Sunteți pe pagina 1din 14

URL: www.hum.au.dk/ckulturf/pages/publications/pfb/antiquity.

htm

This is the electronic edition of Peter Fibiger Bang, Antiquity between


"Primitivism" and "Modernism", Workpaper 53-97, Centre for Cultural
Resarch, University of Aarhus, 1997.

The pagination of the printed edition is indicated by red numbers


marking the beginning of the page.

ISBN: 87-7725-236-5

Electronically published: August 27, 1998

©Peter Fibiger Bang 1988. All rights reserved. This text may be copied
freely and distributed either electronically or in printed form under the
following conditions. You may not copy or distribute it in any other
fashion without express written permission from me. Otherwise I
encourage you to share this work widely and to link freely to it.

Conditions

You keep this copyright notice and list of conditions with any copy you
make of the text.

You keep the preface and all chapters intact.

You do not charge money for the text or for access to reading or copying
it.

That is, you may not include it in any collection, compendium, database,
ftp site, CD ROM, etc. which requires payment or any world wide web
site which requires payment or registration.You may not charge money
for shipping the text or distributing it. If you give it away, these
conditions must be intact.

For permission to copy or distribute in any other fashion, contact


cfk@au.dk

Peter Fibiger Bang

Antiquity between "Primitivism" and "Modernism"

The Revival of "Modernism"[1]

In 1973 the late Cambridge ancient historian Moses Finley published his
pathbreaking book The Ancient Economy. During the 1960s a number of
studies gradually came to show the need for a new overall conception of
the economy of Greco-Roman antiquity. This was what Finley set out to
provide in his book. Thus he revived a debate on the nature of the
Greco-Roman economy which originally took place during the 1890s and
the first decades of this century. At that time the German economist Karl
Bücher had tried to argue that the economy of Antiquity was
fundamentally different from and much less developed than a modern,
capitalist market economy.[2] This caused strong resentment in the field
of classics. The German ancient historian Eduard Meyer conducted the
first wave of attack scornfully dismissing the views of Bücher as
"primitivism". Instead he insisted on a modernizing picture of the
economy of Antiquity stressing its basically modern, capitalist nature.[3]
When the exiled Russian historian Michael Rostovtzeff published his
monumental The Social and Economic History of the Roman Empire in
1926 this "modernist" line of thought received a strong empirical
underpinning. Therefore it managed to achieve a position of almost
complete dominance until some time in the 1960s. Inspired by the old
"primitivist" position Finley now tried to provide an analysis that showed
the Greco-Roman economy to be adverse to the inner principles of
capitalism by emphasizing the conceptual universe of the Ancients
themselves rather than expecting our own way of thinking to be natural
to all men as the "modernists" did.

Finley's book caused something amounting to a revolution within the


field of classical scholarship and stimulated a considerable amount of
new research, especially among scholars with connections to his own
University, Cambridge. In 1983 Keith Hopkins, Finley's successor as
professor in Cambridge, introducing a collection of papers called Trade in
the Ancient Economy and dedicated to Moses Finley, termed the views of
Finley the new orthodoxy.[4] Today, however, this judgement seems a
bit premature. From the very beginning the book received strong
criticism. Martin Frederiksen concluded his Journal of Roman Studies
review by calling Finley's insistence on the use of theoretical models and
idealtypes into question with his carming remark: One may respectfully
suggest that the old laborious methods, of collecting evidence and
interrogating it with an open mind, will remain with us for a longish time
yet.[5] But in recent years the strong criticism seems to have developed
into outright dismissal among large sections of the academe. We are
now beyond the consumer city of Finley a rccently published book edited
by Helen Parkins informs us. Instead of a model, we are offered
(recalling Frederiksen's critique) a jargon free insight ...[and] diverse
approaches ... bringing the Roman city into the nineties.[6]
Consequently terms such as capitalism, modern and industry so
vehemently attacked by Finley have received renewed prominence.

Indeed, this tendency seems to have come to an extreme point as I shall


try to demonstrate by a recent analysis of the Arretine potteries
undertaken by the archaeologist Philip Kenrick. The potteries of Arretium
played a key role in the analysis that M. I. Rostovtzeff presented in his
much influential The Social and Economic History of the Roman Empire.
[7] As mentioned above Rostovtzeff was probably the most important
scholar in the construction of the modernist paradigm that Finley 40 to
50 years later was to discard. However, the tendency of the Arretine
pottery production to be set up in relatively small production units and
later to move to Gaul, conveniently termed decentralization, led
Rostovtzeff to conclude that real industry did not come into existence in
Antiquity. The division of labour simply never developed enough to
render small workshops unprofitable. For Rostovtzeff the break down of
the Arretine terra sigillata production became an important element in
his analysis of the Italian economy of the Early Empire and came to
signify a decline in the Italian economy. Just at the brink of a
breakthrough to a truly modern, industrial economy, the Italian economy
came to a halt and instead began to contract. Thus the economic base of
the Greco-Roman Civilisation was gradually undermined when the same
started to happen in the provinces as they were gradually being
integrated in the imperial economy. Therefore it seems a bit of a
paradox, that Philip Kenrick now argues that exactly this tendency of
decentralisation in the form of setting up of branch workshops in other
cities justifies us in regarding this as an industry in an entirely modern
sense.[8] In other words part of the same characteristic that led one of
the founding fathers of the "modernist" paradigm in ancient economic
history to see a limit in development of a modern economy is now being
evoked in defence of the same "modernist" paradigm. If this appears to
be a bit of a puzzle to some, I shall certainly not protest, for so it does to
me.

This, however, is far from being the only example of puzzling


"modernist" attacks on the Weber inspired models of Finley. The ancient
historian Robin Osborne in Pride and prejudice, sense and subsistence:
exchange and society in the Greek City sets out to prove apparently
against Finley that the Athenian landowning elite certainly depended on
selling the agricultural produce of their estates on the market in Athens
and consequently were interested in profits.[9] This would hardly have
come as a surprise to a man who wrote: Landowners were of course
concerned with the sale of their produce ... Anyone who confuses the
gentlemanliness of agriculture with a disinterest in profits and wealth
closes the door to an understanding of much of the past.[10] For
Osborne, Finley's problem lies in his understanding of Greco-Roman
economic rationality. This has now been further developed by Dominic
Rathbone in Economic Rationalism and Rural Society in third century
Egypt.[11] Following the Finnish historian Gunnar Mickwitz's studies in
the accounting techniques of Antiquity, Finley stressed that we never
encounter an economic rationality in the modern capitalist sense as
Rostovtzeff had held.[12] Contrary to this Rathbone points out that we
do find traces of quite sophisticated accounting systems in the papyri of
the Egyptian desert. It may not have followed all the principles of
capitalist accounting practice but that was because the market system
was too unstable to allow the kind of predictions and comparisons that
modern capitalist accounting demands. Instead their concern...seems to
have been far more with the one crucial element of profitability which
the estate was most able to influence, namely costs of production...
[and] to provide a check against carelessness or dishonesty on the part
of the phrontistai [the managers], a perfectly rational aim in itself.[13]
Allow me to recapitulate their argument albeit polemically, but only for
the sake of clarity. According to these two scholars Finley seems to have
been utterly wrong, nonetheless both in reality conclude that a modern
capitalist approach to investment was not possible. Therefore the
ancients used a different approach focusing on cost control.[14] But this
very same approach was summed up by Finley in Cato's saying: The
pater familias should be a seller not a buyer, exactly in order to control
spending and thus ensure a profit.[15] I must say, the fundamental
conflict eludes me. The difference seems to be a question of details
rather than a matter of principles. Both parties in reality end up in noting
a fundamental difference between a modern capitalist economy and the
ancient one at question.

In a recent paper on mainly Athenian economy this turn away from


"primitivism" is described as a perversity by the the philospher Scott
Meikle.[16] Therefore he proceeds to locate weaknesses in the
"modernist" conception of economy and finds them especially in a too
heavy reliance on neo-classical economic theory. However, this way of
discarting the present failure of "primitivism" as the work of some
perversely unperceptive "modernists" seems to me to be heading in the
wrong direction. It will hardly help to provoke debate with other than the
people all ready adhering to the "primitivist" analysis of the Ancient
Economy. Rather, we need to ask what is it in "primitivism" that fails to
persuade its opponents?

The "Primitivization" of Antiquity

At this stage I would like to point to the fact that "primitivism" is not just
a phenomenon restricted to the debate on the nature of the economy of
Greco-Roman antiquity. Most fields of study within classics have had
their "primitivist" turn. From around 1900 we have seen analyses of the
political life of antiquity stressing the huge differences to modern liberal
democracy with its phocus on alienated rights rather than personal
connections to achieve influence upon the decision making processes. I
am thinking on the huge attention given to clientela in the field of
Roman politics by historians such as Ronald Syme and Mathias Gelzer.
[17] The study of ancient religion too experiences such a turn constantly
reminding us that we cannot grasp phenomena such as the imperial cult
with a modern notion of religion.[18] One of the fields where this
tendency presently seems most outspoken is the field of literary criticism
or classical philology if you wish. One hundred years ago classical
literature was viewed as a means of securing a virtuous education of
young people. Consequently writers such as Petronius was not very
widely read, indeed in the Loeb translation from this period the sexually
most daring parts were not even translated but left in the decent
obscurity of latin - as the translator noted.[19] To deal with such
phenomena one had to visit indigenous people around the world as the
French painter Gaugain did or as the British anthropologist Malinowski,
who later wrote on the liberated sexual life of savages. But today
classical philology abound with studies on sexual matters in Petronius
and in many other writers.

Thus the gap which was perceived between primitive, indigenous people
and Antiquity around 1900 has been gradualy narrowed down in the
course of this century. Indeed, we have even seen attempts at
reinterpreting the estetic heritage of Antiquity as expressed in
neoclassical art and architecture. During the 1920s and 1930s Picasso
incorporated ancient Greek elements in his avantgarde, anti-neoclassicist
pictural language. This was heavily influenced by primitive art from
around the world, perhaps most famous is his Les Demoisselles
D'Avignon painted in 1907 and inspired by African masks. Accordingly it
appears that Picasso's estetic conception of ancient Greek women as in
Femmes à la fontaine from 1921 is closer to the heavy women painted
by Gaugain in Melanesia than the gracious women we find in the art of
for instance the Danish 19th-century sculptor Thorvaldsen.[20] To sum
up. Antiquity has seen numerous attempts at "primitivization". Parallel
we also find examples of the opposite process, that is an "antiquitization"
of primitive peoples. Most instructive, perhaps, is the Corpus
Inscriptionum Agriculturae Quiriviniensis incorporated by Bronislaw
Malinowski in his study of agriculture on the Trobriand Islands Coral
Gardens and their Magic from 1935. The purpose of this was to supply
linguistic material for ethnographical analysis similar to the corpora
preserved from Antiquity. But the contents were not inscriptions found
on these Islands but sayings and native statements recorded by
Malinowski. Therefore the name can better be understood as part of his
program for a New Humanism centered on living man, living language,
and living full-blooded facts contrary to the old Humanism based on the
dead languages of Greek and Latin.[21]

It was precisely such connections between the culture of Greco-Roman


Antiquity and primitive peoples which originaly caused the resistance of
the two founders of the "modernist" position in economic history, Eduard
Meyer and Michael Rostovtzeff. In their mind Antiquity was exactly the
opposite of primitive culture, which to them at best appeared as naive,
simple and childlike.[22] From their point of view the Greeks and
Romans were the great civilizers of history bringing their superior culture
to the various indigenous peoples living within their empires. Indeed,
both Meyer and Rostovtzeff explained the cause of the decline and fall of
the Roman Empire by the ultimate failure of Rome to raise the cultural
level of all her subject peoples to her own high level of civilization. On
the contrary during the third century AD they saw the Roman state being
gradually overtaken by the least civilized people within the Empire and
thus the refined culture of Antiquity was quickly rushed to its end in a
process of barbarization. In other words a comparison with primitive
peoples were not felt to do justice to Antiquity. Brought up in the
bourgeois neoclassicism of the 19th century, they saw that period as the
very model of civilization which therefore could not be connected with its
opposite, the savage peoples of the European colonies around the world.
Thus, rather than being about economic theory I will suggest that the
ongoing debate on Greco-Roman economy might fruitfully be understood
as part of a broader ideological conflict about cultural ideals and
European civilization.

The "defence" of Antiquity

This also seems to be brought out by the way Finley's analysis in The
Ancient Economy was received by his critics. It was often understood as
an attack on Greco-Roman antiquity laying bare deficiencies in the
mental capacities of its inhabitants. This in turn produced remarks such
as Martin Frederiksen's in Journal of Roman Studies: Although our
author is hard on the ancient agronomists and will not believe that their
appeals to local informants are to be taken seriously, it was perhaps
worth reflecting on their later reputations, and why they were read
and imitated for the next fifteen centuries.[23] In other words the
critics view themselves as defending the reputation of antiquity and
perhaps even the myth of the Rennaissance claiming that Antiquity gave
birth to a new flowering European civilization after the "Dark Ages".[24]
At least this seems to be what a new book Inventing Ancient Culture
analyzing Greco-Roman civilization more or less claims to be doing.
Harshly criticizing the "primitivist" point of view in the fields of sexuality,
mentality and the history of feelings, it claims to restore the much
neglected place of Antiquity within modern civilization, seriously
downplaying the importance of the Enligthtenment in the construction of
modernity.[25]

"Primitivism" an "Inverse" Modernism

The Reason to this failure of "primitivism" to cease the day is probably


connected with the European experience of Imperialism. Afterall,
European people mainly encountered the various indigenous populations
in the process of Empire building. There is a certain parallel between the
idea of the Roman Empire civilizing the barbarians and the ideology of
White Man's burden connected with European imperialism.[26] However,
I would suggest that the connection is less straight forward than that -
or perhaps rather has become less straight forward in the course of the
century since Meyer and Rostovtzeff originaly rejected the "primitivist"
position. Today only few people would dare to see the various primitive
cultures brought to our attention by anthropologists as an expression of
barbarism. On the contrary, Europe has lost its empires. Instead it has
adopted many indigenous elements in its culture. As hinted at above, the
whole development of modern art and architecture is completely
unthinkable without the primitive inspiration. In other words primitive
culture has received widespread acceptance and admiration and can, in
fact, at times be seen together with Greek vases in advertisements from
art dealers.[27]

Thus in the light of this apparent success it seems worthwhile to pursue


the question Why has anthropology nevertheless failed to produce a
convincing picture of primitive society or perhaps rather otherness - to
the extent that Antiquity is felt to require defenders? To answer this
question we have to take a closer look on the way anthropology has
presented primitive society. In his pathbreaking The Argonauts of the
Western Pacific from 1922, a study of economic relations on the
Trobriand Islands, one of the founding fathers of modern anthropology,
B. Malinowski revealed an economic system completely foreign to a
capitalist economy based as it was on gift giving rather than
disinterested exchange. However, taking a closer look on his book
reveals that gift giving was far from the only kind of exchange. Indeed,
trade proper did in fact play an important role, but was only superficially
included in his analysis of the economic system. Thus Malinowski himself
seems to have been a victim of the temptation of "curio-hunting" that he
claimed to have substituted with an anlysis of the complete cultural
system of societies.

The consequence of this can be glanced from Marcell Mauss's famous


essay on The Gift first published in the middle of the 1920s. Using the
results of Malinowski he put forward a general theory of the gift.
Insisting that the modern conception of gifts as disinterested objects
given free of attachments was but an ideology, he claimed that all gift
giving builds upon an expectation of reciprocity or, in short, the principle
do ut des. Nonetheless he concluded his essay with a long chapter that
might polemically be termed an eulogy of the disinterested gift. Thus he
ends up by emphasizing the potential of giftgiving to create a stronger
sense of community in Western society otherwise dominated by the
alienation of capitalism - that is to move from gesellschaft to
gemeinschaft. This somewhat romanticizing program using primitive
societies to criticise modern Western society can be found in almost
every prominent anthropologist of this century. In the works of Karl
Polanyi, who was a major source of inspiration to Finley, we find the
same quest for an alternative to capitalism.[28] It is also what seems to
be lying at the core of Levi-Strauss's famous split between warm,
dynamic, constantly changing modern societies and cold, primitive,
static, traditional societies. Of course, the latter type was to be preferred
as it provided a more human environment.[29] Another quite famous
example is the Chicago based anthropologist Marshall Sahlins's
provoking book Stone Age Economics which appeared in 1972. In that
book he proposed to view the hunter/gatherer type of society as the
original affluent society and the Zen road to affluence in strong
opposition to modern, Western comsumer capitalism.[30] Especially
during the decolonization of the 1960s and 70s this program of anti-
Western gemeinschaft was radicalised under the term Tiersmondism,
perhaps best known from the writings of Jean Paul Satre completely
rejecting the Western cultural tradition.[31] However, today it is clear
that this program was as much part of Western culture as the tradition
which it criticised. As I have tried to show it was not just an investigation
of other, foreign cultures. It was as much, and perhaps even more, an
attempt at establishing a completely opposite alternative to modern
capitalism. In other words an "inverse" modernism, rather than an
analysis of otherness.

From "Primitivism" to Otherness

Some valuing those of their own side or mind,

Still make themselves the measure of mankind:

Fondly we think we honour merit then,

When we but praise ourselves in other men.

Alexander Pope, An Essay on Criticism: 452-55

Today where the West seems to have recuperated from the shock of
decolonization we start again to find people arguing confidently for the
values of modern, Western, liberal democracy. It has increasingly
become clear, that the salvation of the world will not come from the third
world. Indeed, the Tiersmondist dream seems completely shattered as it
has become connected with regimes such as that of the murderous Pol
Pot, killing millions under the disguise of the blessings of traditional
society and gemeinschaft.[32]

However, it is not just people traditionally adherring to Western values


who have rejected "primitivism". Surprisingly even among analysists
claiming to represent the 3rd World "primitivism" is under heavy attack.
From the late 70s onwards we have seen a number of analyses arguing
that the "inverse" modernism of "primitivism" was just as ethnocentrist
as the "modernism" it claimed to replace.[33] In his notorious analysis
Orientalism the English-Palestinian literary critic Eduard Said has tried to
show that the European phocus on the radical otherness of foreign
cultures resulted not in a respect for the particular features of each
individual culture, but rather in an ahistoric category of traditional
societies grouping large, extremely complex civilizations such as the
Chinese alongside the more simple and small societies traditionally the
object of anthropology such as Melanesia. In Europe and the People
without History published in 1982 the anthropologist Eric Wolf has
convincinly argued that there is no such thing as traditional, static
society - this idea is but a projection of European dreams of the noble
savage, or gemeinschaft as we have just termed it. Instead, he argues,
cultures are bound to change and develop, constantly under the
influence of mutual interaction.

Bringing our discussion back to Finley's The Ancient Economy we are


know able to locate the weaknesses of "primitivism" in his analysis.
Delineating his program of analysis in the first chapter he made it quite
clear that The Ancient Economy first and foremost was an attempt to
understand Antiquity on its own terms. Thus when Finley noted that
Antiquity did not produce economic analysis in our sense of the word it
was not meant to lay bare an intellectual failing, rather he wanted to
highlight that the ancient people had other goals and interests hence the
famous emphasis on status and economic mentalities. To judge them on
modern standards rested on a fundamental misconception of what these
writings were about.[34] Nonetheless his book is full of many remarks
on the primitiveness of the Greco-Roman world compared to a modern,
capitalist economy. The reason to this, I would suggest, must be found
in the unfortunate bi-polar split between primitive, traditional societies
and modern societies, which we have seen dominate Western discourse
on the other.

The big question now is, what consequences should we draw from this?
The critics of "primitivism" seems to wish to go back to a basically
"modernist" frame of analysis. However, this just seems to turn the
discussion up-side-down once more and cannot really be said to do
justice to the cultures in question as the small citation from Pope at the
beginning of this chapter should remind us. Moreover, it fails to
appreciate a basic experience of the European colonizers. They went out
expecting their own prejudices and conceptions of how the world
functioned to be universally valid. But it quickly appeared that this was
far from being the case. On the contrary doing it the European way often
turned out to be impossible as the numerous complaints about lazy
native workers suggest. In fact, they were not lazy. They just saw no
point in working in a system dominated by European values which meant
nothing to them.[35] In the field of Antiquity such a return to
"modernism" would equally ignore the "primitivist" scholars' observation
of many phenomena, which seem incomprehensible within a modern,
European frame of thinking.

Today these discoveries of the far from universal scope of European


culture and economy receive strong support from the research on the
rise of modern capitalism. Increasingly it becomes clear, that capitalism
far from being a natural occurrence of humanity seems to have come
about by a bit of a coincidence. In other words capitalism seems the
exception rather than the rule.[36] This should make us open to
recognise impressive achievements in other historical societies without
having to resort to capitalism as the explanation. Indeed, the experience
of our century has given us a prime example of that other systems might
be able to produce impressive material achievements. The communist
economy of the Soviet Union managed to industrialise the agrarian
Russian empire and make it one of the two atomic super powers just
about 30 years after its complete collapse in World War I. Thus the huge
agrarian civilizations/empires with material cultures equally impressing
as that of Greco-Roman Antiquity may perhaps form a better area of
comparative analysis than early modern capitalism. None of them
managed to produce an industrial breakthrough, just as Antiquity failed
to do. Nonetheless they were able to put up a breathtaking performance.
Using these cultures as our point of reference may in the end help us to
achieve a better understanding of The Ancient Economy and allow us to
move beyond the debate between "primitivism" and "modernism". In
fact, Antiquity was neither, it was just different. We might call this a
move from "primitivsim" to historical otherness.

Bibliography

Bernal, M. (1987): Black Athena. The Afroasiatic Roots of Classical


Civilization, The Fabrication of Ancient Greece, 1785-1985, Vol. 1,
London.

Boserup, Ester (1965): The Conditions of Agricultural Growth, Chicago.

Bücher, K. (1911): Die Entstehung der Volkswirtschaft, 8th ed. (1893)


Tübingen.

- (1922) "Zur griechischen Wirtschaftsgeschichte", in K. Bücher:


Beiträge zur Wirtschaftsgeschichte, Tübingen, pp. 1-97.

Carrier, J. (ed.) (1995): Occidentalism. Images of the West, Oxford.

Enzensberger, H. (1990):Vanvittig Normal. Fem Essays, Copenhagen.

Finkielkraut, A. (1988): The Undoing of Thought (La Défaite de la


Pensée), London.

Finley, M. I. (1954): The World of Odysseus, New York.

- (1965) "Technical Innovation and Economic Progress in the Ancient


World", Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 18, pp. 29-45.

- (1970) "Aristotle and Economic Analysis", Past & Present, XLVII, pp. 3-
25.

- (1985) The Ancient Economy, 2nd ed. (1973) London.

Frederiksen, M.(1975): "Evidence and Models" (review of Finley 1973),


Journal of Roman Studies, pp. 164-175.
Fukuyama, F. (1992): The End of History and the Last Man, New York.

Gellner, E. (1988): Plough, Sword and Book, Chicago.

Gelzer, M. (1912): Die Nobilität der römischen Republik, Berlin.

Golden, M. & Toohey, P.(1997): Inventing Ancient Culture, London.

Harris, W. (1993): "Between Archaic and Modern", in W. Harris (ed.):


The Inscribed Economy, Journal of Roman Archaeology Supplementary
Series 6, pp. 11-29.

Haskell, T. & Teichgraeber III, R. (eds.) (1993): The Culture of the


Market. Historical Essays, Cambridge.

Hopkins, Keith (1983): "Introduction", in Garnsey, Hopkins & Whittaker


(eds.): Trade in the Ancient Economy, Cambridge.

Kenrick, Ph. (1993): "Italian Terra Sigillata: A Sophisticated Roman


Industry", Oxford Journal of Archaeology, Vol. 12, no. 2, pp. 235-242.

Lévi-Strauss, Claude (1962): La Pensée Sauvage, Paris.

Malinowski, B. (1922): Argonauts of the Western Pacific, London.

- (1935) Coral Gardens and Their Magic, Vol. I-II, New York.

Mattingly, D. (ed.) (1997): Dialogues in Roman Imperialism, Journal of


Roman Archaeology, Supplementary Series, no. 26, Porthmouth.

Mauss, M. (1990): The Gift (Essai sur le Don), trans. W. D. Halls,


London.

McNeill, W. (1980): The Human Condition, Princeton.

Meikle, S. (1995): "Modernism, Economics and the Ancient Economy",


Proceedings of the Cambridge Philological Society, 41.

Meyer, E. (1924): "Die Wirtschaftliche Entwicklung des Altertums", in E.


Meyer: Kleine Schriften, Vol. 1, Halle (2nd ed.), pp. 79-168.

Mickwitz, G. (1937): "Economic Rationalism in Greco-Roman


Agriculture", The English Historical Review 52, pp. 577-89.

Mørk, S. (1990): Civilisationen, Copenhagen.

Nippel, W. (1990): Griechen, Barbaren und "Wilde". Alte Geschichte und


Sozialanthropologie, Frankfurt am Main.

Obeysekere, G. (1992): The Apotheosis of Captain Cook. European


Mythmaking in the Pacific, Princeton.
Osborne, R. (1991): "Pride and Prejudice, Sense and Subsistence:
Exchange and Society in the Greek City", in A. Wallace-Hadrill & J. Love
(eds.): City and Country in the Ancient World, London, pp. 119-145.

Parkins, Helen (ed.) (1997): Roman Urbanism. Beyond the Consumer


City, London.

Petronius (1913): Petronius with an English translation by Michael


Hesseltine, The Loeb Classical Library, New York.

Picasso og Middelhavet, Louisiana Revy, 37. årgang nr. 1, September


1996.

Polanyi, K., Arensberg, C. & Pearson, H. (1957): Trade and Market in the
Early Empires, New York.

Price, Simon (1984): Rituals and Power. The Roman Imperial Cult in Asia
Minor, Cambridge.

Rathbone, D. (1991): Economic Rationalism and Rural Society in Third-


Century A.D. Egypt, Cambridge.

Rostovtzeff, M. (1957): The Social and Economic History of the Roman


Empire, 2nd ed. (1926) Oxford.

Sahlins, Marshall (1972): Stone Age Economics, Chicago.

- (1995) How "Natives" Think: About Captain Cook, For Example,


Chicago.

Said, E. (1978): Orientalism, Harmondsworth.

Satre, Jean-Paul (1961): Preface in Franz Fanon: Les damnés de la


terre, Paris 1961.

Stocking Jr., George W. (1995): After Tylor. British Social Anthropology


1888-1951, London.

Syme, R. (1939): The Roman Revolution, Oxford.

Wolf, Eric (1982): Europe and the People without History, Los Angeles.

østergård, U. (1991): Akropolis - Persepolis Tur/Retur,


Hellenismeforskningen mellem orientalisme, hellenisme, imperialisme og
afkoloniailsering, Aarhus.

østerud, ø. (1987): Det moderne statssystem, Oslo.


Notes

[1] This is a slightly modified version of a paper presented first at the


conference Reception of Antiquity in a Post-industrial Age, at Sandbjerg
Manor-house 18-20 September 1997 under the auspices of the Centre
for the Study of Antiquity, University of Aarhus and later on thursday 25
September at The Centre for Cultural Research, University of Aarhus as
part of a lecturing series on Europe and the Other Civilizations.

[2] Bücher 1911 & 1922.

[3] Meyer 1924.

[4] Hopkins 1983: ix-xv summarises Finley's.

[5] Frederiksen 1975:171.

[6] The book in question is: Helen Parkins (ed.): Roman Urbanism.
Beyond The Consumer City, Routledge 1997. The citation is taken from
the cover which reflects the expectations of the publisher about what
may interest the scholarly audience right now.

[7] Rostovtzeff 1957, especially pp. 70-105.

[8] Kenrick 1993:46.

[9] Osborne 1991

[10] Finley 1985:58 and restated in the extra chapter of the 1985
edition called `Further thoughts' on page 188-189.

[11] Rathbone 1991: Chapter 8, p. 334: quite sophisticated, & pp. 370-
71 for cost cutting

[12] Mickwitz 1937 and especially Finley 1965, but also 1985:110-111,
116-117 & 180-181.

[13] Rathbone 1991:370-71. In the interest of truth it should be


mentioned that besides this primary objective of the accounting system,
Rathbone 1991:369 does hold that profitability analysis probably was
undertaken on the basis of the accounts, although direct evidence is
lacking [SIC!]. Furthermore, even the possibility of such accounting can
only be maintained in a restricted sense as far from all costs are included
(381-84). Although Rathbone desperately discards this problem by
introducing a distinction between significant and unimportant costs (373)
he ends up concluding that the weak market conditions rendered a
capitalist accounting system impossible. Then what was the purpose of
his long analytical ecxercise?

[14] Some may hold that utterly is too strong a word. Nonetheless
Rathbone 1991: 331 does present his analysis as running counter to
Finley and Osborne 1991: 136-140 writes: The claim being made
here...contrasts markedly with the picture painted by Finley.

[15] Finley 1985:109.

[16] Meikle 1995: 41.

[17] Syme 1939 and Gelzer 1912 remain "classics" in this field of
research.

[18] Prominent in this field is the Oxford professor Simon Price with his
Rituals and Power. The Roman Imperial Cult in Asia Minor, Cambridge
1984. The Danish archaeologist Itai Gradell, whose Ph.d. dissertation is
soon to appear on Oxford University Press, also deserves mentioning.

[19] Petronius with an English translation by Michael Hesseltine, The


Loeb Classical Library, New York 1913 p. xvi in the translator's
introduction.

[20] The catalogue, published in connection with the large excebition


Picasso and the Mediterra nean at the Danish museum of modern art,
Louisiana in the autum of 1996, clearly documents the connection
between a primitive estetics and Antiquity in the art of Picasso. See
Picasso og Middelhavet, Louisiana Revy, 37. årgang, nr. 1, september
1996.

[21] Stocking Jr 1995: 267. Malinowski already presented his ideas in


Argonauts of the Western Pacific from 1922 on pp. 22-24.

[22] e.g. Meyer p. 146 & 158-160.

[23] Frederiksen 1975:169, the accentuation is mine.

[24] The comment in Harris 1993 p. 25 "But Columella has in turn been
defended" is symptomatic.

[25] Golden & Toohey 1997: 13-15 and most outspoken in the
contributions of Amy Richlin and Peter Toohey.

[26] Only recently have we seen a growing awareness of the influence of


19th century European imperialism on the field of classical studies thus
østergård 1991 on the Hellenist empires, Mattingly 1997 on the Roman
Empire. Bernal's Black Athena too is an example of this new approach.

[27] E.g. in the advertisement for Antiquities and Tribal Art at Phillips, in
Apollo. The International Magazine of the Arts, July 1996 p. 15.

[28] Nippel pp. 124-151 and Haskel & Teichgraeber pp. 4-8 clearly show
the importance of Polanyi's hostility towards capitalism to his analytical
project. Finley: The World of Odysseus from 1954 is the book most
clearly influenced by Polanyi's concepts.

[29] Lévi-Strauss 1962, especially chapters 8 and 9, illustrates my point


neatly with numerous comments displaying a certain nostalgia for the
inalienated world of la pensée sauvage.

[30] Sahlins 1972: The title of chapter one and page 2.

[31] E.g in his preface to Franz Fanon: Les damnés de la terre, Paris
1961. østergård 1991 pp 39-49 & østerud 1987 pp. 203-215 for an
analysis of tiersmondism.

[32] Thus for instance Hans Magnus Enzensberger in Germany, Alain


Finkielkraut in France, Francis Fukuyama in USA and in Denmark Søren
Mørch.

[33] In addition to the works discussed in the text the Sri Lankan
anthropologist Gananath Obeysekere deserves mentioning. In The
Apotheosis of Captain Cook he vehemently attacks the understanding of
Capt. Cook's encounter with Hawaiian culture proposed by Marshall
Sahlins, the above mentioned analysist of the original affluent society.
He views Sahlins' insistence that the Hawaiians perceived Cook as one of
their gods as a result of a Western ethnocentrism falsely believing that
non-Western peoples perceive of things in a way different from Western
culture. Sahlins 1995 is a reply.

[34] Finley 1985:21. More specifically on Aristotle's lacking economic


analyses Finley 1970.

[35] This observation was at the core of the Danish economist Ester
Boserup's pathbreaking study The Conditions of Agricultural Growth,
Chicago 1965. See further Malinowski 1922: 58 & 156- 157.

[36] Conveniently summarised by Gellner 1988 and McNeill 1980

S-ar putea să vă placă și