Sunteți pe pagina 1din 14

Capitalism, Cities, and the Production of Symbolic Forms

Author(s): Allen J. Scott


Source: Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, New Series, Vol. 26, No. 1 (2001),
pp. 11-23
Published by: Blackwell Publishing on behalf of The Royal Geographical Society (with the
Institute of British Geographers)
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/623142
Accessed: 22/12/2008 08:48

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=black.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the
scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that
promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Blackwell Publishing and The Royal Geographical Society (with the Institute of British Geographers) are
collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Transactions of the Institute of British
Geographers.

http://www.jstor.org
Capitalism, cities, and the production of
symbolic forms
Allen J Scott
A striking characteristic of contemporary capitalism is the increasing importance (in
terms of growth, employment, revenue, etc.) of sectors whose outputs are imbued
with significant cultural or symbolic content. Sectors of these sorts are
predominantly, though not exclusively, located in large cities. I describe how these
cities function as creative fields generating streams of both cultural and
technological innovations. Post-Fordist cities are shown to be especially fertile
terrains of commodified cultural production. A number of these cities have become
major centres of image-producing industries such as film, music recording, or
fashion clothing, and this phenomenon is also often associated with profound
transformations of their physical landscapes. I argue that the economic foundations
of these trends reside, in part, in the structural characteristics of image-producing
industries, marked as they frequently are by modularized, network structures of
production and a strong proclivity to geographic agglomeration. At the same time,
the main centres of the contemporary cultural economy are caught up in insistent
processes of globalization. I suggest that after an initial phase of product
standardization and concentrated development in only a few major centres, the
cultural economy of capitalism now appears to be entering a new phase marked by
increasingly high levels of product differentiation and polycentric production sites. I
also submit that the contemporary cultural economy of capitalism constitutes a
historical shift beyond consumer society as such.

key words creative field consumer society cultural economy globalization


urbanization

Centre for Globalization and Policy Research, School of Public Policy and Social Research, University of
California-Los Angeles.
email: ajscott@ucla.edu

revised manuscript received 25 September 2000

Introduction different fields have pointed out that the economic


is irretrievably embedded in the cultural, and
One of the defining features of contemporary capi- several geographers have responded to this insight
talist society is the conspicuous convergence that is by calling for a vigorous cultural geography of
occurring between the domain of the economic on economic practices (cf Peet 1997; Thrift 1994). In
the one hand and the domain of the cultural on the view of the steady absorption of cultural produc-
other. Vast segments of the output of the modem tion into the economy, it is equally imperative that
economy are inscribed with significant cultural we now also set about the tasks of constructing
content, while culture itself is increasingly being a thorough-going economic geography of cultural
supplied in the form of commodified goods and forms (cf Scott 2000). Indeed, these two analytical
services. Of late years, social scientists from many moments are in principle all but indistinguishable
TransInst Br Geogr NS 26 11-23 2001
ISSN 0020-2754 ? Royal Geographical Society (with The Institute of British Geographers) 2001
12 A J Scott
from one another in the context of advanced capi- I shall now develop an argument that purports
talist society, given that the supply and demand to demonstrate (a) how large cities function as
sides alike are permeated throughout by high creative fields for both cultural and economic pro-
levels of cognitive and expressive content which duction, (b) how the shifting relations between
functions both as an input to production and as a culture and economy have worked themselves out
critical component of final output. under conditions of capitalist urbanization over the
I propose in the present paper to examine one nineteenth and twentieth centuries, (c) how the
important facet of this complex grid of relations, contemporary post-Fordist metropolis is coming to
namely the urban conditions underlying the pro- be the site of a peculiar reintegration of cultural
duction of commodified symbolic forms. I use the and economic life, (d) how globalization appears to
term 'commodified' in the usual (Marxian) sense to be leading in the direction not of cultural uniform-
designate goods and services that are produced by ity but of a new kind of plurality, and (e) how all
capitalist firms for a profit under conditions of of this seems to herald a shift from classical con-
market exchange; and I mean by 'symbolic forms' sumer society to an alternative cultural economy of
goods and services that have some significant capitalism.
emotional or intellectual (ie aesthetic or semiotic)
content. I will now and then use the expression
'cultural products' as a synonym for the latter The city as a creativefield
term, though 'symbolic forms' seems preferable By definition, cities represent dense agglomer-
(despite its prior appropriation by Cassirer (1963) ations of social life. They are places that emerge
for more complex philosophical purposes) given out of a need for proximity when large numbers
the host of ambiguities associated with the notion of individuals are caught up certain kinds of
of 'culture' (Williams 1976). In my sense, then, mutually interdependent activities. Cities are thus
commodified symbolic forms are products of capi- localities marked by intricate webs of human rela-
talist enterprise that cater to demands for goods tionships and interchange, leading in turn to their
and services that serve as instruments of entertain- tendency continually to engender multiplicity, flux,
ment, communication, self-cultivation (however and unexpected events or experiences.
conceived), ornamentation, social positionality, As Hall (1998) has argued in Cities in Civilization,
and so on, and they exist in both 'pure' distil- these features appear to represent one of the con-
lations, as exemplified by film or music, or in ditions underlying the rise of particular cities at
combination with more utilitarian functions, as particular moments in time to high levels of crea-
exemplified by furniture or clothing. In fact, a clear tive energy, no matter whether it be in cultural or
distinction between symbolic and utilitarian func- economic affairs. On the cultural side, we might
tions in many if not most of the products of the exemplify this connection between cities and crea-
contemporary economy is rarely feasible, and we tivity by reference to cases like Paris in the 1880s
can usually only speak of their degree of co- when impressionism was in full flower, or Vienna
presence in any given commodity. That said, the at the turn of the century when Berg, Sch6nberg,
ratio of the symbolic to the utilitarian appears to be and Webern were developing 'atonal' music, or
rapidly rising in the output structure of modem Manhattan in the 1950s when the abstract ex-
capitalism (Lash and Urry 1994), and many of the pressionist school of painters like de Kooning,
sectors that are most insistently focussed on the Motherwell, Pollock, Rothko, and others, was at its
production of symbolic forms are currently moving most creative (cf Levy 1999). On the economic side,
into important positions on the frontier of capitalist an analogous kind of flowering may be noted in
economic expansion. the cases of mid-nineteenth-century Lancashire
In geographic terms, firms in these sectors are with its unusually high levels of invention in
mainly concentrated in large cities scattered across the field of cotton textile machinery, or Southern
the world, and from these bases they are increas- California in the 1920s and 1930s where a burgeon-
ingly engaged in the contestation of domestic and ing aircraft industry suddenly began to generate
non-domestic markets. As we shall see in some numerous path-breaking technological inno-
detail, large cities help to endow these firms with vations, or Silicon Valley today with its unrivalled
advantageous conditions of cultural creativity, capacity to push forward the frontiers of computer
productive efficiency, and competitive advantage. and information technology development.
Symbolicforms 13
What is remarkable about these cases - as I shall particular agglomerations from outside, and
argue - is that they can be conceptually recoded in local production capacities are continually
terms of interactive network structures whose refreshed.
roots penetrate deeply into urban agglomerations. Second, the rapid, ever-changing circulation of
We should also note that the innovations most information through the social and economic
characteristic of each agglomeration tend to be networks of the city, and the intensity and variety
generically interrelated. In today's cultural of human contact, ensure that there is an ever-
economy, cities such as New York, Los Angeles, present tendency to destabilization of prevailing
London, Paris, Milan, or Tokyo, display a remark- norms and practices and a certain propensity for
able capacity to maintain constant streams of new new insights and new ways of proceeding to arise.
outputs in their established lines of specialization This process is magnified where divisions of labour
(whether it be in film, musical recording, publish- in cultural or economic production are strongly
ing, fashion, or whatever), and to innovate in the in evidence; that is, where many specialized but
basic technologies and marketing methods on complementary individuals and organizations
which their economic performance depends. Later, come together in constant interchange, thus
I shall provide a theoretical outline of how and forming functional as well as spatial clusters of
why cities like these come to operate as major poles interrelated activities. Even in purely artistic
of the cultural economy. For the present, and as a communities the division of labour often plays a
preliminary to this attempt, I shall review some of major role in shaping the concrete artifacts brought
the principal factors that make it possible for large into being by creative action, as White and White
cities to function as foci of creativity and inno- (1965) have shown in their study of the emergence
vation, ie as creative fields (Scott 1999a). Three of French impressionism out of the complex
main points may be made. interactions between painters, gallery owners,
First, cities are always at least in part consti- journalists, art critics, patrons, and others in late
tuted as communities of workers who gain their nineteenth century Paris (Becker 1982).
livelihoods in local trades or industries. For rea- Third, cities represent collectivities of human
sons that need not detain us here, different trades activity and interests that continually create
and industries are rarely spread out at random streams of public goods - both as a matter of
across all cities, but usually show strong signs of conscious policy and as purely unintended out-
functional specialization from city to city. This comes of social and economic interaction - that
means that communities of workers will tend to sustain the workings of the creative field. An
be similarly specialized. Consequently, each indi- illustration can be found in the traditions and
vidual community will almost always function as conventions that ordinarily inhere within any
a repository of particular kinds of know-how, community of workers, or in the socialization
skills, and sensibilities, and workers - up to a dynamics which ensure that local knowledge is
point - will have special competencies or instinct- preserved and transmitted from one generation to
like capacities in knowing how to pro- the next (within the family, within specific social
ceed in resolving both routine and non-routine groups, and within the urban community at large).
work-related problems (cf Bourdieu 1980). Com- Another case can be found in the physical and
munities like these invariably act as magnets institutional infrastructures with which communi-
for individuals from other areas, especially for ties equip themselves in order to protect their own
capable and aspiring neophytes who recognize livelihood and future. For example, local public
that personal and professional fulfillment in their authorities frequently set up schools, colleges, and
chosen line of work can best be attained by training centres to prepare workers for skilled
migration to a centre where that sort of work is and specialized employment in the community.
well developed and highly valued (Menger 1993; Private-public partnerships represent another
Montgomery and Robinson 1993). Thus, visual means of sustaining community-wide infrastruc-
artists are attracted in droves from all parts of tures, as illustrated by the many regions that have
the world to Paris and New York, aspiring sought to become vibrant foci of high-technology
scriptwriters and film actors to Hollywood, and or craft industries by means of private-public
ambitious software engineers to Silicon Valley. schemes to promote local technology- or design-
In this manner, new talent is imported into innovation centres (Bianchi 1992).
14 A J Scott
Activation of these mutually-reinforcing syner- order was represented by regimented and often
gies at the core of the urban creative field is often dehumanizing forms of industrialization and
most vigorous where any given regional cohort of urbanization, while the aesthetic ideals of the
producers maintains a strong spirit of experimen- period were enmeshed in otherworldly romanti-
tation and/or competitive rivalry, especially where cism. Ruskin's The Stones of Venice,published right
producers are caught up in a dynamic of expand- in the middle of the century functioned as a paean
ing but discriminating demand for their outputs. to the past of Gothic crafts and architecture, and as
Of course, the structural characteristics of large an indictment of the cultural degradation that was
cities do not always favour a continual flow of new becoming ever more apparent in industrial-urban
cultural/economic methods, products, styles, and Britain. Indeed, the very different social impera-
so on, and cases of stagnation or lock-in to routine tives to which industrialization on the one hand
production configurations are all too numerous to and aesthetic practice on the other were subject at
ignore. Stagnation or lock-in of this sort seems to this time, not only set them in opposition to one
occur particularly when supply and demand con- another as a matter of principle, but also made it
ditions stabilize over long periods of time and exceedingly difficult for them to co-exist in close
when producers become risk averse, as was evi- geographic proximity. By and large, the life of
dently the case in many of the old French industrial the proletariat and the factory owners who
districts in the first half of the present century employed them was bound up with one set of
(Scott 2000). Hence, if and when new producers urban conditions, while the life of artists and their
in other locations begin to contest markets, more most enthusiastic audiences was bound up with
traditional centres are often quite unable to mount another, and these conditions were mutually
an effective competitive response. Scores of the exclusive more often than not. Of course, the
traditional French districts simply collapsed when incompatibility between the two sides was never
faced with competition from cheaper Asian pro- absolute, and in some cities, various sorts of
ducers after the Second World War. Nevertheless, coexistence, if not interdependence, were worked
particular places sometimes acquire durable repu- out, as in the case of late nineteenth century
tations for the distinctiveness and quality of their Chicago with its industrial and commercial bustle
products, so that only thoseplaces can be sources of combined with a remarkable proclivity to architec-
the authentic or real thing, while imitations or tural innovation. In certain metropolitan centres,
alternatives from elsewhere are necessarily in some most notably the Paris of Balzac and Zola, the
sense doomed to appear as imperfect substitutes, worlds of industry and culture came directly
(Molotch 1996). Even when all the creative and into collision with one another at selected points
innovative energies of a given production centre of social and spatial intersection. Even so,
are exhausted, this competitive advantage may places like the surging industrial cities of, say,
enable it to survive, sometimes over considerable northern England or the German Ruhr on the
periods of time. Among the many illustrative cases one hand, and the more traditional historical and
of this phenomenon are certain long-established cultural centres of Europe on the other, seemed to
European centres of china and pottery pro- represent irremediably antithetical universes in
duction, such as Etruria (Wedgewood), Meissen, or this regard.
Limoges, whose products have attained a sort of Over much of the twentieth century, this tension
iconic status. between aesthetics and accumulation continued to
leave its mark on urban life and form in the
advanced capitalist societies. As mass production
Aesthetics, accumulation, and urbanization moved to centre stage of economic development,
urban centres continued to grow and to expand
From its very historical beginnings in the seven- outward in the Mammon quest, while the pursuit
teenth and eighteenth centuries, capitalism, and of cultural production became, if anything, yet
the commercial values that go with it, have been more ghettoized. The metropolitan areas of the
widely perceived as being fundamentally anti- American Manufacturing Belt in particular
thetical to artistic and aesthetic interests. This (Detroit, Cleveland, Pittsburgh, etc.) now became
incompatibility never seemed more complete than to many commentators the archetypes of the utili-
in the nineteenth century, when the economic tarian, philistine city (Lees 1985). Indeed, the mass
Symbolic
forms 15

production system carried the manufacturing and see that the products of capitalist enterprise might
consumption of standardized commodities, (as also accommodate other more positive qualities. In
well as urban development), to new heights of one way or another, culture is always produced in
functional or practical intensity. To begin with, the context of definite historical and social con-
much of the output of the system consisted of ditions that in themselves lie outside the sphere of
consumer goods such as cars, domestic appliances, art but that shape artistic aspirations and practices.
and processed foods, designed largely to absorb Provisionally, then, there is no reason to assert in
the wages of the burgeoning blue-collar workers principle that capitalist firms working for a profit
who made up the majority of the urban populace. cannot turn out goods and services with inherent
In addition, the system flourished on the basis aesthetic and semiotic value (or what Clive Bell
of competitive cost-cutting, and hence (given its (1914), in a rather different context, called 'sig-
machinery-intensive structure), of the search for nificant form'), just as Greek and Roman artisans or
internal economies of scale in production and Florentine painters, sculptors, architects, gold-
the consequent routinization of manufacturing smiths, jewelers, etc., working in relation to the
methods. The system was thus endemically com- definite political and religious obligations by
mitted to the production of undifferentiated and which they were bound, could still produce
desemioticized outputs, leading to the charges of masterworks of transhistorical value (cf Cowen
'eternal sameness' that Frankfurt School critics 1998). In fact, and even as mass production was
were soon to level against its effects as it started to moving into high gear, a modernist aesthetic was
make incursions into popular culture (Adorno already trying to come seriously to terms with its
1991; Horkheimer and Adorno 1972). The large driving logic. Thus, as represented perhaps most
industrial cities themselves were seen in many dramatically by the Bauhaus and the great mod-
quarters as being given over to a syndrome of ernist urban design proposals of architects like
'placelessness' that critics like Relph (1976) Le Corbusier or Oscar Niemayer various aesthetic
ascribed to the increasing domination of technical programmes were mounted in theory and imple-
rationality in mass society. mented in actuality in an attempt to give artistic
To be sure, Walter Benjamin writing in the mid expression to the main thrust of mass-production
1930s had already set forth a series of quite hopeful society (Banham 1960).
views about the potentially progressive nature of An additional matter that the Frankfurt School
what he called 'mechanical reproduction' in the theorists failed to take into account - and they were
arts, and especially in the cinema (cf Benjamin not alone in this - was the possibility that the
1986). By the 1940s, however, the core Frankfurt version of capitalism (or the 'regime of accumu-
School theorists were expressing grave concern lation') that they encountered in mid-twentieth
about the direct incursions of mass production century America might one day be succeeded by
methods into cultural-products industries like film, another. They failed in particular to see that a quite
recorded music, and popular magazines. To people different regime of accumulation, with much more
like Adorno and Horkheimer, these methods, being variegated and inflected symbolic forms inscribed
driven by capitalistic interests, were aesthetically in its outputs, would eventually come to dominate
suspect from the beginning, and they averred that late twentieth and early twenty-first century capi-
the cultural content of the products to which these talism. This so-called post-Fordist regime (or what
methods gave birth were patently manipulative Harvey, 1989, calls 'flexible postmodernity') has
and depoliticizing in practice. It is nowadays fash- been gathering steam since the 1970s, bringing with
ionable to criticize the Frankfurt School theorists it a strikingly new nexus of economic and cultural
for their alleged mitteleuropiischenelitism, though outcomes in the advanced capitalist societies.
the charge is blunted, perhaps, when their work Simultaneously, a sharp intensification of the
is re-contextualized within the conjuncture from economic significance and symbolic content of
which they wrote, with its relatively standardized commodified culture has rather clearly been occur-
and watered-down forms of commercial popular ring, as well as concomitant transformations in
culture. Where they did err was not so much in the function and form of the main urban areas where
imputation of qualities of meretriciousness and this culture is produced. The logic and dynamics
triviality to commodified culture (such qualities are of these transformations now merit extended
all too evident, then as now) but in their failure to discussion.
16 A J Scott
The symbolic economy of the markets are located, are typified by complex re-
contemporary city lations on the supply side that induce them to
congregate together locationally in great masses
One of the more remarkable attributes of the post- within metropolitan areas, often in close proximity
Fordist production system that began to succeed to central business districts. Familiar examples of
mass production as the leading edge of economic this phenomenon are the motion-picture industry
expansion in the advanced capitalist societies after of Hollywood, the media complex of Manhattan,
the 1970s, is the rising significance of cultural- the apparel industry of Paris, or the publishing
products industries in national output and employ- industry of London. Even when their markets are
ment (Hall 2000; Pratt 1997; Scott 1996). These world-wide these sectors still - and perhaps yet
industries comprise the media (eg film, television, more insistently - seek out agglomerated locations
music, publishing), fashion-intensive consumer of this type. Second, many kinds of cultural goods
goods sectors (eg clothing, furniture, jewelry, and and services are relatively immobile in the sense
so on), many different types of services, (eg adver- that they must be consumed close to their point of
tising, tourist facilities, or places of entertainment), production. Theatres, restaurants, art galleries,
and a wide assortment of creative professions (eg concert halls, and so on, supply goods and services
architecture, graphic arts, or web-page design). We of this sort, and they are naturally most densely
may also include in these industries facilities for developed in large metropolitan areas whose
collective cultural consumption like museums, art populations constitute prime markets for all kinds
galleries, or libraries, whether privately or publicly of symbolic products.
controlled. A more complete account of the agglomerative
Industries like these represent substantial (and tendencies of cultural-products industries would
generally expanding) segments of all advanced require considerable time and effort. Fortunately,
capitalist systems. Given the ambiguities of stand- there is already a large literature on the subject,
ard industrial classifications, it is extraordinarily (eg Becattini 1987; Scott 1988, 2000; Storper and
difficult to make precise quantitative assessments Christopherson 1987), and so only a few further
of the full extent of the new cultural economy, but brief descriptive strokes are called for here, with
in one recent study, it was found that in the USA in special reference to the organization and employ-
1992, just over 3 million workers (2.4 per cent of the ment structure of these industries.
total labour force) were employed in 29 cultural- At the outset, note that the production of sym-
products sectors representing both manufacturing bolic forms in modern capitalism is more often
and service activities (Scott 2000). According to than not dependent on large inputs of human
Pratt (1997) a little under 1 million workers (4.5 per manual and intellectual labour, even where digital
cent of the total labour force) were employed in and information technologies play a major role in
cultural industries in Britain in 1991. Both of these the process. Also, markets for final outputs are
sets of figures are almost certainly undercounts. usually extremely uncertain and competitive. In
More importantly for present purposes, employ- view of these conditions, which militate against
ment in cultural-products sectors appears to be internal economies of scale and vertical integration
overwhelmingly located in large cities. Thus, in the in production, firms tend to be small in size
USA just over 50 per cent of the 3 million plus (though big firms certainly can and do make their
workers employed in cultural-products sectors appearance, as we shall see) and to be incorporated
were concentrated in metropolitan areas with as modularized elements into wider production
populations of 1 million or more, and of this networks. These networks are typically constituted
portion, by far the greater majority was actually to as shifting associations of interdependent but
be found in just two centres, namely, New York specialized activities (ie as social divisions of
and Los Angeles. Pratt's data show London as labour), and by the same token, they are the scenes
accounting for 26.9 per cent of employment in of dense transactional flows of information, goods,
British cultural industries. services, and so on. They tend as a consequence to
These locational proclivities of cultural-products be most efficient when the producers caught up
industries can be accounted for by reference to two within them are located in close mutual proximity
main groups of factors. First, many cultural- to one another so that the myriad daily interactions
products sectors, irrespective of where their out of which they are composed can proceed with
Symbolic forms 17
relative dispatch. The same producers share collec- large, but also because the urban landscape itself
tively in local labour markets, each one of which is one of their main outputs (Hutton 2000). Very
may comprise tens or even hundreds of thousands often, too, the same transformations involve
of workers, and this feature helps to accentuate ambitious public efforts of urban rehabilitation in
their spatial concentration because (within limits) the attempt to enhance local prestige, increase
there are significant economic advantages to be property values, and attract new investments and
obtained by the agglomeration of interrelated pro- jobs (Kearns and Philo 1993). When the landscape
ducers close to the centre of a large local labour develops in this manner, whether as a result of
market. Among these advantages are significant public or private initiative, significant portions of
economies of scale associated with job search and the city (though rarely, if ever, all portions) start to
recruitment activities. As we have already seen, function as an ecology of commodified symbolic
the entire local system of production, employment, production and consumption (Urry 1995), in
and social life makes up a geographically- which, and in contrast to the classical industrial
structured creative field that under appropriate metropolis, the functions of leisure and work seem
conditions acts as a fountainhead of learning and to be converging to some sort of (historically-
innovation effects. Finally, with steady improve- specific) social equilibrium. Even advertising
ment in technologies of long-distance transpor- becomes part of the general spectacle that is one
tation and distribution, producers in any given of the important ingredients of this ecology
cluster can sell their outputs on increasingly dis- (O'Connor 1991).
tant markets, thereby enabling it to grow in size, In any ecology like this, moreover, there will
and, by the same token, to become more deeply tend to be powerful and recursively intertwined
differentiated internally through further divisions relations between the meanings that adhere to the
of labour, hence becoming more closely anchored urban landscape and the symbologies of the goods
to a particular place. and services produced in the local area. Thus,
Clusters like these are replete - in the language and on the one hand, the symbolic forms (films,
of the economic geographer - with agglomeration television programmes, recorded music, fashion
economies (ie increasing returns effects), and clothing, and so on) produced for different markets
agglomeration economies in turn give rise - in the invariably draw to some extent on local images,
language of the business economist - to potent cultural associations, social traditions, and so on.
competitive advantages (Porter 1990). More gener- Indeed, this very process is important in authenti-
ally, Soja (2000) refers to these kinds of urban cating and differentiating these symbolic forms in
synergies by the term synekism. This is the incre- the minds of the consumer (Molotch 1996). On the
ment above the simple sum of the parts that holds other hand, the meanings lodged in the same forms
any given urban-industrial structure together as a create images of their places of origin, and the
geographic cluster, while enabling the products same images are often re-assimilated in different
of the most successful clusters to rise to mastery of ways back into the urban landscape of the pro-
national and international markets. ducing centre. Where this relation is especially
The marked progress of the post-Fordist cultural strongly developed - Hollywood is an outstanding
economy of capitalism over the last couple of example - the ever-growing fund of symbolic
decades is evident not only in the expansion of assets that comes to be incarnated in the local
many old and new production agglomerations, but environment then functions as a source of inputs to
also in significant transformations of the land- new rounds of cultural production and commer-
scapes of portions of selected cities and the cialization, leading in turn to further symbolic
revitalization of their symbolic content. In varying enrichment of the urban landscape, and so on.
degree, these transformations are ascribable to the One peculiar version of this sort of urban devel-
success of the cultural economy itself as portions of opment can be found in tourist and resort centres,
it ramify through the city in the guise of shopping like Las Vegas, the cities of the French Riviera, or
malls, restaurants and cafes, clubs, theatres, galler- parts of central London and Paris. In instances like
ies, boutiques, and so on (Zukin 1995). Architec- these, there is an identity of place and production
tural and design trades play an important part in system in the sense that place itself functions at one
this connection, not only because they are flourish- and the same time as the locale and the outcome of
ing components of cultural production systems at producers' efforts. This same trait also means that
18 A J Scott
consumers must travel to the point of production duction. Notwithstanding this long-run prospect,
in order to partake of the local stock-in-trade. In many non-capitalist cultures display a remarkable
the typical case, production is organized in flexible resilience to the messages and meanings embodied
networks of specialized service providers (such as in commodified symbolic forms imported from
hotels, museums, restaurants, theatres, bus and outside, and individuals in these cultures are
boat operators, rental services, guides, etc.). These sometimes capable of quite imaginative feats of
networks are usually subject to governance meas- re-interpretation of these forms (Appadurai 1996;
ures whose objective is to prevent deterioration Jackson 1999). However, if such acts of re-
of the complex as a whole by commercial oppor- interpretation do unquestionably occur with much
tunism and free-riding behaviour. frequency, they are also probably in some retreat as
This analysis would not be complete without a significant force of resistance before the rising
noting, in addition, that beneath the surface afflu- tide of commodified cultural products that is now
ence and glitter that generally accompany urban sweeping through world markets. The central
developments of these types, there is almost questions that we need to pose in this context are
always a less immediately visible economic and these: Does the steady opening up of world mar-
social order as represented by the low-quality jobs kets to these products imply a deepening unifor-
on which the actual work of production is so mization and massification of patterns of cultural
frequently based. Particularly in the large post- consumption across the globe? Alternatively, is it
Fordist city, there is a seemingly endemic and conceivable that many different and dissimilar
deepening cleavage between the well-remunerated centres of cultural production might thrive in the
managers, professionals and technicians who future, thus providing a more varied palette of
are responsible for the conceptualization and offerings (even though non-traditional and com-
execution of high-performance work tasks, not modified) that can be selectively consumed by
only in the cultural economy as such, but across the diverse groups of individuals? And a subsidiary
entire set of post-Fordist sectors, and the swelling question is, can these offerings, even in the
pools of low-wage, low-skill workers who carry presence of variety, be the instruments of any-
out much of the actual physical labour of the urban thing but mendacious aesthetic and semiotic
production system (Sassen 1991). In many cities, experiences?
such as New York, Los Angeles, Paris, or London, A plausible argument can be made to the effect
high proportions of the low-wage, low-skill group that there are processes at work in today's world
consist of illegal immigrants from developing whose terminal point (should it ever be reached) is
countries, whose political marginality reinforces one dominant centre for any given product. The
their economic subordination. The social and argument here plays on the self-reinforcing effects
economic conditions under which the latter indi- of agglomeration economies and increasing returns
viduals live and work represent the other and less effects in large production centres (Romer 1986;
amiable face of the cultural economy of the modern Scott 1998), especially in contexts where competing
city. smaller centres fail to mount viable strategic
responses, whether by inaction or miscalculation
(eg by inadequate or inappropriate differentiation
Globalization: cultural uniformity or of products). It is true, of course, that in the absence
of corrective action, agglomeration diseconomies
polycentricity? will put limits on the growth and competitiveness
The cultural geography of the pre-capitalist land- of any single centre, though urban planners are
scape can be represented in schematic terms as a continually at work to remove the obstacles that
mosaic of many different ways of life and forms periodically threaten the efficient operation of the
of symbolic expression. Throughout the history of urban system. The appearance of one dominant
capitalism there has been a tendency for erosion of centre is all the more predictable in theory where
this more traditional cultural pattern to occur. At distribution costs to the rest of the world are low,
the present time, with globalization proceeding so that in combination with the centre's concen-
apace, it seems clear that much of what remains trated efficiency and learning effects, local pro-
of it is doomed to be submerged or absorbed in ducers can effectively contest markets across the
various ways by the logic of commodity pro- globe. The worldwide impact in the immediate
Symbolic forms 19

post-War decades of popular cultural products music industry, Nashville has attained a subsidiary
fabricated in New York and Los Angeles can prob- but durable standing (after New York and Los
ably at least in part be accounted for in terms like Angeles) by reason of its highly specialized output
these. At the same time, the cultural-products (Scott 1999b). In contrast, the French film industry
industries of New York and Los Angeles also has been facing a severe crisis over the last couple
benefited enormously, as they still do, from the of decades as a consequence of American compe-
presence of multinational corporations which tition. In this instance, even though the product
aggressively pioneered the modern distribution is highly differentiated, it has failed to evoke a
and marketing of commercialized culture on global significant response on wider markets, which does
markets. Network television in the 1950s and not, however, mean that the industry's only
1960s, with its messages tailored to the lowest chances of survival reside in mimicking American
common denominator, was a classic early case films (just the contrary is the case). The commercial
of this phenomenon (Castells 1996). Similarly, problems of the French film industry have been
American cinematic products today represent a compounded by its signal failure to build effective
special threat in many different parts of the foreign distribution and marketing facilities (Scott
world given their seemingly invincible competitive 2000).
force based as it is in the potent agglomeration With this more extended argument in sight, a
economies of Hollywood and the unmatched developmental scenario that looks toward an
distributive capacities of the US entertainment increasing rather than a decreasing number and
and media conglomerates (Aksoy and Robins variety of cultural-products agglomerations across
1992). the globe has much to commend it. As it happens,
This reasoning is limited, however, for the very the new transportation and communications tech-
reason that it does eliminate the effects of alterna- nologies now available will undoubtedly increase
tive competitive strategies, and especially product the likelihood of this scenario emerging into reality.
differentiation, on the part of second or third tier These technologies have two major effects that
centres. To be sure, when individual agglomer- need to be examined here. First, they tend to
ations come into head-on competition with one reduce if not eliminate economies of scale in mass
another, some will stagnate and decline as their distribution systems, while by encouraging deep-
outputs become locked out of markets by more ening social divisions of labour in production they
efficient and appealing producers. Others, how- often actually intensify the play of agglomeration
ever, will find it possible to evade the worst effects economies. Second, this then allows even small
of this competition by focusing on specialized production centres to contest scattered markets
market niches, and this will be notably the case for around the globe. A clear presentiment of this
cultural-products agglomerations that already scenario can be found in the recorded music busi-
enjoy some local monopoly of style or expressive- ness where new internet technologies are making
ness. It is well to recall in this context that product it possible for hitherto quite marginal groups of
differentiation is one of the principal bases - if not producers (such as the immigrant Vietnamese
the principal basis - of monopolistic competition as musicians of Orange County in California) to tap
defined by Chamberlin (1933). Not all attempts at into extended audiences. The internet also elimi-
product differentiation will succeed, of course, but nates several layers of intermediary organization
since - over time and space - there are likely to be between producers and consumers, thus enlarging
many different experiments in this regard, at least a the discretionary power of the latter, and increas-
few of them may be expected to prosper, especially ing their ability to command a greater choice of
where they are also associated with successful products.
efforts to organize wider distribution and market- Given the enduring if not augmented signifi-
ing networks. Thus, in the case of the international cance of agglomeration economies in post-Fordist
high-fashion industry, which was traditionally production systems, it follows that continued
dominated by the grands couturiersof Paris, impor- reductions of distribution costs are not so much
tant complementary centres now also thrive in liable to lead to generalized deterritorialization of
New York, London, Milan, Tokyo, and elsewhere, production as they are to encourage the rise of a
on the basis of their distinctive designers and wide variety of relatively small clusters inter-
constantly evolving styles. In the US recorded spersed among a more limited number of larger
20 A J Scott
clusters. In other words, reductions in distribution probably working to reinforce the incipient geo-
costs can be expected to enhance economic returns graphic differentiation of the global cultural
at big centres and to reinforce their lead, but also to economy described above. Even in the case of
lower the threshold of entry for smaller centres cinematic products, the stranglehold of the
which can survive (ie contest markets) where they American media corporations remains by no
successfully implement competitive strategies to means unassailable, and it is increasingly coming
compensate for their relatively weak agglomer- under attack both from inside and outside the USA
ation economies. Their survival can be further as small independents and film-makers in places as
assured where policy makers at production locales far afield as Australia, Britain, China, Hong Kong,
are able to work out effective systems for the India, and elsewhere seek to cultivate alternative
provision of coordination and steering services market niches. Non-English language films will no
directed to the amplification of these agglomer- doubt be increasingly involved in this competition
ation economies (Scott 1996, 1998). as new computerized production technologies
Besides the clusters of locally-owned firms are further refined, including digital methods for
that generally make up the greater part of reconfiguring actors' lip movements (Martin 1995).
cultural-products agglomerations, multinational Four broad generalizations can drawn from this
corporations also play an active role, and these discussion. First, there was indeed a moment cor-
corporations actually represent an ever greater responding to the period of internationalization, or
force in the production and distribution of cul- what we might call proto-globalization, in the
tural products. Many such corporations (above immediate post-War decades, in which American
all American media and entertainment giants) cultural products tended (though never exclu-
have acquired considerable control over certain sively) to take a lead on world markets. We are
global product markets, and they can unques- by no means yet fully beyond this particular state
tionably be reproached for various kinds of cul- of affairs (Jameson 1998a). Second, and more
tural imperialism. However, major multinational recently, cultural-products agglomerations in
corporations with stakes in the cultural economy many different parts of the world have been
(some of the largest, for example, being Sony responding to intensified competition but also to
Corp., Vivendi, Disney Co., Daewoo Corp., Time increasing market opportunities by means of
Warner Inc., Bertelsmann AG., L'Oreal SA., specialization and product differentiation strate-
Seagram Co., Havas SA., Christian Dior SA., and gies, if not always successfully. Third, new trans-
others) tend to display a surprising variety of portation and communications technologies will
national origins. In addition, they are in numer- probably encourage a further proliferation of
ous cases engaged in active diversification, specialized production locales, many of which
especially by acquisition of affiliated production will be able to survive despite their limited size
units in cultural-products agglomerations all over and limited agglomeration economies because
the world, (though there are evidently occasions they can effectively supply very specific and
when this has resulted in deleterious forms of highly diffuse market niches. Fourth, new styles
mismatch, either for the firm or the agglomer- of corporate organization and behaviour seem on
ation, particularly where firms have been less the whole to be conducive to increasing diversi-
than sensitive to local know-how and conven- fication rather than standardization of outputs.
tional practices (Harrison 1994; Negus 1997)). In Accordingly, if at one stage in the recent past
parallel with this diversification, large corpor- there seemed to be much evidence, both empirical
ations with significant symbolic output have and theoretical, in favour of the view that cultural
shown a proclivity to engage in micro-marketing production and consumption throughout the
of their products, as evidenced by industries as world was becoming more uniform, more
varied as musical recording and brewing (Negus massified, and more Americanized, there are now
1998; Jones 1999). indications to suggest that contrary trends are
There are countervailing signs, then, to suggest occurring, and that the further intensification of
that despite an earlier (fordist) corporate trend globalization processes may well be associated
entailing standardization of outputs, diversifi- with a markedly more polycentric and poly-
cation nowadays represents a more viable pro- phonic system of cultural production than has
ductive strategy, and this, in many instances, is been the case in the recent past.
Symbolicforms 21

Beyond consumer society? The cultural Contemporary culture theorists have invested
economy of capitalism considerable energy in the effort to understand the
social meaning of the symbolic forms now pro-
As Fordist mass production was approaching its duced in such profusion by capitalist enterprise.
climacteric in the 1970s, various authors came up However, few social scientists today appear ready
with dire prognoses of the course of the crisis and its to carry forward the torch of the earlier Frankfurt
aftermath. On the left, theorists like Mandel (1975) School theorists with their scathing condemnations
proclaimed that we were already in a historically of commodified culture.1 Many would even argue
late and presumably penultimate stage of capitalist that if the symbolic forms produced by capitalist
development. On the right, Bell (1976) popularized enterprise today are often in practice devalued and
the influential argument that the increasingly degraded, commodification does not always or
shallow hedonism of consumer society was under- necessarily result in degenerate cultural expression;
mining the practical and moral foundations of indeed, these forms are on occasions at the cutting
capitalist progress. In actuality, capitalism took a edge of new artistic movements, and they have
historical turn after the 1970s that almost no-one, been closely associated with various post-modern
anywhere, anticipated, even as the first intimations aesthetic claims (cf Wollen 1993). This is not the
of the change were starting to appear in the late place to pass judgment on contemporary canons of
1970s. This change has involved a decisive shift of taste. From a purely sociological point of view, we
capitalism into a new post-Fordist configuration, may in some sense cut through the Gordian knot of
resulting in significant economic re-structuring on this puzzle with the observation that capitalism can
both the supply and demand sides. be regarded as just another historical site of cultural
In particular, the many different post-Fordist production, though of course it does not produce
sectors that rose to prominence over the 1980s have just any culture. Nowadays, capitalist firms deliver
unleashed dramatic new rounds of economic an extraordinarily varied fare of cultural products
development and expansion in world capitalism. and experiences in the effort to meet the growing
On the demand side, there has been a distinct and ever-mutating volume of demand. Nor are
enlargement of the pool of individuals practicing consumers merely passive vessels at the receiving
the sort of variegated and discretionary expendi- end of this process. If, as noted, many different
ture that in classical consumer society had largely kinds of contestatory groups are brought into the
been confined to the tiny minority able to afford demand structure of the new cultural economy of
luxury goods. Concomitantly, consumption pat- capitalism, there is also much active conflict over
terns, at least in the advanced capitalist societies, the meanings and images contained in the rising
have tended to progress beyond blunt consumer- flow of goods and services on offer, leading in turn
ism, in the sense of obsessive preoccupation with to a cultural politics that is directly related to,
quantitative acquisition and self-identification with though rarely in fundamental opposition to, the
'middle class' norms of possession (in terms of a commodification of culture. Where the intensifying
package of housing, cars, domestic appliances, and cultural politics of post-Fordist capitalist society
all the rest) into a series of highly differentiated (including new expressions of nationalism and re-
niches and life-style types, thus encouraging a gionalism) will eventually lead is at this stage an
corresponding intensification and diversification of open question. On the basis of the discussion in this
the symbolic content of final goods and services. paper, we may surmise that there is a greater
Even the symbols of contestatory groups like fem- likelihood of its being conducted from a ground-
inists, gays, or ethnic minorities, have in one way work of proliferating social-cum-cultural fractions,
or another been eventually incorporated into this than of its being led by a political avant-garde
economic logic. In parallel, as analysts like Castells struggling on behalf of a massified and psychically
(1996) and Jameson (1998b) have forcefully pointed defenseless consumer society, as envisioned by an
out, traditional distinctions between high and low alternative and older school of thought.
culture are steadily being effaced, while the con-
solidation and spread of capitalism become ever
A final word
more secure by reason of its new-found command
of the instruments of symbolic production in many Geography, of course, is fundamental to all of these
and varied idioms. developments. In the first place, as I have argued,
22 A J Scott
there are definite locational transformations at Appadurai A 1996 Modernityat Large:CulturalDimensions
work in contemporary capitalism, involving the of Globalization University of Minneapolis Press,
growth, spread, and mutual competition of Minneapolis
across the Banham R 1960 Theoryand Design in the First MachineAge
cultural-products agglomerations globe.
In the second place, the expanding world-wide The Architectural Press, London
Becker H S 1982 Art Worlds University of California
network of cultural-products agglomerations will
Press, Berkeley and Los Angeles
almost certainly be accompanied by increasing Becattini G ed 1987 Mercato e Forze Locali: II Distretto
differentiation of outputs as individual centres IndustrialeI1 Mulino, Bolgona
struggle to mobilize whatever place-specific com- Bell C 1914 Art Chatto and Windus, London
petitive advantages they may initially possess, and - D 1976 The Cultural Contradictionsof CapitalismBasic
as they build up reputations for particular kinds of Books, New York
product design and forms of semiotic expression. Benjamin W 1986 Illuminations Harcourt, Brace and
In the third place, if we can envisage the distinct World, New York
Bianchi P 1992 Levels of policy and the nature of post-
possibility that some producers and/or agglomer-
fordist competition in Storper M and Scott A J eds
ations will be able to establish monopoly powers
in certain global market segments, there is also Pathways to Industrializationand Regional Development
Routledge, London
a compensating tendency to geographic diversi- Bourdieu P 1979 La Distinction: Critique Sociale du Juge-
fication of productive efforts and socio-spatial ment Editions de Minuit, Paris
fragmentation of demand. - 1980 Le Sens PratiqueEditions de Minuit, Paris
These complex and shifting trends are likely to -1999 Une r6volution conservatrice dans l'edition Actes
lead to further assertion of the cultural as an de la Rechercheen SciencesSociales126/127 3-28
essential component of the outputs of capitalist Cassirer E 1963 The Philosophyof SymbolicForms (3 vols)
Yale University Press, New Haven
enterprise, and, by the same token, to the deepen-
Castells M 1996 The Rise of the NetworkSociety Blackwell,
ing commodification of culture. We cannot, as
Oxford
Jameson (1998b) has argued, expect any negation
Chamberlin E H 1933 The Theoryof MonopolisticCompe-
of the logic of commodity production by virtue of
tition Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
this tendency, but neither should we necessarily Cowen T 1998 In Praise of CommercialCulture Harvard
expect that it will lead to anything resembling the University Press, Cambridge MA
bleak predictions of an earlier and more pessimistic Hall P 1998 Cities in CivilizationPantheon, New York
generation of culture theorists. - 2000 Creative cities and economic development Urban
Studies 37 639-650
Harrison B 1994 Leanand Mean: the ChangingLandscapeof
Acknowledgements CorporatePower in the Age of Flexibility Basic Books,
I am grateful to Denis Cosgrove, Nicholas Entrikin, New York
and three anonymous referees for their critical Harvey D 1989 The Conditionof PostmodernityBlackwell,
Oxford
comments on an earlier draft of this paper.
Horkheimer M and Adorno T W 1972 Dialecticof Enlight-
enment New York:Herder and Herder
Note Hutton T A 2000 Reconstructed production landscapes
in the postmodern city: applied design and creative
1 A noteworthy exception to this remark is Bourdieu, services in the metropolitan core Urban Geography21
who (notwithstanding his conscientious demystifi- 285-317
cation of the bourgeois cult of art) retains a deep Jackson P 1999 Commodity cultures: the traffic in things
aversion to the incursion of commercial rationality Transactionsof the Institute of British Geographers24
into the sphere of cultural production. See for 95-108
example, Bourdieu (1979; 1999). Jameson F 1998a Notes on globalization as a philosophi-
cal issue in F Jameson and M Miyoshi eds TheCultures
References of GlobalizationDuke University Press, Durham NC
pp 54-77
Adorno, T W 1991 The CultureIndustry:SelectedEssays on - 1998b The Cultural Turn:SelectedWritings on the Post-
Mass CultureRoutledge, London modern,1983-1998 Verso, London
Aksoy A and Robins K 1992 Hollywood for the 21st Jones M T 1998 Blade Runner capitalism, the trans-
century: global competition for critical mass in image national corporation, and commodification Cultural
markets CambridgeJournalof Economics16 1-22 Dynamics 10 287-306
Symbolicforms 23
Kearns G and Philo C eds 1993 Selling Places:the City as Romer P M 1986 Increasing returns and long-run growth
Cultural Capital, Past and Present Pergamon Press, Journalof Political Economy94 1002-37
Oxford Sassen S 1991 The Global City: New York,London, Tokyo
Lash S and Urry J 1994 Economiesof Signs and SpaceSage, Princeton University Press, Princeton
London Scott A J 1988 Metropolis:from the Division of Labor to
Lees A 1985 Cities Perceived:UrbanSocietyin Europeanand Urban Form University of California Press, Berkeley
American Thought, 1820-1940 Columbia University and Los Angeles
Press, New York - 1996 The craft, fashion, and cultural-products indus-
Levy J 1999 Le TournantGeographique: Penser l'Espacepour tries of Los Angeles: competitive dynamics and policy
Lire le Monde Belin, Paris dilemmas in a multisectoral image-producing complex
Mandel E 1975 Late CapitalismNew Left Books, London Annals of the Association of American Geographers86
Martin, R 1995 The French film industry: a crisis of art 306-23
and commerce ColumbiaJournal of World Business 30 - 1998 Regions and the WorldEconomy:the Coming Shape
6-17 of Global Production, Competition, and Political Order
Menger P M 1993 L'hegemonie parisienne: economie Oxford University Press, Oxford
et politique de la gravitation artistique Annales: Econ- - 1999a The cultural economy: geography and the
omies, Societes,Civilisations6 1565-1600 creative field Media, Culture,and Society21 807-17
Molotch H 1996 'LA as design product: how art works in - 1999b The US recorded music industry: on the rela-
a regional economy in Scott A J and Soja E W eds tions between organization, location, and creativity in
The City: Los Angeles and Urban Theory at the End of the cultural economy Environmentand Planning A 31
the Twentieth Century University of California Press, 1965-84
Berkeley and Los Angeles 225-75 - 2000 The Cultural Economy of Cities: Essays on the
Montgomery S S and Robinson M D 1993 Visual artists Geographyof Image-ProducingIndustriesLondon, Sage
in New York: what's special about person and place? Soja E W 2000 Postmetropolis:Critical studies of cities and
Journalof Cultural Economics17 17-39 regions Blackwell, Oxford
Negus K 1997 The production of culture in du Gay Storper M and Christopherson S 1987 Flexible special-
P ed Productionof Culture/Culturesof ProductionSage, ization and regional industrial agglomerations: the
London 68-104 case of the US motion-picture industry Annals of the
- 1998 Cultural production and the corporation: musical Associationof AmericanGeographers77 260-82
genres and the strategic management of creativity in Thrift N 1994 On the social and cultural determinants
the US recording industry Media,Culture,and Society20 of international financial centers: the case of the City
359-79 of London in Corbridge S Thrift N and Martin R
O'Connor K 1991 Creativity and metropolitan develop- eds Money, Power and Space, Blackwell, Oxford 327-
ment: a study of media and advertising in Australia 55
AustralianJournalof RegionalStudies 6 1-14 Urry J 1995 ConsumingPlaces Routledge, London
Peet R 1997 The cultural production of economic forms in White H C and White C A 1965 Canvases and Careers:
R Lee and J Wills eds Geographiesof EconomiesArnold, InstitutionalChangein the FrenchPainting World,Wiley,
London 37-46 New York
Porter M E 1990 The CompetitiveAdvantageof Nations The Williams R 1976 Keywords:a Vocabularyof Culture and
Free Press, New York Society Fontana, London
Pratt A C 1997 The cultural industries production system: Wollen P 1993 Raiding the Icebox:Reflectionson Twentieth-
a case study of employment change in Britain, 1984-91 CenturyCultureIndiana University Press, Bloomington
Environmentand Planning A 29 1953-74 and Indianapolis
Relph E 1976 Place and PlacelessnessPion, London Zukin S 1995 The Culturesof Cities Blackwell, Oxford

S-ar putea să vă placă și