Sunteți pe pagina 1din 9

Applied Financial Economics, 1997, 7, 87Ð 95

Using a VECM to test exogeneity and


forecastability in the PPP condition
S T EF A N C . N O R R B I N , K E V I N L . R E F F E T T * and Y A O H U A JI §
Department of Economics, Florida State University, T allahasee, FL 32306 and
*Department of Economics, Arizona State University, T empe, AZ 85287 , USA

The possibility is explored that purchasing power parity (PPP) can be useful in
forecasting exchange rates and/or prices. The ® rst step shows that the spot exchange
rate is statistically exogenous in the PPP relationship. The next step investigates the
forecastability of the variables in the PPP condition. The results show that a VECM
can beat a random walk only in the case of the US price level.

I. INTRODUCTION rate does not adjust back towards the new equilibrium,
so it would not be forecastable, but prices would be fore-
Recent empirical evidence has indicated support for PPP as castable.
a long-run condition. For example, Cheung and Lai (1993), This paper tests two related issues. The ® rst is whether the
Pippenger (1993) and Fisher and Park (1991) all ® nd sup- spot rate is statistically exogenous. We show how this is
port for long-run PPP using cointegration analysis. Fur- important from a forecasting sense, and test which variables
thermore, Johansen and Juselius (1992) also ® nd support for are statistically exogenous in the PPP relationship. We then
PPP for the UK, but only in conjunction with the un- proceed by using the VECM implied by the long-run PPP
covered interest parity condition. Such a long-run equilib- and test whether we can outperform a simple random walk
rium implies some short-run disequilibrium adjustment,as forecast for ® ve countries: the United Kingdom, France,
pointed out by Granger (1986). This short-run adjustment Germany, Japan and Canada.
process implies some forecastability of the variables in the Section II discusses the exogeneity issue and applies it to
PPP condition. Thus it may be possible that the existence of the PPP condition. It also considers how the vector error
a long-run PPP equilibrium will lead to a forecastable correction model may be a useful approach to testing the
component of exchange rates. Intuitively this means that adjustment behaviour of the cointegrated relationship and
deviations from the equilibrium will lead to adjustments of tests for exogeneity in the PPP condition. Section III dis-
the exchange rates that will eliminate this disequilibrium. cusses the forecasting strategy and results. Section IV is the
Thus an `overshooting’ behaviour of the exchange rate will conclusion.
produce a predictable return to the long-run equilibrium
following an innovation that causes the condition to be out
of equilibrium. The only exception to the short-run fore- II. VECTOR ER ROR CORRECTION MODELS
castability condition of a cointegrated relationship is if a A N D EX O G E N E I T Y
variable is statistically exogenous to the long-run equilib-
rium. Thus a variable may not respond by adjusting to the In this section we discuss how the dynamic adjustment
new long-run equilibrium if it is statistically exogenous. In pattern to PPP will provide information about the spot
the case of PPP statistical exogeneity of the spot rate means exchange rate forecastability. We also discuss how the
that it moves due to some announcement, then prices adjust vector error correction models enable us to perform these
to equilibrate the equilibrium relationship. But the spot tests.

§
Please address comments to Stefan C. Norrbin, Department of Economics, Florida State University, Tallahassee, FL 32306, USA.
0960Ð 3107 Ó 1997 Routledge 87

AFES 94328
88 S. C. Norrbin et al.
Since our focus is on the dynamic adjustment process of 2 to obtain the following vector error correction representa-
PPP, we assume that a symmetric and proportional PPP tion:
holds. If this assumption is not the case, then no signi® -
K± 1
cant adjustment processes would be found to return the Xt = l + + Ci D Xt ± + P Xt ± +e
D i 1 t
variables to the long-run equilibrium. To verify that the i= 1
symmetric and proportional assumption is not the only
reason for the empirical ® ndings, we also test the system = l + C (L ) e t (3)
with an estimated PPP relationship using Johansen’s (1988)
where
MLE methodology. Choosing the United States as the
home country, symmetric and proportional PPP places the Ci = - (I - A1 - ¼ - Ai ), i + 1, ¼ ,K - 1,
following long-run equilibrium restriction on spot rates and
prices: P = (I - A1 - ¼ - AK )
St - PtUS + Pt = 0 (1) and A1 , ¼ , AK are p 3 p matrices of parameter, and l is the
where St is the log of the exchange rate in dollars per foreign deterministic drift in D X. Notice that the long-run informa-
currency, and PtUS and Pt are the log of the price levels for tion in the system is found in the P matrix.
the US and the foreign country. Notice that the equilibrium There are many ways to estimate systems such as Equa-
relationship implied by PPP is silent on issues relating to tion 3. We use two of the most commonly employed in the
the structure of the short-run adjustments in exchange rates PPP literature: the maximum likelihood procedures in
and prices to PPP and on issues relating to statistical Johansen (1988) and a generalized version of the Engle and
causality. Therefore, the actual equilibrium adjustment pro- Granger (1987) least squares procedures. Although we use
cess between the variables that de® ne PPP remains an both procedures, because of ® nite sample and identi® cation
empirical issue. Interestingly, issues relating to both dynam- problems associated with Johansen’s (1988) MLE proced-
ics and long-run behaviour of spot rates and prices can be ure, discussed in Phillips (1994), we focus on the Engle and
formally tested in a VECM that imposes the theoretical long Granger procedure. Let us brie¯ y review the details of the
run restriction in Equation 1. This section shows how the two procedures. For the maximum likelihood procedure,
VECM framework can be useful for establishing the dy- one estimates Equation 3, using a maximum likelihood
namic adjustment pattern to a long-run PPP equilibrium. estimator, by applying the reduced-rank regression tech-
niques pioneered in Anderson (1951) subject to a nor-
malization condition used to identify the VECM. If a coin-
PPP in an error correction model tegrating vector exists then P can be decomposed using
a reduced rank regression into P = a b 9 . In this decomposi-
Many authors, including Granger (1986), Engle and
tion a corresponds to the error correction component of
Granger (1987), Johansen (1988, 1992a), and Phillips (1991a)
each cointegrating vector b 9 . Alternatively, one can use
have proposed econometric procedures for the systems es-
theory to impose an exact structure for b , say b *, then
timation of a VAR in levels in the presence of unit roots.
estimate the error correction model in Equation 3 for the
Since there is evidence that spot rates and prices display unit
remaining parameters and test the adjustment coe cients a .
root behaviour, we begin by considering the following vec-
If any of the adjustment coe cients a are signi® cant, these
tor autoregression of order K for a vector of I(1) variables
variables are endogenous to the PPP condition, whereas
X = [St , PtUS , Pt ] :
a failure to ® nd a signi® cant adjustment coe cient implies
K that the variables are exogenous.
Xt = l + + Aj Xt ± j + e t (2) The role of statistical exogeneity in estimating systems
j= 1
such as Equation 3 has been investigated extensively begin-
where X - K + 1 , ¼ , X0 are ® xed, and {e t} tt == T1 is a sequence of ning with the paper by Engle et al. (1983). Exogeneity is
i.i.d. Gaussian variables with mean zero and covariance particularly important when attempting to understand the
matrix X . To construct a systems estimator for this VAR, it dynamic adjustment process in cointegrated systems. Spe-
is important to deal with the in¯ uence of the unit roots on ci® cally for our situation, having estimated Equation 3 we
the long-run behaviour of the system. It is will known that can test for the structure of the dynamic relationship be-
estimating an unrestricted VAR for X in levels can be tween the exchange rates and prices within the context of
problematic. 1 Granger (1986) notes that, in the presence of a long-run SPÐ PPP structure. Furthermore, tests for statist-
units roots, we can solve for the change in Xt in Equation ical exogeneity can also test for the most parsimonious

1
See Phillips (1991b) and Phillips and Loretan (1991) for a discussion of potential problems with estimating an unrestricted VAR in the
presence of unit roots and cointegration.

AFES 94328
Exogeneity and forecastability in the PPP condition 89
representation for the VECM. For example, it is well known tion 4a) are variation-free with respect to the information in
that, given the weak exogeneity of some variables, it can be the vector X2 t . A vector of parameters is variation-free if
shown that a partial system may be constructed whose that factorization of the conditional probability in Equation
estimators will be fully e cient (Johansen, 1992a). Therefore 4 forms a sequential cut. To elaborate on these terms, let
in this section we discuss how the presence of exogeneity can q be a vector of parameters of interest, and partition Q into
a€ ect the estimation of systems such as Equation 3 using Q = [Q1 , Q2 ] where Q1 are the parameters of the condi-
exogeneity procedures described in Johansen (1992a, b), tional model in Equation 4a and Q2 are the parameters of
Urbain (1992) and Norrbin and Re€ ett (1996). the marginal model in Equation 4b with r 1 and r 2 the
Begin by partitioning the above vector series X = parameter spaces for Q1 and Q2 . Then consider the follow-
[S, P US, P ] into X = [X1 , X2 ] where X1 and X2 are of di- ing de® nition.
mension p1 and p2 and p1 + p2 . = 1. And partition the
parameters of Equation 3, a , C1 , ¼ , CK ± 1 , l , e and X , DeÞ nition The variable D X2 is weakly exogenous over
accordingly. The joint density of D X in the VECM in Equa- a given sample period t = {1, ¼ , T } for q if and only if the
tion 3 can be factorized into the conditional density of D X1 following conditions are satis® ed:
given D X2 , denoted D X1 | D X2 , and the marginal density of
2 1. q is a function of only Q1
D X2 as follows:
2. The factorization in Equation 4 acts as a sequential cut4 ,
D X1 t = v D X2 t + (a 1 - v a 2 ) b 9 Xt ± 1 i.e.,
K± 1 F D X (D Xt , Q) = F D (D X1 | D X2 ; Q1 ) · F D (D X2 , Q2 )
+ + (C1 j - +l
X1 | D X2 X2
v C2 j ) D Xt ± 1 1
1 where Q Î r := r 1 3 r 2 .
- v l 2 +e 1t - v e 2t (4a) The ® rst condition says essentially that the parameters of
K± 1 interest q are only functions of the vector of parameters that
D X2 t = a 2 b 9 Xt ± 1 + + C2 j D Xt ± 1 +l 2 +e 2t (4b) de® ne the conditional model in Equation 4a. The second
1
condition says the parameters in the conditional model and
where v = X 1 2 X 2 21 . Notice that, in general, the parameters
±
the parameters in the marginal model are variation-free; i.e.
of the conditional model and marginal model are related. they do not share any joint restrictions in the system to be
Therefore, full information estimation (such as FIML) is estimated.
required to obtain e cient estimates of that vector of We can now describe how exogeneity in the estimation of
parameters in the system Q = [a , C1 , ¼ , CK ± 1 , X ]. For the vector q in the full system (Equation 4) can occur.
example, consider estimating the ® rst p1 equations in Equa- Consider the case of the weak exogeneity of D X2 t . Johansen
tion 4a. Partition the parameters according to this speci® ca- (1992a, b) proves for D X2 to be weakly exogenous for
tion of the system, e.g. a = [a p 1 , a p 2 ], Cj = [Cj p 1 , Cj p 2 ], etc. q = [a , b ], it must be the case that D X2 does not react to any
Johansen (1992a) shows that to obtain e cient estimates of of the disequilibrium errors in Equation 4b. Therefore, for
(a p 1 , b ), we must use information implicit in the full system weak exogeneity to be present in the system D X2 t can only
speci® cation in Equation 4. This is because, in general, the respond to lagged changes in vector D Xt . In this case the
estimation of parameters (a p 1 , b ) in the partial system of parameter b only appears in the ® rst p1 equations, and the
Equation 4a will involve cross-equationa l restrictions from cross-equation restriction is completely accounted for by
the full system (Equation 4). So when, for example, a 2 ¹ 0, Equation 4a. This makes maximum likelihood estimation of
the parameter b 9 appears in Equation 4a and b. In this case the partial system of the ® rst p1 equations of Equation
the estimation of (a p 1 , b , X 1 1 ) Equation 4a cannot treat 4 fully e cient.
D X2 t as exogenous with respect to the estimation of the A stronger form of exogeneity is also possible. It could be
parameters in the marginal model (Equation 4b).3 the case that D X2 t only responds to lagged changes in D X2 t .
There does exist a very special case of the factorization in And as well as being weakly exogenous, D X1 t does not
Equation 4 for which a maximum likelihood estimate of the Granger-cause D X2 t . A valid conditional forecasting model
parameters of partial system Equation 4a will be the FIML for D X1 t is therefore available by estimating Equation 4a as
estimate. This is when the conditional model in Equation 4a a partial system. In this case, we say D X2 t is strongly
contains as much information concerning parameters of the exogenous since D X2 does not respond to either lagged
cointegrating relationships in vector X as the full systems D X1 t ± j ’s or any of the disequilibrium errors b 9 Xt . Notice
estimator in Equation 4. This case occurs when the esti- that, in terms of the parameters of the system (Equation 4),
mates of the parameters (a p 1 , b ) in the partial system (Equa- strong exogeneity essentially amounts to a zero restriction

2
See for example Johansen (1992b) and Ericsson (1992) for a more complete discussion of this type of factorization.
3
See Phillips and Loretan (1991) and Johansen (1992a) for a complete discussion of this point.
4
See Engle et al. (1983) and Ericsson (1992) for a discussion of sequential cuts.

AFES 94328
90 S. C. Norrbin et al.
Table 1. V ECMs using a symmetric and proportional cointegrating vector

Dependent variable ECV United Kingdom


t- 1 ECV France
t± 1 ECV Germany
t± 1 ECV Canada
t± 1 ECV Japan
t± 1

D St - 0.034 - 0.010 - 0.021 - 0.010 - 0.066


(- 0.698) (- 0.239) (- 0.458) (- 0.219) (- 0.081)
D Pt 0.012 0.001 0.007 - 0.036 0.018
(1.860) (0.143) (1.190) (- 1.795) (1.090)
D PtUS 0.050 b 0.038 a 0.040 b 0.033 0.050 a
(5.585) (4.873) (5.285) (1.236) (4.514)

Notes: the VECMs all have the lag of the deviations from the theoretical PPP relationship, a constant and a deterministic trend
as regressors; no lags of the di€ erenced variables are included as the order of the VAR is 1; however, we also tested higher-order
VARs with similar result; the values in parentheses are t-statistics; the critical values are from MacKinnon (1991).
a
Signi® cance at the 5% critical value of - 4.296.
b
Signi® cance at the 1% critical value of - 4.949.

on both C2 = [Cj 2 1 , ¼ , C2 k ± 1 ]and a 2 . In this sense, the Equation 3 is estimated using no lags in the ® rst di€ erences
strong exogeneity condition is much more restrictive than of X. This is also important for the exogeneity tests as it
the weak exogeneity condition. A ® nding of weak exo- implies that tests showing weak exogeneity also exhibit
geneity means that the variable is unforecastable using the strong exogeneity.
long-run condition, i.e. the variable will not adjust back to In Table 1 we test for exogeneity in vector error correc-
a level where the condition is in equilibrium again. Further- tion models for the PPP relationship. The long-run PPP
more, if it is strongly exogenous, the variable is completely equilibrium is constrained to be symmetric and propor-
unforecastable using other variables in the relationship, i.e. tional, and the lag length of the original VAR is 1. Thus, the
the only variables that may be important for the forecasts test of Equation 4a and b simpli® es to testing the signi® -
are the variable’s own lagged values. cance of a for each country in the following system:
D Xt = l + a b *9 Xt ± 1 +e t (5)
T ests of exogeneity in the PPP condition
where Xt = [St , PtUS , Pt ], a is the error correction coe cient
Before discussing the results of the exogeneity tests, we for the system and b * is [1, - 1, 1], the theoretical cointe-
discuss the data and examine the time-series properties of grating vector of PPP. Hence, b * 9 X is the error correction
the variables for non-stationarity . The data are quarterly variable, or the temporary disequilibrium for the PPP con-
values from 1975:1 to 1991:4. The spot exchange rate and dition.
producer price data are from the OECD database.5 All data Table 1 tests Equation 5 by regressing each variable on
are end-of-quarter data. Logarithms are applied to all data.6 the lagged error correction variable (denoted ECV in the
All data were found to be non-stationar y in levels, but Table). OLS is e cient in this case as the vector error
stationary in ® rst di€ erences. For details on the unit root correction model has the same regressors in each equation
tests see Norrbin and Re€ ett (1994). for a given country. The results in Table 1 show that the
It is well known that many cointegration tests formulated spot rate is weakly exogenous to the system in Equation
in dynamic frameworks are sensitive to the order of the lag 5 since a 1 is not signi® cant. The critical values used for the
length (e.g. Stock and Watson, 1993). Therefore we pretest t-statistics are higher than usual due to the null hypothesis
for the order of the VAR before proceeding. Following the being non-stationarit y of the error correction variable.
suggestions in Mills and Prasad (1992), we use Schwarz’s Therefore the MacKinnon (1991) critical values are used.8
BIC criteria to determine the lag lengths.7 The BIC criteria Intuitively the ® nding of weak exogeneity means that the
for all ® ve countries indicate a VAR of order 1. Thus spot rate does not adjust to a disequilibrium in the PPP

5
We also tried consumer price data with similar ® ndings.
6
We also tried a monthly frequency with similar but weaker results. Furthermore, the sampling issue may be less important in this case
since our emphasis is on the long run. Hakkio and Rush (1991) have shown that the sampling frequency is less important than the length of
the time series in cointegration tests.
7
Mills and Prasad (1992) show that Akaike’s AIC criteria seems to overstate the dynamics in the system relative to the BIC criteria.
8
See Kremers et al. (1992) for a detailed discussion of critical values in extended EngleÐ Granger speci® cations.

AFES 94328
Exogeneity and forecastability in the PPP condition 91
Table 2. V ECMs using a SUR estimation across countries

Dependent variable ECV United Kingdom


t- 1 ECV France
t± 1 ECV Germany
t± 1 ECV Canada
t± 1 ECV Japan
t± 1

D St - 0.039 - 0.067 - 0.087 - 0.009 - 0.122


(- 0.980) (- 2.032) (- 2.537) (- 0.201) (- 2.440)
D Pt 0.002 - 0.008 - 0.008 - 0.051 - 0.008
(0.371) (- 1.698) (- 1.731) (- 2.917) (- 0.574)

Notes: the VECMs all have the lag of the deviations from the theoretical PPP relationship, a constant and a deterministic trend
as regressors; each row is estimated jointly using a SUR estimation technique; values in parentheses are t-statistics; the 5%
critical value is - 4.296, from MacKinnon (1991).

condition. 9 Similarly the foreign price level is weakly a system. However, the US price equation cannot be stated
exogenous. In fact, due to the order of the VAR, the spot in the same way because the dependent variable is the same
rates and the foreign price level are both weakly and strong- for each equation.1 1 Table 2 reports the SUR results for the
ly exogenous.1 0 The change in the US price level is, VECMs. Again none of the coe cients are signi® cant using
however, not exogenous. In four of the ® ve currencies the the MacKinnon critical values. The exchange rate for
response to the deviations from the equilibrium vector is France, Germany and Japan are signi® cant according to the
signi® cant at the 5% level. Only in Canada is the US price standard t-distribution, and also have the correct sign. Thus
response not signi® cant. Thus any deviation away from some marginal evidence of overshooting exists.1 2 The
PPP in the United Kingdom, France, Germany or Japan foreign price equation also improves, in the sense that all
will lead to a US price level adjustment in the future that except one coe cient are of the correct sign. However,
eventually eliminates the disequilibrium. The sign is positive only the Canadian price response is signi® cant using the
as the spot rate is the foreign currency price in dollars. standard t-distribution, and none using the MacKinnon
A positive value for a disequilibrium in Equation 1 can thus distribution.
be eliminated by an increase in the US price level. Obviously In Table 3 we extend our tests by examining whether the
the positive value for Equation 1 could also be eliminated symmetric and proportional restriction is the reason for the
by negative changes in the spot rate or the foreign price adjustment through the US price level. To address this
level. Although the spot rate changes in the correct direction question we estimate the cointegrating vector using Johan-
it is not signi® cant; the foreign price level is also insigni® cant sen’s (1988) full information maximum likelihood technique
and most of the coe cients are of the wrong sign. then use the estimated cointegrating vector in our VECMs.
To check the robustness of the ® ndings in Table 1 we also The equations are thus analogous to Equation 5 but the
tested the same equations using the seemingly unrelated unit cointegration vector b * is replaced with the reduced-
regression (SUR) technique described in Zellner (1962). Al- rank estimates of b *. The estimated cointegrating vectors
though it is true that the VECM system is e ciently esti- were all signi® cant, and are reported in Table 3. 1 3
mated by country, some additional information may exist For France and Japan, we ® nd the same signi® cant US
across countries. Thus, for example, the spot rate equation price adjustment in Table 3 as in Table 1. The results di€ er,
for each country may be included in a system. The spot rate however, for the United Kingdom and Germany. No signi® -
system for all ® ve currencies is estimated using SUR to cant adjustment to the error correction variable is found for
account for the potential comovement in the error terms. these countries. Furthermore, no other variables are signi® -
Similarly the foreign price equations can be stacked into cant using the MacKinnon (1991) statistics. Germany and

9
Note that this di€ ers from the ® nding in Fisher and Park (1991). They ® nd that PPP does not hold for the US dollar, and where it does
hold, the adjustment is primarily through exchange rates. Their study di€ ers from this paper in that we use a symmetric proportional PPP
restriction and an extended EngleÐ Granger methodology as opposed to J-tests.
10
We also tested high-order VARs and found similar conclusions.
11
We have also tried to run the US price equation in one combined equation, but there is not enough space to report it. The results
indicate that the variables jointly are signi® cant, but individually they are not signi® cant. This is due to a high degree of multicollinearity.
12
This supports the ® ndings in Fisher and Park (1991) but is also a bit surprising. The results would imply that exchange rates may be
forecastable. This may imply an ine ciency in the foreign exchange market to the extent that forecastability may lead to pro® ts which
exceed the riskiness of the investment.
13
This may also explain why Fisher and Park (1991) did not ® nd a cointegrating vector for the US dollar. The disequilibrium is removed
so slowly that it may be hard to detect the existence of an equilibrium at all.

AFES 94328
92 S. C. Norrbin et al.
Table 3. V ECMs with estimated cointegration vectors

Dependent variable United Kingdom France Germany Canada Japan

D St 0.025 0.010 0.059 0.005 - 0.034


(2.574) (0.256) (1.896) (0.089) (- 0.400)
D Pt 0.003 - 0.003 - 0.011 - 0.050 - 0.007
(2.425) (- 0.750) (- 3.053) (- 2.025) (- 0.304)
b
D Pt US
0.005 0.031 0.005 0.033 0.064 a
(2.555) (4.377) (0.794) (0.994) (4.033)

Notes: the independent variables in each regression are the lag of the estimated cointegrated relationship, a constant and
a deterministic trend; critical values are from MacKinnon (1991).
Estimated vectors are as follows:
United Kingdom b = (1, - 15.188, 9.442)
France b = (1, - 1.459, 1.067)
Germany b = (1, - 5.532, 7.999)
Canada b = (1, - 1.390, 1.528)
Japan b = (1, - 1.902, 2.366)
a
Signi® cance at the 10% critical value of - 3.970.
b
Signi® cance at the 5% critical value of - 4.296.

Canada have some marginal adjustments of the domestic Forecasting methodology


price level, whereas the United Kingdom has some marginal
The VECM (Equation 5) developed in the previous section
adjustments in all three variables. Therefore the adjustment
can be updated one period to provide forecasts as
cannot be identi® ed to a single variable.
Examining the cointegrating vectors in Table 3 one D Xt+ 1 = m W t + a W t b *9 Xt (6)
notices how di€ erent are the estimated vectors from the
where m W t is the estimated coe cient for all data up to time t,
theoretical vectors of (1, - 1, 1). This is very similar to what
and a t is the estimated coe cient for the data up to time t.
Cheung and Lai (1993) found in their paper. Using these
This allows true out-to-sample forecasts to be estimated by
estimated vectors in an error correction model gives some
updating the data one period at a time and forecasting one
counterintuitive results. The United Kingdom and Ger-
quarter ahead.
many both had signi® cant adjustments using a theoretical
For both VECM model and random walk model, we
vector, but not using the estimated vectors. As pointed out
must ® rst use in-sample observations (1975q1Ð 1986q4)
by Watson (1993), if one can theoretically identify the long-
data to run the base regression. For out-of-sampl e fore-
run restriction, and no evidence exists to reject this restric-
casting, we adopt the rolling regression techniques
tion, then the power of the error correction procedure is
for 1987q1Ð 1991q4. This technique uses the in-sample
improved. 1 4 Therefore we proceed by using the theoretical
observations to run the base regression then update the
vectors.
observation one-period at a time and compute the predicted
values for the VECM model and random walk model,
I I I . A F O R E C A S T I N G C O MP A RI S O N respectively. By using this rolling regression method, we end
up with ® ve years of out-of-sample predicted values for the
In this section we examine the exogeneity issue by conduct- change of spot rates, the change of foreign prices and the
ing a forecast competition between a forecasting model changes of US prices. By comparing the forecasted values
based on the adjustments toward the long-run PPP equilib- with the actual values, we can see which one performs
rium and a random walk model. better.
.

14
In some cases more than one vector was signi® cant. This is puzzling as two signi® cant cointegrating vectors would mean that only one
common trend exists. Thus the innovation must be common to both countries. In the cases where more than one cointegrating vector was
found, the vector with the expected signs was selected.

AFES 94328
Exogeneity and forecastability in the PPP condition 93
Table 4. Statistical values of V ECM coe¦ cients in rolling regressions

Standard
Mean deviation Min Max

UK D S - 0.0206 0.0156 - 0.0427 0.1510


D P 0.0067 0.0049 - 0.0025 0.0129
D P US 0.0544 0.0022 0.0500 0.0586
France D S 0.0001 0.0169 - 0.0204 0.0432
D P 0.0100 0.0027 - 0.0010 0.0088
D P US 0.0436 0.0032 0.0379 0.0492
Germany D S - 0.0064 0.0212 - 0.0309 0.0417
D P 0.0052 0.0019 0.0023 0.0073
D P US 0.0468 0.0043 0.0400 0.0555
Canada D S - 0.0212 0.0459 - 0.1516 0.0169
D P - 0.0612 0.0446 - 0.1684 - 0.0289
D PUS - 0.0028 0.0562 - 0.1432 0.0427
Japan D S - 0.0449 0.0235 - 0.0687 0.0117
D P 0.0120 0.0082 - 0.0059 0.0427
D P US 0.0522 0.0017 0.0490 0.0558

The out-of-sample forecasting accuracy is measured by Results of forecasting comparison


three statistics: mean absolute error (MAE) and root mean
square error (RMSE): At ® rst, we look at the stability of the results for the rolling
regressions; we run 21 group regressions separately based
N± 1 on di€ erent observation sets. The ® rst one includes 48
MAE = + | FCt+ s - ACt+ s | /N observations and the last one includes 68 observations.
0
These rolling regressions can help to test the stability of the

5 6
N± 1 1 /2
long-run PPP relationship and the short-run dynamic ad-
RMSE = + [ FCt+ s - ACt+ s ]2 /N
0
justment pattern.
Table 4 gives the statistical results of the rolling regres-
where FC is the ® tted change value of the variable, and AC sion coe cients. The coe cients, especially the coe cients
is the actual change value. for US prices, have small standard deviations. The di€ er-
In order to see whether VECMs have predictive power for ences between minima and maxima are very close, except in
the variables, we introduce the following random walk pro- the case of Canada. This implies that the dynamic adjust-
cess as a comparison: ment patterns are stable over time. In this sense, the PPP
long-run relationship and the short-run dynamic adjust-
D Xt+ 1 = m W t (7)
ment pattern are robust.
It is easy to see that Equation 7 can be obtained from Table 5 shows that for out-of-sample forecasts, RMSE
Equation 6 simply by ignoring the disequilibrium term of and MAE values in the VECM model for spot rates do not
PPP. We compare the di€ erences between actual values and show any improvement except for Japan, compared with the
the predicted values from these two models to see which one random walk process. However, the improvement for Japan
performs better. If the random walk model performs at least is relatively small, indicating that it may have been a func-
as well as the VECM model of PPP in the out-of-sample tion of the time period. Therefore, for spot rates, the random
forecasting of some variables, then PPP does not have any walk forecasting model performs at least as well as the
predictive power for these variables. This implies that the VECM model. This implies that spot rates are exogenous to
variables are exogenous to PPP equilibrium and simply the PPP relationship and simply follow a random walk
follow a random walk process. But if the VECM model does process. These empirical results are consistent with the
show that PPP has some predictive power for prices Ð the ® ndings in the earlier section.
VECM model improves the performance of the out-of- Earlier it was shown that at least one variable, the US
sample forecasting Ð then these variables are adjusting to- price variable, adjusts toward the long-run PPP equilib-
wards a long-run PPP equilibrium. rium. Table 5 also supports this ® nding as RMSE and MAE

AFES 94328
94 S. C. Norrbin et al.
Table 5. RMSE and MAE statistics in out-of-sample forecasting

VECM Random walk

RMSE MAE RMSE MAE

UK D S 0.0695 0.0580 0.0693 0.0575


D P 0.0076 0.0062 0.0081 0.0066
D P US 0.0127 0.0093 0.0138 0.0104
France D S 0.0706 0.0598 0.0694 0.0582
D P 0.0043 0.0033 0.0043 0.0029
D P US 0.0123 0.0092 0.0138 0.0104
Germany D S 0.0745 0.0635 0.0734 0.0621
D P 0.0047 0.0036 0.0052 0.0038
D P US 0.0125 0.0093 0.0138 0.0104
Canada D S 0.0240 0.0170 0.0219 0.0157
D P 0.0099 0.0087 0.0072 0.0062
D P US 0.0153 0.0122 0.0138 0.0104
Japan D S 0.0660 0.0555 0.0668 0.0560
D P 0.0130 0.0090 0.0136 0.0095
D P US 0.0117 0.0076 0.0138 0.0104

for US prices in the VECM model are smaller than RMSE


and MAE values for the random walk process, except in the
case of Canada. This means US prices do adjust toward
PPP in most cases. Canada exhibits no improvement in the
forecasts for any of the variables, implying that they are all
independent of the PPP relationship. This also supports the
® ndings in Section III.
For foreign prices, RMSE and MAE provide some mixed
results. For the UK, Germany and Japan the VECM model
outperforms the random walk model. For France the
RMSE values are exactly the same for the VECM and
random walk, but MAE is smaller in the random walk model.
These results imply that the PPP relationship has some
forecastability components in prices, and the VECM model Fig. 1 Spot rates, out-of-sample forecasts: (Ð Ð ) actual growth,
does forecast better for prices in some cases. The results (´ ´ ´ ´) forecasted growth using PPP model, (Ð ´ Ð ´) forecasted growth
support the idea that PPP is a long-run equilibrium, and using random walk model
there are dynamic adjustments toward PPP in the short run.
Further support is provided by plots of the forecasts and
actual values. Figures 1 to 3 are for Germany but the plots negative predicted values at the beginning. The rolling re-
are typical. Figure 1 exhibits the actual change, the forecasts gressions do pull up the random walk forecasts, but not
of the random walk and the forecasts for the PPP forecast- enough to be close to the actual values.
ing model for spot rates over the period 1987q1Ð 1991q4.
The random walk forecasts and the PPP model forecasts are
very close, and both models perform poorly when forecast- I V . C O N CL U S I O N S
ing values for actual spot rates. Figure 2 shows the forecasts
for the German price level. The forecast values from the This paper has demonstrated that forecasts of the exchange
PPP model are slightly better than from the random walk rate are not going to be improved by including the PPP
model. Figure 3 shows the forecasts for the US price. The variables in the forecast regression. It shows that the
PPP model forecasts a stable positive change of US price, PPP condition can be thought of as a long-run equilib-
which is reasonable for the period except during rium. A long-run equilibrium (or cointegrated relationship)
1990q4Ð 1991q1 (big decrease of price). The random walk implies an adjustment path to reach it. However, the results
model predicts an almost zero change of the US price. The show that the spot exchange rate is weakly and strongly
substantial negative trend of the in-sample regression led to exogenous to the equilibrium attractor process. Thus the

AFES 94328
Exogeneity and forecastability in the PPP condition 95
Engle, R. and Granger, C. (1987) Cointegration and error correc-
tion: representation, estimation, and testing, Econometrica, 55,
251Ð 76.
Engle, R., Hendry, D. and Richard, J.F. (1983) Exogeneity, Econo-
metrica, 51, 277Ð 304.
Ericsson, N. (1992) Cointegration, exogeneity, and policy analysis:
an overview, Journal of Policy Modeling, 14, 251Ð 80.
Fisher, E. O’N. and Park, J. Y. (1991) Testing purchasing power
parity under the null hypothesis of cointegration, Economic
Journal, 101 , 1476Ð 84.
Granger, C.W.J. (1986) Developments in the study of cointegrated
economic variables, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statis-
tics, 48, 213Ð 28.
Hakkio, C. and Rush, M. (1991) Cointegration: how short is the
short-run? Journal of International Money and Finance, 10,
571Ð 81.
Fig. 2 German prices, out-of-sample forecasts: (Ð Ð ) actual growth, Johansen, S. (1988) Statistical analysis of cointegrating vectors,
(´ ´ ´ ´) forecasted growth using PPP model, (Ð ´ Ð ´) forecasted growth Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12, 231Ð 54.
using random walk model Johansen, S. (1992a) Cointegration in partial systems and the
e ciency of single-equation analysis, Journal of Econometrics,
52, 389Ð 402.
Johansen, S. (1992b) Testing weak exogeneity and the order of
cointegration in UK money demand data, Journal of Policy
Modeling, 14, 313Ð 34.
Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1992) Testing structural hypotheses
in multivariate cointegration analysis of the PPP and the UIP
for UK, Journal of Econometrics, 53, 211Ð 44.
Kremers, J., Ericsson, N. and Dolado, J. (1992) The power of
cointegration tests, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statis-
tics, 54, 325Ð 47.
MacKinnon, J. (1991) Critical values for cointegration tests, in
L ong-Run Economic Relationships: Readings in Cointegration,
ed. R.F. Engle and C.W.J. Granger, Oxford University Press,
Oxford, pp. 267Ð 76.
Mills, J. and Prasad, K. (1992) Comparison of model selection
criteria, Econometric Reviews, 11, 201Ð 33.
Fig. 3 US price level, out-of-sample forecasts: (Ð Ð ) actual growth, Norrbin, S. and Re€ ett, K. (1996) Exogeneity and forward rate
(´ ´ ´ ´) forecasted growth using PPP model, (Ð ´ Ð ´) forecasted growth unbiasedness, Journal of International Money and Finance, 15,
using random walk model 267Ð 74.
Norrbin, S. and Re€ ett, K. (1994) The dynamic adjustment process
of purchasing power parity, Florida State University, manu-
spot rate will not adjust even if the PPP condition is in script.
disequilibrium. This ® nding implies that the PPP disequilib- Phillips, P. C. B. (1991a) Optimal inference in cointegrated sys-
rium variable should be useless in a forecasting equation of tems, Econometrica, 59, 283Ð 306.
the exchange rate. Phillips, P. C. B. (1991b) To criticize the critics: an objective
Bayesian analysis of stochastic trends, Journal of Applied
However, forecasts using a forecasting equation with Econometrics, 6, 333Ð 74.
a long-run PPP variable are better than forecasts from Phillips, P. C. B. (1994) Some exact distribution theory for max-
a random walk for the US price levels. Furthermore, the imum likelihood estimators of cointegrating coe cients in
statistical test show that the US price level is the only error correction models, Econometrica, 62, 73Ð 94.
variable that adjusts towards the PPP equilibrium. Thus Phillips, P. C. B. and Loretan, M. (1991) Estimating long-run
economic equilibria, Review of Economic Studies, 58, 407Ð 36.
PPP provides no improvements in spot rate forecasts, but is Pippenger, M. (1993) Cointegration tests of purchasing power
useful for US price forecasts. parity: the case of Swiss exchange rates, Journal of Interna-
tional Money and Finance, 12, 46Ð 61.
Stock, J. and Watson, M. (1993) A simple estimator of cointegrat-
RE F ER E N C E S ing vectors in higher order integrated systems, Econometrica,
61, 783Ð 820.
Urbain, J. (1992) On weak exogeneity in error correction models,
Anderson, T. W. (1951) Estimating linear restrictions on regression Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 54, 187Ð 207.
coe cients for normal distributions, Annals of Mathematical Watson, M. (1993) Vector autoregressions and cointegration,
Statistics, 22, 327Ð 51. Northwestern University, manuscript.
Cheung, Y. and Lai, K. (1993) Long-run purchasing power parity Zellner, A. (1962) An e cient method of estimating seemingly
during the recent ¯ oat, Journal of International Economics, 34, unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias, Journal of
181Ð 92. the American Statistical Association, 57, 348Ð 68.

AFES 94328

S-ar putea să vă placă și