Sunteți pe pagina 1din 50

Monopoly

A monopoly is the sole producer of a commodity that has no close substitutes and faces many buyers.
The firm and the industry y are identical. The demand curve faced by the firm is the downward-sloping industry demand curve. A monopoly l acts as a price-maker i k

Monopoly
The existence of the downward-sloping downward sloping demand curve sets a constraint on the monopolists monopolist s actions The monopolist can either set the price and then sell the quantity indicated by the demand curve Or O determine d t i the th quantity tit t to b be sold ld and d then find the price at which this quantity can be b sold ld

Market power
A monopolist, as we shall see, has market power That is, it can set a price above marginal cost Whether a market is a monopoly market or not depends on the definition of the market The market must be such that the monopolist monopolists s product has no close substitutes If we define the market too broadly, a monopolist may appear to have rivals If we define it too narrowly, y, we may y identify ya firm as a monopoly when it is not

Where Do Monopolies p Come From?


1 Government blocks the entry of more than one firm fi i into t a market. k t (Wh (Why?) ?) 2 One firm has control of a key y resource necessary to produce a good. 3 Economies of scale are so large that one firm has a natural monopoly. 4 Being first to produce a new product (iPod)

Where Do Monopolies p Come From?


Entry Blocked by Government Action
The government blocks entry in two main ways: 1 By granting a patent or copyright to an individual or firm, giving it the exclusive right to produce a product. 2 By granting a firm a public franchise, making it the exclusive legal provider of a good or service.

Where Do Monopolies Come From?


Entry Blocked by Government Action

Patents and Copyrights Patent The exclusive right to a product for some period from the date the product is invented. invented Copyright A government-granted exclusive right t produce to d and d sell ll a creation. ti Public Franchises Public franchise A designation by the government that a firm is the only legal provider of a good or service.

Where Do Monopolies p Come From?


Control of a Key Resource
Another way for a firm to become a monopoly is by controlling a key resource. To produce aluminium you need bauxite the ALCOA example

Are Diamond Profits Forever? The De Beers Diamond Monopoly


De Beers promoted the sentimental value of diamonds as a way to maintain its position in the diamond market.
http://edwardjayepstein.com/diamond/pro http://edwardjayepstein com/diamond/pro logue.htm

Scale Economies and Monopoly


Monopolist can make a profit because AC lies below the demand curve at some quantities Two firms cannot make positive profits
AC lies li above b Dhalf for f all quantities

17-9

Profit maximization Profit-maximization


Let the equation of the (inverse) demand curve facing the monopolist be P = P(Q), where dP/dQ < 0 0. The total cost function is C = C(Q). The Th monopolist li t tries t i to t maximize i i = TR C, where TR = P(Q).Q and TC = C(Q).

Profit maximization Profit-maximization


The first order condition is d/dQ = dTR/dQ dC/dQ = 0, i i.e., dTR/dQ = dC/dQ. dC/dQ => MR = MC. The second order condition is d2/dQ2 = dMR/dQ dMC/dQ < 0

P fit Maximization Profit M i i ti


$

C t' R

400

300 c 200 150 100 50 0 c 5 t Profits

10

15

20 Quantity

Marginal Revenue
For a straight line demand curve P = a bQ, what h ti is the th MR equation? ti ? TR = PQ = aQ bQ2 Then MR = dTR/dQ = a 2bQ AR = TR/Q = a bQ for Q > 0.

Average g and Marginal g Revenue


$ per unit it of f output

7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0
Marginal Revenue

Average Revenue (Demand)

7 Output

P and MR
Note: MR = dTR/dQ. dTR/dQ But TR = PXQ. Hence MR = P + Q(dP/dQ) = P(1 1/e)

Maximizing Profit When Marginal Revenue q Marginal g Cost Equals


$ per unit it of f output

MC P1 P* AC P2
Lost profit

D = AR MR Q1 Q* Q2
Lost profit

Quantity

Profit maximization Profit-maximization


For e > 1, 1 MR < P; for e < 1, MR will be negative So long as MC > 0, profit-maximization requires MR > 0, 0 i.e. e > 1.

The monopolist will operate on the elastic portion of the demand curve.

The Monopolists Output Decision

An Example C(Q) = 50 + Q2 P(Q) = 40 Q Then MC = 2Q 2Q, MR = 40 2Q MR = MC => Q = 10, P = 30

P fit M Profit Maximization i i ti


$/Q

40

MC

30
P fit Profit

AC AR

20 15 10 MR 0 5 10 15 20
Quantity

Miscellaneous
The Monopolist does not face a Supply

Curve The Lerner Index

- The elasticity of demand affects a monopolists li t price i relative l ti to t its it marginal i l cost - Check the price-marginal cost margin: (p MC)/p )/p

The Lerner Index


MR = p(1 1/e) Then MR = MC implies L = (p ( MC)/p MC)/ = 1/e 1/ For a competitive firm, p = MC => L = 0 The smaller e e, the larger the Lerner index and the greater the monopolists ability to set price above marginal cost cost.

Monopoly
If demand is very elastic elastic, there is little benefit to being a monopolist The larger the elasticity elasticity, the closer to a perfectly competitive market

Taxation of a monopolist
What happens if a tax is imposed on a monopolist? If the tax is a lump lump-sum sum tax T, T it is clear that there will be no effect on either monopoly price or quantity, quantity because the monopolist will now be maximizing T.

Taxation of a monopolist
Suppose that a specific tax of t per unit is imposed. Consider linear demand and cost curves: P = a Q, C = cQ, a > c. Then Q* = (a c)/2 and P* = (a + c)/2. Next, , let the tax be imposed p on quantity q y at the rate t, a > (c+t).

Taxation of a monopolist
The total cost curve facing the monopolist becomes C = (c+t)Q. Quantity is now Q** = (a c t)/2 and price P** = (a+c+t)/2. Hence, H P** - P* = t/2 t/2, which hi h shows h that th t price has increased by only half the amount t of f th the t tax per unit. it

Taxation of a monopolist
However, , it is not generally g y true that the price p increases by less than the tax. Suppose that the demand curve is a constantelasticity demand curve. curve MR = P(1 1/e). Equating q g this to MC = c and solving, g, we get g P = c/(1 1/e). After the tax is imposed, price is P = (c+t)/(1 1/e). 1/e) P P = t/(1 1/e). Since e > 1, , 1 1/e / is a fraction and therefore the increase in price exceeds t.

MONOPOLY
The Th Effect Eff of faT Tax
Suppose a specific tax of t dollars per unit is levied, so that the monopolist must remit t dollars to the government for every unit it sells. If MC was the firms original marginal cost, its optimal production decision is now given by

Effect of Excise Tax on Monopolist

With a tax t per unit, the firms effective marginal cost is increased by the amount t to MC + t. In this example, the increase in price P is larger than the tax t.

Response p to Changes g in Cost


How do monopolies and perfectly competitive markets differ in their response to changes in costs? Consider the case of a marginal cost increase by a given amount at every level of output
Example: E l a specific ifi tax, t t, t on firms fi

The pass-through rate is the increase in price that occurs in response to a small increase in marginal cost, measured d per dollar d ll of f increase in marginal l cost In a competitive market, the pass-through rate is never greater than one g The monopolists pass-through rate depends on the shape of the demand curve
Can be greater than one with a constant-elasticity demand curve

Perfect competition vs. Monopoly


Monopoly is inferior to perfect competition in two respects. (1) In perfect competition competition, the long run equilibrium is when price is driven down to the point of the minimum average cost curve productive efficiency is attained. M Monopolist li t is i not t forced f d to t produce d at t the th lowest point of the average cost.

Perfect competition vs. Monopoly


(2) Perfect competition leads to a situation where the potential gains from trade between buyers and sellers are fully realized allocative efficiency p = MC The monopoly charges a price that is hi h than higher th marginal i l cost t and d there th is i a deadweight loss under monopoly.

Does Monopoly Reduce Economic Efficiency?


Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition
What Happens If a Perfectly Competitive Industry Becomes a Monopoly?

The Social Costs of Monopoly Power


Monopoly power results in higher prices and lower quantities However, However does monopoly power make consumers and producers in the aggregate better or worse off? We can compare producer and consumer surplus l when h in i a competitive titi market k t and d in a monopolistic market

Does Monopoly Reduce Economic Efficiency?


Measuring the Efficiency Losses from Monopoly

The Inefficiency of Monopoly

Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Investments


Firms can make investments in an effort to become a monopolist Example: cable TV firms lobbying government officials to award them franchises If firms compete to become a monopolist, they will spend up to the full monopoly profit (Richard P Posner) ) If they spend on socially wasteful things (e.g., golf outings for local officials) the loss from monopoly may be larger than deadweight loss and include all monopoly profit

Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Investments Rent seeking is socially useless effort devoted to securing a monopoly position Welfare effects of monopoly need not always be so bad Expenditures E dit firms fi make k to t gain i monopoly positions can be socially valuable l bl (e.g., ( R&D spending di in i the th search for patentable drugs)

Regulating Monopoly Power


Since monopoly leads to a higher price and a lower output than a comparable competitive industry industry, governments try to restrict monopoly power in various ways.

Regulating Monopoly Power


Price ceiling - Ch Changes the th demand d d curve facing f i the th firm fi - The profit-maximizing output for monopoly becomes the same as the perfectly competitive output

If price is lowered to PC output increases to its maximum QC and th there i is no d deadweight d i ht loss. l
$/Q Pm

Price Regulation
MC

MR

P2 = PC

AC

AR If left alone, a monopolist produces Qm and charges Pm.


Qm Qc Quantity

Th Social The S i l Costs C t of f Monopoly M l Power P Natural Monopoly


A firm that can produce the entire output of an industry at a cost lower than what it would be if there were several firms. C(Q) < C(q1) + C(q2) + C(q3) + .. + C(qn), where Q = q1+q2+ ..+qn If th the average cost t curve i is d downward d sloping, then there is natural monopoly Sufficient not necessary condition Sufficient,

Natural Monopoly
Suppose pp that the total cost function is C = 50 + 10Q. If output per day is 25, one firm can produce this amount at an average cost of f Rs.12 R 12 and d total l cost of Rs.300. On the other hand, hand if there are two firms and one produces 12 units while the other produces 13 units, the total cost of production is 170 + 180 = Rs.350 which is greater than the cost of production of a single firm.

Regulating the Price p y of a Natural Monopoly


$/Q

Natural monopolies occur because of extensive economies of scale

Quantity

Regulating the Price p y of a Natural Monopoly


$/Q
Unregulated, the monopolist would produce Qm and charge Pm. If the price were regulate to be PC, the firm would lose money and go out of business.

Pm

Setting the price at Pr yields the largest possible output;excess profit is zero.

Pr PC MR
Qm Qr

AC MC AR

QC

Quantity

First-Best vs. Second-Best Pi R Price Regulation l i


Under regulation, ideally prices will be set at the competitive price i Price at which demand and supply curves intersect Aggregate gg g surplus p will be maximized First-best solution to problem of price regulation Two problems with achieving this lead to second-best regulation Regulator may not know the firms marginal costs First-best solution would cause the monopolist to lose money If P < AC Best the regulator can do is set a price that makes aggregate surplus as large as possible, allow the firm to break even Set P = AC
17-43

Regulatory Failure
Difficulties associated with price regulation:

It is very difficult to estimate the firm's firm s cost and demand functions because they change with t e evolving o g market a et co conditions dto s Regulated monopolists make many decisions other than about p price regulation g may y lead to inefficiencies wrt these decisions

Regulatory Goals
Regulators may pursue goals other than the maximization of aggregate surplus - Official mandate may include other objectives, e.g. provision of services to poor consumers p - Regulators may be appointed/elected y can try y to improve p chances of repeat p they appointment or reelection - Regulators g may y be captured p by y the regulated firm

Government ownership
If the government owns the monopoly, - There is no need for elaborate regulatory hearings saves resources - Managers have no incentive to overstate costs But there is no focus on profits which leads to efficiency - the politicians and bureaucrats have their own agendas

Dorfman-Steiner Dorfman Steiner model


Advertising - Adds to cost - But B t shifts hift d demand d curve Let p = price a = advertising expenditure q = q(a, p), q/a > 0, q/p < 0. C( ) = other C(q) th costs t

Dorfman-Steiner model
Consider a profit-maximizing monopolist: = pq(a, ( p) ) C[q(a, C[ ( p)] )] a To maximize profit: /p = q + pq/p (C/q)(q/p) = 0 /a = pq q/a (C/q)(q q/a) )1=0 From (1), q + (p C/q)(q/p) = 0 [p C/q]/p = -(q/p)/(q/p) = 1/ep Lerner condition

(1) (2) ( )

(3)

Dorfman-Steiner model
From (2) (2), (p C/ q)(q/ a) = 1 (p ( C/q) ) = 1/(q/ /a) ) (p C/q) = (a/q)/(a/q)(q/a) (p C/q) = (a/q)/(1/ea) From (3) and (4), (4) we get [(a/q)/ea][1/p] = 1/ep a/pq / = ea/e / p

(4)

Dorfman-Steiner Dorfman Steiner model


a/pq = | Advertising expenditure as a proportion of sales revenue ea/ep | Ratio of elasticities

If ep is large, then less will be spent on advertising the product

S-ar putea să vă placă și