Sunteți pe pagina 1din 9

Strategic Management Journal

Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)


Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/smj.448

RESEARCH NOTES AND COMMENTARIES

CLUSTERS, NETWORKS, AND FIRM


INNOVATIVENESS
GEOFFREY G. BELL*
Labovitz School of Business and Economics, University of Minnesota Duluth Campus,
Duluth, Minnesota, U.S.A

This paper extends current knowledge of industry clusters by disentangling the effects of networks
from cluster (i.e., distinctly geographic) mechanisms on firm performance as well as by studying
the influence of these different mechanisms on firms located inside and outside the industry
cluster. It also highlights the importance of simultaneously modeling multiple networks which
may differentially influence important firm outcomes. In the paper, I model the innovativeness
of Canadian mutual fund companies as a function of their geographic location—inside or
outside the industry cluster of Toronto—and of their centrality in networks of managerial and
institutional ties. I find that locating in the industry cluster as well as centrality in the managerial
tie network enhances firm innovation, while centrality in the institutional tie network does not.
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

INTRODUCTION agglomeration economies (DeBresson and Amesse,


1991; Harrison, 1992; Harrison, Kelley, and Gant,
Industry clusters—groups of geographically proxi- 1996; Pascal and McCall, 1980; Shaver and Flyer,
mate firms in the same industry—are a strik- 2000). Many existing studies model only firms
ing feature of the geography of economic activity in the cluster, ignoring both ties between clus-
(Krugman, 1991) examined by industrial geog- ter members and other (‘remote’) firms (Harrison,
raphers at least since Marshall (1920). Strategy 1994, and Saxenian, 1994b, are notable excep-
scholars are now beginning to study how clusters tions) and the overall industry network struc-
influence firm performance, and have yet to distin- ture (Storper and Harrison, 1991). This paper
guish between benefits associated with enhanced overcomes some of these shortcomings by ask-
social interaction effects (Harrison, 1992) and ing, ‘What is the relationship among industry
clusters, network centrality, and firm innovative-
Keywords: innovation; networks; multiple networks; ness?’ I examine these relationships by examin-
industry clusters; mutual funds ing the influence of clusters and network struc-

Correspondence to: Geoffrey G. Bell, Labovitz School of Busi- ture on the innovativeness of Canadian mutual
ness and Economics, University of Minnesota Duluth Campus,
110 SBE, 412 Library Drive, Duluth, MN 55812, U.S.A. fund companies. My study advances the strategy
E-mail: ggbell@d.umn.edu literature by untangling cluster mechanisms from

Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Received 22 November 1999
Final revision received 14 September 2004
288 G. G. Bell

network mechanisms and showing how they dif- development of new products or services as well
ferentially influence important firm outcomes. It as new administrative systems (Damanpour, 1991;
extends network theory by comparing partially Nohria and Gulati, 1996).
overlapping networks of managerial and institu- Centrality measures the involvement in the net-
tional ties and showing that centrality in differ- work (Knoke and Burt, 1983): the extent to which
ent networks distinctly influences innovativeness. an actor is deeply involved in network relations
The paper proceeds as follows. The next section (Burt, 1980; Wasserman and Faust, 1994). It con-
of the paper develops theory and hypotheses. I siders access to and control over resources (Knoke
then outline my study setting and methodology, and Burt, 1983; Wasserman and Faust, 1994), and
and present results. Finally, I present conclusions, thus is likely to be highly associated with inno-
limitations, and implications for scholars and man- vation, as access to and control over informa-
agers. tion and resources are associated with innovation
(Becker, 1970; Powell, Koput, and Smith-Doerr,
1996; Rogers, 1995; von Hippel, 1988).
THEORY AND HYPOTHESES
Clusters and firm innovativeness
A cluster is a group of firms from the same or
related industries located geographically near to Firms in clusters have better access to information
each other (Becattini, 1990; Brusco, 1990; Har- than do other firms (Bianchi and Bellini, 1991;
rison et al., 1996; Storper and Harrison, 1991). Porter, 1990; Pouder and St. John, 1996), resulting
Scholars such as Harrison (1994) and Porter (1990) from both direct cluster effects as well as network
predict that firms in the cluster should be more processes underlying the cluster (Becattini, 1990;
innovative than others for at least two reasons. Brusco, 1990; Harrison, 1994). Thus, the total
First, firms in the cluster benefit from agglomer- effect of clusters on innovation may be mostly
ation economies such as nearby suppliers attain- indirect, partially influenced by network position.
ing efficient scale (Scott, 1992), direct observa- In this section, I focus on the direct effect of
tion of competitors (Burt, 1987; Harrison et al., clusters on innovation that operate independently
1996), and ability to exploit collective knowledge of network effects.
(Dosi, 1988; Marshall, 1920). Second, firms in Such cluster effects will arise partially because
clusters benefit from network-based effects, espe- there is common knowledge available to members
cially enhanced social interaction (Harrison, 1992). of the cluster (Geroski, 1995) that is not con-
I begin my examination of these influences by sciously transmitted among them (Marshall, 1920),
briefly defining key terms. or is transmitted via chance meetings between
executives that are fostered by geographic prox-
imity (Saxenian, 1994b). Common knowledge is
Key terms: Innovation and centrality
augmented and reinforced by public information
Innovation is the development and implementa- sources, such as the local media or universi-
tion of new ideas to solve problems (Dosi, 1988; ties (Porter, 1998; Saxenian, 1994b). Over time,
Van de Ven, 1986). According to Van de Ven, the common knowledge forms a cluster level of
‘An innovation is a new idea, which may be a absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990).
recombination of old ideas, a schema that chal- The ability to understand and exploit this cluster-
lenges the present order, a formula, or a unique level absorptive capacity is enhanced by the com-
approach which is perceived as new by the indi- mon lineage and heritage of the firms in the cluster
viduals involved’ (Van de Ven, 1986: 591). Inno- and their executives. Specifically, firms in clusters
vation includes a pattern of informal cooperative often share lineage to a common parent firm, such
R&D (von Hippel, 1987), resulting from infor- as the many firms in Silicon Valley directly or indi-
mal information exchange among firms, so firms rectly related to Fairchild (Saxenian, 1994a). More
better positioned to access information should be broadly, executives in geographically proximate
more innovative (Rogers, 1995). Innovation also firms share a common background and understand-
countenances the possibility that an actor may try ing (Paniccia, 1998). This common lineage and
to imitate others, but in the process inadvertently heritage will enable executives to understand infor-
generate new ideas (March, 1994). It entails the mation they may share when they ‘run across each
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)
Research Notes and Commentaries 289

other’ in chance settings (Saxenian, 1994b). Also, of others’ innovative efforts (Becker, 1970). They
because information is sticky and place-specific are less likely than others to miss valuable infor-
and the ability to transfer information decays with mation (Becker, 1970), and have quick access to
distance (Ormrod, 1990; Saxenian, 1994a; von promising new ventures (Powell et al., 1996) that
Hippel, 1994), firms in the cluster will have bet- may generate innovation.
ter access to common knowledge than geographi- Central firms may be better positioned to access
cally remote firms (‘remotes’). Thus, they tend to the veracity of the information they receive as
search locally for information used in innovation well as the information sources themselves (Burt,
(Almeida and Kogut, 1997; Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and 1987). An information source may limit the infor-
Henderson, 1993). mation it provides, either for strategic reasons (to
Additionally, the geographic proximity of firms misrepresent the information) or to be ‘helpful’
in the cluster enhances direct observation of com- (limiting information to what it believes the other
petitors (Burt, 1987; Pascal and McCall, 1980; party needs). The more a firm is involved in its net-
Rogers, 1995). A firm that observes others may try work, the more it can compare information across
to mimic them and inadvertently generate innova- sources and assess its veracity. Moreover, firms
tion (March, 1994). Such inadvertent innovation with multiple information sources are less likely
may operate even in the absence of direct net- to miss vital information as multiple information
work ties, when the imitator cannot simply contact sources provide multiple channels to discover new
the other firm to learn more about an innovation, information, and can combine information in novel
but must rely on cues from observing the other, ways to generate innovation (Van de Ven, 1986).
increasing the likelihood of mutation and inno- Firms and their executives are involved in two
vation. Firms outside the cluster (remotes) would distinct networks: a managerial network of infor-
have access to neither the cluster common knowl- mal ties among firm executives and an institutional
edge nor the ability to directly observe their rivals, tie network of formal ties between firms. The man-
so would not be able to use these conduits for agerial network enhances information flow, espe-
innovation (Powell et al., 1996). Thus: cially the flow of tacit information among firms
(Uzzi, 1996). It provides relatively high-trust con-
Hypothesis 1: In a given industry, after control- text in which to communicate (Argyle and Hen-
ling for network effects, cluster-member firms derson, 1985). Being central in this network may
will be more innovative than remotes. expose managers and their firms to a rich flow of
tacit knowledge useful for innovation. Conversely,
the institutional network provides opportunities to
hear industry news. For example, if a trade associ-
Modeling multiple networks ation approves members’ new products, then serv-
Scholars have long recognized that organizations ing on the association’s boards and committees
are embedded in multiple, only partially overlap- provides early warning about competitor actions.
ping, networks (Powell, 1985; Powell and Smith- Thus, centrality in each network should enhance
Doerr, 1994). Powell (1985) found no boundary innovativeness:
between the work and personal life of his subjects,
suggesting that modeling multiple networks is Hypothesis 2: Centrality in the managerial net-
work enhances firm performance.
needed to understand how different networks influ-
ence outcomes. Consequently, I model a manage- Hypothesis 3: Centrality in the institutional net-
rial network (the network of informal ties among work enhances firm performance.
managers) and an institutional tie network (the net-
work of formal ties between their firms) to capture
both informal and formal ties.
METHODS
Centrality and firm innovativeness Research setting
Central actors are extensively involved in their I collected the data on and from mutual fund
networks (Burt, 1980; Freeman, 1979; Wasserman companies listed in the January 1998 Member-
and Faust, 1994), so have highlighted knowledge ship Directory of the Investment Funds Institute
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)
290 G. G. Bell

of Canada (Investment Funds Institute of Canada, (strongly disagree). Innovation is the summed and
1998b). One of the 78 firms was listed twice in averaged responses received from all respondents
the Directory, but included only once in the study. for each firm. Cronbach’s alpha assessing the reli-
Thus, my final sample consisted of 77 Invest- ability of the three indicators of Innovation was
ment Funds Institute of Canada (IFIC) members, 0.93, indicating a high level of reliability among
representing over 97 percent of assets under man- the measures. Because Innovation was reverse
agement in Canada (Investment Funds Institute of scored (i.e., high values of Innovation indicate a
Canada, 1997). Forty-six of the 77 IFIC mem- lack of innovation), I reverse-coded the results as
ber firms maintain head offices in Toronto (10.6 Innovativeness.
firms per million people in the Toronto area); the
other 31 maintain head offices in 10 cities across
Canada, including nine in Vancouver (4.8 firms
Clusters
per million people) and seven in Montreal (2.1
firms per million people). Given the high concen- I coded the Cluster variable ‘1’ if a firm’s head
tration of mutual fund companies in Toronto, both office is in the cluster (Toronto), and ‘0’ otherwise.
in absolute number and relative to underlying pop- Data for this measure came from the Investment
ulation base, Toronto dominates the geography of Funds Institute of Canada (1998a), company data
this industry and firms in Toronto comprise the (annual reports, etc.), BellCharts (1997), and Pape
industry cluster. (1997).

Data and measures


Managerial centrality
Mutual fund company innovativeness
I collected information on firm innovativeness I collected data on the managerial tie network of
using a survey of industry experts: financial colum- all 77 fund companies using a survey of executives
nists in Canada’s business press and executives (fund managers and top management) administered
of mutual fund data services. I identified poten- in February 1998. I developed the sample of fund
tial experts from lists of Southam News’ business company executives by contacting each mutual
columnists (including the Financial Post), invest- fund company and requesting a list of its execu-
ment and mutual fund reporters for the Globe tives, supplemented where necessary with alternate
and Mail, financial newsletter editors, and Cana- sources such as the firm’s web site. I sampled one
dian mutual fund data sources. My initial sample to six executives from each firm. When the firm
consisted of 23 persons, of whom 14 were gen- employed six or fewer executives, I surveyed all
eral business writers unable to provide the detailed of them. When the firm employed more than six,
information I needed. The remaining nine persons I selected six randomly. Six firms were exceptions
had primary or sole duty analyzing the Canadian to this rule. Four cases consisted of two related
mutual fund industry. I received responses from companies from which I selected more than six
seven of the nine experts, six of whom provided respondents. In two cases, I sent more than six sur-
enough information to be usable. Five of the seven veys because a respondent specifically suggested
respondents were located in Toronto, two outside. or requested that I send a survey to someone else
Cronbach’s alpha score testing inter-rater reliabil- in the firm.
ity across the six respondents was 0.80, indicating The procedures I followed closely parallel those
broad consensus about firm innovativeness. advocated by Dillman (1978). I sent a cover letter
I measured innovativeness along three dimen- and questionnaire to each executive in the sample
sions by asking the industry experts to respond to asking them to respond by a certain date. Approx-
three statements about each fund company: ‘This imately 2 weeks later, I phoned the respondents
firm often leads the industry at (1) introducing and asked for their assistance, and 1 week later
new products/. . . (2) introducing new services/. . . I sent non-respondents a second copy of the sur-
(3) adopting new technologies.’ Respondents vey and an updated cover letter. I also called them
scored their responses to each statement on a 5- and asked them to watch for the survey and assist
point scale ranging from 1 (strongly agree) to 5 me by completing it. Of the 305 surveys sent, 102
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)
Research Notes and Commentaries 291

executives (33%) from 64 different firms (83%) Directors, IFIC Management Committee, and IFIC
responded.1 Retail Council. I created three measures of insti-
In the survey, I asked questions about the exec- tutional ties: IFIC Board of Director Ties, IFIC
utives’ friendships, information, and advice net- Management Committee Ties, and IFIC Retail
works which I used to develop the managerial Council Ties. Because of the reciprocal nature of
tie network. For each of these variables, in cases these relationships, I measured these as symmetric
where more than one executive from a given firm ties. I recorded each of these relations in separate
responded to the survey, I pooled their responses 77 × 77 matrices, wherein cell ij was coded ‘1’ if
such that I record a friendship, information, or there was a tie between firms i and j , and ‘0’ other-
advice tie if any of the executives reported such wise. There was high agreement among these net-
a tie. I mapped each of the friendship, informa- works, with QAP correlations ranging from 0.95
tion, and advice networks in a 77 × 77 matrix. to 0.97. I summed the matrices into the Institu-
I coded cell ij ‘1’ if any executive at firm i tional Tie matrix, whose cells are valued from
was the recipient of a friendship, information, ‘0’ (none of the three ties are present) to ‘3’ (all
or advice tie, respectively, and ‘0’ otherwise. To three of the ties are present). As with the Manage-
assess agreement among the networks, I used the rial Tie matrix, I created Institutional Centrality
‘simple matching’ QAP correlation routine (Bor- by dichotomizing the Institutional Tie matrix and
gatti, Everett, and Freeman, 1999), which calcu- summing the columns of the resultant matrix.
lates the extent to which there is the same entry
in each cell in two matrices. The QAP correlation
scores ranged from 0.90 to 0.93. I created the Man- Control variables
agerial Centrality matrix by summing the three Prior studies identified a significant positive rela-
matrices and dichotomizing the result to record tionship between firm size and innovativeness and
whether or not a tie existed from firm j to firm a significant negative relationship between firm
i. I symmetrized the results because centrality age and innovativeness. I control for these factors.
assesses involvement in the network (Knoke and Market Share is the firm’s assets under manage-
Burt, 1983). I then measured in-degree (Wasser- ment as at December 31, 1997 divided by total
man and Faust, 1994) as Managerial Centrality industry assets under management at that date.
for each firm by summing the columns to yield Firm Age is 1998 less the earlier of either the date
the number of firms tied to i. of founding of the fund company or (in two cases
where that was unavailable) the date of inception
of the company’s oldest fund.
Institutional centrality
I created the Institutional Tie matrix using data
from the Investment Funds Institute of Canada RESULTS
(1998a), which listed the 1997–98 IFIC Board of
Variable correlations
1
To examine potential problems associated with having respon- Table 1 presents means, standard deviations, and
ses from only 64 of 77 firms, I reran all analyses using matrices
generated by data from the 64 responding firms. There were no correlations among variables included in the anal-
significant differences from the results reported herein. ysis.
Table 1. Means, standard deviations, and correlations

Variable Mean Standard deviation 1. 2. 3. 4. 5.

1. Innovativeness 2.70 1.01 –


2. Toronto 0.62 0.49 0.39∗∗∗ –
3. Managerial centrality 15.17 11.47 0.49∗∗∗ 0.26∗ —
4. Institutional centrality 4.60 7.44 0.43∗∗∗ 0.11 0.44∗∗∗ —
5. Market share 1.30 2.31 0.60∗∗∗ 0.20† 0.43∗∗∗ 0.61∗∗∗ —
6. Firm age 18.81 13.63 0.12 0.13 0.18 0.14 0.36∗∗∗

∗∗∗ ∗∗
p < 0.001; p < 0.01; ∗ p < 0.05; †p < 0.10

Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)
292 G. G. Bell
Table 2. Predictors of firm innovativeness DISCUSSION
Variable Innovativeness
Clusters, networks, and firm innovativeness
Toronto 0.50∗∗ (0.19)
Managerial centrality 0.02∗ (0.01) This study set out to examine the relationship
Institutional centrality 0.00 (0.02)
Market share 0.21∗∗∗ (0.05) among clusters, networks, and firm innovativeness,
Firm age −0.01 (0.01) and proposed that clusters and network centrality
Adjusted R 2 0.47∗∗∗ should enhance firm innovativeness. Indeed, locat-
ing in the cluster enhances firm innovativeness,
∗∗∗
p < 0.005; ∗∗ p < 0.01; ∗ p < 0.05; †p < 0.10 even after separately accounting for the influence
Results for coefficients; standard errors in parentheses.
of network structure. Expanding on Marshall’s
notion that in clusters information is ‘in the air’
forming a common good available to all (Marshall,
Hypotheses testing 1920), common knowledge may reflect chance
I tested the hypotheses using a regression equation meetings that are likely to occur when executives
model that modeled the influence of the cluster are geographically proximate (Saxenian, 1994b)
variable, the network variables, and the controls and when they share a common lineage (Saxenian,
on firm innovativeness (see Table 2). 1994a) and background (Paniccia, 1998). Alterna-
tively, the positive influence of clusters may reflect
ready access to geographically proximate support-
ing industries, such as commercial banks and the
Factors influencing firm innovativeness Toronto Stock Exchange.
The study also shows the differential effects of
Hypothesis 1 (locating in the Cluster enhances managerial and institutional ties on firm innova-
Innovativeness) is strongly supported (β = 0.50; tiveness. As hypothesized, centrality in the man-
p < 0.01). Firms in the cluster are significantly agerial tie network enhanced firm innovativeness,
more innovative than remotes. Hypothesis 2 suggesting that the informal friendship and com-
(Managerial Centrality enhances Innovativeness) munication network provides an important source
was also supported (β = 0.02; p < 0.05), while of novel information useful in innovation (Uzzi,
Hypothesis 3 (Institutional Centrality enhances 1996). On the other hand, I found no significant
Innovativeness) was not supported (β = 0.004; relation between institutional ties and innovative-
n.s.). Market Share was positively significantly ness. Perhaps, in this industry at least, institutional
associated with Innovativeness (β = 0.21; p < ties were used solely for the transmission of rela-
0.001) and Firm Age was not significant (β = tively well-known information, and failed to gener-
−0.01; n.s.). ate communication that was enough, deep enough,
Moreover, the possibility exists that innovation
or novel enough (Uzzi, 1996) to enhance innova-
influences centrality as well as centrality influ-
tion.
encing innovation (the dimension of causality I
hypothesized here). I tested this by estimating the
model with a two-stage least-squares (2SLS) tech-
nique using instrumental variables for the two cen- Limitations of the study
trality variables (results not reported). I applied
a Hausman test, which tests whether the coeffi- The study does not account for firm-specific fac-
cients under the 2SLS estimate (which are efficient tors influencing innovativeness, such as absorptive
if innovation influences centrality) differs from capacity. Because the study focused on the role of
the OLS estimates (which are efficient if innova- geographic clusters and networks, it did not mea-
tion does not influence centrality). The Hausman sure absorptive capacity or similar firm-specific
test could not reject the null hypothesis that the factors that may influence firm ability to translate
two sets of estimates are the same (chi-square of information into innovation. On the other hand,
χ 2 (5) = 6.34, Prob > χ 2 = 0.2745), meaning that size and age may provide reasonable controls for
we can rely on the OLS estimates. these differences.
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)
Research Notes and Commentaries 293

Implications for research more innovative than remotes, managers who are
concerned with innovation should consider locat-
This study challenges both strategy and network ing some of their innovative-related operations to
researchers. For strategy scholars, the study shows the cluster. I do not suggest that moving to the
the importance of distinguishing cluster and net- cluster will necessarily make a firm more innova-
work mechanisms. Simply aggregating cluster and tive; however, doing so will likely increase access
network mechanisms into ‘cluster effects’ (Bianchi to firms that tend to be more innovative. Addi-
and Bellini, 1991) confounds benefits related to tionally, managers must recognize the importance
clustering per se with benefits arising from net- of network ties, especially their managerial net-
work ties. Thus, the study shows the importance of work ties, on the performance of their firms. While
examining cluster effects in greater detail, clearly managers have recently focused their attention on
differentiating different mechanisms that drive per- structuring their firms’ network of formal ties, such
formance. as strategic alliances (Doz and Hamel, 1998), this
For network scholars, this study shows the study shows that managers need to manage their
importance of clearly choosing the network(s) informal networks carefully as well (Burt, 1992).
modeled, and modeling multiple networks when
necessary (Baum and Dutton, 1996; Powell and
Smith-Doerr, 1994). Network scholars may choose CONCLUSION
the networks they model on the basis of con-
venience. However, if, as in this study, differ- This paper responds to a call for researchers to
ent networks distinctly influence important out- examine innovation in service industries, espe-
comes, then modeling only a single network on the cially in financial services (Drazin and Schoonho-
basis of convenience risks attributing to one net- ven, 1996). It ‘untangles’ cluster effects by sep-
work effects actually generated by another, produc- arately modeling cluster-based mechanisms and
ing a cross-level fallacy (Rousseau, 1985). Thus, social interaction (network) mechanisms. In so
this study also amplifies the importance of study- doing, it finds that both cluster and network mech-
ing multiple networks simultaneously (Galask- anisms influence Canadian mutual fund company
iewicz and Zaheer, 1999; Powell, 1985; Powell and innovativeness and that innovativeness, in turn,
Smith-Doerr, 1994). While Powell (1985) found enhances firm prestige.
that actors may use their networks for personal
use, I find the opposite also holds: managers may
use their personal networks for the benefit of their ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
firms. Although not tested in this study, it is quite
possible that different networks reflect different I thank Milton Boyd, Phil Bromiley, Joe Galask-
causal mechanisms. (For example, Galaskiewicz iewicz, Aks Zaheer, the University of Minnesota
and Zaheer, 1999, assert that agents’ social net- Strategy Research Group, and two anonymous
works are more likely to contain affective content SMJ reviewers for their input into this project. I
than are interorganizational networks.) Thus, net- also thank the University of Minnesota for provid-
work scholars must seriously consider what mech- ing financial assistance for this project.
anisms they expect to operate in the context they
are studying and choose networks that capture
those mechanisms. REFERENCES
Almeida P, Kogut B. 1997. The exploration of techno-
Implications for managers logical diversity and geographic localization in inno-
vation: start-up firms in the semi-conductor industry.
My study shows that, even accounting for net- Small Business Economics 9(1): 21–31.
work ties, firms in clusters are more innovative Argyle M, Henderson M. 1985. The Anatomy of Relation-
than are remotes. However, because the study did ships and the Rules and Skills Needed to Manage them
not examine specific mechanisms underlying clus- Successfully. William Heinemann: London.
Baum J, Dutton J. 1996. The embeddedness of strategy.
ter effects, we must be cautious in providing advice In Advances in Strategic Management, Vol. 13,
to managers. However, managers can take away Shrivastava P, Huff AS, Dutton JE (eds). JAI Press:
several points. First, because cluster members are Greenwich, CT; 3–40.
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)
294 G. G. Bell
Becattini G. 1990. The Marshallian industrial district as Harrison B. 1994. Lean and Mean: The Changing
a socio-economic notion. In Industrial Districts and Landscape of Corporate Power in the Age of
Inter-firm Co-operation in Italy, Pyke F, Becattini G, Flexibility. Basic Books: New York.
Sengenberger W (eds). International Institute for Harrison B, Kelley MR, Gant J. 1996. Innovative firm
Labour Studies: Geneva; 37–51. behavior and local milieu: exploring the intersection of
Becker MH. 1970. Sociometric location and innovative- agglomeration, firm effects, and technological change.
ness: reformulation and extension of the diffusion Economic Geography 72(3): 233–258.
model. American Sociological Review 35: 267–282. Investment Funds Institute of Canada. 1997. December
BellCharts. 1997. BellCharts for Windows. The Financial Statistics. The Investment Funds Institute of Canada:
Post DataGroup: Toronto. Toronto.
Bianchi P, Bellini N. 1991. Public policies for local Investment Funds Institute of Canada. 1998a. Listing
networks of innovators. Research Policy 20: 487–497. of Board and Committee Members. The Investment
Borgatti S, Everett MG, Freeman LC. 1999. UCINET 5 Funds Institute of Canada: Toronto.
for Windows: Software for Social Network Analysis Investment Funds Institute of Canada. 1998b. Member-
(5th edn). Analytic Technologies: Natick, MA. ship Directory. The Investment Funds Institute of
Brusco S. 1990. The idea of the industrial district: Canada: Toronto.
its genesis. In Industrial Districts and Inter- Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M, Henderson R. 1993. Geo-
firm Co-operation in Italy, Pyke F, Becattini G, graphic localization of knowledge spillovers as evi-
Sengenbeger W (eds). International Institute for denced by patent citations. Quarterly Journal of Eco-
Labour Studies: Geneva; 10–19. nomics 108(3): 577–598.
Burt RS. 1980. Models of network structure. Annual Knoke D, Burt RS. 1983. Prominence. In Applied
Review of Sociology 6: 79–141. Network Analysis: A Methodological Introduction,
Burt RS. 1987. Social contagion and innovation: cohesion Burt RS, Minor M (eds). Beverly Hills: CA; 195–222.
versus structural equivalence. American Journal of Krugman P. 1991. Geography and Trade. MIT Press:
Sociology 92(May): 1287–1335. Cambridge, MA.
Burt RS. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of March JG. 1994. A Primer on Decision Making: How
Competition. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, Decisions Happen. Free Press: New York.
MA. Marshall A. 1920. Principles of Economics. Macmillan:
Cohen WM, Levinthal DA. 1990. Absorptive capacity: London.
a new perspective on learning and innovation. Nohria N, Gulati R. 1996. Is slack good or bad for
Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 128–152 innovation? Academy of Management Journal 39(5):
Damanpour F. 1991. Organizational innovation: a meta- 1245–1264.
analysis of effects of determinants and moderators. Ormrod RK. 1990. Local context and innovation
Academy of Management Journal 34(3): 555–590. diffusion in a well-connected world. Economic
DeBresson C, Amesse F. 1991. Networks of innovators: Geography 66(2): 109–122.
a review and introduction to the issue. Research Policy Paniccia I. 1998. One, a hundred, thousands of industrial
20: 363–379. districts: organizational variety in local networks of
Dillman DA. 1978. Mail and Telephone Surveys: The small and medium-sized enterprises. Organization
Total Design Method . Wiley: New York. Studies 19(4): 667–699.
Dosi G. 1988. Sources, procedures, and microeconomic Pape G. 1997. Gordon Pape’s 1998 Buyer’s Guide to
effects of innovation. Journal of Economic Literature Mutual Funds. Prentice-Hall Canada: Scarborough,
26(September): 1120–1171. Ontario.
Doz YL, Hamel G. 1998. Alliance Advantage: The Art of Pascal AH, McCall JJ. 1980. Agglomeration economies,
Creating Value through Partnering. Harvard Business search costs, and industrial location. Journal of Urban
School Press: Boston, MA. Economics 8: 383–388.
Drazin R, Schoonhoven C. 1996. Community, popula- Porter ME. 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations.
tion, and organization effects on innovation: a mul- Free Press: New York.
tilevel perspective. Academy of Management Journal Porter ME. 1998. Clusters and the new economics of
39(5): 1065–1083. competition. Harvard Business Review 76(6): 77–90.
Freeman LC. 1979. Centrality in social networks: Pouder R, St. John CH. 1996. Hot spots and blind
conceptual clarification. Social Networks 1: 215–239. spots: geographical clusters of firms and innovation.
Galaskiewicz J, Zaheer A. 1999. Networks of competi- Academy of Management Review 21(4): 1192–1225.
tive advantage. In Research in the Sociology of Organi- Powell WW. 1985. Getting Into Print: The Decision-
zations, Andrews S, Knoke D (eds). JAI Press: Green- Making Process in Scholarly Publishing. University
wich, CT; 237–261. of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL.
Geroski P. 1995. Markets for technology: knowledge, Powell WW, Koput KW, Smith-Doerr L. 1996. Interor-
innovation and appropriability. In Handbook of the ganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation:
Economies of Innovation and Technological Change, networks of learning in biotechnology. Administrative
Stoneman P (ed). Basil Blackwell: Oxford; 90–131. Science Quarterly 41: 116–145.
Harrison B. 1992. Industrial districts: old wine in new Powell WW, Smith-Doerr L. 1994. Networks and
bottles? Regional Studies 26(5): 469–483. economic life. In The Handbook of Economic
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)
Research Notes and Commentaries 295

Sociology, Smelser NJ, Swedberg R (eds). Princeton industrial production systems and their forms of
University Press: Princeton, NJ; 368–402. governance in the 1990s. Research Policy 20:
Rogers EM. 1995. Diffusion of Innovations (4th edn). 407–422.
Free Press: New York. Uzzi B. 1996. The sources and consequences of embed-
Rousseau DM. 1985. Issues of level in organizational dedness for the economic performance of organi-
research. In Research in Organizational Behavior, zations: the network effect. American Sociological
Vol. 7, Cummings LL, Staw BM (eds). JAI Press: Review 61: 674–698.
Greenwich, CT; 1–37. Van de Ven AH. 1986. Central problems in the
Saxenian A. 1994a. Lessons from Silicon Valley. management of innovation. Management Science
Technology Review 97(5): 42–51. 32(5): 590–607.
Saxenian A. 1994b. Regional Advantage: Culture and von Hippel E. 1987. Cooperation between rivals:
Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128 . Harvard Informal know-how trading. Research Policy 16:
University Press: Cambridge, MA. 291–302.
Scott AJ. 1992. The role of large producers in industrial von Hippel E. 1988. The Sources of Innovation. Oxford
districts: a case study of high technology systems University Press: New York.
houses in Southern California. Regional Studies 26(3): von Hippel E. 1994. ‘Sticky information’ and the locus
265–275. of problem solving: implications for Innovation.
Shaver JM, Flyer F. 2000. Agglomeration economies, Management Science 40(4): 429–439.
firm heterogeneity, and foreign direct investment in the Wasserman S, Faust K. 1994. Social Network Analysis:
United States. Strategic Management Journal 21(12): Methods and Applications. Cambridge University
1175–1193. Press: Cambridge, U.K.
Storper M, Harrison B. 1991. Flexibility, hierarchy and
regional development: the changing structure of

Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 287–295 (2005)

S-ar putea să vă placă și