Sunteți pe pagina 1din 6

ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS

Maximization of a function with a constraint is common in economic situations. The rst section considers the problem in consumer theory of maximization of the utility function with a xed amount of wealth to spend on the commodities. We consider three levels of generality in this treatment. The second section presents an interpretation of a Lagrange multiplier in terms of the rate of change of the value of extrema with respect to the change of the constraint constant. The rst subsection gives a general presentation, the second subsection illustrates this formula for a particular situation, and then the third subsection derives the formula in general. In the third section, we calculate a rate of change of the minimal cost of the output with respect to the change of price of one of the inputs. 1. Maximize Utility with Wealth Constraint 1.1. Three commodities. Assume there are three commodities with amounts x1 , x2 , and x3 , and prices p1 , p2 , and p3 . Assume the total value is xed, p1 x1 + p2 x2 + p3 x3 = w0 , where w0 > 0 is a xed positive constant. Assume the utility is given by U = x1 x2 x3 . The maximum of U on the commodity bundles given by the wealth constraint satisfy the equations x2 x3 x1 x3 x1 x2 w0 = p1 = p2 = p3 = p1 x1 + p2 x2 + p3 x3 .

If we multiply the rst equation by x1 , the second equation by x2 , and the third equation by x3 , then they are all equal: x1 x2 x3 = p1 x1 = p2 x2 = p3 x3 . One solution is = 0, but this forces one of the variables to equal zero and so the utility is zero. If = 0, then p1 x1 = p2 x2 = p3 x3 w0 = 3p1 x1 w0 = p1 x1 = p2 x2 = p3 x3 . 3 Thus, one third of the wealth is spent on each commodity. This gives the maximization of U . 1.2. Maximize of a Weighted Utility. We make the same assumptions on the commodities as the last 1 a2 a3 example, but assume the utility is given by U = xa 1 x2 x3 with a1 > 0, a2 > 0, and a3 > 0. This utility function gives a weight to the preference of the commodities as the solution to the maximization problem shows. The maximum of U on the commodity bundles given by the wealth constraint satisfy the equations
1 1 a2 a3 a1 xa x2 x3 = p1 1 1 a2 1 a3 a2 xa x3 = p2 1 x2 1 a2 a3 1 a3 xa = p3 1 x2 x3 p1 x1 + p2 x2 + p3 x3 = w0 .

ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS

If we multiply the rst equation by x1/a1 , the second equation by x2/a2 , and the third equation by x3/a3 , then they are all equal:
1 a2 a3 xa 1 x2 x3 =

p1 x1 p2 x2 p3 x3 = = . a1 a2 a3

One solution is = 0, but this forces one of the variables to equal zero and so the utility is zero. If = 0, then p2 x2 p3 x3 p1 x1 = = , a1 a2 a3 aj p1 x1 , pj xj = a1 a2 a3 a1 + a2 + a3 w0 = p1 x1 1 + + = p1 x1 , a1 a1 a1 a1 w0 p1 x1 = , a1 + a2 + a3 a2 w0 p2 x2 = , and a1 + a2 + a3 a3 w0 p3 x3 = . a1 + a2 + a3 Thus, the wealth is distributed among the commodities in a way that uses the exponents as weights. Again, these choices give a maximization of U . 1.3. Maximize of a General Utility Function. Now we assume there are n commodities with amounts xi for 1 i n, and a utility function U (x1 , . . . , xn ) that depends on the amount of commodities but we do not give a specic formula. We assume the wealth w0 = p1 x1 + + pn xn is xed. The equations given by the Lagrange multiplier method are U = pi for 1 i n xi w0 = p1 x1 + + pn xn . A solution satises 1 U for all i. pi xi Thus, the ratio of the marginal utility to price is the same for each commodity. The amount of money U dmi U U spent on the ith -commodity is mi = pi xi . The partial derivative, = = pi . Thus, xi mi dxi mi 1 U U = is the marginal utility per dollar spent on the ith -commodity and is called the marginal pi xi mi utility of money. = 2. Interpretation of a Lagrange Multiplier Let x = (x1 , . . . , xn ) be the variables. Consider the problem of nding the maximum of f (x) subject to the constraint g (x) = w. We discuss the problem in the case when f is the prot function of the inputs and w denotes the value of these inputs. For each choice of the constant w, let x (w) of x that maximizes f , so f (x (w)) is the maximal prot for xed value of the inputs w. The derivative d f (x (w)), dw represents the rate of change in the optimal output from the change of the constant w.

ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS

Corresponding to x (w) there is a value = (w) such that they are a solution to the Lagrange multiplier problem, i.e., f(x (w)) = (w)g(x (w)) w = g (x (w)). We claim that (1) (w) = d f (x (w)). dw

Therefore, the Lagrange multiplier also equals this rate of the change in the optimal output resulting from the change of the constant w. If f is the prot function of the inputs, and w denotes the value of these inputs, then the derivative is the rate of change of the prot from the change in the value of the inputs, i.e., the Lagrange multiplier is the marginal prot of money. For the example of the next subsection where the function f is the production function, the Lagrange multiplier is the marginal product of money. In Section 19.1 of the reference [1], the function f is a production function, there are several constraints and so several Lagrange multipliers, and the Lagrange multipliers are interpreted as the imputed value or shadow prices of inputs for production. 2.1. Change in budget constraint. In this subsection, we illustrate the validity of (1) by considering the maximization of the production function f (x, y ) = x2/3 y 1/3 , which depends on two inputs x and y , subject to the budget constraint w = g (x, y ) = p1 x + p2 y where w is the xed wealth, and the prices p1 and p2 are xed. The equations for the Lagrange multiplier problem are 2 1/ 3 1/3 x y = p1 , 3 1 2/3 2/3 x y = p2 , and 3 p1 x + p2 y = w. These have a solution as follows: 2 1/3 1/ 3 1 x y = 3 = x2/3 y 2/3 , p1 p2 1 p2 y = p1 x, 2 1 3 w = p1 x + p1 x = p1 x, 2 2 2 p1 x = w, and 3 1 p2 y = w. 3 To indicate the dependence on these optimizing points on w, we write x (w) and y (w). For these values, 2 (w) = (x )1/3 (y )1/3 3p1 = = 2 3p1 22/3 3 2w 3p1 1 2 p1 p2
1/3

w 3p 2 .

1/3

1/ 3

ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS

On the other hand, the values of f at the points of maximum are f (x (w), y (w)) = (x )2/3 (y )1/3 = = and d 1 22 / 3 = (w). f (x (w), y (w)) = 1 / 3 dw 3 (p2 1 p2 ) Thus, the increase in the production at the point of maximization with respect to the increase in the value of the inputs equals to the Lagrange multiplier, i.e., the value of represents the rate of change of the optimum value of f as the value of the inputs increases, i.e., the Lagrange multiplier is the marginal product of money. 2.2. Change in inputs. In this subsection, we give a general derivation of the claim for two variables. The general case in n variables is the same, just replacing the sum of two terms by the sum of n terms. The details of the calculation are not important, but notice that is just uses the chain rule and the equations from Lagrange multipliers. By the Chain Rule, f dx f dx d f (x (w)) = (x (w)) 1 (w) + (x (w)) 2 (w). dw x1 dw x2 dw Because the points solve the Lagrange multiplier problem, f g (x (w)) = (w) (x (w)). xi xi Substituting into the previous equation, d g g dx dx 1 2 f (x (w)) = (w) (x (w)) (w) + (w) (x (w)) (w) dw x1 dw x2 dw g dx g dx = (w) (x (w)) 1 (w) + (x (w)) 2 (w) . x1 dw x2 dw Because g (x (w)) = w for all w, 1= d g dx g dx g (x (w)) = (x (w)) 1 (w) + (x (w)) 2 (w). dw x1 dw x2 dw 2w 3p 1
2/ 3

w 3p 2

1/ 3

22/3 1 w, 1/3 3 (p2 1 p2 )

Substituting into the previous equation, d f (x (w)) = (w). dw This proves the desired result. See [1], Section 19.1, for a discussion with more than one constraint. They also interpret the Lagrange multipliers as imputed value or shadow prices of inputs for production.

ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS

3. Rate of Change of Minimal Cost of Production Let Q = F (L, K ) be the production function of a single output in terms of two inputs, labor L and capital K . Let w be the price of labor (wages) and r the price of capital (interest rate). Thus the cost function is (w, r) be the C = wL + rK . Assume the output Q = Q0 is xed and the cost is minimized. Let L = L amount of labor and K = K (w, r) be the amount of capital which realizes this minimum. Dene (w, r) = w L (w, r) + r K (w, r) C be the minimal cost at these values. Shephards Lemma says that C (w0 , r0 ) (w0 , r0 ) = L and w C (w0 , r0 ). (w0 , r0 ) = K r This says that the rate of change of cost with respect to change in wages is equal to the size of the labor force, and does not depend on the change of the size of the labor force or amount of capital. See [2] for a discussion of the economic interpretation.

K0 (w, r) K wL + rK = wL0 + rK0

(w, r) wL + rK = C (w, r) L L0 (w0 , r0 ) and K0 = K (w0 , r0 ) be the size of labor and The derivation is not too difcult. Let L0 = L capital at this minimum for wages w0 and interest rate r0 . We form the function (w, r) w L0 r K0 . g (w, r) = C The terms subtracted involve the changing cost of labor and capital while holding the amounts xed. The (w0 , r0 ) w0 L0 r0 K0 = 0 by the denitions. For (w, r) = (w0 , r0 ), C (w, r) value g (w0 , r0 ) = C (w, r) w L0 + r K0 because (L0 , K0 ) satises the production constraint and the new values L(w, r) and K minimize the cost. Therefore, g (w, r) 0 and g attains its maximum at (w0 , r0 ), so g C (w0 , r0 ) = (w0 , r0 ) L0 w w g C 0= (w0 , r0 ) = (w0 , r0 ) K0 , r r 0= so C (w0 , r0 ) (w0 , r0 ) = L0 = L w C (w0 , r0 ) (w0 , r0 ) = K0 = K r as claimed. and and

ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS

R EFERENCES
[1] C. Simon and L. Blume, Mathematics for Economists, W. W. Norton & Company, New York, 1994 [2] D. Besanko and R. Braeutigam, Microeconomics: An Integrated Approach, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York, 2002.

S-ar putea să vă placă și