Sunteți pe pagina 1din 9

2

The Left Turns: Why They Happened


and How They Compare
Juan Pablo Luna

e ompared to five or ten years ago, the politieal map of Latin Ameriea today
contains significantly more political movements and governments that call
themselves leftist or are classified as sueh by external observers.' What explains
these left turns? Has the region shifted left? lf so, how do we analyze conver-
gence and divergence within the left tums?
Current seholarship on the rise of the left provides relatively homologous
answers to the first question, but seems inadequately equipped to address the
remaining and perhaps more pressing anes. Theoretical perspectives focus al-
most exclusively on analyzing leadership style, politieal diseourse and rheto-
rie, and short-term institutional developments. Empiricall y, there is a lack of
fieldwork on how these politieal parties and leaders builttheir electoral eoali-
tiao s Qver time, how these coalitions are structured today, and what mean s
were employed and ehallenges faeed (espeeially distributive dilemrnas) by
contemporary leftist governments in seeking to promote socioeconomic
change in Latio America while institutionalizing their power.
Moreover, sorne aspects of Qur conventional view of ruling leftist govem-
ments could hinder our exploration of these additional questions. A case in
point is the established diehotorny of the "good" (soeial-demoeratie) and
"bad" (pop ulist) left, whieh needs to be ehallenged. These classifieations are
excessively driven by reactions to di stincti ve leadership styles and rhetoric
and are usually based on short-term analyses of the eonditions that enabled the
emergenee of those leaderships. In a nutshell, as in biology, analOmy should
precede taxonomy.
In thi s chapte r 1 frrst sketch the emerging scholarly consenSllS on the rise
of the left. 1 then propose an alternative approaeh to analyzing eurrent leftist
governments, illustrating its po tential ll sefulness with a cursory analysis of
two "soeial-demoeratie" governments (Chile and Uruguay) and a mueh briefer
exantination of two other cases (Boli via and Venezuela).
24 Thinking About the Left The Left Turns 25

The Left Turns: Why and How? tors, such as the nature of the pany system in which the pany/movement com-
peted before taking office (Castaeda 2006; Lanzaro 2007).
Four statements synthesize the convenlional wisdorn on the ri se of the left in
Latin America: Although the normative overtones of J. G. Castaeda's c1assification are
obvious (Weyland 2007), both K. Weyland and 1. Lanzaro essentially coincide
1. Parlies and individual leaders self-proclaimed as left, center-Ieft, or with Castaeda's clustering of leftist governments into two different groups: a
progressive made significant electoral inroads in the recent wave of eJections. populist left (i.e., those led by Hugo Chvez in Venezuela, Nstor Kirchner in
This mean S that today approximately 60 percent of Latin Americans are cur- Argenti na, Evo Morales in Bolivia, Rafael Correa in Ecuador, and Daniel
rently being governed by the left (Arnson 2007). Ortega in Nicaragua) and a reconstructed radicalleft that originated in the rev-
2. Citizens' disenchantment with the state of affairs in their countries olutionary movements and leftist fronts of the 1960s and 1970s (i.e., those
could be said lo be the lowest common denominator explaining the rise af the headed by Lula da Silva in Brazil, Ricardo Lagos and Michelle Bachelet in
left. This disenchantment is twofold: On the one hand it stems from the fail- Chile, and Tabar Vsquez in Uruguay).' According to this view, while the re-
ure of market reforms implemented during the 1990s to fulfi ll their promise of constructed or social-democratic left prioritizes social policies while embrac-
deli vering salid econonUc growth and social progress, instead creating new ing liberal democracy and a market eco'lomy, the populist version is charac-
vulnerabilities, with the aggravating factor of a recession that was sparked by terized by weak ideological underpinnings and a basic desire to maintain its
the 1998 Asian fina ncial crisis. On the other hand was the political discontent popularity at any cost, even when this results in economic mismanagement,
with traditional parties or more generally with the polit;cal system represent- the erosion of democratic values, or harsh anti-US rhetoric.
ing the status qua; this usually emerged in the midst of governance erises Among others adhering to the "two lefts" thesis, Castaeda (2006) and
and/or corruption scandals Iinked to political arrangements that consolidated Lanzaro (2007) coincide in explaining these divergent configurations in terms
in the aftermath of each country's transition to democracy. This discontent was of political institutions. In this regard, Weyland's focus on the preeminence of
rooted in weak and poor-quality democratic institutions and by major failures state rents (oil, natural gas) in populist cases is an exception that is especially
of political representation (Mainwaring, Bejarano, and Pizarro 2006). important for explaining how different leaders attempted to institutionali ze
In su m, the leftist governments currently in office in Latin America seem to their electoral coalition once in office. 3 In general, though, the authors offer a
have won recent elections on the basis of a minimum common denominator com- similar causal account: while social-democratic or reconstructed lefts origi-
posed of hree elements: (1) opposing incumbents (in almost every case tradi- nated in the context of an institutionalized party system and underwent a long
tional parties or traditional politicians) by mobilizing economic and political dis- process of partisan adaptation (renovation, moderation) to compete efficiently
content duri ng the regional economic crisis; (2) being able to bring in that system, populist variants are prototypical of inchoate party systems in
together a broad, socially heterogeneous electoral constituency in the context of which charismatic leaderships emerge rapidly 10 fill a power vacuum left by
fragmented civil societies, usually drawing on highly segmented mobilization the collapse of an outgoing pany system.
and electoral strategies to atlract different types of (disenchanted) voters; and (3) While it is true that this type of explanation provides important insights
having a charismatic leader who was able to bring together the broad con- into the nature of tbese political parties and movements, it also suffers from
sti tuency nceded to unseat incumbents. This fonnula seems not only to apply to sorne blind spots that reduce analytical leverage. Specifically, available narra-
so-called populist cases but also to situations in wruch an institutionalized leftist tives fail to identify and explain the important political and policy divergences
party reached power, aided at least in part by strong leaders who were able to that occur within each type, not distinguishing between cases pertaining to dif-
broaden the electoral appeal of thei, panies (e.g., Lula, Vzquez, and Bachelet). ferent leftist types and to crucial intragroup divergences. The next section dis-
3. Leftist governments freshly arri ved into office were until recently en- cusses these limitations and propases an alternative analytical approach.
joying extended periods in power during the economic bonanza created by the
commodity boom. This boom has helped to sustain and strengthen the shift to
the left in contemporary Latin America and provided sorne room for policy Unpacking Leftist Types: "Anatomy" and
shifts regarding the region 's development mode!. Its Implications for Government Action
4. Apart from the three commonalities listed aboye, significant divergences
exist among governments that have recently been elected in the region. Available 1 argued aboye that the nature of the recentl y arrived heterogeneous leftist gov-
analyses have largely attributed these divergences to political-institutional fac- ernments in Latin America, and what they do once in office, is contingent upon
26 Thinking About the Left The Left Turns 27

each country's long-terrn development. Although lhat long-term trajectory Socialist Party. Instead, given my interest in the analysis of leftist govem-
plays out in the type of leadership, party, and social base of lhe left that is pres- ments, in Chile's case 1 will refer to the government of the Concertacin,
ent in each case, ir also introduces other types of constraints that are relatively which al so ineludes nonleftist parties such as the Christian Democrats, the
independent from the type of leadership and party (where those exis!) that it Radicals, and at least some leaders of the Partido por la Democracia, and not
creates. To drive this point home, a brief discussion of the typology recently solely lhe Socialist Party. In short, the actions of govemments in which leftist
put forth by S. Levitsky and K. M. Roberts (forthcoming) seems worthy. parties take part are obviously related to those parties' organizational patterns
Levitsky and Roberts's (forthcoming) proposal adds a second dimension and mobilization strategies. However, different partisan constraints and a se-
to the institutionalization-based classification of leftist types, which lhey cap- ries of nonpartisan ones should be more centrally considered to understand
ture by classifying leftist parties as "established parties vs. new political move- what those governments actually do while in office.
ments." The second point they consider is the "degree to which political au- Second, in terms of parti san constraints, my typology lends more atten-
thority is concentrated in the hands of a dominant personality," which tion to distributive and programmatic conflicts occurring within the partisan
translates ioto either top-down (usually "autocratic") exercises of power or organization and social base of the left in government. Although I concur
into processes that allow leadership accountability to the "broader interests of with Levitsky and Roberts's general classification of organizationall
parties and or movements," making possible instanees of political mobiliza- mobilizational strategies, ] suggest these might not be predominant strate-
tian from below. This dimension contributes significantly to our understand- gies (perhaps with the exception of the populist left type). Socioeconomic
ing of the left in Latin America by taking into account the predominant type and nterest group fragmentation in contemporary Latin America makes it
of linkages that exist between the party or leader and its constituents. This en- difficult for political parties to craft a winning electoral coalition on the basis
ables, for instanee, the unpacking of the "populist, wrong left" group into three of only one type of linkage to their electorates. UsuaBy, as argued aboye,
analyticaBy different types: a populist machine (established party organization leftist parties have won elections by putting together a diverse electorate,
and concentrated power) 5uch as is present in Kirchner's Peronism, the sharing relatively high levels of discontent with the status quo as a minimum
Alianza Popular Revolucionaria Americana (APRA), and the Frente common denominator. Beyond this minimum common denominator, leftist
Sandinista de Liberacin Nacional (FSLN); "a populist left" (new political party social bases are heterogeneous and bring together distinct electoral
movement, concentrated power) present in the cases of Chvez, Gutirrez, and bases with different and, in some cases, opposing stakes regarding eventual
Correa; and a "movernent left" (new political rnovernent, disperse power) rep- policy shifts. In those cases, distributive conflicts are stark and governing
resented by the Bolivian Movimiento al Socialismo (MAS). The remaining leftist parties face the challenge to reconcile divergent and frequently com-
group corresponds to the "institutionalized, good left" type, collapsing the peting interests, while sirnultaneously seeking to irnplement reforms and
Partido dos Trabalhadores (PT) in Brazil, the Socialist Party in Chile, and maintain their electoral appeal.
Frente Amplio (FA) in Uruguayas "electoral-professional left." The diversity of leftist party social bases and the potential distributive
By enriching our understanding of lhese parties' organizational pattems, conflicts that might run wilhin each party's electorate should then be conse-
this typology does a lot in terms of illuminating lhe nature of electoral mobiliza- quential for analyzing government action and cannot be completely grasped
tion occurring in each case and sorne very relevant characteristics of the current by only looking at the institutionalization and concentration of power present
leftist govemments in Latin America. The typology 1 propose is more focu sed in different cases. In short, the distributive struggles created by the necessary
on trying to understand how lhese different lefts govem and, eventually, how combination of different linkage types with alternative constituencies might
lhat knowledge will help predict which types of policymaking will occur under introduce, for government action, constraints that are more consequential than
each leadership type. In particular, 1 am interested in policymaking lhat relates those yielded by the predominant (or more visible) linkage type. This type of
[O eventual shifts in each country's developrnent rnodel. For that reason, struc- constraint might be caBed "endogenous," as it still deals with lhe nature of the
tural constraints and opportunities for seeking and institutionalizing those shifts electoral mobilization vehiele and its relationship to civil society.
should be brought into lhe analysis. While some of lhose constraints and oppor- Third, though they partially translate into lhe trajectory of each party (in-
tunities derive from lhe type of party in power and the relative autonomy it has stitutionaLized vs. new) and into the endogenous constraints 1 just described,
from civil society, others relate to palh-dependent configurations that are left out nonpartisan factors also introduce significant "exogenous" constraints into gov-
of the picture if we focus too stringentIy on party leaderships. ernment action. In shOlt, two leftist governments sharing similar programmatic
This different emphasis is also consequential for case selection. Levitsky agendas might govern differently and might seek different policy outcomes not
and Roberts (forthcoming), while dealing with lhe Chilean case, analyze the only due 10 endogenous (partisan) constraints, but also due to the influence of
28 Thinking About the Left The Left Turns 29

structural (exogenous) anes. For nstanee, in each case state institutions and 80- Within contemporary left turns it is possible to identify two different pro-
ciostructural configurations flowing from each country's long-term trajectory grammatic currents attempting to iron out conflicting goals. The first seeks
and from a country's specific ways of integrating iota the global econorny in- gradual sociostructural change (i.e., greater equality) within the contours of
troduce a different set of constraints. At least in the cases 1 analyze below, ex- liberal democracy and a market economy. Given these features, it could be la-
ogenous and endogenous constraints seem to be largely collinear, which justi- beled a social-democratic project that seeks reforms to ameliorate social con-
fies collapsing both types of constraints iota a single dimension distinguishing ditions and reduce the friction between liberal democracy and a market econ-
between high or low constraints on government action. However, for the sake omy. 5 This does not mean, however, that the project is dri ven by and
of clarity, 1 claim it makes sense to keep endogenous and exogenous limits to implemented through the type of sociopolitical coalitions of the kind observed
government action as analytically distinct constraints. in social-democratic Europe. In Table 2.1, this programmatic current is labeled
In this section 1 show how taking these nonpartisan and noninstitutional "ameliorationist/institutional" and will be referred to as such in the remainder
(exogenous) constraints into consideration produces a different elassification of this chapter.
of country cases than those already available. In particular, it yields the un- The second current represents a more radical programmatic inclination,
packing of the social-democratic type that has so far been treated as a single one that has been labeled-mistakenly in my view-as a "populist" or
current by those who have discussed Castaeda's influential two-group elassi- "neopopulist" project. These labels are both too normatively biased and ana-
fication and proposed more !han two types (Levitsky and Roberts, forthcom- Iytically obscuring, in part because those approaches usually confiate political
ing; Lanzaro 2007; Roberts 2007b; Schamis 2006). All these alternative clas- phenomena (an unmediated, top-down relationship between a leader and an
sification attempts cluster social-democratic govemments (Brazil, Chile, and amorphous pueblo) and policy output (irresponsible policymaking) (see
Uruguay) together, while introducing distinctions within the populist left. The Weyland 1996).
unpacking of the social-democratic type also justifies the greater attention I ProgrammaticalIy, this second cunent is characterized by its wilLingness
pay to what follows in the cases that have been, for the moment, treated as a lO seek alternatives for political and econornic inelusion that might go beyond
single group. In this chapter, I focus only on Chile and Uruguay among cases liberal democracy and a market econorny. In this sen se it entails a predisposi-
typically included in the social democratic campo To clarify the argument, I tion toward what Arditi (2008) calls a "post-liberal" attempt at promoting a
also provide a cursory discussion of Venezuela and Bolivia. new sociopolitical arrangement. This implies the search for a foundational
Table 2.1 classifies the currently goveming lefts in Chile, Uruguay, project. Therefore, following Beasley-Murray, Cameron, and Hershberg's in-
Venezuela, and Bolivia into two dimensions: the prograrnmatic orientation of the troductory chapter to this volume, 1 abel this current "radical/constituent."
leftist project carried by !he goveming party or leader and!he level of (endogenous In analyzing cases within this second current, we should not underestimate
and exogenous) constraints that each government faces regarding government !he possibility that foundational attempts could significantly depart from the
action. Regarding !he first dimension structuring the typology-the orientation ideals of liberal democracy and a market economy. In a nutshell, foundational
of the goveming party or leader's project-I argue !hat current left tums in Latin movements rnight either crystallize into Iliberal or radical democratic regimes,
Arnerica represent a contemporary manifestation of the region's perennial strug- which both represent attempts to solve the political incorporation crisis. In turn,
gle to pursue political and socioeconornic inelusion simultaneously.4 initiatives for socioeconornic incorporation could range from a fuIl-blown so-
cialist attempt to the massive clientelistic redistribution of state rents in the
Table 2.1 A leftist Government Typology: Nature 01 Change Sought
short runo Interestingly, in either of these two possibilities, these regimes rnight
and Levels of Endogenous (partisan) and Exogenous achieve greater social incorporation and, therefore, enjoy broader popular sup-
(nonpartisan) Constraints on Government port than their predecessors. In short, massive social nelusion-at least in the
short run---could and does frequently occur in the context of political regimes
Nature of Change Sought
by Leftist Project Levels of Endogenous and Exogenous Constraints that might not fulfiJl our acadernic checldist of a liberal democracy. In a way,
these regimes exemplify the sometimes overlooked contradictions that the pur-
Low High suit of radical social democratization might entail when attempted through lib-
eral-democratic means and in the context of highly unequal social structures. _
Ameliorationistllnstitutional Chile Uruguay Dismissal of these endeavors as merely "populist" means we lose much
Radical/Constituent Venezuela Bolivia
of their apparent analytical significance. Instead, we need to understand and
30 Thinking About the Left The Left Turns 31

analyze these political movements as attempts, quite possibly doomed at- the goveming elite lacks complete access to an autonomous state bureaucracy,
tempts, to eraft a new compromise between a political regime and a socioeco- either because the state apparatus is too weak or because it is powerful but
namic development model. Drawing insights from the historie interaction be- largely autonomous from the executive power. Therefore, in low-constrained
tween capitalism and democracy in currently advanced capitalist democracies systems public policy is largely implemented through top-bottom processes,
(see, e.g., Moore 1966; Skocpol1979; Rueschemeyer, Stephens, and Stephens while in highly constrained systems public policy results from a much more
1992), it is possible to expect these processes to entail sociopolitical and/or complex interaction between top-bottom and bottom-up processes.
economic violen ce. In arguing the use of this second dimension of analysis, 1 would like to
What basically characterizes this second current is its rejection of a COffi- drawa short comparative sketch of the populist lefts of Venezuela and Bolivia
prornise between a market economy and a liberal democracy and its apparent that closely paraHels lhe analysis of Roberts (2007b) and that of Levitsky and
search for something new. This search is particularly intense in pIaces where Roberts (forthcoming). In Venezuela, Chvez carne into power through a
fadures in political representation and social exclusion in the 1990s created a pow,rvacuum createdoy-the-cotlap;; of the partidocracia. His rapid rise
political vacuum that leftist leaders are now attempting to fill through con- meant that he lacked more organic ties with organized social interests, which
sti tuent referms. Beyond their minimum common denominator, which 1 pro- gave him a high degree of autonomy once he took office. On this basis, and
pose to use as a demarcating criteria and that combines the rejection of both drawing on massive cash inflows, Venezuela's president was able to institu-
past policies and traditional potitical arrangements, it would be wrong to view tionalize his support from aboye by creating a "dependent civil society"
such attempts as a unified and prograrnmatically cohesive current. (Roberts 2006; Hawkins and Hansen 2006).
In summary, the first dimension (nature of change sought by the leftist In contrast, MAS in Bolivia originated from a very welI-organized social
leader/party)
.
1 propose using to analyze current leftist oaovernments distin: movement that was very active in the demise of the country's traditionaI party
gUlshes between ameliorationist/institutional and radical/constituent pro- system during the 1990s and earIy 2000s. Moreover, the country's ethnic and
grams. Beyond conceptual specifications, this dimension produces a classifi- regional cleavages converged with opposition to the implementation of neolib-
eation that is largely collinear with those already available (good vs. bad left, eral policies (Van Cott 2005; Yashar 2005). Evo Morales, therefore, carne into
social-democratic vs. populist left), which place Chile, Uruguay, and Brazil in the president's office with a much clearer mandate from organized civil soci-
one group and Venezuela, Bolivia, and Ecuador in the other. 6 From an ex- ety, which translates into significantly less autonomy than Chvez in govern-
planatory perspective, these classifications might also resonate well with con- ment action. As a result, Morales's govemment faces the challenge of keeping
ventional wisdom, which sees the social-democraric left as having emerged a hold on its moderate middle-class vote while simultaneously fulfiHing the
from long-standing leftist parties that pursued a gradual process of ideological more radical demands of its original social base in MAS and organized civil
moderation, and the foundational left as the offspring of deeper crises of po- society. Exogenous constraints (Iike those imposed by the organizational ea-
Iibcal representation and the collapse of traditional parry systems. pacity and power resources of the opposition and by central state weakness)
... seem also higher in this case .
* * * 1 now turn to a more thorough narrative ofthe cases of Chile and Uruguay.
This comparison might yield additional support for a typology that, by consid-
Different insights into conventional wisdom can be gained from introducing a ering constraints in a broader sense, looking beyond partisan factors, is able to
second dimension, that is, the presence of low or high levels of constraint on unpack the social-democratic type.
leftist governments' ability to carry out lheir prograrnmatic agendas. In the low- In Chile, the combination of radical economic reforms under Pinochet, the
constraints category 1 place governments that enjoy greater autonomy from or- renewal of the Chilean left in exile folIowing the forced ending of Allende's
ganized civil society, that control partisan organizations from aboye (in this re- government, and the exclusion of the Communist Party from the Concertacin
spect this is colIinear to Levitsky and Roberts's category), and that have at their effectively unraveled the organic tes between the Socialist Party and orga-
disposal autonomous state apparatus. In contrast, highly constrained nized popular sectors (Garretn 1989; Oxhorn 1995; Roberts 1998). Today, the
cases have stronger autonomously organized civil society and institutionalized relationship between organized labor and the Concertacin is marginal, creat-
linkages to the governing party or social movement; partisan organjzations ing low levels of endogenous constraints.
have greater resources to constrain leadership; the leftist social base is strained Meanwhile, since the transition to democracy, ideological linkages be-
by distributive contlicts tied to the country's economic development model; and tween parties and the citizenry have generally been determined by the author-
32 Thinking About the Left The Left Turns 33

itarian/democratic cleavage or by pro- versus anti-Pinochet identification party, and 65 percent of these partisan sympathi zers are ren/eamplis/as
(Tironi and Agero 1999; Torcal and Mainwaring 2003). Moreover, mass (LAPOP 2006).
alienation from potitics and the party system has grown steadily, leading to a In short, the Uruguayan leftist party is broadly supported by the eitizenry
significant decrease in voter tumout (Altman 2006) and invalid voting (Carlio and has a dual support base that ineludes strong ties to organized groups.
2006). In 2004, when asked to position themselves as "Ieft," "center," "right," Moreover, distinct fractions of the party have privileged relations with differ-
or "independent," more than 40 percent of Chileans did not position them- ent segments of its social base.
selves in any category or chose "independent" (Centro de Estudios Pblicos, In other cases-those historically characteri zed by the presence of clien-
CEP Survey, annual average, www.cepchile.cl).In 2006, roughly 75 percent telistic Iinkages between traditional parties and voters-the erosion of oli-
of Chileans did not sympathize with any particular political party and only 9 garchie parties' ability to provide nonprogrammatie side payments to their
percent considered a candidate's party to be the most important factor (vis-a- constituents led to party-system collapse (e.g., in Venezuela), increasing voter
vis individual candidate traits) in deciding their vote (LAPOP 2006). alienation (e.g., in Colombia and Costa Rica), or the reerafting of nonprogram-
As a corollary matic cooptation patterns by incumbents (e.g., in Peru and Argentina, and
. . to these trends, office-seeking politicians from all camps , Venezuela under Chvez). Uruguay's case is distinguished by the different so-
f ace strong incentIves to compete on nonprogrammatic linkages for the sup-
port of an increasingly ideologically dealigned electorate. At the national cial eoalitions of import-substitution indusLrialization (lSI) beneficiaries and
level, candidate-centered appeals seem to explain the electoral a1legiance of their taeit allianee with the FA, whieh systematically helped to eontain popu-
dealigned voters. The recent presidential candidacies of Joaqun Lavn in 2000 lar discontent while at the same time enhancing interest aggregation levels in
and Bachelet in 2005 were the most successful in obtaining the vote of non- Uruguayan society, and the significance of prograrnmatic linkages for party
ideological voters; particularly in lower strata, both candidacies were signifi- competition in the system.
canU y better in generating electoral support among independents and Moreover, the enduring strength of traditional partisan subcultures and the
dealigned voters than their opponents. gradual nature ofthe reforms (and econontic decay) eushioned electoral dealign-
It is therefore possible to conclude that a sizable group of voters who sup- ment and laid the foundation for a prograrnmatic realignment, through which FA
ported the candidaey of the radical right in 200 I switehed in 2005 to favor became the interpreter of popular discontent with reform attempts of the 1990s
Baehelet's presidential bid. In spite of their obvious differences, both eandida- and their aftennaths. The divergent pattem observed in Uruguay is therefore re-
eies represented a strong renovating swing , campaigning against the oId poli- lated to a specific causal configuration centered on a well-institutionalized and
tics of the Concertacin and promising a new, closer-to-the-people governing "uncontantinated': party with longstanding friendly ties with interest groups,
style. Finally, while Bachelet's eandidaey emerged from her high popularity good territorial organizatlon, consolidated leadership, prograrnmatic appeal, and

J
ratings in pubLic apioion polls and in contrast to the Concertacin's rank and goveming experience at the munieipallevel. In tum, Lhis partisan and social base
file, the eandidate did not systematieally pursue links with labor unions or configuration translates into higher levels of endogenous constraints than in
other social movements representing popular sectors. Therefore, apart trom Chile. A brief exeursion into the political management dilemmas faced by the
Lhe need todiseipline the Concertaein's eongressional delegation, Baehelet's Vzquez administration might serve to illu strate this point.
admmlstratlOn enJoys considerable autonomy from the parties that supported In the electoral debaele with traditional parties in 2004 when the FA took
her candidacy and from civil society in general. office, the party's maln challenge was to remain unified to ensure effective gov-
In eontrast to the Chilean left, Uruguay's FA is portrayed as a party with emance and maintain a working majority in Congress. Thus it was essential to
mass appeal mat emerged and won office by opposing neoliberal reform at- align mainstreann FA fractions with the executive. To aeeomplish this, Tabar
tempts in the context of redemocrati zation. FA's original support base was the Vsquez appointed the heads of the Senate Iists of eaeh majar fraetion to his eab-
organized working c1ass and progressive sectors of the middle c1asses and the inet; they also were the most prominent fractional leaders.
intell igentsia. During the 19908, these groups solidified their link to FA as the By filling up the executive braneh with powerful FA leaders, Tabar
party opposed subsequent reform attempts that were only marginally success- Vsquez sought to circumscribe potential conflicts to the council of minlsters,
fuI. Later on, drawing on public discontent with traditional parties, FA won where they eould be solved while avoiding harsher and more deeentralized
over the unorganized poor, a segment historieally eoopted by traditional par- confrontations in Congress. Once issues were settled in the executive, con-
ties, while retainlng its strong Iinks to its historical constituency. As a result, gressional majorities would be secured through fraetional discipline. For dif-
today roughly 55 pereent of Uruguayans align themselves with a politieal ficult issues, Vsquez allowed his ministers, who represented different frac-
34 Thinking About the Left Th e Left Turns 35

tional views 0 0 controversial issues, to di seu ss their discrepancies openly, The challenge is that while the FA's traditional constituency might becollle
even in the press, up lo the point where the continuity of a minister was threat- alienated by reformist attempts and possesses the organizational capacity to
ened. On those occasions the president stepped in to arbitrate the conflicto es- block them (essentially by mobilizing fractional support), the party's emergent
tablishing the final position and sometimes compensating the losing side, ei- constituency-the one most likely to benefit from such reforms-Iacks this de-
ther symbolically or through tangible side payments. When congressional gree of organizational capacity, its recent allegiance to the FA being especially
approval was needed, fraction leaders were then made responsible for secur- motivated by economic and political discontent with the status quo. The
ing discipline in Congress. emerging consti tuency might therefore become alienated from the party if tan-
Frente Amplio's government has a1so confronted difficult times with labor gible improvements (Le., job creation) are nol forthcomjng . However, such im-
unions. While the reinstatement of tripartite collective bargaining and the provements would depend in part on implementing reforms that are politically
passing of a new statute protecting union activities solidified the links between costly for the party, especially to certain FA fractions with strong ties to orga-
FA and the Plenario Intersindical de Trabajadores-Convencin Nacional de _ nized labor. These ties are not only salient vis-a-vis state employees, but are
Trabajadores (PIT-CNT), recent state reform proposals have triggered labor also prominent in the case of unions that would have an important say in any
mobilizations opposing the government. After the approval of reforms that had refonns that were introduced in areas such as pensions or education.
been part of the party's historical platform-such as the creation of a direct in-
come tax and a new health insurance system-the party's main challenge, ac- * * *
cording to one tap government official, is "to prevent interests groups [i.e.,
pension beneficiaries, civil servants, banking system unions] from perforating We turn now to Chile, where state and market reforms have yielded a du al so-
those reforms" through the approval of ad hoc exemptions and subsidies con- cial configuration that assigns a much greater role to market allocation and a
ceded in response lo social and fractional mobilization.7 much lesser one to the state and ISI-related corporations. Here, the weakening
To sum up, the anatomy of the FA government translates into significant of organized interest groups has its counterpart in indi viduali zed access to fi-
political management dilemmas that imposed salient tradeoffs during the first nance and mass consumption. Finally, while upper and upper-middle sectors
half of the presidential termo In this example, different pattems of linkage to purchase social protection (pensions, health, and education) on the private
specific social bases yield important differences that are especially useful for market, lower social segments have access to targeted, state-supplied social
analyzing the actions of Latin American leftist forces currently in power. For assistance of significantly lower quality. The municipalization of health care
instance, distinct distributive dilemmas could be derived from each leftist and education has further fragmented and weakened the organizational capac-
party's historical trajectory and current social base configuration. However, ity of unions tied to these sectors (Castiglioni 2005).
the salience and shape of such distributive struggles also depend on the inter- As a result of this configuration, popular sectors and public servants' orga-
action between politico-institutional factors (endogenous constraints) and so- nizations have significantly weakened, while business interests and private com-
cial and state structures (exogenous constraints). Although both types of con- panies responsible for providing health care (Instituciones de Salud Provisional,
straints seem to be largely collinear for classification purposes, they are or IS APREs), pensions (Administradores de Fondos Previsionales, or AFPs),
analytically distinct. Again, a cursory comparison of Chile and Uruguay seems and education (pri vate corporations running educational establishments) have
useful to illustrate this claim. grown stronger (Castiglioni 2005). Due to this trajectory the Concertacin lacks
In Uruguay, the ISI model was only partially dismantled in the 1990s. organic ties with the labor movement. 8
From a sociological perspective, this reformist pattero gave rise to "three This state of affairs translates into lower constraints for the Concertacin,
Urugu ays," eaeh of which roughly encompassed a third of the population: (1) which in tufO means that progressive policy change, while not impossible in
a pri vatized, market-oriented sector represented by upper social segments; (2) Chile, wi lllikely depend on top-down political agency. Indeed, two recent ex-
a corporatist Uruguay dependent on state rents, mainl y composed of the mid- amples-the approval of Plan AUGE (Acceso Universal con Garantas
die classes; and (3) a socially marginalized group unable to compete in the Explcitas en Salud) under the Lagos govemment, whieh significantly con-
market and that has lost, or never had access to, state protection (Filgueira et tributed to reducing social inequity in health care provision (Dvila 2005), and
al 2006). In a loosely schematic way the second group represents FA's tradi- the present administration 's introduction of a noncontributory universal pen-
tional constituency and the third group the party's emerging one. sion that would also improve social welfare in Chile-were proposals that
36 Thinking About the Left The Left Turns 37

originated among the political elite and in the absence of oterest groups push- ies, who are the FA's historical social base and have organic ties with sorne of
ing for their implementation. This low-constrained configuration is nol only the party fractions.
the result of partisan (endogenous) factors. Pinochet regime's dismantling of In short, to pursue such reforms, the FA is constrained by the lack of po-
the ISI model translated into elite autonomy after the transition to democracy litical and institutional autonorny, which results from its social base configu-
by weakening or simply wiping out oterest groups tied to previous policies. ration, a state with much less autonomy and institutional capacity than its
This places Chile in sharp contrast with Uruguay, where any reformist attempt Chilean counterpart and a more difficult insertion into the global economy. In
must confront and accornmodate oterest groups tied to the benefits of previ- tenos of state structures, and paraphrasing Peter Evans's famous formula of
ous policies and to lhe FA itself. the state's need for "embedded autonomy" (1995), it cauld be argued that
The different configuration of constraints that these governments face while lhe Chilean state has autonomy and lacks embeddedness, the Uruguayan
could also explain why the Concertacin in Chile has confronted increasing state is socially embedded but not autonomous.
levels of social inequality but has exc1uded a progressive tax referm from its This section has not sought to provide a systematic analysis of leftist pol-
agenda, while in Uruguaya progressive ncome-tax referm was implemented itics and policies in contemporary Chile and Uruguay, but rather has attempted
by Frente Amplio after only tWQ years in office. Moreover, while the FA res- to illustrate sorne of the insights that can be gained from paying more atten-
urrected collective wage bargaining irnmediately after taking office (which tion to leftist government features that go beyond leadership style and partisan
rapidly translated into a further strengthening of the labor movement), the organization. Specifically, I have argued that greater attention should be paid
Concertacin's agenda has been more oriented toward further liberalization in to structural variables and state structures that nteract with those politico-
labor. Meanwhile, the divergent trajectory of these two political forces could institutional variables in a path-dependent sequence, creating leaderships that,
also explain why FA decided not to sign a free trade agreement (FTA) with the beyond the prograrnmatic current they pertain to (ameliorationistlinstitutional
United States (after Vsquez and his finance minister actively pursued it) in vs. radical/constituent), are more autonomous or more constrained due to both
the midst of fractional and activists' confrontations, while the Chilean govern- partisan (endogenous) and nonpartisan (exogenous) configurations. While such
ment under Lagos signed one without facing any significant opposition from path dependence is not deterrninistic, the scope, shape, and political manage-
civil society or partisan activists. ment of future policy shifts will inevitably entail substantiaUy divergent
To further argue the role of exogenous constraints into government action processes and outcornes in each case. To close, Table 2. 1 places the four cases
it could be useful to assume for a moment that pursuing a "social-democratic" brietly analyzed in this section within the two-dimensional typology 1 have pro-
model is both feasible and satisfying. Chile and Uruguay confront very distinct posed for future analyses of Latin America's left turns.
challenges and opportunities in their path toward "social democracy." In
Chile, the state should take a more active role in reregulating the economy and
in providing greater decornmodification of social welfare. To do so it has a Conclusion
leaner and more autonomous state bureaucracy and political leadership that
has gained increasing autonomy from popular sectors, which in turn have Leftist parties and leaderships swept into office on the promise of solving what
gradually become, alienated from political mobilization in exchange for indi- Luis Reygadas and Fernando Filgueira (Chapter 9, this volume) aptly caU the
vidualized market consumption, access to targeted social assistance, and/or region's "second incorporation crisis." This second (social and political) ncor-
plain social anomy. However, powerful business sectors here are likely to poration crisis paraUels the first, which resulted in popular sectors being enfran-
block those reforms and have the political c10ut to do so. chised and partiaUy incorporated through different sociopolitical arrangements
In Uruguay, crafting a more competitive and profitable insertion into the under import-substitution industrialization (CoUier and CoUier 1991; Filgueira
global economy while improving social welfare involves a complex combina- 1999, 2007). The emergence of lhis second crisis after the exhaustion of ISI
tion of deregulation and reregulation in state and social policy reforms. Both brought Latin American countries into disequilibrium, providing leftist and pro-
business sectors and marginalized social groups would benefit from strategi- gressive leaders the opportunity to make recent electoral inroads by promising
cally induced productive investments that enhance both profits and employ- a more inclusive socioeconomic and political regime than those of the l 990s.
ment. However, to provide better investment conditions (including social cap- The relative durability (conjunctural vs. structural) of the leftward shift in a
ital), state and social policy reforms should be undertaken. Such reforms given country depends on the current government's capacity to solve Reygadas
would inevitably undercut the current incornes and benefits of ISI beneficiar- and Filgueira's second incarporation crisis effectively, pursuing both viable po-
38 Thinking About the Left The Leh Turns 39

litical and socioeconomic inclusion. In doing so, these governments could in- 4. For simplicity's sake 1 am emphasizing policies related lO each couotry 's so-
duce a new and more stable socioeconomic and political equilibrium. However, cioeconomi c developrnent model and downplaying other poli cy domaios that might be
bo1h useful and pertinent for drawing altemative distinction s.
avai1able options for change are limited because of a country 's relative social, 5. Although labeling this project as soc ial-democratic cou ld be questionable, see
institutional, and produetive endowments. The presenee of highly fragmented Panizza (2005a) for a lucid argument in defense of thi s particular terminology.
civil societies and weak states are two contextual factors that complicate the 6. Argentina and Peru might pertain to a third "messy" category (as argued by
eventual solutions to a second incorporation cri sis. In short, while current leftist Roberts 2007b).
governments faee the ehaJIenge of providing greater social and politieal inclu- 7. Personal conversation with an official from the Oficina de Planeamiento y
Presupuesto, October 2007.
siveness whi le erafting a viable developing model, path-dependent trajeetories 8. Congress members from the Concertacin and the Alianza a1ike point to busi-
wi lJ shape specific opportunities and constraints in each case. ness interests and lobbies as the most acti ve groups in agenda setting and policymaking
Therefore, lo analyze these left turns in terms of government action, it is in Chile. In the Uruguayan case, pensioners and the PlT-CNT are identified by congress
neeessary to eomplement institutional approaehes and leader/party-eentered members as the dominant civil society actors shaping congressional poli cyrnaki ng
accounts with lhe incorporation of a longer-tenn perspective and sociostruc- (personal interviews 2002-2003).
tural variables. Moreover, beyond party system institutionaJi zation, the nature
of party li nkages with different social bases, eaeh with its own level of orga-
ni zation and specific, often competing, interests in the country's current devel-
opment model, needs to be brought into the analysis. In other words, to better
understand the left turn and its eventual implieations for demoeraey, the analy-
sis of political regimes should be reembedded into the soeioeeonomie and
state struetures in whieh those regimes operate (Cullel 2004; O'Donnell 2004).
By the same token, analyses of eeonomie polieies or of the broader devel-
opment model that leftist governments might pursue should pay more atten-
tion to the social , political, and institutional variables in which those models
are neeessarily embedded, as well as to the soeiopolitieal eoalitions that make
them workab le (or not) in the long runo In a highly simplified way 1 have
ealled this the "anatomy" of leftist governments, whieh translates into high or
low levels of co nstraints. Those constraints are at least as important as the pro-
grammatic projects that seem to inspire the actions and rhetoric of each leftist
party or leader currently in office.

Notes

l. This refers only to the e1ectoralleft (parties and leaders thm have contested, and in
most cases won, recent e1ections in Latin America). Therefore, while meaningful for ana-
Iyzing the rise of the lef! and its broader implications, "other lefts" such as those found in
cultural movements and civil societies in the region fall beyond the scope of this chapter.
2. More recently, Lanzaro (2008); Levitsky and Roberls (forthcoming) ; and
Roberts (2007b) have proposed unpacking the populist left, splitting the cases of
Ali anza Popular Revolucionaria Americana (APRA) in Peru and the Peronist Party in
Argentina from the other populist cases in which a historical populist party is lacking
(Venezuela, Ecuador) or where the populist leader has an organic soc ial-movement
base (Boli via).
3. Obviously, lhe Chi lean case is an exception to thi s pattem; Weyland accommo-
dates this disparity by referring to the Chilean state's hi storical autonomy from polilical
leadership.

S-ar putea să vă placă și