Sunteți pe pagina 1din 8

Modern Actuarial Risk Theory

Rob Kaas, August 4, 2003

Note: this pdf-file contains the slides such as they are used in my classes at the University of Amsterdam. They are made available to teachers using Modern Actuarial Risk Theory as is, without any warranty or pretense. Users are urged to share any criticism with the author of this text, at R.Kaas@UvA.nl, to the benefit of all users.
1

Summary Ch. 1 The expected utility hypothesis explains why insureds pay so much more than the net premium that insurance companies can exist; also it gives a way to compute sensible premiums. Various classes of different utility functions exist that each have different desirable properties. E.g., quadratic utility requires only mean and variance of the risk, exponential utility leads to a premium independent of the (possibly random or unknown) current capital. Stop-loss reinsurance (more general, insurance with a deductible), is optimal because the retained loss has the lowest variance when the net premiums are equal. In fact, it also leads to the best resulting expected utility. In other situations, other types of coverage may be optimal.
24

Left as exercises: 1: As above for d [2,3]; give numerical answers for B = 405 and d = 2 / d = 3. 2: Optimize over d [2,3]; also for B = 404 3: When d = 2, compute the survival probability using NP

51

If the claims are exponential() then v,t: Pr[U(T) > y U(T0) = v, T = t] = Pr[X > v+y X > v] = e(v+y) / ev = ey U(T) T < ~ exp() denominator = / (R). Because of = 1 / 1 and R = / (1+), we have: (u) = 1 u 1 u ), exp( ) = exp( 1+ 1+ 1+ 1+ 1

so (u) = (0) eRu.

101

The process of a driver moving through this scale can be described by a Markov system. After the effects of the initial scaling have worn off, we get the steady state distribution; it is an eigenvector of the transition matrix. One may assess the efficiency of the bonus-malus system by using the elasticity of the average premium paid in the steady state to the mean number of claims (Loimaranta).

151

Choice of model: multiplicative model tariff Example: Usage(1) Usage(2) Weight(1) Weight(2) Weight(3)

Private Business 900 kg 1000 kg 1100 kg

basis: 100% +15% basis: 100% +10% +20%

1 = 1 2 = 1.15 1 = 1 2 = 1.1 3 = 1.2

Sijkl = i j k l + "purely random error" log Sijkl log + log i + ... + log l (log-linear model) j, ... such that Estimation: determine values , i, j l observations sijkl k estimated values i

201

: i Completing the triangle by predictions X ij j 1 2 3 4 5 1 A A C D F 2 A A C D 3 A A C D* 4 B B X 34 X44 5 E

just outside the observed data is computed as follows The element X 34 (here (C) denotes the total of all elements C in the table): + + ) ( 3 ( 2) (C) (B) 1 2 3 4 1+ X34 = = 34 = (A) + + ) ( 1+ 2) ( 1 2 3 since (C) and (B) are marginal totals, and (A) = R1 + R2 K4 K5. } (D) {(B) + X (D) (B) 34 = Also, X = . 44 {(A) + (C)} (A)
251

10.5 Incomplete information


For a risk Y we assume that it is known that E[Y] = Pr[0 Y b] = 1 Which risk Y leads to the extremal stop-loss premium in a given priority d? Minimal risk: Maximal risk: X Z: Pr[Z=b] = b = 1Pr[Z=0] (concentration) (dispersion) See book Fig. 10.3, page 244. These same extremal risks lead to extreme ruin probabilities and extreme compound Poisson stop-loss premiums. Both lower and upper bound have a degenerate claim size distribution (adjusting the Poisson parameter for the upper bound from to / b). See also exer 10.5.7.
301

S-ar putea să vă placă și