Sunteți pe pagina 1din 17

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)
P1: KUV
10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.070204.105121

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006. 9:11125


doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.9.070204.105121
c 2006 by Annual Reviews. All rights reserved
Copyright
First published online as a Review in Advance on Dec. 12, 2005

WHAT AFFECTS VOTER TURNOUT?


Andre Blais

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

Department of Political Science, Universite de Montreal, Montreal PQ H3C 3J7,


Canada; email: andre.blais@umontreal.ca

Key Words

institutions, electoral systems, party systems, closeness

Abstract Why is turnout higher in some countries and/or in some elections than
in others? Why does it increase or decrease over time? To address these questions,
I start with the pioneer studies of Powell and Jackman and then review more recent
research. This essay seeks to establish which propositions about the causes of variations
in turnout are consistently supported by empirical evidence and which ones remain
ambiguous. I point out some enigmas and gaps in the field and suggest directions for
future research. Most of the research pertains to established democracies, but analyses
of nonestablished democracies are also included here.

INTRODUCTION
The dominant view in the literature is that the existing research on voter turnout
has established some robust patterns, that we know relatively well why turnout
is higher in some countries than in others, and that the main factors that affect
variations in turnout are institutional variables. My verdict is different. Many of
the findings in the comparative cross-national research are not robust, and when
they are, we do not have a compelling microfoundation account of the relationship.
And the impact of institutional variables may be overstated.

THE PIONEER STUDIES


The study of voter turnout started with Powells (1982) award-winning book,
Contemporary Democracies, which posited electoral participation as one of the
three main indicators of democratic performance, and two American Political
Science Review articles by Powell (1986) and Jackman (1987).
Powells APSR article examined mean turnout in 17 countries in the 1970s. He
found turnout to be higher in countries with nationally competitive districts and
strong party-group linkages. Nationally competitive districts enhance turnout
because parties and voters have equal incentive to get voters to the polls in all
parts of the country (Powell 1986, p. 21), and vote choice is simpler when and
where groups (e.g., unions, churches, professional associations) are clearly associated with specific parties (Powell 1986, p. 22). Powells main conclusion is that
1094-2939/06/0615-0111$20.00

111

6 Apr 2006 15:59

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

112

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

BLAIS

American turnout is inhibited by its institutional context, and the main emphasis
is on party-group linkages, which is the most powerful variable in his model.
Jackmans (1987) article followed in the same spirit, with an even stronger emphasis on institutions. Jackman looks at mean turnout in 19 countries in the 1970s,
and he comes out with much cleaner results, showing that five institutional variables affect turnout: nationally competitive districts, electoral disproportionality,
multipartyism, unicameralism, and compulsory voting.
Jackman was inspired by Powells work, but the specific set of variables he retained was different. Most importantly, Powells main factor, party-group linkage,
was left out, because it was found to have no systematic effect. It was Jackmans
set of variables that defined the research agenda.
A number of comments can be made about Jackmans study. First, although
the emphasis is on institutional factors, one of themthe number of parties
should be considered as the consequence of the institutional context. Second,
two variablesnational competitive districts and electoral disproportionality
are aspects of the electoral system. They are correlated with each other (larger
districts produce more proportional outcomes), and it is not clear why the two
should be incorporated into the same model. Third, Jackmans analysis does not
include any socioeconomic variable. A fuller model should integrate the role of
the socioeconomic environment.
Powells 1982 book considers a greater array of countries, 29 in total, although
the analysis of turnout is restricted to 23 cases. His model distinguishes three blocs
of variables: the social and economic environment, the constitutional setting (institutions in the strict sense of the term), and party systems and election outcomes.
In his final path analysis model (figure 6.1, p. 121), Powell (1982) identifies four
significant variables: one socioeconomic (gross national product per capita), two
constitutional (proportional representation and mobilizing voting laws), and one
party system (party-group linkage).
Powells sequential model, which identifies a distant set of variables (socioeconomic), an intermediate set (institutions), and more proximate factors (party
systems and election outcomes), seems quite useful. I review the evidence on the
effects of these three types of factors, beginning with the impact of institutions,
which has been the focus of most research.

THE IMPACT OF INSTITUTIONS


Jackman identifies three institutions that appear to foster turnout: compulsory
voting, the electoral system, and unicameralism. Other institutional variables have
also been proposed.

Compulsory Voting
Jackman (1987) estimates that compulsory voting increases turnout by about 13
percentage points. This pattern has been confirmed by every study of turnout in
western democracies, and the magnitude of the estimated impact is almost always

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

WHAT AFFECTS TURNOUT?

113

around 10 to 15 points (Blais & Carty 1990; Blais & Dobrzynska 1998; Franklin
1996, 2004; Blais & Aarts 2005). Compulsory voting increases turnout can be
construed as a well-established proposition.
This raises more questions. Must compulsory voting legislation be accompanied
by sanctions in order to be efficient? What kinds of sanctions are more prone to
induce recalcitrant citizens to go to the polls? How tough must these sanctions
be? How strictly must they be enforced? The literature provides precious little to
answer these questions.
Perhaps there is more to be learned from the experience of nonestablished
democracies. Norris (2002) finds that compulsory voting increases turnout only
in older democracies, and she speculates that the law may be enforced less
strictly elsewhere or that its impact is conditional on the presence of broader norms
about the desirability of obeying the law. Fornos et al. (2004) develop a four-point
compulsory voting scale, and they report a strong impact of compulsory voting
on turnout in Latin America, the region with the highest frequency of compulsory
voting laws. They do not sort out, however, the specific contribution of sanctions
and their degree of enforcement. Finally, Blais et al. (2003) examine the effect
of compulsory voting with and without sanctions in their sample of 61 countries,
covering both established and new democracies. They find that compulsory voting
makes a difference only when there are sanctions (they do not examine the effect
of enforcement).
In summary, we know that compulsory voting increases turnout and that its
impact depends on its enforcement. But we do not know how strict that enforcement must be in order to work. We know nothing about the publics awareness
and perceptions of the law and its implementation. And there are no comparative
analyses of the determinants of turnout in countries with and without compulsory
voting. This is an unfortunate state of affairs. If a sense of duty is a crucial motivation for voting (Blais 2000), most people should be predisposed to vote, and
loosely enforced, light fines should be sufficient to produce a high turnout. And
according to rational choice, the factors that shape the decision to vote or not to
vote should be very different when there is a concrete financial cost associated with
abstention. In short we know nothing about the microfoundations of compulsory
voting (Achen 2002, but see Bilodeau & Blais 2005).

Electoral System
Jackman (1987) finds that turnout is higher in systems with nationally competitive
districts, the reason being that in large districts parties have an incentive to mobilize
everywhere while some single-member districts may be written off as hopeless.
Jackmans four-category ordinal variable takes into account the electoral formula and the size of the districts. Further research has utilized either the same
variable, or dummy variables that distinguish electoral formulas, or a summary
disproportionality index (also included by Jackman). Studies that have been confined to advanced democracies (Blais & Carty 1990, Jackman & Miller 1995,
Franklin 1996, Radcliff & Davis 2000) as well as one study of turnout in postcommunist countries (Kostadinova 2003) have confirmed that turnout is higher in

6 Apr 2006 15:59

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

114

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

BLAIS

proportional representation (PR) and/or larger districts, whereas research dealing


with Latin America reports no association (Perez-Lina n 2001, Fornos et al. 2004),
and an analysis that incorporates both established and non-established democracies concludes that the electoral system has a weak effect (Blais & Dobrzynska
1998). See Blais & Aarts (2005) for a more detailed review of these studies.
There are two possible interpretations of the available evidence. The more
optimistic view is that PR increases turnout except perhaps in Latin America, a
region where there is some dose of proportionality in every country. The more
pessimistic view is that once one moves outside Europe there is no generalized
correlation between the electoral system and turnout. I lean toward the second,
more skeptical position. On the one hand, the study by Fornos et al. (2004) that
comes up with negative results in Latin America is at least as methodologically
sophisticated as research on established democracies. On the other hand, as I
indicate below when discussing the impact of the party system, those studies that
come up with positive results have failed to specify how and why PR fosters turnout.

Unicameralism
Jackmans (1987) last key institutional variable is unicameralism. He shows that
turnout is significantly higher in countries where power is concentrated in one
legislature. The reason is that, when there are two chambers, power is usually
shared between the two and elections for the lower house play a less decisive role
in the production of legislation where bicameralism is strong (Jackman 1987,
p. 408). The more powerful the body that is being elected, the stronger the incentive
to vote. We would expect turnout to be particularly low when and where the
legislature has little power. Jackman uses a scale [proposed by Lijphart (1984)]
with the highest score for unicameral countries and the lowest score for countries
in which the upper house is as powerful as the lower house.
Jackman focused on the division of power between the lower and upper houses,
but the same rationale should apply to the division of power between the president
and the legislature, between the central government and subnational (or supranational) governments, or between the government and the courts. The general
proposition is that the more powerful the body that is being elected, the higher the
turnout.
Surprisingly perhaps, the findings about the impact of unicameralism on turnout
are mixed. Positive results are reported by Jackman (1987), Jackman & Miller
(1995), and Fornos et al. (2004). However, Blais & Carty (1990), Black (1991),
Radcliff & Davis (2000), and Perez-Lina n (2001) indicate no effect. Siaroff &
Merer (2002) find support for the hypothesis that turnout is lower where there is a
relevant directly elected president and where there are strong regional governments. Blais & Carty (1990) and Black (1991) indicate that turnout is not higher
in federated countries. All in all, the studies that have looked at specific indicators
of the relative power of lower chambers relative to other institutions have not systematically confirmed the conventional wisdom that turnout is higher where the
lower chamber has greater leverage.

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

WHAT AFFECTS TURNOUT?

115

Perhaps what is needed is a summary measure of the power of national lower


houses that takes these many dimensions into account. Blais & Dobrzynska (1998)
created an electoral decisiveness scale that considers the presence or absence
of subnational elections in federations, upper house direct elections in bicameral
countries, and presidential direct elections. They find a strong positive correlation
with turnout, but their results have not been replicated.
Franklin (2004) pays close attention to parliamentary responsibility in his account of turnout change in established democracies. Franklins main concern is to
explain why turnout increases or decreases over time in different countries. His key
variable is competitiveness, which I consider below. He also argues that turnout
in legislative elections increases when parliamentary responsibility increases, and
that it decreases when parliamentary responsibility is weakened. The former is
exemplified by Malta gaining independence in the 1960s and decisions of the legislature no longer being subject to ratification by a British appointed governor.
The creation of a government cartel in Switzerland after the 1960s, which made
elections meaningless, is an illustration of the latter.
It is hard to believe that turnout is unaffected by the salience of an institution.
Yet the empirical evidence on that question is ambiguous. The challenge is to come
up with reliable scales that encompass the different dimensions of salience. The
measures used in the extant research are not very satisfactory.

Other Institutional Variables


At least two other institutional factors have been shown to affect turnout: voting
age and rules designed to facilitate voting. It is a well-established fact that the
propensity to vote increases with age (Wolfinger & Rosenstone 1980, Blais 2000),
and so we would expect turnout to be lower when the voting age is 18 instead of
21. Research that examines turnout in contemporary advanced democracies does
not incorporate that variable for the simple reason that the voting age is now 18
almost everywhere (Massicotte et al. 2004), and there is thus no variation.
Blais & Dobrzynska (1998), whose sample of elections starts in the 1970s, do
include a voting age variable and they find a relatively strong effect; their results
suggest that lowering the voting age from 21 to 18 reduces turnout by five points.
Voting age is also a key factor in Franklins (2004) study of turnout dynamics. He
estimates that the lowering of the voting age in most democracies has produced a
turnout decline of about three percentage points.
The evidence on the effect of vote-facilitating rules is more limited and ambiguous. Franklins (1996) initial analysis suggests that turnout is higher when
voting takes place on Sunday, so that people presumably have more time to go to
the polling station, and when postal (absentee) voting is available. But these same
variables proved incapable of predicting changes in turnout over time (Franklin
2004). Norris (2002) examines the effect of specific rules (number of polling days,
polling on rest day, postal voting, proxy voting, special polling booths, transfer
voting, and advance voting), and she finds no significant effect. Blais et al. (2003)
created a summary scale that reflects the presence or absence of postal, advance,

6 Apr 2006 15:59

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

116

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

BLAIS

and proxy voting, and they find a rather strong positive association between the
presence of such voting facilities and turnout.
It makes sense to assume that people are more prone to vote if it is easy. Gimpel
& Schucknecht (2003), in particular, have shown that turnout is affected by the
accessibility of the ballot box. Likewise, there is strong evidence that allowing
voters to vote by mail increases turnout (Southwell 2004, Rallings & Thrasher
2006). The question is not whether voting facilities influence turnout but rather
which ones matter most, and how great a difference they make. In order to correctly
address these questions we need more accurate measures of these voting facilities
over time and across countries, which means that we need to know not only whether
such facilities exist but also how easy it is to use them. We also need to take into
account the endogeneity of election laws; measures to facilitate the vote may be
more likely to be adopted in countries where turnout is low or declining (Franklin
2004, p. 148). This is no easy task. For the time being, the verdict must be that we
know little about how much difference these rules make.

Conclusions
The primary focus of cross-national studies of turnout has been on the impact
of institutional variables. That impetus was shaped in good part by Jackmans
influential article. The general perception in the field (and, I must confess, my own
perception before I re-examined the evidence more closely in preparation for this
article) is that cross-national differences in turnout can be relatively well explained
by institutional variables. The perception is that we have come up with a number
of well-established propositions about how institutions influence turnout.
That perception may not be well founded. We can safely assert that compulsory
voting increases turnout, but we do not know whether a very light sanction suffices
and whether that sanction needs to be enforced. Most of the literature supports the
view that PR fosters turnout, but there is no compelling explanation of how and why,
and the pattern is ambiguous when the analysis moves beyond well-established
democracies. Many studies support the common-sense proposition that turnout
increases with the saliency of the election, but many studies report no effect. I find
it hard not to believe that turnout is higher when and where it is relatively easy to
vote, yet the empirical evidence on the effect of voting facilities is inconsistent.
All in all, our understanding of the impact of institutions on turnout is shaky.

THE SOCIOECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT


We know that at the individual level the propensity to vote is associated with a number of sociodemographic characteristics, particularly age and education (Wolfinger
& Rosenstone 1980, Blais 2000). It would be natural to assume, in the same vein,
that cross-national variations in turnout are associated with socioeconomic differences between countries. Powell (1982) considers the impact of the socioeconomic

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

WHAT AFFECTS TURNOUT?

117

environment and finds that turnout does tend to be higher in more economically
developed countries. He also reports that turnout tends to be higher in smaller
nations, but the relationship is not statistically significant.
The most influential analyses thereafter have neglected this line of inquiry (see
especially Jackman 1987 and Franklin 1996, 2004), perhaps because they deal with
a small number of established democracies among which there is little variance in
the level of economic development. There is, however, relatively strong support for
the hypothesis that turnout is higher in economically advanced countries (Blais &
Dobrzynska 1998, Norris 2002, Fornos et al. 2004). The relationship is not linear,
the main difference being between the poorest countries and all others (Blais &
Dobrzynska 1998).
This raises the question of whether turnout increases or decreases with downturns in the economy. As Radcliff (1992) points out, both effects are possible;
economic hardship may induce people to mobilize to redress grievances, but it
may also lead them to withdraw entirely from the political process. Given these
two contradictory possibilities, the most likely outcome is a nil overall effect,
and this is precisely what most studies report (Arcelus & Meltzer 1975, Blais &
Dobrzynska 1998, Blais 2000, Kostadinova 2003, Fornos et al. 2004; for an
exception see Rosenstone 1982).
Radcliff (1992) argues that economic downturns increase turnout at high and
low levels of welfare spending but depress it at intermediate levels. However,
some of the findings are perplexing (Blais 2000, p. 34), and they have failed to be
replicated (Jackman & Miller 1995, Appendix B, note 3). The conclusion must be
that there is no clear relationship between the economic conjuncture and turnout.
In my own research, I have been struck by the fact that the highest levels of
turnout are reported in small countries such as Malta (Blais & Carty 1990. Blais &
Dobrzynska 1998). The real difference is between very small countries and all others, and the pattern is less clear at the subnational level (see Blais 2000, p. 59). The
same pattern has been observed at the local level (Oliver 2000). I have speculated
that this might result from stronger social networks in smaller communities, but that
hypothesis is inconsistent with the absence of a correlation between turnout and
urbanization [see Siaroff & Merer 2002, Fornos et al. 2004; Kostadinova (2003)
reports a negative correlation but it is quite weak]. Another interpretation is that
voters are more likely to feel that their vote could be decisive in a small country.
Still another interpretation, and the one I find the most plausible (although it is contradicted by Rose 2004), is that smaller countries have fewer electors per elected
member, which makes it easier for candidates and parties to mobilize the vote.
Not surprisingly, political scientists have paid closer attention to the impact
of institutions than to the effect of the socioeconomic environment. Still, extant
research shows that turnout is substantially lower in poor countries and exceptionally high in exceptionally small countries. Few other consistent patterns have
been reported. Given the prominence of the resource model in the field of political
participation (Brady et al. 1995), we would expect more systematic analyses of
how poverty and/or illiteracy affect turnout.

6 Apr 2006 15:59

118

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

BLAIS

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

PARTY SYSTEMS AND ELECTORAL OUTCOMES


Powells (1982) initial analysis indicated that turnout was higher in countries with
strong linkages between social groups and parties. That finding was not replicated
by Jackman (1987), and subsequent studies have left out this variable. Jackman
introduced a new variable, the number of parties, which is now incorporated in
most research.
The intuition is that turnout should be higher the more parties there are, for at
least two reasons. First, voters have more options to choose from. When there are
six or seven parties instead of two or three, voters are more likely to find a party
whose platform is reasonably close to their own views on the major issues of the
election, and they should be less inclined to feel that none of the options is satisfactory. Second, the more parties there are, the greater the electoral mobilization.
As Jackman points out, party fractionalization may also have negative consequences on turnout. The more parties there are, the greater the likelihood that the
government will be made of a coalition of parties. In systems that have coalition
governments, electoral outcomes are less decisive, because the final composition
of the government depends on the deals that parties are willing (or unwilling) to
make. The presence of many parties may mean that voters have little say in the
actual selection of the government (Downs 1957).
Because of these possible contradictory consequences, it is not clear whether we
should expect the correlation of turnout with the number of parties to be positive,
negative, or nonexistent. Moreover, it is not clear that it is the number of parties
per se that counts. If it is the decisiveness of the outcome that matters, then we
should look at the (anticipated) presence or absence of deals after the election
and the most important distinction could be between elections producing singleparty majority governments (which are decisive) and those producing minority or
coalition governments.
Almost all empirical research has found a negative correlation between the
number of parties and turnout (Jackman 1987, Blais & Carty 1990, Jackman &
Miller 1995, Blais & Dobrzynska 1998, Radcliff & Davis 2000, Kostadinova 2003).
The only exceptions are studies of turnout in Latin America, where there seems to
be no relationship (Perez-Lina n 2001, Fornos et al. 2004).
This is a perplexing finding. It seems to imply that people are not more inclined
to vote when and where there are more options to choose from, and/or that party
mobilization does not matter much (or that the arrival of new parties does not
enhance overall mobilization). Furthermore, the usual interpretation that a higher
number of parties reduces turnout because they produce coalition governments
(and elections are therefore less decisive) is not empirically supported. Blais &
Carty (1990) and Blais & Dobrzynska (1998) report that turnout is not higher in
elections that produce single-party majority governments.
The bottom line is that we have a poor understanding of the relationship between
the number of parties and turnout. We must reject the simple intuition that having
more parties fosters turnout. This is an important nil finding. PR and/or larger

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

WHAT AFFECTS TURNOUT?

119

district magnitude increases the number of parties (Taagepera & Shugart 1989,
Blais & Carty 1991, Lijphart 1994, Cox 1997). We can say that if PR fosters turnout,
it is not because it produces more parties. Because we do not know exactly how and
why PR may affect turnoutthat is, we do not understand the microfoundations
(Achen 2002)the pessimistic reading that there is no generalized correlation
between electoral system and turnout seems justified.
It is also time to question the standard interpretation that the often observed
negative correlation between the number of parties and turnout reflects the impact
of the decisiveness of elections. That interpretation must be directly tested, which
means developing measures of election decisiveness. Such measures have been
used in other streams of research (see, in particular, Powell & Whitten 1993); they
might have to be amended or refined, but they should be incorporated in future
studies. It could also be argued that what really matters is clarity of choice, that is,
voters need to know with relative certainty the coalitions that might be formed. If
that is the presumed process, then clarity-of-choice indicators must be constructed.
As things stand, the fact that turnout appears to be lower when there are more parties
is intuitively odd, and the supposition that this is so because more parties mean
less decisive elections is only a supposition. (I do not find the interpretation that
the number of parties increases information costs very plausible either. Voters do
not have to inform themselves about each party. Information costs may increase,
however, if and when the party system is in great flux.)
There is one final variable that was not included in the pioneer work of Powell
and Jackman but has been incorporated in many subsequent studies: the closeness
of the electoral outcome. This variable has produced the most consistent findings.
My earlier summary of the evidence still holds: the verdict is crystal clear with
respect to closeness: closeness has been found to increase turnout in 27 of the
32 studies that have tested the relationship, in many different settings and diverse
methodologies. There are strong reasons to believe that, as predicted by rational
choice theory, more people vote when the election is close (Blais 2000, p. 60).
This is the most firmly established result in the literature. I cannot see how this
finding could be wrong.
This does not mean that the issue is settled. It does not suffice to say that
closeness fosters turnout; we need to specify the magnitude of the impact. I have
been struck, in my own research, by its smallness. My cross-national analysis
suggests that turnout is reduced by one or two points when the gap between
the leading and the second parties increases by 10 points (Blais & Dobrzynska
1998). Very similar patterns emerge in cross-sectional analyses of constituency
level turnout (Loewen & Blais, unpublished)1 and time-series studies of national
turnout in Canada (Nevitte et al. 2000).
It is possible that the impact of closeness is underestimated because the variable
is not adequately measured. The standard indicator is the vote gap between the
1
Loewen PJ, Blais A. 2005. Did C-24 Affect Voter Turnout? Evidence from the 2000 and
2004 Elections. Typescript.

6 Apr 2006 15:59

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

120

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

BLAIS

leading and second parties. The indicator makes sense, although it is not clear
whether it is the seat or the vote gap that matters. (I personally think it is the vote
gap because voters receive much information about vote intentions from polls
and because many have a poor understanding of how votes are translated into
seats.) In systems with coalition governments, it may be the closeness of the race
between the two major coalitions that matters. More complex measures need to
be constructed. Furthermore, it is always assumed that the relationship between
closeness and turnout is linear. It could be that what matters is that the outcome not
be a foregone conclusion, and that the real difference is between elections where
the winner wins by a very wide margin and all others. Or perhaps it is only very
close elections that excite voters and boost turnout.
Cross-national research typically looks at the overall closeness of the national
election. It could be that what matters is the closeness of the race at the district level.
Franklin (2004) uses mean margin of victory at the district level as an indicator of
closeness, and this is clearly an avenue worth exploring. We should not assume,
however, that closeness must absolutely be measured at the district level. In an
analysis of individuals decision to vote or abstain in the 1996 British Columbia
election, we found that the perceived closeness of the race at the provincial level
had a greater impact than perceived closeness at the district level (Blais et al. 2000).
Finally, there is the question of whether closeness matters in PR systems.
Franklin (2004) takes the radical view that the margin of victory matters only
in plurality systems. He may be right, but that is an empirical proposition that
should be directly tested. The most difficult question is whether closeness (or
competitiveness) should be measured the same way in different electoral systems.
Margin of victory is the logical indicator in plurality systems because the probability of casting a decisive vote is directly related to margin of victory. In a PR
system, however, the outcome can sometimes be a foregone conclusion even if it is
close. In a five-seat district, for instance, it may be obvious to voters that party A
and party B will each win two seats and party C one seat (and that could have been
the outcome of the previous three elections), yet party As lead over party B may
be minuscule. Such an outcome would be coded as very close, yet the probability
of casting a decisive vote in such a district would be as tiny as in single-member
noncompetitive districts. The probability of casting a decisive vote is equally
minuscule in PR and non-PR systems. We need to think hard about what closeness
or competitiveness actually means in PR systems.

DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH


The dominant view in the field is that cross-national variations in turnout can be
explained mostly by institutional factors that make some elections more salient and
competitive than others. That view is well expressed by Franklin (1996, p. 232):
A country with low salience elections and an electoral system that was not very
proportional could easily show turnout levels 40% [sic; it should be 40 percentage

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

WHAT AFFECTS TURNOUT?

121

points] below a country with high salience elections and a highly proportional
system. Such differences arise purely from differences in the institutional context
within which elections are conducted.
I am not convinced. As I have indicated, the evidence that turnout is higher
under PR (which is supposed to produce more competitive outcomes) and in more
important elections is far from robust. The evidence on the impact of closeness
is consistent, but that impact appears to be strikingly weak. Institutions matter less
than we are prone to believe. Their impact is conditional on the presence of other
factors.
In order to disentangle these more complex relationships, we need to reconsider our research designs and methodologies. The standard approach in the field
has been a cross-sectional analysis of variations in turnout across countries. This
approach is appropriate for sorting out the effect of variables that tend to be stable over time, such as the socioeconomic environment or the electoral system
and compulsory voting. The challenge is to include more cases, as the number of
democracies expands, so as to test the robustness of the findings observed among
established democracies.
But many variables differ from one election to another, and for these variables the analysis should be explicitly dynamic. In his ground-shaking work Voter
Turnout and the Dynamics of Electoral Competition in Established Democracies Since 1945, Franklin (2004) confronts the issue of moving variables and
clearly points in the direction that future research should take (see also Franklin
et al. 2004). Franklin makes two crucial points. First, the logical way to ascertain
the impact of a variable on turnout is to examine whether turnout increases or decreases when that variable changes. In other words, the analysis should be dynamic.
Second, the impact of any change should be felt mostly on the new cohorts, who
have not yet developed a habit of voting (or abstaining).
This approach leads Franklin to perform empirical analyses in which previous
turnout is included as a control variable, thus making the analysis explicitly dynamic. Franklin also creates interactive variables between institutional factors and
the proportion of the electorate that is new (facing one of its first three elections).
In some cases, he also uses cohorts as the unit of analysis, which allows him to
directly test the hypothesis that institutional variables have a stronger effect on
new cohorts.
This is an impressive accomplishment. Franklin (2004) has challenged us to
revisit how to test hypotheses about the influence of institutions or party systems
on turnout. However, the study has three serious flaws. First, Franklin omits the
main effects associated with new cohorts in his estimations because of the presence of multicollinearity. This is not a compelling justification. Brambor et al.
(forthcoming) show that when the theoretical model entails interaction effects,
all the constitutive terms must be included and that the problems associated with
multicollinearity have been greatly overstated. Second, Franklin frequently refers
to how generational replacement affects turnout, yet he confines his analysis to
the consequences of new cohorts entering the electorate. He does not tackle the

6 Apr 2006 15:59

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

122

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

BLAIS

crucial and difficult question of whether new cohorts vote less because they enter
politics in a less competitive context (his argument) or because they belong to a
new generation with a different set of values (Blais et al. 2004). Third, the kind
of model that Franklin proposes calls for the use of multilevel analysis, in which
characteristics of voters interact with characteristics of the electoral context.
Despite these shortcomings, Franklin has indicated the new direction that research in the field has to follow. We must pay closer attention to the dynamics
of turnout, we must examine how changes in the party system and/or closeness
of the election outcome affect electoral participation, and we should explicitly
test whether these factors have a greater impact on new cohorts. In that sense,
Franklins book is as much a pioneer study as Powells and Jackmans work
20 years ago.
Franklins central argument, which corresponds to the dominant view in the
field, is that the degree of electoral competition is the most crucial determinant of
turnout. I remain skeptical. As indicated above, turnout is only weakly affected by
the closeness of an election. Extremely close elections typically boost turnout
by a few percentage points. Furthermore, I have seen no evidence that elections
are becoming systematically less competitive over time, and so the recent decline
in turnout can hardly be attributed to the lack of competition.
Franklin alerts us to the possibility that the impact of institutional characteristics
may vary across types of voters. We must also examine the possibility that their
effects vary across systems. For instance, turnout may be differentially related
to the number of parties and/or the closeness of the election in PR and non-PR
countries. Likewise, what increases or decreases turnout may be quite different
in rich and poor countries. Because the number of democracies and democratic
elections is greatly expanding, it is now possible to test interaction effects between
the socioeconomic environment, institutional variables, and party systems and to
separate general patterns that hold everywhere from conditional ones that apply
only in some specific contexts.

CONCLUSION
Cross-national studies of turnout have produced a number of robust findings. We
can confidently say that turnout is lower in poor countries and higher in small
ones, that compulsory voting fosters turnout, and that turnout increases in closely
contested elections. But I am more impressed by the gaps in our knowledge. We
have a poor understanding of how compulsory voting enhances turnout, and we
have a poor appreciation of how much or little competition matters and of how
it plays out in PR systems. It makes sense to believe that turnout is lower in less
salient elections but what makes an election more or less salient is still obscure.
We can do better. As the number of democracies and the number of democratic
elections are greatly expanding, we can test our hypotheses with more cases and
with greater variance in both the dependent and independent variables. This means

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

WHAT AFFECTS TURNOUT?

123

we must move beyond established democracies and check whether the patterns that
we observe among them hold in new democracies. This is why the work of Fornos
et al. (2004), which tests some of the standard hypotheses about the determinants
of turnout in a new environment (Latin America), is so useful and important. If
some factors, such as the electoral system or district magnitude, appear to have
an impact only in some subset of countries, we should develop a more complex
theory about when and where they matter more and lessor we should perform
additional analyses to check whether the apparent relationship could be spurious.
With the advent of data sets such as the Comparative Study of Electoral Systems, it also becomes possible to examine the conditional impact of institutions
on different types of voters (see, e.g., Long & Shively 2005). This opens up a
fascinating avenue of research. Franklin (2004), Gerber et al. (2003), and Plutzer
(2002) have all argued that there is an important habit component in voting. If
they are right, we should expect contextual factors to have a much greater effect
on new cohorts. That logically calls for a multilevel analysis linking institutional
variables with individual voter characteristics.
The Annual Review of Political Science is online at
http://polisci.annualreviews.org
LITERATURE CITED
Achen CH. 2002. Toward a new political
methodology: microfoundations and ART.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 5:42350
Arcelus FJ, Meltzer AH. 1975. The effect of aggregate economic variables on congressional
elections. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 69:123265
Bilodeau A, Blais Andre. 2005. Le vote obligatoire a-t-il un effet de socialisation politique?
Presented to Colloque int. vote obligatoire,

Inst. dEtudes
Polit. Lille, Oct. 2021
Black JH. 1991. Reforming the context of the
voting process in Canada: lessons from other
democracies. In Voter Turnout in Canada, ed.
HI Bakvis, pp. 61176. Toronto: Dundurn
Blais A. 1991. The debate over electoral systems. Int. Polit. Sci. Rev. 12:23960
Blais A. 2000. To Vote Or Not To Vote? The
Merits and Limits of Rational Choice. Pittsburgh: Univ. Pittsburgh Press
Blais A, Aarts K. 2005. Electoral system
and turnout. Presented at Int. Expert Meet.
Changing the Electoral System: The Case
of the Netherlands, Amsterdam, Sept. 14
15

Blais A, Carty K. 1990. Does proportional representation foster voter turnout? Eur. J. Polit.
Res. 18:16781
Blais A, Carty K. 1991. The psychological impact of electoral laws: measuring Duvergers
elusive factor. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 21:7993
Blais A, Dobrzynska A. 1998. Turnout in electoral democracies. Eur. J. Polit. Res. 33:239
61
Blais A, Gidengil E, Nevitte N, Nadeau R. 2004.
Where does turnout decline come from? Eur.
J. Polit. Res. 43:22136
Blais A, Massicotte L, Dobrzynska A. 2003.
Why is Turnout Higher in Some Countries
than in Others? Ottawa: Elections Canada
Blais A, Young R, Lapp M. 2000. The calculus
of voting: an empirical test. Eur. J. Polit. Res.
37:181201
Brady HE, Verba K, Schlozman L. 1995. Beyond SES: a resource model of political
participation. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 89:271
95
Brambor T, Roberts Clark W, Golder M.
2006. Understanding interaction models:

6 Apr 2006 15:59

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

124

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

BLAIS

improving empirical analyses. Polit. Anal.


14:6382
Cox GW. 1997. Making Votes Count. New
York/London: Cambridge Univ. Press
Downs A. 1957. An Economic Theory of
Democracy. New York: Harper
Fornos CA, Power TJ, Garand JC. 2004. Explaining voter turnout in Latin America, 1980
to 2000. Comp. Polit. Stud. 37(8):90940
Franklin M. 1996. Electoral participation. In
Comparing Democracies: Elections and Voting in Global Perspective, ed. L LeDuc, RG
Niemi, P Norris, pp. 21635. Beverly Hills,
CA: Sage
Franklin M. 2004. Voter Turnout and the Dynamics of Electoral Competition in Established Democracies Since 1945. Cambridge,
UK: Cambridge Univ. Press
Franklin M, Lyons P, Marsh M. 2004. Generational basis of turnout decline in established
democracies. Acta Polit. 39:11551
Gerber AS, Green DP, Shachar R. 2003. Voting may be habit-forming. Am. J. Polit. Sci.
47:54050
Gimpel JG, Schuknecht JE. 2003. Political participation and the accessibility of the ballot
box. Polit. Geogr. 22:47188
Jackman RW. 1987. Political institutions and
voter turnout in industrial democracies. Am.
Polit. Sci. Rev. 81:40524
Jackman RW, Miller RA. 1995. Voter turnout in
the industrial democracies during the 1980s.
Comp. Polit. Stud. 27(4):46792
Kostadinova T. 2003. Voter turnout dynamics
in post-Communist Europe. Eur. J. Polit. Res.
42(6):74159
Lijphart A. 1994. Electoral Systems and Party
Systems. Oxford, UK: Oxford Univ. Press
Lijphart A. 2000. Turnout. In International Encyclopedia of Elections, ed. R Rose, pp. 314
22. Washington, DC: CQ Press
Long JK, Shively WP. 2005. Applying a twostep strategy to the analysis of cross-national
public opinion data. Polit. Anal. 13:32744
Massicotte L, Blais A. 1999. Mixed electoral
systems: a conceptual and empirical survey.
Elect. Stud. 18:34166
Massicotte L, Blais A, Yoshinaka A. 2003.

Establishing the Rules of the Game: Election Laws in Democracies. Toronto: Univ.
Toronto Press
McDonald MP, Samuel P. 2001. The myth
of the vanishing voter. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev.
95(4):96374
Nevitte N, Blais A, Gidengil E, Nadeau R. 2000.
An Unsteady State: The 1997 Canadian Federal Election. Toronto: Oxford Univ. Press
Norris P. 2002. Electoral Engineering: Voting Rules and Political Behavior. New York:
Cambridge Univ. Press
Oliver JE. 2000. City size and civic involvement
in metropolitan America. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev.
94:36173
Perez-Lina n A. 2001. Neoinstitutional accounts
of voter turnout: moving beyond industrial
democracies. Elect. Stud. 20(2):28197
Plutzer E. 2002. Becoming a habitual voter: inertia, resources and growth in young adulthood. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 96:4156
Powell GB. 1982. Comparative Democracies:
Participation, Stability and Violence. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press
Powell GB Jr. 1986. American voter turnout in
comparative perspective. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev.
80(1):1743
Powell GB, Whitten GD. 1993. A crossnational analysis of economic voting: taking
account of the political context. Am. J. Polit.
Sci. 37:391414
Radcliff B. 1992. The welfare state, turnout, and
the economy. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 86:44456
Radcliff B, Davis P. 2000. Labor organization and electoral participation in industrial
democracies. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 44(1):13241
Rallings C, Thrasher M. 2006. The turnout
gap and the costs of voting: a comparison
of participation at the 2001 general and 2002
local election in England. Br. J. Polit. Sci. In
press
Rose R. 2004. Voter turnout in the European
Union member vountries. In Voter Turnout
in Western Europe since 1945, ed. R Lopez
Pintor, M Gratschew, pp. 1724. Stockholm:
Int. IDEA
Rosenstone SJ. Economic adversity and voter
turnout. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 26:2546

6 Apr 2006 15:59

AR

ANRV276-PL09-06.tex

XMLPublishSM (2004/02/24)

P1: KUV

WHAT AFFECTS TURNOUT?

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

Siaroff A, Merer JWA. 2002. Parliamentary


election turnout in Europe since 1990. Polit.
Stud. 50:91627
Southwell PL. 2004. Five years later: a reassment of Oregons vote by mail electoral process. PS: Polit. Sci. Polit. 37:8993

125

Taagepera R, Soberg Shugart M. 1989. Seats


and Votes: The Effects and Determinants
of Electoral Systems. New Haven, CT: Yale
Univ. Press
Wolfinger RE, Rosenstone SJ. 1980. Who
Votes? New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press

P1: JRX

April 5, 2006

20:54

Annual Reviews

AR276-FM

Annual Review of Political Science


Volume 9, 2006

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

CONTENTS
BENTLEY, TRUMAN, AND THE STUDY OF GROUPS, Mika LaVaque-Manty
HISTORICAL EVOLUTION OF LEGISLATURES IN THE UNITED STATES,
Peverill Squire

RESPONDING TO SURPRISE, James J. Wirtz


POLITICAL ISSUES AND PARTY ALIGNMENTS: ASSESSING THE ISSUE
EVOLUTION PERSPECTIVE, Edward G. Carmines and Michael W. Wagner
PARTY POLARIZATION IN AMERICAN POLITICS: CHARACTERISTICS,
CAUSES, AND CONSEQUENCES, Geoffrey C. Layman, Thomas M. Carsey,
and Juliana Menasce Horowitz

WHAT AFFECTS VOTER TURNOUT? Andre Blais


PLATONIC QUANDARIES: RECENT SCHOLARSHIP ON PLATO,
Danielle Allen

ECONOMIC TRANSFORMATION AND ITS POLITICAL DISCONTENTS IN


CHINA: AUTHORITARIANISM, UNEQUAL GROWTH, AND THE
DILEMMAS OF POLITICAL DEVELOPMENT, Dali L. Yang
MADISON IN BAGHDAD? DECENTRALIZATION AND FEDERALISM IN
COMPARATIVE POLITICS, Erik Wibbels
SEARCHING WHERE THE LIGHT SHINES: STUDYING
DEMOCRATIZATION IN THE MIDDLE EAST, Lisa Anderson
POLITICAL ISLAM: ASKING THE WRONG QUESTIONS? Yahya Sadowski
RETHINKING THE RESOURCE CURSE: OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE,
INSTITUTIONAL CAPACITY, AND DOMESTIC CONSTRAINTS,
Pauline Jones Luong and Erika Weinthal

A CLOSER LOOK AT OIL, DIAMONDS, AND CIVIL WAR, Michael Ross


THE HEART OF THE AFRICAN CONFLICT ZONE: DEMOCRATIZATION,
ETHNICITY, CIVIL CONFLICT, AND THE GREAT LAKES CRISIS,
Crawford Young

1
19
45
67

83
111
127

143
165
189
215

241
265

301

PARTY IDENTIFICATION: UNMOVED MOVER OR SUM OF PREFERENCES?


Richard Johnston

REGULATING INFORMATION FLOWS: STATES, PRIVATE ACTORS,


AND E-COMMERCE, Henry Farrell

329
353
vii

P1: JRX

April 5, 2006

viii

20:54

Annual Reviews

AR276-FM

CONTENTS

COMPARATIVE ETHNIC POLITICS IN THE UNITED STATES: BEYOND


BLACK AND WHITE, Gary M. Segura and Helena Alves Rodrigues
WHAT IS ETHNIC IDENTITY AND DOES IT MATTER? Kanchan Chandra
NEW MACROECONOMICS AND POLITICAL SCIENCE, Torben Iversen
and David Soskice

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2006.9:111-125. Downloaded from arjournals.annualreviews.org


by UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA on 06/14/06. For personal use only.

QUALITATIVE RESEARCH: RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN CASE STUDY


METHODS, Andrew Bennett and Colin Elman
FOREIGN POLICY AND THE ELECTORAL CONNECTION, John H. Aldrich,
Christopher Gelpi, Peter Feaver, Jason Reifler,
and Kristin Thompson Sharp

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND DEMOCRACY, James A. Robinson

375
397
425
455

477
503

INDEXES
Subject Index
Cumulative Index of Contributing Authors, Volumes 19
Cumulative Index of Chapter Titles, Volumes 19

ERRATA
An online log of corrections Annual Review of Political Science chapters
(if any, 1997 to the present) may be found at http://polisci.annualreviews.org/

529
549
552

S-ar putea să vă placă și