
1999 were somewhere between $8.6 billion 2. See, for instance, Brian Dunkiel, Gawain
Kripke, and Erich Pica, “Dirty Little Secrets: 1998
and $11.3 billion and included tax expendi- Update,” Friends of the Earth, Washington, 1998.
tures, direct expenditures, excise taxes, and
R&D expenditures. The oil industry received 3. Douglas Koplow and Aaron Martin, “Fueling
a subsidy of approximately $567 million, a Global Warming: Federal Subsidies to Oil in the
United States,” Greenpeace, Washington, June 1998.
tiny fraction of the total sum of energy sub-
sidy and a far smaller sum than other energy 4. Douglas L. Norland and Kim Ninassi, “Price It
industries received from the federal govern- Right: Energy Pricing and Fundamental Tax
ment. The largest share of subsidies supports Reform,” Alliance to Save Energy, Washington, 1998.
electricity-generating fuels and technologies. 5. Energy Information Administration, “Federal
Conventional estimates of subsidies, how- Energy Subsidies: Direct and Indirect Interven-
ever, use accounting or budget data that are tions in Energy Markets,” November 1992, p. ix.
seriously misleading. Subsidies are difficult
6. This study examines subsidies provided by the
to define because they have no unique char- federal government and considers some energy
acteristics that distinguish them from other subsidies provided by state and local govern-
energy policy actions. Furthermore, subsidies ments. It does not consider state utility regula-
are difficult to estimate and the beneficiaries tion, which is now widely recognized as causing
significant distortions in electricity and natural
are difficult to identify. Finally, subsidies do gas markets.
not necessarily distort markets in that they
do not necessarily affect consumer decision- 7. See Barry Brownstein, “The Price-Anderson Act: Is It
making or behavior. Consistent with a Sound Energy Policy?” Cato
Institute Policy Analysis no. 36, April 17, 1984. For a
A critical component of subsidy analysis is defense of the Price-Anderson Act from an efficiency
determining whether the government sub- perspective, see Benjamin Zycher, “Accounting for
sidy reduces a market failure or introduces a Costs and Cost Biases,” Letter to the editor, Regulation
government failure. Moreover, the apparent- 15, no. 2 (Spring 1992): 3–4.
ly simple task of estimating subsidies is not 8. Koplow and Martin, p. 1.1.
feasible without measuring the costs or ben-
efits of the subsidy in question. In the 9. Energy Information Administration, “Federal
absence of a cost/benefit analysis, we should Energy Subsidies: Direct and Indirect Interven-
tions in Energy Markets,” p. ix.
interpret accounting measures of subsidies
with caution. 10. Charles Wolf Jr., Markets or Governments:
Government subsidies to the oil industry Choosing between Imperfect Alternatives (Cambridge,
do not appear to produce significant distor- Mass.: MIT Press, 1991).
tions in energy markets.46 Oil subsidies pri- 11. That economic loss is the sum of producer
marily redistribute wealth and leave energy and consumer surplus and is referred to as a
markets relatively unaffected. Consequently, “deadweight loss.”
changes in oil prices and oil use reflect
12. The benefit to producers and consumers would
changes in underlying supply and demand equal their increment in producer and consumer
conditions, rather than government subsi- surplus, which can only be estimated if one knows
dies. Despite measurement problems, energy the appropriate supply and demand curves.
subsidies appear to be relatively small and
13. Energy Information Administration, “Federal
declining over time. Intervention and Subsidies in Energy Markets
1999: Energy Transformation and End Use,”
SR/OIAF/2000-02, May 2000, p. xi.
Notes 14. Ibid., p. 53.
1. Of course, eliminating inefficient subsidies is
preferable to adding an offsetting inefficient sub- 15. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Tax Policy:
sidy. Elimination removes a drain on the econo- Tax Expenditures Deserve More Scrutiny,”
my; offset adds another drain. GAO/GGD/AIMD-94-122, June 1994, p. 14.

11
16. Energy Information Administration, “Federal 24. Energy Information Administration, “Household
Intervention and Subsidies in Energy Markets Energy Consumption and Expenditure 1993,”
1999: Primary Energy,” Table 7, p. 16. Section 43 of DOE/EIA-0321(93), October 1995, p. 75.
the Internal Revenue Code provides taxpayers an
enhanced oil recovery (EOR) credit equal to 15 per- 25. Energy Information Administration, “Federal
cent of qualified EOR costs. This credit, however, is Energy Market Interventions 1999: Energy
phased out if oil prices rise above $28 a barrel in Transformation and End Use,” p. 49.
inflation-adjusted 1991 dollars. Ibid., p. 19.
26. Robert J. Shapiro, Cut-and-Invest: A Budget
17. U.S. General Accounting Office, p. 50. Strategy for the New Economy (Washington:
Progressive Policy Institute, March 1995), p. 19.
18. Ibid., p. 84.
27. Budget of the United States Government: Fiscal Year
19. Most of the important decisions about the 2001, Appendix (Washington: U.S. Government
LIHEAP’s implementation—the mix and dollar Printing Office, 2000), pp. 1187–88.
range of benefits and the manner in which bene-
fits will be provided—are left to the states. In gen- 28. Other energy trust fund programs include the
eral, program recipients must have incomes less Abandoned Mine Reclamation Program, the
than 150 percent of the poverty level for their Nuclear Waste Fund, the Uranium Enrichment
state or less than 60 percent of the state’s median Decontamination and Decommissioning
income. No household with income below 110 Program, the Leaking Underground Storage
percent of the poverty guidelines may be exclud- Program, the Pipeline Safety Fund, and various
ed. In addition, a “reasonable” amount of funds aquatic resource programs such as boat safety
must be set aside by the states for energy crisis programs, coastal wetland projects, and sport fish
intervention and up to 15 percent of the states’ restoration programs. Energy Information
allotments (up to 25 percent with a waiver) may Administration, “Federal Energy Market
be used for low-cost residential weatherization or Interventions 1999: Primary Energy,” p. 37.
other energy-related home repair. Energy Infor-
mation Administration, “Federal Energy Market 29. Ibid., p. 36.
Interventions 1999: Energy Transformation and
End Use,” pp. 9–10. 30. Energy Information Administration, “Federal
Energy Subsidies: Direct and Indirect Interven-
20. Most of the LIHEAP was directed toward tions in Energy Markets,” p. 7.
heating assistance, and EIA estimates that only 23
percent of the program’s recipients rely on home 31. Effective December 1, 1990, the federal gas tax
heating oil in the winter. Ibid., pp. 8–9. was increased from 9.1 cents per gallon to 14.1
cents, with 2.5 cents per gallon dedicated to gen-
21. In fiscal year 1996—the latest year for which eral revenue. The federal tax was increased to 18.4
data are available—the average annual LIHEAP cents per gallon on October 1, 1993, and 6.8 cents
benefit per recipient ranged from $54 to $403 for per gallon went to general revenue. Effective
heating assistance, from $77 to $623 for winter October 1, 1995, 2.5 cents of the 6.8 cents was
crisis aid, and from $15 to 146 for cooling assis- rededicated to the Highway Trust Fund, and
tance. The national average energy benefit for effective October 1, 1997, the remainder of the 4.3
households receiving heating or winter crisis cent per gallon tax on gasoline that had been
assistance, or both, is estimated to be $180. going to general revenues was rededicated to the
Energy Information Administration, “Federal Highway Trust Fund. Excise taxes of 4.3 cents per
Energy Market Interventions 1999: Energy gallon on rail diesel fuel and fuel used on inland
Transformation and End Use,” p. 9. According to waterways, as well as a 6.8 cents per gallon tax on
Leon Litow of the Division of Energy Assistance motorboat fuel, small engine gasoline, and special
of the U.S. Department of Health and Human fuels, however, continue to be deposited in the
Services, the subsidy covers an average of about 53 general fund. Energy Information Administra-
percent of the heating bills of the recipients. tion, “Federal Financial Interventions and
Personal correspondence. Subsidies in Energy Markets 1999: Primary
Energy,” p. 41.
22. Energy Information Administration, “Federal
Energy Subsidies: Direct and Indirect 32. Federal Highway Administration, “Highway
Intervention in Energy Markets,” p. ix. Statistics 1998,” FHWA-PL-99-017, November
1998, p. iv.9.
23. Energy Information Administration, “Federal
Energy Market Interventions 1999: Energy 33. Rayola Dougher, “The Funding of Roads in
Transformation and End Use,” p. 9. the United States: How the Taxes and Fees

12
Collected from Motorists Are Spent,” Research 43. For a review of EPA’s policies addressing vehic-
Study no. 088, American Petroleum Institute, ular pollution, see Arnold Howitt and Alan
Washington, March 1997. Altshuler, “The Politics of Controlling Auto Air
Pollution,” in Essays in Transportation Economics and
34. Jerry Taylor, Testimony at Hearing on Fiscal Policy, ed. Jose Gomez-Ibanez, William Tye, and
Year 1998 Budget Authorization for Department Clifford Winston (Washington: Brookings
of Energy, Environmental Protection Agency, and Institution, 1999), pp. 223–55.
National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administra-
tion before the Subcommittee on Energy and 44. W. Kipp Viscusi et al., “Environmentally
Environment of the Joint Committee on Science, Responsible Energy Pricing,” Energy Journal 15,
105th Cong., 1st sess., April 9, 1997; and Ronald no. 2 (1994): 23–42. The authors ignored the
Sutherland, “Federal Energy R&D Expenditures: potential costs of greenhouse gas emissions, how-
A Case of Misplaced Incentives,” Cato Institute ever, given the uncertainty surrounding those cal-
Policy Analysis, forthcoming. culations.

35. Data obtained from Robert Bradley, 45. A potential weakness of the analysis, however, is
“Renewable Energy: Not Cheap, Not ‘Green,’” the fact that gasoline taxes are currently thought of
Cato Institute Policy Analysis no. 280, August 27, as user fees for highway construction and mainte-
1997, p. 63. Original source: U.S. Department of nance. In a sense, then, gasoline taxes are already
Energy, Office of Chief Financial Officer. dedicated to the internalization of a different set of
externalities, the cost of the public provision of high-
36. Energy Information Administration, “Federal ways. Yet transportation economists believe that
Energy Subsidies,” pp. 153, 154. automobile drivers are massively cross-subsidizing
the trucking industry through the gasoline tax.
37. Energy Information Administration, “Annual Most highway construction and maintenance costs
Energy Outlook 1997,” DOE/EIA-0383(97), are necessitated by the demand for—and damage
December 1996, p. 108. done to—interstate highways by the trucking indus-
try. An efficient gasoline tax, these economists
38. Peter VanDoren, Politics, Markets, and believe, would be borne entirely by the trucking
Congressional Policy Choices (Ann Arbor: University industry (fuel taxes would be imposed only on diesel
of Michigan Press, 1991), pp. 59–63. fuel). Automobile drivers would “free ride” on the
diesel tax except where congestion-based pricing was
39. J. B. Wahl, “Oil Slickers: How Petroleum necessary to ration access. Thus, we can still con-
Benefits at the Taxpayers’ Expense,” Institute for clude that gasoline taxes at present internalize driv-
Local Self Reliance, Washington, 1996. ing externalities for auto mobiles, at least at the
macro level. See Kenneth Small, Clifford Winston,
40. Koplow and Martin. and Carol Evans, Road Work: A New Highway Pricing
and Investment Policy (Washington: Brookings
41. Council of Economic Advisers, Economic Institution, 1989).
Report of the President, 1999 (Washington:
Government Printing Office, 1999), p. 421. 46. This conclusion is not meant to suggest that
oil subsidies are efficiency enhancing. It is simply
42. Congressional Research Service, “The External intended to establish that critics of the oil indus-
Costs of Oil Used in Transportation,” CRS Report try have exaggerated the benefits received by the
for Congress 92-574ENR, June 17, 1992. industry.

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000
Massachusetts Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern
time), fax (202) 842-3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

13

S-ar putea să vă placă și