Sunteți pe pagina 1din 6

The mixed theoretical and empirical evidence leads to the following two hypotheses:

We examine the association between the quality of private information and cost of equity capital, after
controlling for market beta, earnings growth, firm size, book-to-price and the quality of public
information. We employ separate empirical proxies for the precision of individual analysts private and
public information sets, to capture the quality of private and public information, respectively. Our proxy
for the cost of equity capital is the internal rate of return that equates current stock price to analysts
forecasts of future dividends and target prices

The study most related to our research is Easley, Hvidkjaer, and OHara (EHO) (2002). EHO examine the
association between average realized returns (their proxy for cost of equity capital) and the probability
of information-based trading (PIN) (their proxy for private information), after controlling for market
beta, firm size and book-to-price. While EHO document a strong positive association between PIN and
averaged realized returns, none of the coefficients on their other risk proxies is consistent with
expectations, suggesting that their dependent variable may not be a reliable proxy for cost of equity
capital. Moreover, EHO do not control for cross-sectional differences in public information in their
analysis.
The remainder of our paper is organized as follows. Section 1 develops our hypotheses with reference to
applicable prior research. Our research design and the empirical proxies employed in our analyses are
described in Section 2. Section 3 outlines our sample selection procedures and presents descriptive
statistics pertaining to our sample. The results of our analyses are found in Section 4, and Section 5
concludes the paper and offers suggestions for future research.
We include market beta, growth, firm size, book-to-price, and the precision of public information in our
model to control for sources of risk that could confound our analysis and to validate our proxy for cost
of equity capital. The Capital Asset Pricing Model indicates that cost of equity capital is increasing in
market beta. Accordingly, we expect the coefficient on BETA to be significantly positive. Beaver, Kettler
and Scholes (1970) argue that abnormal earnings streams derived from growth opportunities are more
risky because they are subject to erosion as competition enters the market. This suggests a positive
association between expected long-term earnings growth and cost of equity capital. Berk (1995) argues
that, unless the empirical model for expected returns includes all risk factors, a negative
associationbetween firm size and expected returns should be observed as market value is inversely
associated with risk in general. Accordingly, we expect the coefficient on firm size (measured by the
market value of equity) to be negative. Moreover, Berk (1995) argues that book-to-price inversely
proxies for firm size and, consequently, we expect the coefficient on BP to be positive. Finally, a
relatively large body of research suggests that greater public disclosure is associated with a lower cost of
equity capital through greater liquidity or reduced estimation risk. Thus, we expect the coefficient on
RPUBLIC to be negative.
2.2.2 Market Beta (BETA)
Market beta is estimated using the market model with a minimum of 30 out of 60 monthly returns and a
market index return equal to the value weighted NYSE/AMEX return. We obtain the data to estimate
BETA from CRSP. The estimation period for BETA ends on June 30th of the year rDIVPREM is estimated.
2.2.4 Firm Size (LMKVL)
Our proxy for firm size is the market value of equity. We estimate market value of equity by multiplying
the number of common shares outstanding by stock price at the quarter-end immediately prior to June
30th of the year rDIVPREM is estimated. We draw these data from the quarterly Compustat tape. If
these data are unavailable, we substitute the market value of the firm reported on CRSP as of June 30th
of the Value Line publication year. Market value of equity is stated in millions of dollars. We use a
natural log transformation of the data to mitigate skewness in the distribution of market value of equity.
2.2.3 Book-to-Price (BP)
We compute book-to-price by scaling the common equity of the firm by the market value of equity. Both
the numerator and the denominator of the ratio are measured at the quarter-end immediately prior to
June 30th of the year rDIVPREM is estimated. We collect these data from the quarterly Compustat tape.
If these data are unavailable, we substitute data for the fiscal year-end immediately prior to June 30th of
the year rDIVPREM is estimated. These data are collected from the annual Compustat tape.
Mean (median) BETA for our sample is approximately 1.07 (1.01). These data indicate that our average
sample firm is relatively risky, whereas our median sample firm presents a level of market risk similar to
that of the market portfolio. Mean (median) expected long-term growth in earnings (GROW) is 17.1%
(14.5%). These growth statistics are similar, albeit higher, than the 15.1% mean and 13.7% median long-
term growth in IBES earnings documented by Gode and Mohanram (2002) for an earlier time period.
Mean MKVL is $8225.7 million; the median is $2286.0 million, which indicates a sample populated by
relatively large firms and a skewed distribution. Mean (median) book-to-price (BP) equals 0.45 (0.39).
This indicates that firms trading at a substantial premium above book value characterize our sample.
Consistent with the different theoretical views, the empirical evidence is mixed on the relation
between more frequent disclosures and the cost of equity. Botosan (1997) finds a negative
relation between her self-constructed disclosure index and the firms cost of equity for firms
with low analyst following but not for firms with high analyst following. Botosan and Plumlee
(2002) and Francis et al. (2008) document that the relation between the cost of equity and
voluntary disclosures varies across different disclosure measures. Specifically, Botosan and
Plumlee (2002) find that the cost of equity decreases in the annual report disclosure level but
increases in the quarterly report disclosure level. Their interpretation is that more detailed
quarterly reports attract the attention of transient investors, whose trading activities elevate
the cost of equity by increasing the return volatility. Francis et al. (2008) show that the cost of
equity is negatively related to the disclosure measure based on annual reports and 10-K filings,
positively related to disclosure measures based on management forecasts and conference calls,
and unrelated to press-release based disclosure measures. In sum, the mixed theoretical and
empirical evidence suggests that whether financial reporting frequency affects the cost of
equity remains an intriguing empirical issue.
Botosan and Plumlee (2002)




Froot, Perold and Stein All else being equal, anincrease in volatility leads investors to demand
higher returns from their shares as compensation for the added risk. From the perspective of the
corporation,this translates into a higher cost of capital that must be used when evaluating
prospective investments, thus reducing the aggregate level of investment
Bushee and Noe





Having done so, he is then able to classify institutions into three types: dedicated, transient and
quasi-indexer. Dedicated institutions tend to trade infrequently and hold large positions in a few
firms. Transient institutions are characterized by having small ownership stakes in several firms
and turning over their portfolios frequently. Quasi-indexers hold large well diversified portfolios
and do not trade frequently.
However, Hughes, Liu, and Liu (2007) prove that this result does not hold when the economy
becomes large, as more information may only affect the (aggregate)market premium but not a
rms cost of capital directly. They prove that information about the systematic factor is the
only information priced by the market. Lambert, Leuz, andVerrecchia (2007) derive whether
the presence of additional information in a multi-asset economy would increase or decrease
cost of capital. They nd that a disclosing rm has a lower cost of capital than this same rm in
the economy prior to disclosure; however, after disclosure has occurred, a disclosing rm may
have a higher cost of capital than a rm that did not disclose. Armstrong, Banerjee, and Corona
(2008) also consider a multi-rm model where information quality affects cost of capital
through systematic risk. They show that observed beta and information quality are negatively
related for positive beta stocks but positively related for negative beta stocks. One problem,
noted by Christensen, De la Rosa, and Feltham (2008), is that, if there are no real decisions,
disclosure should only affect the timing of resolution of uncertainty, and thus a commitment to
disclosure does not increase welfare of the manager disclosing or, even, that of investors.
, Banerjee, and Corona (2008) We show that both systematic and rm-specic information
quality decreaseexpected returns for positive beta stocks but increase expected returns for
negative betastocks - this is what we call the beta eect of information quality.

An alternative stream of the literature considers the effects of incomplete, but symmetric,
information on asset prices. Building from Merton (1987), a number of authors (see, e.g., Basak
and Cuoco (1998) and Shapiro (2002, p. 49)) analyze asset pricing when traders can be unaware
of the existence of some assets. In this setting, cross-sectional differences in returns can emerge
simply because traders cannot hold assets they do not know about; the lack of demand for these
unknown assets results in their commanding a higher return in equilibrium.2 T
On the other hand, it is not clear whether the predictions from these single-rm model should
survive in a setup with multiple rms and diversiable risk. In a multi-asset, noise rational
expectations model, Hughes, Liu and Liu (2007) show that information does not have any cross-
sectional eects on the cost of capital. This is because rm-specic information idiversied
away and systematic information aects factor risk-premia but not factor loadings in large
economies. Moreover, other empirical work nds little or no evidence of a negative relation
between cost of capital and information quality. For example, Botosan (1997) nds no evidence
of a relationship between disclosure and the cost of capital for her full sample of rms and only
weak evidence of a negative relationship for the sub-sample of rms with low analyst coverage.
Botosan and Plumlee (2002) show that only the sub-component of AIMR scores related to
annual report disclosures has a modest negative association with the cost of capital. Core, Guay
and Verdi (2008) test Lambert, Leuz and Verrecchias (2007)prediction that asymmetric
information eects should be diversied away, and empirically document that accruals quality
is not a priced risk factor. Similarly, Duarte and Young(2007) decompose the PIN measure into
asymmetric information and liquidity components and show that only the liquidity component
is priced. It is important to note that since information quality is not a priced risk factor in our
model, but aects expected returns through factor loadings, the results in these papers are not
inconsistent with our theoretical predictions or empirical results.
On the other hand, Hughes, Liu and Liu (2005) and Lambert, Leuz and Verrecchia (2005) show
that in a large economy the eect of asymmetric information on expected returns is
diversiable. They argue that asymmetric information is priced in Easley and OHara (2004)
because the number of assets in their model is nite and hence asymmetric information risk
cannot be diversied away. In spite of the fact that private information should be diversiable
in a large economy, empirically a proxy for information asymmetry, PIN, is positively and
signicantly related to average stock returns.
Duarte and Young(2007)
This paper examines whether PIN is priced because of information asymmetry or because of
other liquidity eects that are unrelated to information asymmetry. Our starting point is a
model that decomposes PIN into two components, one related to asymmetric information and
one related to illiquidity. In a two-pass Fama-MacBeth regression, we show that the PIN
component related to asymmetric information is not priced, while the PIN component related
to illiquidity is priced. We conclude, therefore, that liquidity eects unrelated to information
asymmetry explain the relation between PIN and the cross-section of expected returns.
Armstrong, Banerjee, and Corona (2008)
We show that an increase in information quality of either type (systematic or rm-specic) has
two effects on a rms expected re turns: (i) a beta effect which decreases expected returns
when beta is positive, but increases expected returns when beta is negative, and (ii) a
convexity expect which generally increases the expected returns.
Unlike single rm models which generally predict a negative relationship between the two, our
model predicts a non-monotonic relationship between expected returns and information
quality. However somewhat surprisingly, the eect of both types of information quality are
similar. We show that both systematic and rm-specic information quality decrease expected
returns for positive beta stocks but increase expected returns for negative beta stocks - this is
what we call the beta eect of information quality. There is also a direct, convexity eect of
information quality which may increase or decrease expected returns. We show that the
convexity eect of systematic information quality unambiguously increases expected returns,
by lowering aggregate uncertainty and hence increasing the risk-free rate. However, the
convexity eect for rm-specic information quality is positive only when systematic IQ is low,
and negative otherwise.

S-ar putea să vă placă și