Sunteți pe pagina 1din 18

1 Introduction

1. The autumn of 2008


In mid-July 2007 the global credit markets came to a standstill. On the face of it, the continuous decline in the US housing market and the overexpansion of US and European banks in the US market for sub-prime mortgages led them to accumulate serious and mostly hidden losses. Mounting losses gave rise to a crisis of confidence where no bank would lend money to any other regardless of its credit standing. At the same time, the flows of capital to the global market for structured credit products all but disappeared. Gradually, the liquidity problems encountered by US and European banks were transformed into solvency problems due to their high leverage and low capitalization escalating the confidence crisis. In the process, bank problems became so deep as to develop into a full-blown financial crisis, the worst the world had seen since 1929. Although an event of unprecedented severity, the Global Financial Crisis(GFC) had rather humble beginnings. The first ominous episode was the collapse of a medium-size mortgage provider in the UK, Northern Rock.1 It was followed by the collapse of the fifth biggest US investment bank, Bear Stearns, in March 2008, which became the subject of a quasicompulsory takeover by JP Morgan. However, while the clouds of the unprecedented storm were gathering, most bankers and policy-makers still believed that the crisis would be contained. Then in the space of few weeks from early September (when the collapse of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac was followed by Lehman Brothers failure) to early October 2008, the global financial system teetered on the brink of collapse on a daily basis.2 It was rescued at a huge cost to US and European taxpayers and
The Run on the Rock, (House of Commons, Treasury Committee, Fifth Report of Session 200708, 24 January 2008). 2 I provide a concise overview of the events of autumn 2008 in Chapter 2, Section 6.2. For an authoritative timeline of the events leading to the GFC and its aftermath from the eruption of the sub-prime mortgage crisis in March 2007, see Council of Foreign Relations,
1

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 1

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2060564

2/28/2012 6:32:00 PM

Introduction

bail-outs gave rise to a heated debate in most parts of the world, although, in the conditions prevailing at the time, they seemed the only sensible option available. The bail-outs of the autumn of 2008 were followed by a global economic recession that was felt mostly in the developed world.

2. Why the GFC was not prevented?


The GFC was not the first truly global financial crisis, that dubious honour belongs to the 1929 crisis, and it is not going to be the last, but it was the biggest to date. The questions raised by the GFC permeated all levels and spheres of the global policy debate, touching on the politics, economics and legal/regulatory infrastructure underpinning global finance. Arguably, some of these questions have already been settled. One example is the set of new regulations and market infrastructures that are currently being introduced to deal with Over the Counter (OTC) derivatives trading and the risks associated with it. Other important questions, such as the issue of how to tackle best the too-big-to-fail institution and moral hazard attached to its operation, are still being debated. The body of so-called soft law rules or standards comprising international financial regulation and the structures of the international financial architecture, mostly comprising Transnational Regulatory Networks (TRNs), clearly failed to predict or prevent the crisis. The reasons for this failure vary but two things are clear about pre-GFC international regulatory arrangements: their over-reliance on private sector input and lack of even a rudimentary institutional infrastructure to handle cross-border crises were contributing factors both in building up the conditions that led to the GFC and in exacerbating its consequences. But these observations do not tell the full story. In the two decades preceding the GFC, a host of deregulation and other market-oriented policies, including monetary policies, inspired by the then unstoppable neo-liberal consensus, were pursued in an environment of relentless market innovation and technological advancement. The combination of these factors led to a gigantic expansion of global markets, a number of which most critically the OTC derivatives market and
Timeline: Global Economy in Crisis, available at www.cfr.org/economics/timelineg lobal-economy-crisis/p18709. See also Mauro F. Guilln, The Global Economic & Financial Crisis:A Timeline, The Lauder Institute, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, available at lauder.wharton.upenn.edu/pages/pdf/Chronology_Economic_ Financial_Crisis.pdf. See also Hank Paulson, On the Brink (New York: Hachette Books, 2010).

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 2

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2060564

2/28/2012 6:32:01 PM

Introduction

the shadow banking sector were not subject to any kind of regulatory oversight. It is not surprising that, when malevolent forces in the formal banking sector, namely, excessive credit expansion to unsuitable borrowers, combined with unregulated market activities that concealed excessive leverage in the shadow banking sector and with interconnectedness, arising from largely opaque transactions in the OTC derivatives markets, the wave of destruction became unstoppable. This combination was also largely responsible for the severity of the crisis. Although regulatory inertia was to a large extent influenced by the neoliberal consensus and, to a certain extent, by capture, this is in many ways a very crude explanation of market and regulatory myopia. Therefore, not in order to discard those interpretations but rather to overhaul and shed light on them, it is worth re-examining the main forces that, alongside trade liberalization, shaped the development of global financial markets more than any other: the financial revolution. This is defined here as the sum of three contemporary developments: open markets due to liberal ization; technological advancements in communications and computing power; and financial innovation. The concurrent emergence of these three seemingly independent developments radically transformed the global marketplace and sealed its fate. The utilization of the three elements of the financial revolution not only generated mega-profits but also colossal amounts of well concealed tiny risks that, if combined with other risks of equally low probability, could bring financial devastation. I provide an analytical examination of the causes of the GFC in Chapter 3. Even a first reading of the empirical and theoretical studies discussed in Chapter 3 show that the unpredictable combination of all those low probability risks was made possible because of financial innovation and the existence of fast moving and open global markets. I argue in this book that, while a small number of insiders had a fairly good understanding of financial innovation and its possible interaction with the other forces of financial revolution and time-old (and little explained) characteristics of financial markets, such as herding, in most cases policymakers, regulators and even senior bankers preferred to live in a state of blissful ignorance. They did so either because the new developments exceeded their cognitive capacities or because they preferred to take the easy route of merely watching rising market prices and widespread euphoria and not delving deeper, trying to understand what was truly pushing the unprecedented price rises in most global asset markets. Misunderstanding a major knowledge revolution, as recent financial innovations should be held to be, is nothing new. Not only do communities

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 3

2/28/2012 6:32:01 PM

Introduction

of experts tend to be confused as to the actual epistemological properties of new knowledge/technology, but economists have also traditionally under-estimated its value.3 Therefore, the possibility of financial innov ation (perceived here as a knowledge revolution) being used as a benevolent force to achieve global welfare objectives should not be discarded. On the contrary, proper research/knowledge structures with a global reach should be built to help policy-makers and possibly the markets to gain a better understanding of the properties (and risks) of financial innovation4 and of the financial revolution in general in order to manage them in a way that would not endanger financial stability and would even facilitate the achievement of other global welfare objectives.

3. Why is finance so important? 3.1 Overview


The financial system provides a large number of critical functions (analytically discussed in Chapter 2) which are inextricably linked with the welfare of modern economies and day-to-day life. To mention but a few, financial markets allow private and public actors to fund their consumption and investment needs by means of bank loans or finance provided by the capital markets, a mechanism that would not have been so readily available in the absence of well functioning markets. The reason is that the financial system provides investors, through market prices, with a reliable criterion of value. The interplay of supply and demand allows price formation (discovery) through the filtering out of traders heterogeneous expectations as well as the dissemination of privately held market information. In principle, financial markets, through the provision of a price discovery mechanism, facilitate the efficient allocation of scarce resources, using savers, and investors funds most efficiently. The financial system protects, through the use of futures markets, producers and consumers of physical commodities and traders and users of financial assets from adverse price movements. In addition, there is a very strong (mutual causation) link between financial system development
See for an overview of relevant studies and explanations, Yong J. Yoon, Science, Scientific Institutions, and Economic Progress, George Mason University Working Paper in Economics No. 1036, 3 November 2010, available at papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers. cfm?abstract_id=1702675. 4 Cf. John Gerard Ruggie, International Responses to Technology: Concepts and Trends (1975) 29 International Organization 557.
3

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 4

2/28/2012 6:32:01 PM

Introduction

and economic growth (and possibly poverty eradication), an aspect of financial markets that is extensively discussed in Chapter 2. The principal financial institutions that tend to have a cross-border presence are: (1) commercial banks; (2) investment banks; (3) savings banks and credit unions, also called thrift institutions; (4) insurance companies; (5) private pension funds; (6) specialized finance companies which deal either with consumer or commercial loans; and (7) investment funds, including mutual funds, money market funds, hedge funds and sovereign wealth funds, which mainly invest their governments d isposable wealth accumulated through trade surpluses. All financial institutions perform some of the functions listed above, but only commercial banks perform all of them. The traditional banking system has three actors: savers, borrowers and banks and provides credit intermediation through the recycling of savers deposits into loans. Credit intermediation involves credit, maturity and liquidity transformation, since it generally uses highly liquid shortterm deposits to provide, in principle, illiquid long term loans. More specifically, in a modern economy, banks provide three critical services that foster economic development: (1) they ameliorate the information problems between fund providers, such as depositors and investors, and borrowers or securities issuers by monitoring the latter and ensuring a proper use of the providers funds; (2) they provide inter-temporal smoothing of risk that cannot be diversified at a given point in time as well as insurance to depositors against unexpected consumption shocks; and (3) they provide payments infrastructure.5 For these reasons the sound and safe operation of banks is of strategic importance not only in fostering economic development but also in ensuring social and economic stability. If savers are confident about the safety and sound operation of the formal banking sector, they will avoid channelling their savings to the informal banking sector, which is highly inefficient and is sometimes operated by criminal syndicates. Accordingly, the sound and safe operation of a competitive banking system ensures interested firms can access bank finance at reasonable market-based interest rates, allowing them to implement investment plans that are dependent on such financing and avoid over-borrowing.
5

Franklin Allen and Elena Carletti, The Role of Banks in Financial Systems, March 2008, available at fic.wharton.upenn.edu/fic/papers/08/0819.pdf.

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 5

2/28/2012 6:32:01 PM

Introduction

Similar principles relate to the workings of capital markets, where investor confidence in the operation of the price formation mechanism is paramount to the proper allocation of resources performed by those markets. Investor confidence boosts liquidity, one of the main ingredients of capital markets, but it is normally withdrawn when markets malfunction or are ridden with abuse, whether in the form of fraud, insider dealing or market manipulation.

3.2 Should finance be regulated?


Arguably, the most important and sensitive function of financial markets is efficient allocation of resources. Yet this is a fragile mechanism and may easily be disturbed by exogenous and endogenous shocks/distortions or may not perform properly due to market failures. In addition, because of maturity mismatches between their assets and liabilities, and the risk of contagion due to information asymmetries, banks are vulnerable to runs and represent a serious source of systemic risk. Hence the need for extensive regulations which broadly intend to:6 (1) preserve the confidence of the providers of finance (whether this means depositors and other creditors or investors) and of consumers of financial services in the function, processes and efficient outcomes of financial markets; (2) remedy market failures (e.g., disclosure and market integrity regulations); and (3) protect the financial system from unforeseen but likely shocks such as bank runs (e.g., deposit insurance and capital adequacy regulations). It follows that one of the main justifications of financial regulation is that the multitude of externalities and failures finance providers and users encounter have such a large impact on the real economy that financial sector institutions should be tightly regulated to make them more resilient and their liquidity has to be subsidized through central bank support. Securing the sound, safe and efficient operation of the banking system is no easy business. In fact it may be impossible to totally eliminate financial crises and bank failures, although financial systems have over the years
6

See Charles Goodhart, Philipp Hartmann, David T. Llewellyn, Liliana Rojas-Suarez and Steven Weisbrod, Financial Regulation, Why, How, and Where Now? (London: Routledge, 1998); Ross Cranston, Principles of Banking Law (Oxford University Press, 2nd edn, 2002), Chapter 3; Emilios Avgouleas, The Mechanics and Regulation of Market Abuse A Legal and Economic Analysis (Oxford University Press, 2005), Chapter 5.

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 6

2/28/2012 6:32:02 PM

Introduction

been increasingly subject to strict government regulations attempting to prevent bank collapses, which may trigger contagion through generalized lack of confidence. Any given body of rules that is trying to create and preserve a sound and safe banking system must address four concerns: (1) ensure the efficient and effective operation of banks, since due to the principal/agent problem savers do not know the true quality of the management that operates the bank with which they have trusted their savings; (2) ensure that banks have adequate financial resources either to avoid a failure or to compensate their depositors and other creditors properly; (3) devise a public system of regulations and supervisory techniques which ensure that, in the event of a bank failure, any depositors run is effectively averted/contained and does not lead to a systemic crisis and the collapse of the banking system due to contagion; and (4) ensure that the financial system is not used to facilitate criminal activities and, especially, to legalize the proceeds of crime (money laundering). While national public authorities might find it easy to build regulatory systems that try to achieve these goals and end up pursuing them with moderate success, they are bound to find it impossible to deal with crossborder contagion and loss of confidence stemming from it in an era of global markets. As a result, a number of formal and informal international bodies, such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the European Union (EU), the Group of 20 most developed countrie(G-20), and the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), and a number of other Transnational Regulatory Networks (TRNs) have produced multiple sets of financial standards and regulations that intend to secure the sound and safe operation of international banks and other parts of global financial mar kets.7 Where the sources of these rules are TRNs, they normally become binding either through national implementation or EU legislation. During the 1990s, as finance became increasingly global, so did financial crises. Following the Mexican and Asian financial crises, a set of new arrangements was put in place to meet the needs of global finance, the New International Financial Architecture (NIFA). In essence, these reforms amounted to little more than establishing another TRN, the
7

See, for more extensive analysis, Chapter 4 of this book and Rosa Lastra, Legal Foundations of International Monetary Stability (Oxford University Press, 2006), Part III.

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 7

2/28/2012 6:32:02 PM

Introduction

Financial Stability Forum (FSF), to co-ordinate the disparate soft law networks. At the same time, a system of voluntary monitoring through the Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP)8 meant that, for the first time, international standard setting would be supported by a rudimentary review process. Yet NIFA structures proved entirely unsuitable to regulate properly the financial revolution and address the challenges this created. In fact, Basel capital standards, which were one of the central parts of NIFA, proved to be terribly flawed. They were very pro-cyclical and fostered regulatory arbitrage that allowed regulated banks to resort to highly leveraged shadow banking activities, which proved a very significant and well concealed source of systemic risk. Indeed, the total absence of any kind of institutional capacity in the field of crisis management and bank cross-border resolution meant that NIFA soft law structures were rendered irrelevant during the GFC.9 In the middle of the current crisis, two significant changes have taken place in the edifice of the international financial architecture. The first has been the emergence of the G-20 heads of state level as the predominant body for the co-ordination of international policy responses to the GFC and the second the reconstitution of the FSF that was renamed as the Financial Stability Board (FSB).10 The FSB is increasingly taking a leadership role in international micro-prudential supervision matters.

4. The post-2008 reforms


It is not surprising that the GFC triggered a frenetic period of reform in an attempt to mend the broken arms of domestic and global finance and restore its functions. In the UK, the FSA will be abolished to be replaced by two new regulators, one responsible for prudential supervision (Prudential Regulation Authority) and one for investor protection and market conduct (Financial Conduct Authority). There will also be a new Financial Policy Committee in the Bank of England, which will be the macro-prudential supervisor having primary responsibility for maintaining financial stability.11
See IMF, Factsheet- The Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP), 23 March 2011, available at www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/fsap.htm. 9 See Chapters 3 and 5 below. 10 See also Joseph J. Norton, NIFA-II or Bretton Woods- II?: The G-20 (Leaders) Summit Process on Managing Global Financial Markets and The World Economy Quo Vadis?, (2010) 11 Journal of Banking Regulation 261301. 11 The UK Treasury intends thus to adopt a twin peaks plus approach to financial supervision. See HM Treasury, A New Approach to Financial Regulation: The Blue Print for Reform (Cm 8083, July 2011).
8

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 8

2/28/2012 6:32:02 PM

Introduction

Switzerland, which is not an EU member but came close to a systemic crisis due to the problems experienced by its two biggest banks (UBS and Credit Suisse), also restructured its system of financial supervision moving in a direction opposite to that in which the UK Treasury intends to move. Since January 2009 a single authority, the Financial Markets Authority (FINMA), has held responsibility for both prudential and investor/consumer protection regulation, succeeding the Swiss Federal Banking Commission and other sectoral regulators. The Swiss National Bank has retained responsibility for the stability of the financial system.12 In the US and the EU, legislators have brought about sweeping changes as regards the regulation, supervision and resolution of large banks and other Systemically Important Financial Institutions (SIFIs), OTC derivatives trading and ratings production by the credit rating agencies (CRAs). In addition, the BCBS has produced a radically upgraded capital framework for banks. After a period of gestation and amid mutual recriminations between Democrats and Republicans as to who is to blame for the collapse of Wall Street, the US Senate approved the massive DoddFrank Act in July 2010. The Act brings about significant reforms (analytically discussed in Chapters 6 and 7) as regards the structure of systemic risk supervision in the US, with the establishment of the Financial System Oversight Council (FSOC) and expansion of the Federal Reserve Boards (FRBs) supervisory remit to insurance companies and other non-bank financial institutions that, in the opinion of the new macroprudential supervisor, are systemically important. It also regulates the activities of commercial banks and introduces a strict regime for the standardization of OTC derivatives and centralization of trading and settlement of trades. Another very important reform DoddFrank has introduced is the establishment of a new special resolution regime (the Orderly Liquidation Authority or OLA) for SIFIs, whether banks or non-bank financial institutions. These will have to go through compulsory liquidation if they enter the scheme. The pace of reform has been relentless in the EU as well and at least as wide ranging as in the US. The EUs reliance on a supervisory model that was centred on national supervisors proved to be very ineffective. Three major problems were identified. First, there was a marked lack of any framework for the monitoring of systemic risk on a pan-European basis. Second, home country control proved problematic and exposed
12

See Swiss Financial Market Supervisory Authority Act (FINMASA) (effective 1 January 2009).

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 9

2/28/2012 6:32:02 PM

10

Introduction

the gaps in cross-border supervision of banking groups. Third, the u nco-ordinated bank rescues highlighted the lack of pan-European structures for cross-border crisis management. Since these gaps in financial supervision called for a radical rethinking of regulatory structures in the EU, the Commission mandated a High-Level Group chaired by Jacques de Larosire to make recommendations on how to strengthen European supervisory arrangements and improve investor/consumer/ depositor/taxpayer protection. The High-Level Group, in its final report of 25 February 2009 (the de Larosire Report),13 suggested reforms to the structure of financial supervision in the EU and consistent implementation of harmonized rules. Thus, the structure and processes of financial regulation in the EU have undergone very significant transformation, as a result of which: (1) the newly established European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) has become the European macro-prudential supervisor, although it has no formal standing in EU law; (2) the principles of minimum harmonization and mutual recognition have largely disappeared, since the standard setting competence of the new European Supervisory Authorities (ESAs) makes them the central pillars and channels of maximum harmonization; and (3) certain aspects of the supervision of cross-border groups have (implicitly) shifted from home country control to transnational supervisory structures comprising, essentially, supervisory colleges14 and the new ESAs. In addition, the EU has proposed or enacted legislation to bring credit r ating agencies under the direct supervision of the new European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA), to regulate hedge fund managers and to encourage OTC derivatives standardization and centralization of clearing and settlement.
The de Larosire Report is available at ec.europa.eu/internal_market/finances/docs/ de_larosiere_report_en.pdf. 14 Directive 2009/111/EC of 16 September 2009 amending Directives 2006/48/EC, 2006/49/ EC and 2007/64/EC as regards banks affiliated to central institutions, certain own funds items, large exposures, supervisory arrangements, and crisis management OJ L 302/97 17 November 2009. This Directive maintains that the supervisory powers of national competent authorities are not diluted, Recital 6. However, given the powers of Colleges and of the ESAs, and the authority Colleges may establish over systemically important branches, this claim looks maximalist. See new Art. 42a of Directive 2006/48/EC inserted by means of Art. 1 of Directive 2009/111/EC.
13

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 10

2/28/2012 6:32:02 PM

Introduction

11

International regulators have also been very active. The BCBS has radically redesigned its capital adequacy standards and has introduced a new supervisory framework to regulate bank capital. It has also designed liquidity and leverage ratios, as well as macro-prudential measures to complement the capital ratio, together called the Basel III framework.15 In addition, BCBS has issued standards to improve risk management and governance in the banking sector. The main objective of the new capital measures introduced by Basel III is to resolve the chronic problem of bank undercapitalization, a widespread phenomenon during the current crisis, which led to a massive number of bailouts. Basel III aims to ensure that banks are able to withstand the type of stress experienced during the GFC, including banks exposure to the economic cycle, bubbles and other macro-economic developments. The preceding Basel framework was exclusively reliant on micro-prudential regulation measures. Basel III introduces higher levels of capital for banks. As a result, the minimum requirement for common equity, which is regarded as the best form of loss absorbing capital, will be raised from the 2 per cent level of the previous Basel Accords, before the application of regulatory adjustments, to 4.5 per cent of risk-weighted assets (RWAs). To this shall be added a capital conservation buffer of up to 2.5 per cent of RWAs, which will bring the total minimum of common equity in bank capital to 7 per cent of RWAs by 2019 when all reforms will have been implemented. Furthermore, Basel III gives supervisors the discretion to require additional capital buffers during periods of excess credit growth in order to contain asset bubbles, the so-called counter-cyclical buffer, and introduces comprehensive leverage and liquidity ratios that would lead to more resilient banks. Finally, in an attempt to tackle more effectively moral hazard emanating from public bail-outs of too-big-to-fail institutions, a number of proposals have been set out, chiefly by the IMF and the BCBS, regarding the proper approach to cross-border resolution of financial institutions. The EU has released for consultation its own plans on the same matter (analytically discussed in Chapter 7), which include a pan-European crisis management and cross-border resolution regime.

15

BCBS, Basel III: A Global Regulatory Framework for more Resilient Banks and Banking Systems, December 2010.

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 11

2/28/2012 6:32:02 PM

12

Introduction

5. Whither governance of global financial markets? 5.1 The books subject matter
This book examines the global structures governing international finance in the period from 1944 to 2008 and the substantive and structural reforms that have been proposed or implemented after 2009. The view adopted is that the specific elements underpinning global markets governance comprise, inter alia: (1) national/regional regulations with a cross-border or extra-territorial policy impact or compliance/enforcement dimension, like US and EU financial markets legislation (with the EU being a supra-national structure/organization per se); (2) International agreements and institutions established under such agreements, such as the IMF or the new (ESAs); (3) soft law arrangements in the form of international regulatory standards and TRNs, such as BCBS, responsible for global regulatory co-operation and production of standards; and (4) private sector organizations, such as the Group of Thirty or the International Swaps and Derivatives Association (ISDA) that either provide policy input on matters pertinent to the regulation of global markets or the legal infrastructure on which global market participants conclude their transactions. Accordingly the arrangements governing international finance involve a constellation of public and private actors and national, European, international and soft law rules and institutions all play an important role. It follows that the only way to provide a credible discussion of these arrangements is by adopting a multidisciplinary approach and to integrate into this study, depending on context, the methodologies, findings, ideas and perspectives of at least three distinct disciplines: legal analysis, economic analysis and international relations theory. Insights of regulatory theory and institutional economics, finance theory and behavioural economics are also utilized in the course of this study but these should be seen as sub-divisions of the three major disciplines mentioned above.

5.2 Towards a new governance model


There has never been a better time to discuss the possibility of a supranational governance system for global financial markets without fearing

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 12

2/28/2012 6:32:03 PM

Introduction

13

scornful rejection of such an impractical adacemic exercise. The reason for this assertion is that the problems that the current system presents are very conspicuous and threatening to ignore. Chapters 6 and 7 engage in an in-depth analysis of the reforms that are currently under way. These reforms are, in most cases, a significant step in the right direction. Yet the lack of any governance structures to support them will probably mean that their effective implementation will be undermined. Furthermore, existing reforms, whether already implemented or just at the planning stage, do little to address a host of issues that have also been at the heart of the current crisis and greatly contributed to its severity. First, current reforms do not secure effective cross-border supervision of SIFIs or even more importantly of the new super class of financial institutions, operating in a multitude of jurisdictions and markets, called Globally Systemically Important Financial Institutions (G-SIFIs).16 Second, current proposals for effective cross-border crisis management and orderly resolution/insolvency of international financial institutions, and especially financial groups, remain very unconvincing in the absence of fiscal sharing arrangements and arguably of a supra-national authority charged with this task. Third, the newly established systemic risk supervisors in the US and the EU will still be faced with blind spots when it comes to shadow banking activity. This is a major shortcoming, since the volume of transactions taking place in the global shadow banking sector is worth several trillions of dollars more than those taking place in the formal banking sector. Fourth, it is very likely that the design of flawed regulatory standards and regulators wrongful approach to bank supervision might have been caused by inadequate knowledge of the ramifications of the financial revolution and especially financial innovation. It is paradoxical that the current soft law structures retain their overreliance on private sector input for their information/education. As explained in Chapter 3, private sector input can often be unreliable for reasons that go beyond the apparent conflict of interests and have to do with inability of private actors to observe the whole picture and lack of incentives to acquire more knowledge than is necessary for them to carry
16

The FSB defines G-SIFIs as institutions of such size, market importance, and global interconnectedness that their distress or failure would cause significant dislocation in the global financial system and adverse economic consequences across a range of countries. Standards for large global financial firms should be commensurate with the system-wide expected losses that their failure would produce. See FSB, Reducing the Moral Hazard Posed by Systemically Important Financial Institutions FSB Recommendations and Time Lines, 20 October 2010.

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 13

2/28/2012 6:32:03 PM

14

Introduction

out their business. In addition, private actors understanding of emerging market risks and above all of their correlations with other market phenomena, such as herding, irrational exuberance and widespread loss-aversion or panic (all discussed extensively in Chapter 2 below) might be as low as that of public actors. Finally, the new structures continue to ignore the very big importance to the global development objective of the close causal link between availability of finance and economic growth, well enshrined in the United Nations Millennium Development Goals.17 Therefore, there is an urgent need for a new governance paradigm for global financial markets.18 This new paradigm should incorporate rather than demolish the effective parts of the current soft law arrangements and especially the rule-making functions of the TRNs and credible private sector input/ co-operation.19 On the other hand, the new governance regime for global markets and institutions should be based on a formal, hierarchical and multilayered20 architecture and have at its centre formal international law bodies. I provide in Chapter 8 a proposal for a new governance system for global financial markets that has strong evolutionary characteristics and is based on four regulatory pillars: (1) a global systemic risk/ macro-prudential supervisor, a role that should be discharged by the IMF; (2) a micro-prudential supervisor for G-SIFIs with a strong cross-border asset or liabilities base, a role that should be discharged by a reconstituted FSB; (3) a regulatory policy and risk knowledge management body overseeing the TRNs, a role that may be discharged by the OECD and the research department of the Bank for International Settlements; and (4) a global resolution authority, which would be exclusively concerned with the resolution of big cross-border institutions or groups.
The MDGs seek to, inter alia: (1) reduce extreme poverty and hunger by 2015; (2) achieve universal primary education by 2015; (3) reduce by two thirds, between 1990 and 2015, the under-five mortality rate; (4) ensure a sustainable environment, etc. In addition the MDGs call for the creation of a global partnership for development. See UN Human Development Report 2003, Millennium Development Goals: A Compact among Nations to End Human Poverty, UN Development Programme, 2003. 18 On this imperative see David Held, Cosmopolitanism: Ideas and Realities (Cambridge: Polity Press, 2010), Chapter 6. 19 Douglas W. Arner and Ross P. Buckley, Redesigning the Architecture of the International Economic System (2010) 11 Melbourne Journal of International Law 185239. 20 See Thomas Cottier, Multilayered Governance, Pluralism, and Moral Conflict, (2009) 16 Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies 64779.
17

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 14

2/28/2012 6:32:03 PM

Introduction

15

Moreover, it is suggested that a new system of governance for global financial markets should identify a core of shared values in the form of general principles and sub-principles underpinning the operation of the system.21 The most important (and unassailable) of the principles underpinning the proposed governance system ought to be financial stability.22 Yet there should be room for global regulators to facilitate the development agenda, without compromising systemic stability. It is anticipated that, if the insights of new institutional economics hold true,23 a governance model like the one proposed here will provide global finance operators with welfare enhancing norms of behaviour, even in the absence of any threat of enforcement.

6. Book structure
This book is a multidisciplinary work. Thus, it has been structured so it facilitates reader understanding of different concepts and developments and also gradually builds its argument on solid foundations. In this respect the book is divided in three parts.

Rolf H. Weber, Multilayered Governance in International Financial Regulation and Supervision (2010) 13 Journal of International Economic Law 683704, 68990. 22 The terms financial stability and systemic stability are used interchangeably in this book. They are both rather imprecise terms and in most cases defined by reference to what happens in their absence. A formal but not all encompassing definition has been offered by the EU Regulation establishing the European Systemic Risk Board, which defines systemic risk as: [the] risk of disruption in the financial system with the potential to have serious negative consequences for the internal market and the real economy. All types of financial intermediaries, markets and infrastructure may be potentially systemically important to some degree, EU Regulation 1092/2010 on European Union macro-prudential oversight of the financial system and establishing a European Systemic Risk Board, OJ L 331/11, 15 December 2010, Art. 2(c). An earlier working definition was offered by Garry Schinasi, who defined financial stability as the ability of the financial system to facilitate and enhance economic processes, manage risks and absorb shocks. See Garry J. Schinasi, Defining Financial Stability, IMF Working Paper No. 04/187, October 2004, available at papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=879012. For an analytical account see Garry J. Schinasi, Safeguarding Financial Stability Theory and Practice (Washington, DC: IMF, 2005), pp. 77134. For attempts to quantify (model) the different properties of financial stability see C. Goodhart and D. Tsomocos, Analysis of Financial Stability, Special Paper 173, Financial Markets Group, London School of Economics, 2007; O. Aspachs, C. Goodhart, M. Segoviano, D. Tsomocos and L. Zicchino, Searching for a Metric for Financial Stability, Special Paper 167, Financial Markets Group, London School of Economics, 2006. 23 See, in general, Douglass North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, (Cambridge University Press, 1990).
21

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 15

2/28/2012 6:32:03 PM

16

Introduction

Part I deals with financial markets and financial crises and comprises Chapters 2 and 3. Chapter 2 examines the modern development of global financial markets with particular focus on those that were the product of financial innovation, namely OTC derivatives markets and the shadow banking sector. The chapter is in seven sections. It first explains the economic functions of financial markets and their role in economic development. Then it provides an analysis of the most innovative segments of contemporary financial markets. It proceeds with a critical review of efficient market hypothesis and behavioural finance as the main tools of analysis of market behaviour and asset bubbles. As the analysis of global markets would be incomplete without discussion of policies that stimulated their growth, the chapter also introduces the neo-liberal consensus policies that fostered the continuous expansion of global financial markets and unfettered use of financial innovation. Finally, it offers an analytical discussion of the most common causes of financial crises and examines Hyman Minskys hypothesis that financial markets are inherently unstable. In this context, it provides concise accounts of the Asian Crisis and of the GFC. Chapter 3 discusses the causes of the Global Financial Crisis and is in six sections. It first considers the macro-causes of the GFC in accordance with the conventional explanations that have already been offered by academics and policy-makers. It provides an extensive analysis of neoliberal policies such as deregulation and the Jackson Hole Consensus and considers the impact of the latter on asset bubble formation. It also examines the public housing policies that seem to have contributed to the build up of the GFC. Then, it surveys the micro-causes and sheds light on the issue of misaligned incentives in a variety of contexts ranging from corporate governance and executive compensation to the operation of the originate-to-distribute model. It also considers the flawed regulations that contributed to the GFC. Consequently, it proceeds with a novel look at both the development of global financial markets and the recent crisis. In this context, it suggests that the GFC was above all the result of a little understood financial revolution that was badly mis-managed, due to insider rent-seeking and widespread moral hazard. Part II is dedicated to a discussion of pre-existing governance structures for global finance (19462008) and an evaluation of the soft law aspects of those structures (Chapters 4 and 5). Chapter 4 discusses the evolution of global financial governance and international financial regulation. It first provides an account of early age global governance structures and maps the path that led to the emergence of the BCBS and of the

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 16

2/28/2012 6:32:03 PM

Introduction

17

other major TRNs in the sphere of international finance. It also explains the path of trade liberalization and the rise of multilateral development institutions during the same period. It then proceeds to give an analysis of the NIFA and a critical overview of the emerging international finance architecture in the post-GFC period and the role of the G-20 in global regulatory reform and international finance governance. Chapter 5 provides a critical evaluation of the soft law structures in international financial regulation and highlights the existing supervisory and crisis management deficit in global financial markets. The chapter discusses TRN theory and its importance in international relations. It charts the methods used by TRNs to achieve co-operation in the absence of a binding international treaty. It then proceeds to explain the limits of TRN theory in the sphere of international finance and the failure of the Basel capital framework. It finally provides an exposition of the shortcomings of existing soft law structures, especially when it comes to crossborder crisis management and resolution. Part III examines the most important structural and substantive regulatory reforms of the post-GFC period, regardless of whether they have already been endorsed and implemented, or they are still at the planning and consultation stage. It also outlines a proposal for a new governance system for global financial markets as an answer to the problems identified in this study. It comprises Chapters 6, 7, and 8. Chapter 6 is in four sections. It provides a critical and in-depth analysis of the most important of the current EU and US reforms, especially as regards the regulation of systemic risk, OTC derivatives and CRAs. It also gives an analytical account of structural reforms in these jurisdictions and of the powers and tasks of the ESRB and of the European Supervisory Authorities. It then proceeds to offer an in-depth view of the Basel III framework. Chapter 7 provides an analysis of current reform proposals pertaining to the supervision of and capital requirements planned to be imposed on too-big-to-fail institutions and the emerging resolution regimes in the US and the EU. It first provides an analysis of the emerging consensus for the regulation and supervision of SIFIs expressed through the recommendations of the FSB. It then discusses the size limitations the US DoddFrank Act has placed on SIFIs through the Volcker Rule and other provisions and the structural restrictions that the UK authorities are considering imposing on large banks. It proceeds with an in-depth analysis of FSB/BCBS approach to regulating the risk of G-SIFIs through capital surcharges. It also considers the costs and benefits of contingent capital instruments. Consequently, it offers a critical evaluation of BCBS,

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 17

2/28/2012 6:32:04 PM

18

Introduction

FSB and IMF recommendations on cross-border resolution of financial institutions and financial groups, followed by a concise analysis of the DoddFrank special resolution regime for SIFIs. The chapter considers the ramifications of the OLA both for the regulation of too-big-to-fail institutions in the US and co-ordination of cross-border resolutions. Finally, the chapter provides a critical analysis and evaluation of the EU Commission proposals for a pan-European crisis management and resolution regime for banks and certain investment firms. Chapter 8 provides a proposal for a new model of governance for global financial markets in order to address most of the shortcomings of current governance structures and to support effectively and advance recent reforms. It aims to protect the ideal of open global markets and enhance their legitimacy. The proposed global governance structure would have four pillars: (1) macro-prudential; (2) micro-prudential; (3) financial policy, regulation and knowledge supervisor; and, (4) a global resolution authority. The suggested governance system pre-supposes the negotiation and signing of an (umbrella) international treaty governing the most important aspects of international finance. It would be based on a set of general principles and sub-principles that, on the one hand, would stress the paramount importance of financial stability and, on the other, promote the global development objective.

9780521762663c01_p1-18.indd 18

2/28/2012 6:32:04 PM

S-ar putea să vă placă și