Sunteți pe pagina 1din 27

JOURNAL OF THE EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF BEHAVIOR 2013, 99, 98124 NUMBER 1 (JANUARY)

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS AND EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY


STEVEN R. HURSH AND PETER G. ROMA
INSTITUTES FOR BEHAVIOR RESOURCES
AND
DEPARTMENT OF PSYCHIATRY AND BEHAVIORAL SCIENCES, JOHNS HOPKINS UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MEDICINE

The application of economics principles to the analysis of behavior has yielded novel insights on value and
choice across contexts ranging from laboratory animal research to clinical populations to national trends of
global impact. Recent innovations in demand curve methods provide a credible means of quantitatively
comparing qualitatively different reinforcers as well as quantifying the choice relations between
concurrently available reinforcers. The potential of the behavioral economic approach to inform public
policy is illustrated with examples from basic research, pre-clinical behavioral pharmacology, and clinical
drug abuse research as well as emerging applications to public transportation and social behavior.
Behavioral Economics can serve as a broadly applicable conceptual, methodological, and analytical
framework for the development and evaluation of empirical public policy.
Key words: behavioral economics, demand curve, exponential model, essential value, reinforcer
interactions, choice, public policy

The contribution of Psychology proper to defined as objects of scarce consumption by


Economicswhat most economists and social economists. A second point of convergence is
scientists would recognize as Behavioral Eco- an interest in the process of choice: For the
nomicsis largely limited to cognitive process- economist, the allocation of limited resources to
ing hypotheses of why humans actual financial the consumption of competing goods in the
behavior so often violates the assumptions and marketplace (consumer choice), and for the
models upon which neo-classical economic behaviorist, the division of operant behavior
theory is built, that is, the behavior of economics among competing reinforcers.
(Thaler & Mullainathan, 2008). In contrast, Indeed, the blending of behavioral principles
Behavioral Economics within Psychology is with microeconomic theory has been a fruitful
generally defined as the application of econom- area of research (Green & Freed, 1998;
ic principles as a means of understanding Hursh, 1980, 1984; Hursh & Bauman, 1987;
behavior (typically reinforcement) in animals Kahneman, Slovic, & Tversky, 1982; Lea, 1978;
and humans, that is, the economics of behavior. Of Rachlin & Laibson, 1997) and provides a
course, there are several points of convergence translational framework for extending princi-
between economics and behavioral psychology. ples derived from laboratory studies to an
One is a common interest in the value of goods, understanding of consumer choice observed
defined as reinforcers by the behaviorist, and in whole communities and the influence of
governmental policies on those choices. In this
Preparation of this manuscript and portions of data exposition we will focus more on the application
collection were supported by intramural funds from the of economic methods of analysis and consistent
Institutes for Behavior Resources, the US National Space functional relations than on hypothetical eco-
Biomedical Research Institute through NASA NCC 9-58-
NBPF01602 (Joseph V. Brady and PGR) and Directed
nomic concepts such as utility functions, indif-
Research Project NBPF00008 (PGR), and US National ference curves, and optimal choices in the
Aeronautics and Space Administration grant NNX13AB39G consumer marketplace (Watson & Holman,
(PGR). Some content composed by SRH also appears in 1977). What emerges is an important extension
Hursh, Madden, Spiga, DeLeon, & Francisco (2012), The of behavioral principles and a broadly applica-
translational utility of behavioral economics: The experi-
mental analysis of consumption and choice, in G. J. Madden ble framework for empirical public policy.
(Ed.), APA Handbook of Behavior Analysis: Vol. 2. Translating Concepts of behavioral economics have
Principles Into Practice. proven useful for understanding the environ-
Address correspondence to Dr. Steve Hursh or Dr. Pete mental control of overall levels of behavior for a
Roma, Institutes for Behavior Resources, 2104 Maryland
Avenue, Baltimore, MD 21218, USA (e-mail: srhursh@ibrinc.
variety of commodities in closed systems (Bickel,
org or peteroma@gmail.com). DeGrandpre, Higgins, & Hughes, 1990, 1991;
doi: 10.1002/jeab.7 Foltin, 1992; Hursh, 1984; Lea, 1978; Lea &
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 99

Roper, 1977; Rashotte & Henderson, 1988) the relationship between cost and consumption
and the factors that control the allocation of provides a fundamental definition of the value
behavioral resources among available rein- of reinforcers. In this context, responding is
forcers (Hursh, 1980, 1984; Hursh & Bauman, regarded as a secondary dependent variable
1987). Behavioral economics as practiced by that is important because it is instrumental in
students of operant conditioning and behavior controlling consumption of valued reinforcers.
analysis has borrowed concepts from microeco- In order to study the fundamental relationship
nomics, especially consumer demand theory between responding and consumption in the
and labor supply theory (Allison, 1983; Allison, laboratory, control of deprivation has been
Miller, & Wozny, 1979; Green & Freed, 1998; eliminated and subjects are allowed to control
Lea, 1978; Rachlin, Green, Kagel, & Battalio, their own level of consumptionwhat Hursh
1976; Staddon, 1979; see Watson & Holman, (1980) has termed a closed economy. A wide
1977 for a review of relevant microeconomic range of studies have documented the behav-
theory). When applied in laboratory experi- ioral adjustments that occur in closed econo-
ments, economic concepts are operationalized mies, especially when the reinforcers are
in special ways that build on more fundamental biological necessities like food or water that
behavioral processes such as reinforcement, are physically consumed (see Bauman, 1991;
discrimination, differentiation, and the like. Collier, 1983; Hall & Lattal, 1990; Hursh,
These experiments have directed our attention 1978, 1984; Hursh & Natelson, 1981; Hursh,
to new phenomena previously ignored and new Raslear, Bauman, & Black, 1989; Hursh, Raslear,
functional relations previously unnamed. As Shurtleff, Bauman, & Simmons, 1988; LaFiette
applied here, behavioral economics is focused & Fantino, 1989; Lucas, 1981; Roane, Call, &
on the analysis of consumption of various Falcomata, 2005). Studies of food reinforce-
reinforcers and the responding that produces ment in closed economies demonstrate strik-
that consumption. ingly persistent behavior that is very resistant to
This review provides some basic definitions the effects of reinforcer cost (see Bauman, 1991;
and demonstrates how those concepts can be Foltin, 1992; Hursh, 1978). Other studies in
applied to retrospective and prospective public which subjects are permitted to self-administer
policy research, development, and evaluation. psychoactive drugs have shown similar rela-
We draw on available evidence from laboratory tions with sensitivity to cost varying with the
and clinical settings and will use those results to characteristics of the drug (Griffiths, Bigelow, &
illustrate extensions to human behavior in Henningfield, 1980; Hursh & Winger, 1995;
larger populations and communities. Based on Johanson, 1978).
the preponderance of research and public
health policy initiatives of particular interest to
us, our presentation relies heavily on the Demand Curve Analysis
behavioral pharmacology and drug abuse litera- The relationship between reinforcer cost
ture, and is by no means exhaustive. However, a and reinforcer consumption is known as a
founding principle of this behavioral-economic demand curve, a term adopted directly from
approach is the broad applicability of the traditional economics. As the cost of a com-
underlying concepts and techniques, and as modity increases, consumption generally de-
such, we also incorporate a variety of hypotheti- creases, as illustrated in Figure 1 (left panel).
cal examples, as well as emerging applications of The rate of decrease in consumption (sensi-
behavioral economics to other research and tivity to price) relative to the initial level of
policy-relevant domains. consumption is called elasticity of demand. When
consumption remains inflexible or declines
The Value Of Reinforcers slowly with proportionately large increases in
price, we define that as inelastic demand. For this
One of the most important contributions of to occur, total responding must increase with
behavioral economics has been to redirect our increases in cost, as seen in the right panel of
attention to total daily consumption of rein- Figure 1. For example, when the price of
forcers as a primary dependent measure of gasoline increased by 300% during the 1970s
behavior and the way consumption varies with from 33 cents per gallon to over one dollar per
the cost of reinforcers. Ultimately, the shape of gallon, consumption decreased by only 10%.
100 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

Fig. 1. Left Panel: Diagrammatic demand curve showing the usual shape and increasing elasticity across the demand
curve. The vertical line marks the point of unit elasticity (slope 1) which is the transition from inelastic to elastic demand.
The level of demand is denoted as the y-intercept or the quantity consumed at zero price (Q0). Right Panel: Diagram of total
daily consumption that would be required to support the levels of demand shown in the left panel. The vertical line marks the
point of unit elasticity and the peak response output (Omax). The price at that point is called Pmax.

This near-fixed level of consumption despite terns of consumption. Demand for such goods
rising prices was an example of inelastic is generally elastic, as consumption is highly
demand, and the result was that a larger share sensitive to price.
of household budgets was allocated to gasoline The difference in demand between elastic
than was before the price increase. Other and inelastic goods is easily demonstrated in the
commodities, such as luxury goods (e.g., laboratory. Figure 2 depicts the consumption by
vacation travel) or goods with many substitutes monkeys of saccharin sweetened water with an
(e.g., bottled water), have steeply sloping alternative source of water and consumption of
demand curves illustrating their flexible pat- food pellets without alternative food. The

Fig. 2. Left Panel: Two demand curves by rhesus monkeys working for either food (squares) or saccharin sweetened water
(triangles). The functions show the total number of reinforcers earned (Consumption) each day under a series of fixed-ratio
(FR) schedules (Prices) that ranged from FR 10 to FR 372. Right Panel: Daily output of responding that accompanied
the levels of consumption shown in the left panel. The curves were fitted with an exponential equation (Hursh &
Silberberg, 2008).
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 101

demand curve for saccharin is generally elastic reinforcement. At its heart, the Exponential
and is steeply sloping; the curve for food is Model is a way to quantify and generalize the
generally inelastic and decreases more slowly relations illustrated in Figure 2. Any quantifiable
with increases in price of the respective risk of lossbe it physical effort/energy, time,
reinforcers. In the figure, the price of each money, professional stability, or social relation-
commodity was gradually increased from ten shipscould qualify as price. Similarly, pro-
responses per reinforcer to over 372 responses curement of anything of value, including the
per reinforcer in a closed economy. As a aforementioned variables (effort, time, money,
corollary to the differences in the demand etc.), could qualify as consumption. Indeed, this
curves, total responding for food increased over generalizability is a fundamental principle that
a broad range while responding for saccharin defines the behavioral psychology school of
generally decreased over the same range. behavioral economics. In the operant paradigm,
The distinction between elastic and inelastic price is usually modeled by fixed-ratio response
reinforcers may be viewed as binary, with elastic requirements per reinforcer delivery, and con-
demand emerging at the point when a 1% sumption is usually the total number of rein-
increase in price produces >1% decrease in forcers earned at each price.
consumption; however, elasticity in general rests Within this theoretical framework, reinforce-
along a continuum anchored by extreme elastic ment is not defined by consumption at any one
and inelastic demand. Assuming a finite budget, price, the price at which maximum consump-
consumption of all reinforcers becomes elastic if tion occurs, or the highest price at which any
the price is elevated sufficiently; the difference consumption occurs. Rather, reinforcing effica-
between reinforcers can be specified in terms of cy is defined by sensitivity to price as derived
the price at the point of transition between from changes in consumption across the entire
inelastic and elastic demand and coincides with range of prices. As illustrated in Figure 2,
the peak of the response rate functions (Pmax) reinforcer efficacy is defined in terms of the
shown in the right panel of Figures 1 and 2 rate of change in consumption with increases in
(dashed lines). If that transition occurs at price and is both conceptually and computa-
relatively low prices, then demand for that tionally independent of reinforcer size/dose
reinforcer is generally more elastic than de- effects seen in absolute level(s) of consumption.
mand for a reinforcer that sustains response In principle, the inelastic/inflexibly-consumed
increases (thus maintaining consumption lev- item (food in Figure 2) is more reinforcing than
els) over a broad range of prices. As we will see the elastic/flexibly-consumed item (saccharin
later, there is a mathematical model that fits in Figure 2), so one could argue based on these
these curves and the rate constant in the model patterns that food is more reinforcing than
determines the Pmax value. saccharin. But how best to quantitatively express
Demand curves for drug reinforcers conform this relationship? Under traditional methods,
to the same nonlinear, decreasing function the question is seriously confounded by the fact
typified by those in Figure 2 and responding that the reinforcers are qualitatively different:
is an inverted U-shaped function of price Even though saccharin squirts and food pellets
(see below for details; also see review by differ from each other at all price points, the
Bickel et al., 1990). As discussed by Bickel, prices themselves and the units of consumption
DeGrandpre, and Higgins (1993) and in later cannot be directly compared. The Exponential
sections of the present report, elasticity of Model of Demand accounts for baseline differ-
demand may be a useful basic metric for ences in absolute consumption while defining
comparing the value of different reinforcers, reinforcement independent of reinforcer type,
such as the abuse liability of drug reinforcers, unit size, or consumption and price at any one
and for assessing the potency of interventions to point along the curve, providing a quantitative
reduce demand for drugs and other reinforcers. comparison of reinforcer values that is indepen-
dent of intrinsic differences in the physical
properties of those reinforcers.
The Exponential Model of Demand As depicted in Figure 2, demand curves
Hursh and Silberberg (2008) formally intro- are seldom linear, so precisely specifying
duced the Exponential Model of Demand as a slope requires a nonlinear function. A basic
novel approach to defining and quantifying exponential function appears to adequately
102 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

describe most demand curves when plotting the tation of motivational effects in traditional
log of consumption as a function of cost (Hursh measures of relative reinforcing efficacy.
& Silberberg, 2008): This leaves us with the most important term in
  the model, and certainly the most unique: the a
logQ logQ 0 k e aQ 0 C 1 1 parameter. With differences in baseline consump-
tion isolated in Q0, the a parameter and
derivatives thereof (e.g., 1/a; Banks, Roma,
The independent variable is Cost (C) mea- Folk, Rice, & Negus, 2011; Bidwell, Mackillop,
sured either as responses or units of time per Murphy, Tidey, & Colby, 2012) define reinforcing
reinforcer. Log of consumption (log Q) is a efficacy by quantifying sensitivity to price, or
function of Cost and is maximal at zero cost elasticity of demand, across the entire range of
(log Q0) and specifies the highest level of prices. Reinforcer efficacy is challenged across a
demand. The rate constant a (alpha) deter- wide range of prices, and indeed elasticity itself is
mines the rate of decline in relative consump- not constant across all adjacent price points, as
tion (log consumption) with increases in cost shown in Figures 1 and 2. The Exponential Model
(C). The value of k is a scaling constant that takes shifting elasticity into account when fitting
reflects the range of the consumption data in log the a parameter, and the result is a fundamentally
units and is generally set to a common constant unique quantitative definition of reinforcing
across comparisons. The slope of the demand efficacy reflecting sensitivity to price.
curve, elasticity, when k is constant, is deter- Larger values of a reflect steeper demand
mined by the rate constant a. The value of a curves and less essential value, and small a values
then forms the basis for defining the essential come from shallow demand curves. Thus, a
value of the reinforcer via sensitivity of con- values are inversely related to essential value. A
sumption to changes in cost.1 less comprehensive but arguably more intuitive
The Exponential Model is a descriptive rather measure of essential value, and one which may
than predictive model. In practice, once a be derived from a, is the price at the point of
demand curve is measured, both price and unit elasticity, as depicted in Figures 1 and 2,
consumption are known and the model is fitted called Pmax.2 Pmax is inversely proportional to a
to the results to find the values for the para- and can be found using the following approxi-
meters that account for as much variance as mation3:
possible in the fixed data of the empirical
demand curve; these values then form the P max 0:65=aQ 0 k 1:191 2
quantitative basis for defining reinforcing effi-
cacy. To this end, the two key parameters for Perhaps the most compelling feature of the
applying the Exponential Model are Q0 and a. exponential model is that because the effects of
The Q0 parameter is a single number generated reinforcer magnitude/dose/etc. are mathemat-
for each demand curve that represents pre- ically isolated in Q0, the a parameter putatively
dicted consumption at zero price based on the represents the absolute and theoretically con-
trajectory of the curve. Simply put, Q0 equals stant reinforcing efficacy of the commodity. This
baseline consumption when the goods are
free. Unencumbered by effort or cost, Q0
mathematically isolates the effects of reinforcer 2
Other potentially useful metrics are consumption at Pmax
magnitude (e.g., 2% vs. 4% vs. 8% alcohol), which is found by solving Equation 1 with C Pmax; and
qualitative differences (e.g., g/kg alcohol vs. Omax, peak response output which is found by taking the
mg/kg cocaine), and individual differences in solution of Equation 1 with C Pmax and multiplying this
underlying physiology (e.g., male vs. female level of consumption by Pmax.
3
absorption rates) that often confound interpre- Because Q0 appears twice in the first derivative of
Equation (1), there is no closed form solution for Pmax,, price
at which the first derivative of Equation (1) 1, and exact
Pmax values can only be found using an iterative solver.
However, Equation (2) provides a close approximation
1
A custom-programmed Exponential Model analysis and within a specified range of values of k. The expression
graphing template for GraphPad Prism 5 is freely available approximates Pmax with a precision that is virtually exact for
upon request to the authors or via the Institutes for Behavior k 5. The error increases with expanded range, and is thus
Resources website (http://www.ibrinc.org/index.php?id within / 2% for 2  k  6 and within / 5% for
181). 1.8  k  8, with an average error of 1.5% for 2  k  6.
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 103

Fig. 3. Demand curves (see equation 1) fitted to average consumption of four doses of the opioid drug Alfentanil self-
administered by rhesus monkeys (data from Ko et al., 2002 as re-analyzed by Hursh & Silberberg, 2008).

is what Hursh and Silberberg (2008) term the Based on data from multiple animal experi-
essential value of the reinforcer. ments conducted over the years, Equation 1 has
This principle was demonstrated in their been applied to a range of reinforcers and
reanalysis of Ko, Terner, Hursh, Woods, and values of a have been determined. Figure 4
Wingers (2002) monkey self-administration summarizes the findings from those experi-
data of the opioid drug Alfentanil. As seen in ments ordered in terms of 1/a so that larger
the demand curves presented in Figure 3, there numbers indicate higher essential value. Note
was an orderly inverse relationship between that alfentanil and remifentanil are two power-
dose and baseline consumption, as reflected in ful opioid reinforcers with equal essential value
Q0, presumably reflecting the need for more and yet they differ by an order of magnitude in
infusions of the lower doses to achieve the same potency, supporting the notion that essential
effect as fewer infusions of the higher doses. value is independent of scalar properties of
With the dose effects relegated to Q0, the reinforcement. Perhaps most importantly, note
essential value of the drug (as derived from a) that drug and nondrug reinforcers are inter-
was revealed as constant across all doses. spersed throughout the array indicating a range
If dose effects and other confounds can be of essential values across commodities. The
reasonably isolated in Q0 and the essential value beauty of the Exponential Model, and we believe
of a reinforcer is presumed stable at any given its promise, lies not only in its unique definition
time, then any differences or changes in a of reinforcement, but in its inherent ability to
between reinforcers or across sessions and provide a credible means of quantitatively
conditions are that much more meaningful. comparing qualitatively different reinforcers.
Quantitatively, a large a indicates high sensitivity Under appropriately controlled conditions, one
to price, and thus low essential value, whereas a could quite literally compare apples to oranges!
small a indicates low sensitivity to price, and thus
high essential value. In colloquial terms, re-
inforcers with high essential value are insensitive Demand and Choice
to price because they are worth fighting for, One way to conceptualize demand is as a
motivation to sustain baseline levels of con- choice between engaging in activities to acquire
sumption (Q0) is strong enough to warrant one commodity versus engaging in other
paying any price, whereas commodities of low activities to acquire another commodity. For
essential value are weaker reinforcers because example, a person is usually not offered a single
the preferred level of consumption is not worth option to obtain food, but rather multiple
defending. choices to earn a range of different foods. The
104 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

Fig. 4. Essential value of various reinforcers in animals based on reanalysis of archival laboratory data. Note that free
food refers to the indicated portion of maximum daily food amounts being offered after experimental sessions where food
was earned under FR schedules.

elasticity of demand for one food is dependent alternatives require a specific number of re-
in part on the price and availability of other sponses per reinforcer delivery, the subjects
foods (cf. Oliveira-Castro, Foxall, Yan, & Wells, generally show exclusive preference for the least
2011). This is just one example of a more costly of the alternatives (Green, Rachlin, &
general set of interactions that can occur among Hanson, 1983; Herrnstein, 1958; Herrnstein
commodities available simultaneously or se- & Loveland, 1975). This situation is akin to
quentially in the course of an organisms comparison shopping for identical items from
interaction with the environment (Green & different stores: All else being equal, one will go
Freed, 1993). Within a behavioral economic to the store with the lowest price.
framework, reinforcer interactions are classified Most choices in the natural economy are
into several categories, as illustrated in Figure 5. between commodities that are not perfect
Most studies of choice with animals have substitutes. The other interactions depicted in
arranged for the alternative behaviors to Figure 5 are imperfect substitutes, comple-
provide the same, perfectly substitutable rein- ments, and independent reinforcers. Figure 6
forcerusually food. This yields a specific kind
of interaction in which the amount of behavior
to each roughly matches the amount of rein-
forcement received from each (the matching law,
see Davison & McCarthy, 1988). When the two

Fig. 6. Diagram of hypothetical changes in consumption


of commodity B as a function of the price of commodity A.
Fig. 5. Diagram of four hypothetical forms of reinforcer The solid line indicates a complementary relation; the
interactions (see text for explanation). dashed line indicates a substitutable relation.
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 105

illustrates the difference between imperfect than when methadone was offered alone. This
substitutes and complements. Along the xaxis reciprocal tradeoff between consumption of
is the price of commodity A; along the yaxis is two reinforcers is typical of imperfect substi-
consumption of the alternative fixed-price tutes. In the experiment depicted in the right
commodity B. As the price of A increases, panel, subjects could respond for a drink of
consumption of A decreases (the usual demand ethanol alone or in comparison with cigarette
relation, not shown). If, at the same time, the puffs. As the price of ethanol increased and
consumption of fixed-price commodity B in- ethanol consumption decreased, consumption
creases in response to the increasing price of A, of cigarette puffs also decreased even though
then B is defined as a substitute for A. If the the price of cigarette puffs remained constant,
consumption of B decreases along with in- suggesting that the reinforcing value of ciga-
creases in the price of A, then B is defined as a rettes is enhanced by concurrent ethanol. This
complement of A. parallel pattern of consumption between two
Choice between two substitutes and com- reinforcers as the price of only one increases is
plements is exemplified in Figure 7 (Spiga, indicative of a complementary relationship.
Martinetti, Meisch, Cowan, & Hursh, 2005; Own-price and cross-price elasticity. Own-
Spiga, Wilson, & Martinetti, 2011). Here, price elasticity of demand refers to the slope of
human subjects chose between reinforcers the demand curve for a commodity when
available after pressing one lever under an plotted in the usual loglog coordinates and
increasing series of FRs. The other alternative reflects proportional changes in consumption of
was a different commodity available under the commodity with proportional changes in its
a constant FR schedule. In the experiment own price. The Exponential Model of Demand
depicted in the left panel, subjects could presented in equation (1) provides a method for
respond for the opiate drug methadone alone quantifying and comparing own-price elastici-
or in comparison with another opiate, hydro- ties. The faster elasticity increases with price, the
morphone, an imperfect substitute. As the price greater the elasticity is at any given price. As
of methadone increased and methadone con- described above, the a parameter of the
sumption decreased, consumption of hydro- demand equation represents the rate of change
morphone increased as a partial substitute. The in elasticity of demand and is a convenient
elasticity of demand for methadone was greater parameter for comparison across conditions
with hydromorphone concurrently available and experiments.

Fig. 7. Left panel: Substitutable reinforcer interaction demonstrated by mean daily consumption by human subjects of
methadone and hydromorphone as a function of the unit price (FR schedule) for methadone. Right panel: Complementary
reinforcer interaction demonstrated by mean consumption by human subjects of alcohol (ethanol solution) and nicotine
(cigarette puffs) as a function of the unit price (FR schedule) for nicotine.
106 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

Extending the model to accommodate choice The Behavioral Economics of


procedures with concurrent reinforcers, cross- Addiction and Treatment
price elasticity of demand is the slope of the Drug Abuse Liability Assessment
function relating the consumption of a fixed-
price commodity to the changes in price of The rank ordering of drug and nondrug
another commodity (see Figure 7). As suggested reinforcers by essential value has direct applica-
above, if this function has positive slope, then tion for the assessment of abuse liability and the
the fixed-price alternative commodity is termed application of public policy for the control of
a substitute for the primary commodity (Fig- certain medications. The Federal Drug Admin-
ure 7, left). If the slope is negative, then the istration applies certain control mechanisms on
fixed-price alternative is termed a complement the prescription, sale, and distribution of drugs
of the primary commodity (Figure 7, right). If that depends in part on the potential that the
the slope is zero, then the reinforcing efficacies drug might lead to excessive use, dependence,
of both commodities are considered indepen- and addiction, especially when such use would
dent of each other.4 Mathematically, an exten- have adverse health effects on abusers and/or
sion of exponential demand may be used to fit impose a burden on society that is dispro-
cross-price demand curves such as those in portionate to the therapeutic benefit of the
Figure 7 for hydromorphone (substitute for medicine. Virtually all drugs which have effects
methadone) or for ethanol and cigarettes on the central nervous system must be assessed
(complements to each other): for their potential to serve as a reinforcer and
condition excessive use beyond that which is
Q logQ al one I e bC 3 justified by it medical use.
Until recently, controls were based on a
where Qalone is the maximum level of consump- simple binary decision about whether the drug
tion for the fixed-price alternative commodity would serve as a reinforcer. More recently,
when the price of the primary commodity is behavioral experiments have shown that drugs
infinity (i.e., zero demand at the right end of the can differ in efficacy as a reinforcer; for
function rather than the left), I is the interaction example, studies using progressive ratios (PR)
constant, b is the sensitivity of fixed-price have been used to rank order drugs by the size of
commodity consumption to the price of the the highest fixed ratio that will sustain respond-
primary commodity, and C is the cost of the ing, the so-called break-point assay. While
primary commodity. With methadone versus superficially similar to a demand curve analysis,
hydromorphone, the interaction term I was this assay does not assess the shape of the entire
negative (-3.04), indicating a reciprocal or demand function but rather uses only the size of
substitution relationship between consumption the very last ratio completed as the basis for the
of the two commodities; in choice between metric. Using the break-point procedure, one
ethanol and cigarette puffs, the interaction term reinforcer is deemed more effective than
I was positive (0.63) indicating a parallel or another if it yields higher PR break-points
complementary relationship between consump- (Griffiths, Bradford, & Brady, 1979; Katz,
tion of ethanol and cigarettes.5 1990; Stafford, LeSage, & Glowa, 1998). This
method can be informative, but unfortunately,
limitations have been noted over the years. For
example, the break point is sensitive to paramet-
ric conditions (i.e., the specific FR sequence
4
A custom-programmed Cross-Price Elasticity analysis and imposed), and more importantly for drug
graphing template for GraphPad Prism 5 is currently being reinforcer scaling purposes, is often dose-
developed and may be available upon request from the
authors.
dependent even when tested under the same
5
If the prices of both commodities are changing, then FR sequence. Nevertheless, the break-point
equation (3) can be expanded by replacing the log(Qalone) analysis has been beneficial in showing that
term for consumption of one commodity at a fixed price with abuse liability should not be a binary evaluation.
equation (1) for consumption of that commodity with Drugs can vary widely in reinforcer efficacy and
variable pricing. This expanded form provides an economic
foundation for determining choice ratios as the ratio of from a policy perspective, if a drug is mildly
several such expanded demand equations, a topic beyond reinforcing but will be available in the context of
the scope of this chapter. other far more efficacious and substitutable
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 107

reinforcers, then the true abuse liability could zation with the drug and then later after a 2-
be very small when evaluated within the broader week long history of infusions (Christensen,
economic context of the actual marketplace. Silberberg, Hursh, Roma, & Riley, 2008). In
Based on the exponential demand curve parallel, demand curves for food were also
approach, drugs may be scaled in a dose inde- obtained. Figure 8 illustrates the effect of the
pendent manner according to the a of their extended history for cocaine. There was both an
respective demand curves; drugs with high increase in the level of demand and a change in
sensitivity to price (relatively large a) are less elasticity of demand for cocaine following the
likely to sustain behavior in the context of other extended history. Here, we focus on the change
reinforcers. This has important public policy in elasticity of demand; the demand curve for
implications. For example, many potent analge- cocaine has been plotted as changes in con-
sics that bind to one or more opiate receptors sumption, with Q0 set as the 100% level of
also serve as reinforcers. Recent advances in consumption at the lowest price (see Hursh &
pharmacology have created analgesics that can Winger, 1995). This figure shows that the
relieve pain with less affinity for the receptors additional history with cocaine reinforcement
mediating euphoric/reinforcing effects (e.g., led to a 50% reduction in sensitivity to price (a)
Negus, Schrode, & Stevenson, 2008; see also and an increase in essential value with Pmax
Staahl, Olesen, Andresen, Arendt-Nielsen, & increasing from 19 to 37 responses per unit
Drewes, 2009). Nevertheless, mild positive reinforcement (dashed lines). Hence, the
reinforcement can still be demonstrated under fundamental nature of addiction may be
laboratory conditions. Scaling these drugs defined as a shift in the essential value of a
according to essential value relative to other commodity resulting from some threshold level
drugs as well as reinforcers that are not of experience with the effects of the reinforcer.
controlled substances could serve as a basis for The implications for evidence-based policy are
a more precise quantitative assessment of abuse intriguing: If addiction can be defined in a
risk. Such an approach could open the door for
more rational and proportional drug control
policies that would reduce costs and limitations
associated with the prescription of analgesics.
There are a number of economic theories
available to explain the development of an
addiction as defined as an increasingly strong
tendency to seek and consume a specific
commodity (e.g., Foxall & Sigurdsson, 2011).
Here, the application of the demand law offers a
systematic and longitudinal way to describe the
neurobehavioral changes that are described as
addiction. Rather than attempt to construct a
hypothetical process to explain the develop-
ment of an addiction, we merely provide a
convenient way to measure and track the
process. The underlying processes that predis-
pose individuals to addiction and sustain it once
established most certainly involve the dynamic
interplay between biological, psychosocial, and
broad environmental factors, but there is no
consensus on the exact nature of the process.
Nevertheless, there is a growing literature that
indicates that for some commodities, extended
exposure to the reinforcing properties of the Fig. 8. For the mean of a group of rodents, consumption
item lead to progressive changes in demand of cocaine infusions as a function of increasing fixed ratio
schedule before (open circles) and after an extended history
(Ahmed & Koob, 1998). In a recent experiment of exposure to cocaine (filled triangles), in loglog
with rodents, demand curves for infusions of coordinates. The shift in Pmax is shown as the two vertical
cocaine were determined after a brief familiari- dashed lines (data from Christensen et al., 2008).
108 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

standardized manner using a-based metrics has many of the psychoactive properties of
across contexts (animal laboratory, human heroin and morphine. It is explicitly formulated
laboratory, human clinical, human market- so that an oral dose will prevent opiate
place) as a significant increase in the essential withdrawal but will not produce a pronounced
value of a commodity and a decrease in elasticity euphoria or high. It substitutes for heroin to
of demand, then, perhaps, successful treatment prevent withdrawal symptoms, the aversive
for addiction can be defined and tracked as the consequences of nondrug use, but does not
reversal of that processa reduction in essential substitute for the immediate positive reinforcing
value and an increase in elasticity of demand. consequences of euphoria. One could predict,
then, that even if a large price differential
existed between the two commodities, some
Therapy and Demand Interactions heroin would still be purchased from illicit
In addition to the conceptual and procedural sources for its unique reinforcing features (see
strengths of the demand curve approach for Stitzer, Grabowski, & Henningfield, 1984). In
predicting and quantifying drug abuse, the addition, heroin is often consumed as part of a
concepts of substitution and complementarity social ritual and these social events serve as
provide some insights into important limitations complements to the primary reinforcing effects
of individual therapy programs for the control of the drug. To the extent that the substitute,
or elimination of behaviors in excess in methadone, must be consumed in a clinical,
individual clients. Within a behavioral frame- nonsocial environment, its value will be dimin-
work, one can conceptualize the therapeutic ished as an adequate substitute for heroin
situation as one in which the clinician attempts because it is not accompanied by important
to shape new behavior under the control of complementary social reinforcers (see Hunt,
acceptable reinforcers that compete with and Lipton, Goldsmith, & Strug, 1984).
reduce the occurrence of behavior to obtain Antagonist therapy. The use of methadone as
unhealthy commodities, be it illicit drugs, a treatment for heroin is an example of the use
alcohol, cigarettes, or excessive amounts of of an agonist to substitute for the drug of abuse
food. Thus, the reinforcers arranged by the and drive up elasticity of demand. An alternative
therapeutic process interact with the problem approach is to provide a drug therapy that is a
commodity of therapeutic interest (see Carroll, specific antagonist for the drug of abuse; the
1993; Thompson, Koerner, & Grabowski, 1984). antagonist binds to the neurochemical receptor
For example, when monkeys were allowed to and blocks or reverses the action of the drug
work for a sweet saccharin solution concurrently without itself producing a psychoactive effect.
with consumption of PCP, elasticity of demand Although the biological mechanisms differ, a
for PCP increased and Pmax moved to the left; functionally similar effect would be expected
however, considerable amounts of PCP were still from various antidrug vaccines currently in
consumed despite the presence of a competing development (Shen, Orson, & Kosten, 2012).
reinforcer (Carroll, 1993). The effectiveness of A common antagonist for opiate drugs is
the competition between a drug reinforcer, for naltrexone or naloxone; it is used in emergency
example, and other reinforcers will depend, at rooms to rapidly block the action of opiates
least in part, on several economic factors: the in patients that have taken an overdose. As a
amount of direct substitution between the therapy, the antagonist partially or completely
two sources of reinforcement, the availability blocks the action of the target drug and
of desirable complements to the therapeutic presumably would reduce demand. This pre-
reinforcers that will maximize their effective- sumption has been tested in a study reported by
ness, and the amount of direct competition that Harrigan and Downs (1978). Monkeys worked
exists between the two sources of reinforcement, for morphine under a series of increasing unit
whether performance for one precludes or prices for morphine, arranged by decreasing the
prevents reinforcement from the other. These morphine dose per reinforcer. Morphine self-
factors can be illustrated by considering the administration was studied either alone or when
effectiveness of methadone therapy for users of combined with one of three doses of intrave-
heroin. nous naltrexone. This yielded four separate
Agonist therapy. Methadone is an imperfect consumption curves. Generally, the level of
substitute for heroin; it is an opiate agonist and consumption of morphine at the lowest unit
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 109

price increased in direct relation to the dose of increases, and this potentially increases the
naltrexone and sensitivity to the effects of need for funds to obtain the drug and to engage
increasing the unit price also increased with in illegal activities to raise the funds. Second, it
the dose of naltrexone. This apparently compli- increases the revenues to the drug suppliers.
cated effect of naltrexone can be resolved by Third, for self-injected drugs, it may increase the
examining exponential demand for morphine use of contaminated needles and thus increase
alone and in combination with naltrexone. the risk of contracting and spreading diseases
Fitting exponential demand revealed that sensi- such as hepatitis C and HIV. But the primary
tivity to price (a) was unchanged but rather, challenge for any antagonist therapy is that it
there was an upward shift in Q0 such that the requires that the subject voluntarily administer a
demand curves with naltrexone were uniformly drug that will drive up the functional cost of
shifted to the right to higher effective prices another reinforcer. Ordinarily, consumers
considering the larger baseline levels of con- choose to minimize cost, so such a choice would
sumption required to reach satiation. To state it have to be compensated by a correlated increase
another way, naltrexone did not change the in benefit from other sources of reinforcement,
essential value of morphine but did lower the such as the retention of a well-paying job by a
potency of each morphine infusion and raised physician addicted to opiates. For many drug
the effective price of the drug. users, however, such alternatives may not be
At first, one might conclude that this indicates available unless provided by the therapeutic
that antagonist therapy has no utility for the process itself.
treatment of opiate drug seeking since it does
not alter sensitivity to environmental price Hypothetical Demand Curves for
variables. In fact, this is not precisely true. The Policy Analysis
effect of naltrexone was to reduce the functional
potency of the morphine. This had the effect of In the prior sections we discussed the factors
increasing the functional cost of morphine under that serve to control the choices of a person to
each environmental cost, that is, the unit dose work for and consume drugs of various sorts.
of morphine. Hence, increases in naltrexone Many other policy decisions relate to similar
moved the demand curve to the right and to choices for other commodities. For example, in
lower daily levels of consumption. A sufficiently the arena of environmental and energy policy,
high dose of naltrexone would virtually elimi- tax incentives and rebates are often provided to
nate any reinforcing value of morphine and, encourage citizens to purchase more fuel-
consequently, would move the functional price efficient cars, to increase the insulating proper-
sufficiently far to the right that all consumption ties of homes, or to adopt alternative energy
would cease under all levels of environmental sources for home electricity. The power of such
cost. In effect, the morphine would be rendered policies depends on the price sensitivity of the
ineffective as a reinforcer and the costbenefit commodities at issue. When attempting to
ratio for expending any effort to obtain it would encourage alternative energy choices, high
approach infinity. This would occur, not be- price sensitivity is a virtue because it suggests
cause the fundamental demand for morphine that small reductions in price (using rebates, for
was changed, but because the functional poten- example) will have relatively large effects on
cy of morphine as a reinforcer was changed. consumption. When attempting to discourage
The clinical value of antagonist therapy is wasteful use of resources, such as taxes on the
complicated by several considerations. As indi- use of paper bags, high price sensitivity is again a
cated above, the initial effect of an antagonist virtue because a small cost, such as 5 cents per
when the environmental price is low and the bag, might be expected to have a relatively
dose of the antagonist is insufficient to eliminate powerful effect on consumption. When attempt-
drug reinforcement is an increase in the total ing to reduce drug use, provision of medically
number of injections per day (increase in Q0). administered alternatives like methadone are
This increase is motivated by the need to expected to increase price sensitivity of demand
compensate for the functional decrease in the for substitutable illicit alternatives, resulting in
potency of the drug of abuse that brings with it an overall decrease in consumption of the illicit
several undesirable side effects. First, the commodity in favor of the lower cost (and legal)
number of doses of the drug required per day medical alternative.
110 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

When formulating such policies, it is impor- line through the hypothetical consumption
tant to understand the demand elasticities of the curve is the best fitting exponential demand
commodities at issue; in effect, it is important to curve, and accounted for 99% of the variance in
be able to establish the value of a for the various consumption. The expenditure function also
alternatives. This requirement presents a chal- was well described by the function, and the point
lenge because often there are no naturalistic of maximum consumption (Pmax) coincided
data available to allow for the mapping of the closely with the maximum of the exponentially
basic demand curve. When naturalistic data are derived output function. While we have no
available based on market fluctuations or differ- independent way to assess the true levels of
ences in supply (and price) across different consumption of alcohol in these students, the
geographic locations, the range of prices is often systematic relationship obtained using the
very limited. This makes it difficult to precisely hypothetical method is encouraging.
map the demand curve and determine the One way to assess the usefulness of such
value of a. Along with other economics-oriented functions is to determine if they vary in a rational
approaches (e.g., Roddy, Steinmiller, & way with other ecologically valid variables. To
Greenwald, 2011), recent experiments have that end, Murphy and MacKillop (2006) related
been conducted using hypothetical demand the demand curves in these students to their
curves constructed by asking subjects to indicate reported overall use of alcohol. They divided the
the levels of consumption that they would adopt 267 students into two groups defined as light
if confronted with different prices for the and heavy alcohol users. The two resulting
commodity in question. These experiments demand curves (Figure 10) differed from each
have shown that such hypothetical demand other in both Q0 and a. Heavy drinkers had
curves (1) have a consistent shape well de- higher levels of consumption, as might be
scribed by the exponential demand equation expected from their self-assessment of overall
and (2) have values of a that vary with use, but they also showed less sensitivity to
hypothetical contextual variables. alcohol price, with an a value about half that of
For example, Murphy and MacKillop (2006) light drinkers. In a similar study, MacKillop et al.
surveyed alcohol consumption as a function of (2008) reported that minimal users of nicotine
price in 267 undergraduate students. Figure 9 is products had price sensitivity (a) that was 5
the resulting demand curve (left panel) and times higher than that reported by those with
response output function (right panel). The moderate nicotine use.

Fig. 9. The reported consumption of standard alcoholic drinks as a function of the cost of each drink from a group of 267
college undergraduates responding to a set of questions about hypothetical alcohol consumption (from Murphy and
MacKillop, 2006).
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 111

Fig. 10. The reported consumption of standard alcoholic drinks as a function of the price of each drink from two groups
of college undergraduates, one group self-reporting as light drinkers (n 78) and the other group self-reporting as heavy
drinkers (n 189). Subjects responded to a set of questions about hypothetical alcohol consumption (from Murphy and
MacKillop, 2006).

These findings suggest that hypothetical might outweigh any environmental benefit. To
demand curves may be used as a tool to inform combat this disincentive, the policy maker may
public policy that will use taxes to increase prices have to provide counteracting incentives to the
to discourage certain behaviors, or use incen- consumer, such as refueling rebates and tax
tives and rebates to encourage other behaviors incentives. In addition, the policy maker may
(e.g., MacKillop et al., 2012). Such research will need to take steps to reduce the disincentives,
provide two important pieces of information. such as encouraging producers to increase
First, it will help define the overall shape of the availability of the alternative fuel. But the
underlying demand curves and the associated a question ultimately becomes one of how much
values. Second, it will help define where the compensation is required to have a beneficial
current prevailing price is relative to Pmax, that is, impact on alternative fuel use. The use of
is demand elasticity in the vicinity of the current hypothetical demand curves provides a meth-
price elastic or inelastic? This will lead to directly odology for evaluating the impact of these
verifiable predictions of the policys (price incentives on expected consumption, providing
increase or decrease) effect size on resulting an empirical basis for a rational costbenefit
consumption. analysis of the proposed policy.
Consistent with a behavioral economic ap-
proach, some policy initiatives impose nonmon-
etary costs. For example, consider a policy that Novel Applications and Recent Developments
would encourage the use of an alternative
ethanol-based fuel for automobiles. Even if the Time Cost and Transportation Mode Choice
price of the fuel were equivalent to the price of In the previous section we introduced the
regular gasoline, other costs might have a idea that time costs can be just as important as
dramatic impact on utilization, such as the monetary costs. Interestingly, this notion was
travel time and distance to the alternative fuel explored experimentally with rodents by
station, the potential to travel to a location that Bauman (1991). Here, a group of rats obtained
does not have such fuel, and a possible their daily ration of food according to an FR
reduction in fuel mileage necessitating in- schedule. Across days the value of the FR was
creased frequency of refueling. If the vehicle increased (27 FRs from 1-446 per pellet) and
would run on both kinds of fuel (i.e., if the two demand curves for food were determined in the
fuels were functionally substitutable), the much traditional way, similar to that shown in Figure 2.
higher convenience of using the standard fuel In the next phase of the experiment, the same
112 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

fic congestion and deterioration of highways,


facilitates access to cities business, cultural, and
recreational centers, and creates a lower carbon
impact than automobile or aviation alternatives.
However, passenger rail service in the US does
not command a large market share in most
travel corridors, and a major contributor may be
a simple matter of time cost.
In Europe, where high speed rail has been
very successful, studies have been conducted
that relate journey time to rail market share
(Esplugas, Teixeira, Lpez-Pita, & Saa, 2005;
Sinclair Knight Merz, 2010). The resulting time-
Fig. 11. The number of food pellets earned by a single rat cost demand curve for rail market share
each day as a function of the time from the first response to presented in Figure 12 is remarkably similar to
the reinforcer, either under a fixed-ratio requirement the time-cost demand curve for rodents working
(Ratio) or under a response initiated fixed-interval (Delay;
from Bauman, 1991). for food, but with a longer time horizon, of
course (Sinclair Knight Merz, 2010). Using this
type of analysis, let us consider the 342 mi
(550 km) travel corridor in the western United
subjects obtained their daily ration of food by States between San Francisco and Los Angeles,
completing response-initiated FI schedules, the California. A passenger train that travels an
durations of which were set to match the time average of 60 mph (100 km/h) would have a
taken to complete each of the FR schedules by journey time of 5.7 hrs (342 min), placing it at
that subject. Across days, the value of the FI was an estimated market share based on Figure 12 of
increased and demand curves were created as a about 10%. If the average speed were increased
function of the duration of the FI. When the to 140 mph (225 km/h), the journey would
results were subsequently analyzed, the demand take 2.4 hrs (144 min) and may increase market
curves for consumption based on time, ar- share to above 70%. Hence, a 133% increase in
ranged either by FRs or matched FIs, were speed could result in a 700% increase in market
nearly equivalent and had shapes similar to share.
that expected of exponential demand (see In the spirit of empirical public policy, the sort
Figure 11). Of course, equivalent curves based of information exemplified above can then be
on responses, rather than time, under the two directly applied to estimate ultimate ridership,
conditions were not at all equivalent. Taken potential revenue, and the monetary return on
together, these data underscore the critical investment for building the infrastructure to
importance of time cost per se as a fundamental support the system. Furthermore, since rail
independent variable that can explain decreases travel creates a carbon load per passenger mile
in consumption with increases in price. that is about half that of alternative automobile
Time cost has fundamental importance for or aircraft travel, this investment could yield a
many public policy decisions, and behavioral commensurate environmental benefit. While all
economic analyses along this dimension can of this is somewhat hypothetical, the reasoning
yield important insight on some of societys most illustrates how a basic economic model of time
pressing issues. Consider Americas aging infra- cost as a factor in consumer choice can be
structure6 and initiatives to promote expanded translated into an empirical foundation for
high-speed rail service in the United States policy decisions, business investment, and ulti-
(trains operating at 150220 mph [240 mately, environmental impact and quality of life
350 km/h]7). Rail transportation mitigates traf- (Magoon & Hursh, 2011). The tools for such
analysis have already been developed for
6
evaluation of hypothetical demand for several
http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article.cfm?ar- commodities and need only be translated into
ticleid2627 and http://www.nytimes.com/2010/02/16/
opinion/16herbert.html other commodities and costs to be relevant to
7
US Federal Railroad Administration: http://www.fra. virtually any public policy that relies on a change
dot.gov/rpd/passenger/31.shtml in consumer choice.
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 113

Fig. 12. The percent share of the European transportation market allocated to rail as a function of the rail journey time
(min). Different symbols denote different reporting periods and the data are approximated by a logit curve (adapted from
Sinclair Knight Merz, 2010).

Behavior Analysis of Cooperation, The price of cooperation. We have been


Productivity, and Fairness developing and testing a simple, rapid, objec-
tive, and language-free computer-based task as a
Despite the shared interest in quantifiable standardized assay of cooperative propensity,
behavior between economists and psychologists, productivity, and fairness in small groups. This
the philosophy and methods of behavior analy- tool, known by the current prototype softwares
sis have not been enthusiastically embraced by generic working title Price of Cooperation
economists beyond acknowledging the rele- (PoC), applies behavioral economic demand
vance of some seminal work (e.g., Herrnstein, curve principles, with voluntary cooperative
1961) predating Hurshs more formal introduc- behavior as the primary commodity that in-
tion and expansion of Behavioral Economics in creases in price over the course of the session.
Psychology (Hursh, 1978; 1980; 1984). However, We recently published details of our preliminary
the subfield of economics known as Experi- development efforts for a team performance
mental Economics (Kagel and Roth, 1995) task (Emurian et al., 2011) and several forth-
represents an area of methodological overlap coming papers are now in preparation describ-
that could be enriched by the behavior analytic ing the PoCs parameters and early validation
approach described throughout this review, in efforts, including its sensitivity to contextual
effect feeding behavioral psychologys econom- variables such as budget (i.e., increased
ics-based innovations back into the parent field cooperation with increased session length)
which inspired them. Experimental economics and social distance (i.e., ability to objectively
generally focuses on controlled laboratory discriminate between groups composed of
studies targeting the fundamental behavioral friends vs. groups composed of strangers).
and social decision-making processes underly- Through support from the U.S. space program,
ing bargaining and resource allocation, and is our work thus far has focused primarily on
the primary field associated with standardized construct validity and how trait-like PoC pro-
economic games such as the Ultimatum Game, files may predict and track variations in
Prisoners Dilemma, and Public Goods task interdependent task performance and social
(e.g., Amir, Rand, & Gal, 2012). It is within this cohesion in long-term work groups. However,
context that an emerging behavioral-economic the PoC yields several sensitive individual and
technology within Psychology could provide group-level metrics that in and of themselves
empirical insight to economists and others make the assay a potentially face-valid model
with a vested interested in social policy. of cooperation, productivity, and fairness in
114 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

response to external conditions akin to public ously choose between passivity, allocating effort
policy and various societal structures. Thus, as toward individual point accumulation, or
described below, in addition to its potential allocating effort toward facilitating the point
value as a research tool, such work may also yield accumulation efforts of others in the group.
insight on basic social-behavioral processes Conceptually, the design draws from evolution-
while providing a scalable conceptual and ary theory under the auspices of prosociality,
methodological framework of relevance at the namely altrusim (helping others at cost to
policy level. oneself), or more specifically, a form of
To briefly summarize the PoC task itself, the reciprocal altruism (Trivers, 1971) known as
current prototype software was designed for parochial altruism, defined as helping a
three-person groups with all members partici- member of ones own group at cost to oneself,
pating simultaneously through networked PC with or without aggression to members of
computers. All behaviors are mutually exclusive other groups (Choi & Bowles, 2007; De Dreu
as controlled through the computer mouses et al., 2010; also see Locey, Safin, & Rachlin,
left-click button. During a session, each partici- 2013, and Rachlin & Locey, 2011 for a behavior-
pant earns points (which may be assigned a fixed analytic perspective on altruism). This line of
monetary value) by using the computer mouse research is entirely new and therefore not nearly
to click and drag blocks from a Resource zone as developed as the body of basic and transla-
at the top of the screen into the Target zone at tional behavioral pharmacology work enriched
the bottom of the screen without striking any by the behavioral economic perspective de-
barriers in the process. Barriers are randomly scribed herein. However, the example data
dispersed throughout the field for random below highlight some of the PoCs key features,
amounts of time before resetting and changing and based on this conceptual and analytical
positions. Each barrier strike deducts a point approach, we offer some speculative but en-
from the offending group members score and couraging policy-relevant extensions.
immediately releases the offending resource These data come from a mixed-gender group
block from his/her control. Each group mem- of 3 college-educated adults who share an
ber owns an equal number of barriers that only extended history working together on various
s/he can see but will still result in lost points if team tasks in our laboratory. This group was part
struck by a resource block. If an individual of an experiment of five groups (N 15; Roma,
wishes to help the rest of the group by revealing Hursh, Hienz, Brinson, & Brady, 2012), and was
a barrier to the rest of the team, s/he must click chosen for this illustrative presentation because
and hold that barrier with the mouse for a fixed the qualitative and inferential statistical patterns
amount of time. Individuals do not know who of effects described below are identical to those
owns which barriers, and thus all barrier reveals of the larger subject pool. The analyses are
are anonymous. Since all behaviors are mutually based on individual average barrier reveal and
exclusive, revealing barriers facilitates the rest of point-scoring behaviors over three consecutive
the groups point-scoring efforts but precludes 6-minute PoC sessions per condition. The
ones own accumulation of points during that conditions were Fixed Income where each partici-
barrier-reveal time. The time requirement per pant received a flat fee of $20 USD/hr regard-
barrier-revealthat is, the price of cooperation less of performance, Collective Incentive where the
increases from 0.25 sec during the first one groups collective point total was multiplied by
third of the session to 1.0 sec during the middle 10 US cents and the earnings were divided
one third of the session to 4.0 sec during the evenly amongst all group members, and Individ-
final one third of the session. Real-time displays ual Incentive where each individual group
present each participant with the current member collected their respective point total
barrier-reveal requirement, notification of bar- multiplied by 10 US cents regardless of the other
rier hits, and updated point totals (individual group members behaviors.
and group). All behavior is completely volun- As seen in Figure 13, the sensitivity of the
tary, and no particular behaviors are required demand curve approach to simple policy
from any one individual to participate in a changes is apparent: Although baseline cooper-
session. ation (Q0) did not vary by price or condition,
At its heart, the PoC is an operant choice the group was significantly less willing to
procedure in which the subject must continu- sustain their cooperative efforts (1/a) under
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 115

entity, but informative metrics beyond group


means and sums are not abundant (see Wild-
man, Bedwell, Salas, & Smith-Jentsch, 2010 for
a thoughtful review of this issue in applied
settings). To this end, the following section
explores some genuine group-level metrics that
may be used to characterize a social system
within the PoC. Specifically, we first explored
the Gini coefficient (Gini, 1912), which is a
measure of distribution inequality based on the
shape of the empirical cumulative distribution
curve versus the cumulative distribution curve of
perfect equality. This metric ranges from 0,
where all members have an equal amount, to 1,
where a single member has everything, and is
widely used in macroeconomics, sociology, and
anthropology to quantify income inequality
between nations or between municipalities
within a nation (De Maio, 2007). However, by
Fig. 13. Summary of overall mean cooperation by relying on the shape of the empirical cumulative
incentive condition as a function of the price of cooperation. distribution of a resource relative to a perfectly
Although maximum/baseline cooperation (Q0) did not vary equal distribution, it may be applied to any
by condition, the group was significantly less persistent in situation where a finite amount of a commodity
their cooperative efforts (1/a) under the Individual
Incentive condition versus both other conditions
is divided amongst a finite number of entities.
(*p < .05, **p < .01; Exponential Model parameter values This makes it appropriate for analyzing the
compared via Sum-of-Squares F Test). distributions of cooperation, productivity, or
any other behavior within the PoC paradigm.8
Figure 15 shows that inequality in cooperative
the Individual Incentive versus both other effort and income generally increase as the price
conditions. of cooperation increases, thus reflecting the
For a closer look in the behavior-analytic spread of individual values at the highest price
tradition, Figure 14 presents cooperative effort depicted in all panels of Figure 14. However,
(top row) and productivity (bottom row) data from an economics and policy perspective, it is
for each individual group member (S1, S2, S3) interesting that income distribution is appar-
in each condition (columns). Although both ently most equitable in the Individual Incentive
behaviors tended to decrease in all group condition despite the rising price of coopera-
members as the price of cooperation increased, tion. Clearly the Gini coefficient provides a
it is interesting to note that in the conditions sensitive group-level metric, but is income
where all participants received equal pay, S1 was inequality a sufficient measure of group
the least cooperative and S3 was the most function?
cooperative with a correspondingly opposite The PoC task differs from other economic
relationship in productivitya de facto division games in several fundamental ways; cardinal
of labor where S1 could claim credit as the most among them is the fact that all individual
productive member of the microsociety productivity starts at zero and is earned via
(Brady, Bernstein, Foltin, & Nellis, 1988; Emur- successful block deposits rather than negotiated
ian et al., 2009). However, when individual down or otherwise divided from a zero-sum
earnings were based solely on individual points, endowment provided by a benevolent benefac-
S3 reduced cooperation at the highest price tor. Moreover, the PoCs inclusion of metrics for
thus maintaining relative homogeneity in both individual productivity and cooperative
productivity.
Units of analysis. The consistent functional 8
For details and tools for calculating the Gini coefficient,
outcomes of dynamic behavioral interactions see http://people.hofstra.edu/geotrans/eng/ch4en/
within a group such as those described above meth4en/ch4m1en.html and http://www.wessa.net/co.
can arguably define that group as a singular wasp
116 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

Fig. 14. Cooperative effort (top row) and productivity (bottom row) data for each individual group member (S1, S2, S3)
in each condition (columns) as a function of the price of cooperation.

effort provides a novel yet direct means of another. The PoCs combination of earned
quantifying fairness. Whether macroeconomi- individual productivity and contribution to the
cally from a global policy perspective or common good within a quasi-operant paradigm
behavioral-economically in the laboratory, a differentiates it from all other economic games
practical limitation of the Gini Coefficient as a of which we are aware, and a fortunate con-
measure of group fairness based solely on sequence of this constellation of features is a
income inequality is accounting for what people derivative measure we call the Fair Share Index
give to society relative to what they take from it, (FSI). Simply put, the FSI is ones percentage of
even if they do not take directly from one the groups total cooperative effort (barrier
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 117

zero indicates perfect fairness, in that ones


cooperative contributions exactly matched
ones individual productivity regardless of any-
ones absolute levels of barrier reveals and
points scored.
The top row of Figure 16 displays individual
FSIs for each of the conditions as a function of
the price of cooperation. As with the other
measures, the demand curve approach produ-
ces the most interesting data when cooperative
propensity is challenged at the highest price,
with the division of labor in the conditions with a
priori equal payouts still apparent, featuring S1
dominating the point-scoring, S3 dominating
the cooperative facilitation, and S2 contributing
equally to both. However, in the Individual
condition, we see how S1 continues to operate
selfishly but at a somewhat reduced rate as S2
and S3 focus their efforts on generating fairer
outcomes for themselves. For a group-level
metric incorporating fairness data, we calculat-
ed the sum of squared individual FSIs, divided
the product by 20,000 (i.e., the maximum
possible amount), then multiplied that by 100.
The resulting group unfairness index scales
unfairness from 0 to 100, with 0 indicating a
perfectly fair group in which what each member
gave was exactly proportionate to what s/he
took, and 100 indicating a perfectly unfair group
where one individual took everything but gave
nothing (free-rider) at the expense of another
individual who took nothing but gave everything
(sucker) while all other group members
remained completely inactive (bystander
(s)). In effect, this metric quantifies the extent
to which one could gain by exploiting others in
the group, or conversely, the risk of being
Fig. 15. Group-level inequality of cooperative effort and exploited or otherwise unproductive as a
individual productivity (Gini Coefficient) in each incentive
condition as a function of the price of cooperation. member of the group.
Like the Gini Coefficient, the group unfair-
ness index provides a genuine group-level
metric, but a more comprehensive one since it
reveals) minus ones percentage of the groups incorporates both cooperative effort and earned
total productivity (points). A positive FSI productivity. Nonetheless, the calculation that
indicates that ones cooperative contributions defines the group unfairness index, or really any
were disproportionately larger than ones indi- measure of variability or skew, cannot identify
vidual productivity (cooperative bias terminat- the underlying source(s) of variability, but when
ing at 100 for contributing 100% of the barrier considered with the individual FSI data from
reveals while earning zero points); a negative which it was derived, a more thorough under-
FSI indicates that ones individual productivity standing of group function emerges. In our
was disproportionately larger than ones coop- example data, the group unfairness index
erative contributions (selfish bias terminating at presented in the bottom panel of Figure 16
100 for earning 100% of the points while reveals the group as one that is generally fair
contributing zero barrier reveals); and an FSI of even at its worst, but still with the potential risk of
118 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

Fig. 16. Individual-level Fair Share Index (FSI) and group-level unfairness index in each incentive condition as a function
of the price of cooperation.

fragmentation at the hands of a single free-rider thereby increasing both cooperation with native
as the price of cooperation increases. insurgents and aggression against those whose
Policy implications. The systematic applica- ultimate goal is self-sustained safety and stability
tion of behavioral economic demand curve for the general population. In effect, invoking
methods and analyses to social behavior is new, those evolutionarily conserved psychosocial
so the ability of the PoC assay to inform public mechanisms increases the essential value of in-
policy is indeed an empirical matter that group membership (cf. Klor & Shayo, 2010)
remains to be seen. However, one recent despite the often tragically high price of
example of how multiperson resource alloca- cooperation for all involved. Of course, stan-
tion tasks can generate policy-relevant insight dardized behavioral tasks are no more practical
comes from Sambanis, Schulhofer-Wohl, and or appropriate for field deployment in high-risk
Shayos (2012) review of parochialism, specifi- operations than hypothetical demand curves
cally in the very serious context of international are for administration to drug abusers during
counterinsurgency operations. They note how interactions with their dealers, but what this
several variables consistently shown to precipi- work does is illustrate how prospective experi-
tate parochialism in laboratory settings, if not mental research can produce knowledge on
managed properly in the field, can reinforce basic social-behavioral processes while poten-
local citizens perception of government and tially offering an empirical foundation for
counterinsurgency forces as an out-group, estimating the effects and risks of relevant
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 119

historical, cultural, and legal variables when nation, expressed that as a difference score
formulating sociopolitical policy. relative to the OECD country with the lowest
On the other end of the social behavior average work-hours commitment (The Netherlands,
spectrum, cooperation in relatively stable indus- at 1379 hr/yr), then divided the resulting
trialized societies often takes the form of disparity by 12 as a rough estimate of a nations
voluntary donations, and considerable strategic relative price of cooperation per month for
effort is expended by government agencies and the average worker to give free time to help
charitable organizations to facilitate this pro- others. All data were sorted by the work hours
cess. Not surprisingly, the frequency and variable and binned into quintiles, the means of
quantity of monetary donations are strongly which were then analyzed using the Exponential
associated with income at the individual, Model of Demand.
organizational, and national levels (Giving The results depicted in Figure 17 reveal
USA, 2012; Charities Aid Foundation, 2011), several noteworthy features. First is that at all
and certainly policy initiatives such as tax points, helping strangers is far more prevalent
incentives are intended to further reduce the than donating time to an organization. This
price of cooperation for charitable financial relationship would be expected from a behav-
giving9. However, money itself is not always the ioral-economic perspective, as spontaneous acts
price of cooperation nor is it always the of kindness such as giving someone spare
commodity consumed by the recipient. Indeed, change, offering directions, picking up dropped
consistent with the behavioral-economic ap- items, etc. all bear a very low time cost compared
proach advanced throughout this report, time to the formal process of scheduling and
itself is a core commodity of tremendous value, delivering time to an organization. Indeed, a
especially given the fact that income is non- sum-of-squares F test confirms that maximum
accumulating and no ones daily budget can demand for helping strangers (Q0) is signifi-
possibly exceed 24 hours regardless of financial cantly higher than that of volunteering time to
wealth. an organization (51% vs. 36%; F(1,6) 11.0,
To illustrate the broader relevance to social p < .05). These two forms of prosocial behavior
policy of the PoCs conceptual foundation and are further dissociated by their relations to
quantitative behavioral-economic approach increasing work demands. Given the low and
from which it draws, we analyzed the most relatively constant time cost of momentarily
recent data published in 2011 from 32 of the 34 helping strangers, this particular behavior is
highly developed member countries of the insensitive to the price imposed by increasing
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and commitment to work, as indicated by the
Development (OECD). Specifically, based on resulting demand curve that is modestly fitting
initial processing of data from the Gallup World at best (R2 .66) and yielding an extremely low
Poll10 by the Charities Aid Foundation (2011), a value that does not significantly differ from
we examined two national-level prosocial behav- zero (sum of squares F(1,3) 5.8, p > .09).
ior variables: (1) percentage of the population Most importantly, and as expected, the proba-
that helped a stranger or someone they did not bility of donating time to an organization
know within the last month and (2) percentage showed a very orderly decreasing relationship
of the population that volunteered their time to to the price of cooperation, with a well-fitting
an organization within the last month. The demand curve (R2 .93) and a significantly
predictor variable against which those outcomes higher sensitivity to price (a) than that of
were plotted was based on the OECDs summary momentarily helping a stranger (sum of squares
of Gallup World Poll data regarding 2011 work F(1,6) 33.0, p < .01).
hours among those nations employed citi- This international analysis of prosocial behav-
zens11. Specifically, we took the average annual ior is empirical by virtue of its integration of
hours actually worked per worker for each actual data, but is by no means definitive, nor do
we offer it as such. Prevalence rates of any
9
complex behavioral pattern are most certainly
http://www.economist.com/node/21556570 influenced by a variety of economic, cultural,
10
https://worldview.gallup.com. Original survey data
from representative samples of Ns 5001000 per country. and psychological factors; however, if the
11
http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode relations described here hold true, then the
ANHRS social policy implications are intriguing. First is
120 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

Fig. 17. Prevalence of nonmonetary prosocial behaviors in working citizens of industrialized nations as a function of the
price of cooperation in the form of increasing work hours. All model parameters were tested via sum-of-squares F test (Left
panel: slope differs from 0, **p < .01; Right panel: difference between behaviors, *p < .05, **p < .01).

that all prosocial behaviors are clearly not Discussion


created equal, and so strategies to promote
civility need not appeal to short-term conve- The preceding overview described recent
nience as a motivating factor. More importantly, advances in theory, research, and analysis in
while helping strangers and donating time may Behavioral Economics within Psychology, with a
both yield long-term benefits to society, the view toward potential applications of demand
latters apparent sensitivity to work hours makes curve principles to public policy development
worklife balance a reasonable target for policy and evaluation in various domains such as drug
consideration at all levels. For example, if basic abuse, transportation choice, and social behav-
economic needs and productivity goals could ior. Although many of the basic concepts have
still be met, then decreasing the lowest quintiles been tested in operant learning and behavioral
worker hours by as little as 10% (from 52 to 47 pharmacology settings, the use of economic
hr/month difference score) could potentially demand curves in any form is still fairly limited,
yield a 20% increase in the prevalence of and application of the various quantitative
monthly charitable donations of time. These models is still in its infancy.
data suggest that modest changes in worklife In terms of policy implications, focused efforts
balance can not only directly benefit workers to develop behavioral-economic approaches for
and their families as typically intended (Lee, formal inclusion in drug abuse risk manage-
McCann, & Messenger, 2007), but the behavior- ment would require considerable public and
al-economic strategy of reducing the price of private investment to ensure reliable and valid
cooperation for donating time may also pay techniques and metrics across reinforcers, drug
residual dividends to others in the community. classes, and species. Despite the broader
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 121

implications, much of this would naturally fall as well, thus quantifying complementsubstitute
under the auspices of basic research. For relations in a wide variety of contexts.
example, for any given reinforcer, what is the Despite its deceptively simple nature, the PoC
best quantity (or dose) for establishing a yields a suite of objective metrics that provide
demand curve or complementsubstitute test? the means for a rich, multidimensional view of
Does a hypothetical demand curve lose credi- group function and individual behaviors within
bility if the range of prices far exceeds realistic an interactive social setting. The representative
range? Does a vary based on the particular social-behavioral example data presented here-
prices used or the width of the range of those in are encouraging, and while admittedly
prices; and if so, what is the most appropriate premature, it is not difficult to imagine a fully
interpretation of such findings? These and researched and developed tool one day inform-
other empirical issues would have to be ing decisions as a standardized assay of cooper-
systematically addressed to lay the foundation ative propensity for personnel selection and
for behavioral economics as a policy tool team composition in diverse organizational
(cf. Loewenstein, Asch, Friedman, Melichar, & settings, as a simple assessment or training
Volpp, 2012), but given the unique conceptual- exercise in educational settings, or as part of a
ization of reinforcement embodied by the latest diagnostic and treatment efficacy-tracking ap-
generation of behavioral economic models such proach in clinical neuropsychiatric populations
as the Exponential Model of Demand, it would characterized by social deficits (e.g., autism
also likely yield insights on basic neurobiological spectrum, schizophrenia). Techniques such as
and behavioral mechanisms of reinforcement. hypothetical demand curve questionnaires can
Similar issues are also relevant for question- provide empirical insights on a wide range of
naire-based assessments in any area, either for policy domains, and behavioral assays built on
preclinical research and development, clinical/ behavioral economics and behavior-analysis
marketing surveys, field research, or broad principles can provide experimental insight to
public polling. The most obvious but no less test theories and model the effects of policy
critical issue is developing questionnaires with variations and social context on broader issues
acceptable psychometric properties that pro- within and across cultures, including communi-
duce data suitable for behavior-economic analy- ty engagement, cooperation, productivity, fair-
ses while remaining relevant to the participants ness, and other aspects of good citizenship of
and informative to those conducting the re- concern to behavioral scientists, social scientists,
search. Clearly, the laboratory setup of a lever and policy-makers alike.
and food-hopper or conventional market analy- Whether studying basic reinforcement mech-
sis of financial price and purchasing frequency anisms, drug abuse, consumer choice, social and
must give way to creative hypothetical adapta- economic behavior, or any other topic with
tions that can still reliably quantify motivation. broad societal implications, an emphasis on
Fortunately, innovative work in drug abuse has empirical policy rooted in behavior analysis
exemplified the flexibility of the hypothetical requires predictive validity in the tools used to
demand curve approach by defining essential inform, develop, and evaluate said policy.
value at the population level as the percent of Elasticity of demand and the essential value
subjects making a binary choice to purchase of commodities may very well contribute to
drugs under various conditions (Greenwald, individual differences in consumption, and
2010). Emerging survey development in the exquisitely controlled laboratory assays and
transportation sector has also framed questions carefully crafted questionnaires may very well
as the probability of individual drivers of flex- produce reliable metrics of the underlying
fuel vehicles selecting E-85 fuel as a function of motivational effects of various commodities,
distance and time from a standard fueling but ultimately, the variability observed in any
station12. Further adaptation of these techni- behavioral-economic measure must correspond
ques could produce hypothetical demand to peoples behaviors and choices in the real
curves suitable for cross-price elasticity analyses world that public policy seeks to shape. Even
with this and other challenges in mind, based on
12
Roma, P. G., Hursh, S. R., & Magoon, M. (2012, May). previous work and recent advances in the field,
Fuel Purchasing Behavior Survey. [Available upon request to we remain optimistic in our belief in the value of
the Authors]. science and evidence as the primary bases for
122 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

decision-making at all levels. In this spirit, we factors in learning (pp. 223274). Chichester, England:
believe that behavioral economics offers great Wiley.
potential as a broadly applicable and cross- Davison, M., McCarthy, D. (Eds.). (1988). The matching law: A
research review. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
cutting theoretical, technical, and analytical De Dreu, C. K., Greer, L. L., Handgraaf, M. J., Shalvi, S., Van
framework for research, development, and Kleef, G. A., Baas, M., Feith, S. W. (2010). The
evaluation of empirical public policy. neuropeptide oxytocin regulates parochial altruism in
intergroup conflict among humans. Science, 328(5984),
References 14081411.
De Maio, F. G. (2007). Income inequality measures. Journal of
Ahmed, S. H., & Koob, G. F. (1998). Transition from Epidemiology and Community Health, 61(10), 849852.
moderate to excessive drug intake: Change in hedonic Emurian, H. H., Canfield, K., Roma, P. G., Brinson, Z. S.,
set point. Science, 282, 298301. Gasior, E. D., Hienz, R. D., Brady, J. V. (2011). A
Allison, J. (1983). Behavioral economics. New York: Praeger. multiplayer team performance task: Design and evalua-
Allison, J., Miller, M., & Wozny, M. (1979). Conservation in tion. In M. M. Cruz-Cunha, V. H. Varvalho & P. Tavares
behavior. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 108, (Eds.), Business, technological and social dimensions of
434. computer games: Multidisciplinary developments (pp. 201
Amir, O., Rand, D. G., & Gal, Y. K. (2012). Economic games 219). Hershey, PA: IGI Publishing.
on the internet: The effect of $1 stakes. PLoS One, 7(2), Emurian, H. H., Canfield, K., Roma, P. G., Gasior, E. D.,
e31461. Brinson, Z. S., Hienz, R. D., Brady, J. V., (2009).
Banks, M. L., Roma, P. G., Folk, J. E., Rice, K. C., & Negus, S. Behavioral systems management of confined micro-
S. (2011). Effects of the delta-opioid agonist SNC80 on societies: An agenda for research and applications.
the abuse liability of methadone in rhesus monkeys: A Proceedings of the 39th international conference on
behavioral economic analysis. Psychopharmacology, 216, environmental systems (paper number 2009-01-2423).
431439. Warrendale, PA: SAE International.
Bauman, R. (1991). An experimental analysis of the cost of Esplugas, C., Teixeira, F., Lpez-Pita, A., Saa, B., (2005,
food in a closed economy. Journal of the Experimental September). Threats and opportunities for high speed
Analysis of Behavior, 56(1), 3350. rail transport in competition with the low-cost air
Bickel, W. K., DeGrandpre, R. J., & Higgins, S. T. (1993). operators. Presented at the 9th International Confer-
Behavioral economics: A novel experimental approach ence Series on Competition and Ownership in Land
to the study of drug dependence. Drug and Alcohol Passenger Transport. Lisbon, Portugal.
Dependence, 33, 173192. Foltin, R. W. (1992). Economic analysis of the effects of
Bickel, W. K., DeGrandpre, R. J., Higgins, S. T., & Hughes, J. caloric alternatives and reinforcer magnitude on
R. (1990). Behavioral economics of drug selfadminis- demand for food in baboons. Appetite, 19(3), 255271.
tration. I. Functional equivalence of response require- Foxall, G. R., & Sigurdsson, V. (2011). Drug use as consumer
ment and drug dose. Life Sciences, 47, 15011510. behavior. Behavioral & Brain Sciences, 34(6), 313314.
Bickel, W. K., DeGrandpre, R. J., Higgins, S. T., & Hughes, J. Gini, C. (1912). Variabilit e mutabilit. Reprinted in
R. (1991). Behavioral economics of drug selfadminis- E. Pizetti & T. Salvemini (Eds.), Memorie di Metodologia
tration. II. A unitprice analysis of cigarette smoking. Statistica (pp. 211382). Rome: Libreria Eredi Virgilio
Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 55, 145 Veschi. 1955.
154. Giving USA. (2012). The Annual Report on Philanthropy for the
Bidwell, L. C., MacKillop, J., Murphy, J. G., Tidey, J. W., & Year 2011. Chicago: Giving USA Foundation.
Colby, S. M. (2012). Latent factor structure of a Green, L., & Freed, D. E. (1993). The substitutability of
behavioral economic cigarette demand curve in adoles- reinforcers. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior,
cent smokers. Addictive Behaviors, 37(11), 12571263. 60(1), 141158.
Brady, J. V., Bernstein, D. J., Foltin, R. W., & Nellis, M. J. Green, L., & Freed, D. E. (1998). Behavioral economics. In
(1988). Performance enhancement in a semi-autono- W. ODonohue (Ed.), Learning and behavior therapy
mous confined microsociety. The Pavlovian Journal of (pp. 274300). Boston, MA: Allyn & Bacon.
Biological Science, 23(3), 111117. Green, L., Rachlin, H., & Hanson, J. (1983). Matching and
Carroll, M. E. (1993). The economic context of drug and maximizing with concurrent ratio-interval schedules.
non-drug reinforcers affects acquisition and mainte- Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 40, 217
nance of drug-reinforced behavior and withdrawal 224.
effects. Drug and Alcohol Dependence, 33(2), 201210. Greenwald, M. K. (2010). Effects of experimental Unem-
Charities Aid Foundation. (2011). World Giving Index 2011. ployment, Employment and Punishment analogs on
https://www.cafonline.org/publications/2011-publica- opioid seeking and consumption in heroin-dependent
tions/world-giving-index-2011.aspx. volunteers. Drug and Alcohol Dependence, 111(12),
Choi, J. K., & Bowles, S. (2007). The coevolution of parochial 6473.
altruism and war. Science, 318(5850), 636640. Griffiths, R. R., Bigelow, G. E., & Henningfield, J. E. (1980).
Christensen, C. J., Silberberg, A., Hursh, S. R., Roma, P. G., & Similarities in animal and human drugtaking behavior.
Riley, A. L. (2008). Demand for cocaine and food over In N. K. Mello (Ed.), Advances in substance abuse (Vol. 1,
time. Pharmacology, Biochemistry and Behavior, 91(2), 209 pp. 190). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
216. Griffiths, R. R., Bradford, L. D., & Brady, A. V. (1979).
Collier, G. H. (1983). Life in a closed economy: The ecology Progressive ratio and fixed ratio schedules of cocaine-
of learning and motivation. In M. D. Zeiler & P. Harzem maintained responding in baboons. Psychopharmacology
(Eds.), Advances in analysis of behaviour: Vol. 3. Biological (Berl), 65(2), 125136.
EMPIRICAL PUBLIC POLICY 123

Hall, G. A., & Lattal, K. A. (1990). Variable-interval schedule Klor, E. F., & Shayo, M. (2010). Social identity and
performance in open and closed economies. Journal of preferences over redistribution. Journal of Public Econom-
the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 54(1), 1322. ics, 94, 269278.
Harrigan, S. E., & Downs, D. A. (1978). Continuous intra- Ko, M. C., Terner, J., Hursh, S., Woods, J. H., & Winger, G.
venous naltrexone effects on morphine self-administra- (2002). Relative reinforcing effects of three opioids with
tion in rhesus monkeys. Journal of Pharmacology and different durations of action. Journal of Pharmacology and
Experimental Therapeutics, 204(2), 481486. Experimental Therapeutics, 301, 698704.
Herrnstein, R. J. (1958). Some factors influencing behavior LaFiette, M. H., & Fantino, E. (1989). Responding on
in a two-response situation. Transactions of the New York concurrent-chains schedules in open and closed
Academy of Sciences, 21, 3545. economies. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior,
Herrnstein, R. J. (1961). Relative and absolute strength of 51(3), 329342.
response as a function of frequency of reinforcement. Lea, S. E. G. (1978). The psychology and economics of
Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 4, 267272. demand. Psychological Bulletin, 85, 441466.
Herrnstein, R. J., & Loveland, D. H. (1975). Maximizing and Lea, S. E. G., & Roper, T. J. (1977). Demand for food on
matching on concurrent ratio schedules. Journal of the fixed-ratio schedules as a function of the quality of
Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 24, 107116. concurrently available reinforcement. Journal of the
Hunt, D. E., Lipton, D. S., Goldsmith, D. S., & Strug, D. L. Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 27, 371380.
(1984). Problems in methadone treatment: The influ- Lee, S., McCann, D., & Messenger, J. C. (2007). Working
ence of reference groups. NIDA Research Monographs, 46, time around the world: trends in working hours, laws and
822. policies in a global comparative perspective. New York:
Hursh, S. R. (1978). The economics of daily consumption Routledge.
controlling food- and water-reinforced responding. Locey, M., Safin, V., & Rachlin, H. (2013). Social discounting
Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 29(3), and the prisoners dilemma game. Journal of the
475491. Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 99, 3850.
Hursh, S. R. (1980). Economic concepts for the analysis of Loewenstein, G., Asch, D. A., Friedman, J. Y., Melichar, L. A.,
behavior. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, & Volpp, K. G. (2012). Can behavioural economics
34(2), 219238. make us healthier? British Medical Journal (Clinical
Hursh, S. R. (1984). Behavioral economics. Journal of the research ed.), 344, e3482.
Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 42(3), 435452. Lucas, G. A. (1981). Some effects of reinforcer availability on
Hursh, S. R., & Bauman, R. A. (1987). The behavioral the pigeons responding in 24-hour sessions. Animal
analysis of demand. In L. Green & J. H. Kagel (Eds.), Learning & Behavior, 9, 411424.
Advances in behavioral economics (Vol. 1, pp. 117165.). MacKillop, J., Few, L. R., Murphy, J. G., Wier, L. M., Acker, J.,
Norwood, NJ: Ablex. Murphy, C., Stojek, M., Carrigan, M., & Chaloupka, F.
Hursh, S. R., & Natelson, B. H. (1981). Electrical (2012). High-resolution behavioral economic analysis of
brain stimulation and food reinforcement dissociated cigarette demand to inform tax policy. Addiction 107
by demand elasticity. Physiology & Behavior, 26, 509 (12), 21912200.
515. MacKillop, J., Murphy, J. G., Ray, L. A., Eisenberg, D. T.,
Hursh, S. R., Raslear, T. G., Bauman, R., & Black, H. (1989). Lisman, S. A., Lum, J. K., & Wilson, D. S. (2008). Further
The quantitative analysis of economic behavior with validation of a cigarette purchase task for assessing the
laboratory animals. In K. G. Grunert & F. lander relative reinforcing efficacy of nicotine in college
(Eds.), Understanding economic behavior. Dordrecht, smokers. Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology,
Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers, Theory 16(1), 5765.
and Decision Library. Magoon, M., & Hursh, S. R. (2011). The Behavioral
Hursh, S. R., Raslear, T. G., Shurtleff, D., Bauman, R., & Economics of Transportation Travel Time, Mode
Simmons, L. (1988). A cost-benefit analysis of demand Choice and Carbon Impact. Presented at the 5th
for food. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 50, annual Behavior, Energy and Climate Change Confer-
419440. ence (BECC), Washington, DC. [http://www.stanford.
Hursh, S. R., & Silberberg, A. (2008). Economic demand and edu/group/peec/cgi-bin/docs/events/2011/becc/
essential value. Psychological Review, 115, 186198. presentations/9%20The%20Behavioral%20Economics
Hursh, S. R., & Winger, G. (1995). Normalized demand for %20-%20Mike%20Magoon.pdf]
drugs and other reinforcers. Journal of the Experimental Murphy, J. G., & MacKillop, J. (2006). Relative reinforcing
Analysis of Behavior, 64, 373384. efficacy of alcohol among college student drinkers.
Johanson, C. E. (1978). Drugs as reinforcers. In D. Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology, 14(2), 219
E. Blackman & D. J. Sanger (Eds.), Contemporary research 227.
in behavioral pharmacology (pp. 325390). New York: Negus, S. S., Schrode, K., & Stevenson, G. W. (2008). Mu/
Plenum Press. kappa opioid interactions in rhesus monkeys: Implica-
Kagel, J. H., Roth, A. E. (Eds.). (1995). The handbook of tions for analgesia and abuse liability. Experimental and
experimental economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univer- Clinical Psychopharmacology, 16(5), 386399.
sity Press. Oliveira-Castro, J. M., Foxall, G. R., Yan, J., & Wells, V. K.
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (1982). Judgment (2011). A behavioral-economic analysis of the essential
under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. New York: Cam- value of brands. Behavioural Processes, 87(1), 106
bridge University Press. 114.
Katz, J. L. (1990). Models of relative reinforcing efficacy of Rachlin, H., & Laibson, D. (1997). The Matching Law: papers
drugs and their predictive utility. Behavioural Pharmacol- on psychology and economics by Richard Herrnstein.
ogy, 1(4), 283301. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
124 STEVEN R. HURSH and PETER G. ROMA

Rachlin, H., & Locey, M. (2011). A behavioral analysis of Staahl, C., Olesen, A. E., Andresen, T., Arendt-Nielsen, L., &
altruism. Behavioural Processes, 87(1), 2533. Drewes, A. M. (2009). Assessing efficacy of non-opioid
Rachlin, H., Green, L., Kagel, J. H., & Battalio, R. C. (1976). analgesics in experimental pain models in healthy
Economic demand theory and psychological studies of volunteers: An updated review. British Journal of Clinical
choice. In G. Bower (Ed.), The psychology of learning and Pharmacology 68(3), 322341.
motivation (Vol. 10, pp. 129154). New York: Academic Staddon, J. E. R. (1979). Operant behavior as adaptation to
Press. constraint. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 108,
Rashotte, M. E., & Henderson, D. (1988). Coping with rising 4867.
food costs in a closed economy: Feeding behavior and Stafford, D., LeSage, M. G., & Glowa, J. R. (1998).
nocturnal hypothermia in pigeons. Journal of the Progressive-ratio schedules of drug delivery in the
Experimental Analysis of Behavior 50, 441456. analysis of drug self-administration: A review. Psycho-
Roane, H. S., Call, N. A., & Falcomata, T. S. (2005). A pharmacology (Berl), 139(3), 169184.
preliminary analysis of adaptive responding under open Stitzer, M. L., Grabowski, J., & Henningfield, J. E. (1984).
and closed economies. Journal of the Experimental Analysis Behavioral intervention techniques in drug abuse
of Behavior, 38(3), 335348. treatment: Summary of discussion. NIDA Research
Roddy, J., Steinmiller, C. L., & Greenwald, M. K. (2011). Monographs, 46, 147157.
Heroin purchasing is income and price sensitive. Thaler, R. H., & Mullainathan, S., (2008). Behavioral
Psychology of Addictive Behaviors, 25(2), 358364. economics. The Concise Encyclopedia of Eco-
Roma, P. G., Hursh, S. R., Hienz, R. D., Brinson, Z. S., & nomics. Library of Economics and Liberty. Retrieved
Brady, J. V., (2012). The price of cooperation: A novel November 11, 2012 from the World Wide Web: http://
behavioral economic task as a simple, rapid, and www.econlib.org/library/Enc/BehavioralEconomics.
objective assay of voluntary cooperation, productivity, html.
and fairness in small groups. Manuscript in preparation. Thompson, T., Koerner, J., & Grabowski, J. (1984).
Sambanis, N., Schulhofer-Wohl, J., & Shayo, M. (2012). Brokerage model rehabilitation system for opiate
Parochialism as a central challenge in counterinsurgen- dependence: A behavioral analysis. NIDA Research
cy. Science, 336(6083), 805808. Monographs, 46, 131146.
Shen, X. Y., Orson, F. M., & Kosten, T. R. (2012). Vaccines Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism.
against drug abuse. Clinical Pharmacology and Therapeu- The Quarterly Review of Biology, 46(1), 3557.
tics, 91(1), 6070. Watson, D. S., & Holman, M. A. (1977). Price theory and its uses,
Sinclair Knight Merz. (2010). International Rail Travel (4th ed.). Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Demand Model for HS2 (IRTDM): A Report for HS2. Wildman, J. L., Bedwell, W. L., Salas, E., & Smith-Jentsch,
London, UK. K. A. (2010). Performance measurement at work:
Spiga, R., Martinetti, M. P., Meisch, R. A., Cowan, K., & A multilevel perspective. In S. Zedeck (Ed.), APA
Hursh, S. (2005). Methadone and nicotine self-admin- handbook of industrial and organizational psychology:
istration in humans: A behavioral economic analysis. vol. 1, Building and developing the organization
Psychopharmacology (Berl), 178(23), 223231. (pp. 303342). Washington, DC: American Psycholog-
Spiga, R., Wilson, K., & Martinetti, M. P., (2013). Human ical Association.
drug self-administration: An exponential analysis of
nicotine and ethanol interactions. Manuscript in
preparation (http://psychology.pages.tcnj.edu/files/ Received: June 12, 2012
2011/12/Martinetti-Vitae-updated-2011-12-06.pdf). Final Acceptance: October 7, 2012

S-ar putea să vă placă și