Sunteți pe pagina 1din 15

534534

research-article2014
PRQXXX10.1177/1065912914534534Political Research QuarterlySingh and Carlin

Article
Political Research Quarterly

Happy Medium, Happy Citizens:


2015, Vol. 68(1) 317
2014 University of Utah
Reprints and permissions:
Presidential Power and Democratic sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/1065912914534534

Regime Support prq.sagepub.com

Shane P. Singh1 and Ryan E. Carlin2

Abstract
Institutional and behavioral theories of democracy abound but rarely intersect. Do executive lawmaking power and
prowess condition democratic regime support in presidential democracies? We develop theoretical expectations
linking the lawmaking powers of the president and mass regime support and test them by analyzing survey data
from eighteen Latin American countries over ten years. As hypothesized, results indicate that preference for, and
satisfaction with, democracy is highest where presidents have moderate legislative powers and success and lowest
where presidents either dominate policymaking or face gridlock. Hence, a happy medium of presidential power
promotes the attitudinal foundations of democracy.

Keywords
attitudes toward democracy, satisfaction with democracy, presidential powers

At the outset of the third wave of democratization, theo- presidentialisms capacity to produce democratic stability
rists were highly concerned with getting the institutions and quality. For behavioralists, appreciating the larger
right. To the potential chagrin of many (e.g., Mainwaring political environments within which democratic attitudes
1993; Shugart and Carey 1992; Stepan and Skach 1993), are nested (e.g., Dalton and Anderson 2011) will help
Latin American constitution drafters uniformly main- identify the institutional roots of regime support. On a
tained presidential models of democracy. Seeking to practical level, understanding the interplay between mod-
avoid the political instability that plagued the first two els of presidentialism and legitimacy will be valuable to
waves, in many cases they modified the legislative pow- institutional engineers tasked with crafting workable
ers of the presidency (Negretto 2009; Shugart and Carey institutions for nascent democracies worldwide.
1992). Today, presidents lawmaking powers (Mainwaring Joining the institutional and behavioral theoretical tra-
and Shugart 1997; Negretto 2009) and legislative success ditions, we model democratic regime support as a function
rates (Alemn and Calvo 2010; Alemn and Navia 2009; of presidents legislative powers, conceived in three
Saiegh 2009, 2011) vary greatly across the region. Taking dimensions: formal powers, partisan powers, and recorded
stock of the empirical record, scholars reckon that, despite legislative success rates. We expect these powers to influ-
the persistence of multipartism and the frequency of pres- ence public regime evaluations in a nuanced fashion. On
idential challenges and interruptions, modern presidential one hand, strong presidentialism puts citizens in the para-
regimes have delivered more democratic stability than doxical situation of electing executives they cannot easily
predicted (Melo 2009; Pereira and Melo 2012; Prez- or effectively control. So presidents who dominate policy-
Lin 2007). Still, theorists link these regimes long-run making should be associated with lower regime support.
viability to the support they foster among citizens On the other hand, if citizens value the political voice and
(Almond and Verba 1963; Altman and Prez-Lin 2002; accountability representative democracy, in theory, affords
Diamond 1999; Easton 1975; Lagos 2003; Linz and (Dahl 1971; Powell 2000), they may disparage political
Stepan 1996; Norris 1999; Torcal and Montero 2006).
Do the diverging types of presidentialism influence 1
University of Georgia, Athens, USA
mass regime support in Latin American democracies? 2
Georgia State University, Atlanta, USA
The scant consideration this question has received reveals
Corresponding Author:
a major gulf between institutional and behavioral theories Shane P. Singh, Department of International Affairs, University of
of democracy, and exploring it will benefit both camps. Georgia, 303 Candler Hall, Athens, GA 30602, USA.
For institutionalists, it will inform venerable debates on Email: singh@uga.edu
4 Political Research Quarterly 68(1)

systems in which the presidents agenda is repeatedly bill introduction powers. Proactive powers help presi-
thwarted. And by obscuring policy responsibility, weak dents change the status quo, while reactive powers help
presidents frustrate citizens ability to exact accountability them defend it. Both types of power give presidents tools
(Mainwaring and Shugart 1997; Powell and Whitten to limit the legislatures role in the policymaking process
1993; Samuels 2004). So presidents who cannot advance (Mainwaring and Shugart 1997; Negretto 2004).
their agendas should also be associated with lower regime Democratic transitions in Latin America were gener-
support. By contrast, models of presidentialism that strike ally accompanied by new constitutions or major amend-
a balance between these two extremes should optimize ments to existing ones that altered the presidents formal
public regime evaluations. If so, citizens should be happi- legislative powers. In many cases, however, these institu-
est with democracy where presidents enjoy a happy tions remained in flux. Indeed, Negretto (2013, 39) counts
medium of power. eighteen post-transition reforms in the region from 1978
We test these expectations with survey data from eigh- to 2008, two-thirds of which strengthened presidential
teen Latin American countries over a ten-year span. In lawmaking ability. Of these, only two instances (El
line with our theoretical priors, two instrumental evalua- Salvador in 1983 and Uruguay in 1996) raised power
tions of regime supportbelief that democracy is the exclusively by bolstering the presidents veto power; the
best political system and satisfaction with how democ- rest strengthened presidents agenda-setting powers. By
racy is functioningare lowest under extremely power- 2008, only constitutions in Costa Rica, the Dominican
ful and extremely weak presidents and highest at middling Republic, Mexico, and Nicaragua deprived presidents of
levels of presidential power and prowess. Theoretically significant agenda-setting power.
and practically, this suggests models of presidentialism
and legitimacy are linked: democracys attitudinal moor-
ings are least secure when presidents lawmaking power
Partisan Powers of the President
is either grossly inflated or completely emasculated and Beyond formal de jure powers, presidents de facto parti-
most secure under institutional designs that foster com- san powers strongly shape their policymaking capabili-
promise between presidents and legislatures. ties. These powers vary with party discipline, legislative
and party system fragmentation, unified (vs. divided)
Presidential Powers and government, and majority (vs. coalition) rule. They affect
presidential lawmaking insofar as changing policy
Policymaking becomes increasingly costly as the number of parties to a
The linkage between presidential power and mass demo- negotiation, or the diversity of their preferences,
cratic regime support begins with the lawmaking process increases (Cox and McCubbins 2001, 27). Besides the
in presidential regimes, which is largely conditioned by number and preferences of the actors, their distribution
executivelegislative relations. As each branch holds its across lawmaking bodies matters as well. Veto players
own electoral mandate, the dual legitimacy problem theory views partisan powers in terms of individual and
makes their relationship inherently tense (Linz 1990). collective actors (e.g., legislative coalitions and legisla-
Exactly how this plays out in the policymaking arena tive chambers) who must agree to change the status quo
depends on the branches relative powers as well as the (Tsebelis 2002). Presidentialism in Latin America consis-
institutional arrangements and ideological constraints to tently takes place within multiparty contexts, and party
which they are subject. For their part, presidents possess discipline and ideological cohesion in the legislature and
two types of lawmaking powers: formal constitutional the government can vary widely. These facts of political
powers and partisan powers derived from the distribution life often require presidents to form coalitions or to cob-
of partisan support in the legislature. We expect these ble together majorities bill by bill (Mainwaring and
powers, along with presidents actual success in lawmak- Shugart 1997).
ing, to shape mass democratic regime support.
Legislative Success of the President
Formal Legislative Powers of the President Presidents actual policymaking prowess can be gauged
Presidents formal powers come in legislative and non- by their statutory success. According to Saiegh (2009,
legislative varieties. As our theory concerns the bilateral 2011), Latin American presidents pass their policy pro-
policymaking process, we restrict our analysis to the for- posals at rates ranging from 10 to 90 percent. Saiegh
mer.1 Legislative powers are classified as proactive or argues executive statutory success is complicated by the
reactive. Proactive powers include decree authority, uncertainty introduced by cross-pressured legislators
agenda-setting powers, and budgetary powers; reactive who factor their values, constituents views, position-
powers consist of the veto, the partial veto, and exclusive taking, and party leader preferences into their votes. Latin
Singh and Carlin 5

American presidents legislative success also reflects and Verba 1963; Miller 1974), then feeling left out of the
their more ephemeral and imprecise knowledge of the policymaking process could spur disillusionment with
political lay of the land (Cox and Morgenstern 2002, the principles and performance of democratic regimes
466). Thus, formal powers and partisan support imper- (Anderson et al. 2005, 2326). Where presidents do not
fectly affect presidents clout because party discipline (or are not obliged to) respect the balance of policymak-
and presidents own perceptions are imperfect. ing power, perceived government responsiveness should
diminish and disgruntlement with democracy should
grow.
Theory
Just as very powerful presidents fuel democratic dis-
Under the assumption that democratic attitudes are held content, so should very weak ones. Because presidents,
by individuals who are embedded in political contexts like legislators, are directly elected and enjoy their own
(Dalton and Anderson 2011, 3), much work on Europe mandates, an enfeebled presidency can generate a princi-
(e.g., Anderson and Guillory 1997) and beyond (e.g., palagent problem of representation similar to that just
Lijphart 2012; Norris 1999; Singh 2014) explores how described. Moreover, presidents who lack formal and/or
models of democracy affect regime support. Shugart and partisan legislative powers can contribute to two demo-
Mainwaring (1997, 53, emphasis added) posit that the cratic deficits. The first goes by several names: policy
most important explanation for presidentialisms poor stalemate, gridlock, deadlock, impasse, or immobilism.
record of democratic stability in the region is not insti- When leaders cannot alter national conditions, it can
tutional, but rather is an effect of lower levels of develop- exclude marginalized groups from the governing process
ment and nondemocratic political cultures. Yet neither (Young and Dugan 2011) and threaten stability
they nor others (e.g., Booth and Seligson 2009; Vairo (Mainwaring 1993). Second, otherwise powerless presi-
2012) test how models of presidentialism influence dents may advance their agendas with plebiscitarian or
regime support. Taking this possibility seriously, we authoritarian overtures such as resorting to unilateral
advance a theory linking presidential power and prowess decree powers, holding national referenda, effecting self-
to regime support, which encompasses instrumental eval- coups, replacing the constitution, or packing the courts.
uations of democratic principles and performance (Dalton Therefore, either by failing to resolve policy immobilism
2004; Easton 1975). We expect regime support is greatest or resolving it in ways that undermine representation by
where presidents enjoy moderate degrees of lawmaking violating the letter or spirit of the law, hamstrung presi-
clout and lowest where they are either exceedingly weak dents may hinder the attitudinal consolidation of democ-
or exceptionally strong. racy (Linz and Stepan 1996).
Our proposition that extreme executive power erodes Overall, power extremitiestoo little or too much
regime support hinges on two principalagent problems. should accentuate these principalagent problems under
First, voters (principals) who elect presidents (agents) presidentialism and, in turn, weaken citizen evaluations
expect a degree of control. Direct elections at once raise of regime principles and performance. From a citizens
control by making executives more identifiable perspective, then, the sweet spot should lie in a happy
(Mainwaring and Shugart 1997), but also inflate per- medium. This expectation resonates with research on
ceived mandates: [t]he feeling of having independent presidentialism and governability. Viewing the lawmak-
power, a mandate from the people . . . is likely to give a ing process as a multilateral game, Pereira and Melo
president a sense of power and mission that might be out (2012) argue strong presidentialism works best when
of proportion to the limited plurality that elected him executives control discretionary coalition goods and face
(Linz 1994, 19). Thus, citizens should be more critical of checks and balances in fragmented legislatures. While
the regime where the rules of the democratic game they acknowledge strong legislatures could bias policy
embolden them to elect exceedingly powerful presidents toward the status quo and weak legislatures might not
but provide only rare opportunities to rein these rulers in. check executives (Pereira and Melo 2012, 16768), they
A second principalagent problem emerges regarding nonetheless propose party fragmentation itself works to
representation. Voters (principals) elect legislators constrain a powerful executive, functioning as a kind of
(agents) who they expect to represent their interests in the parliamentary oversight (Pereira and Melo 2012, 161).
policymaking process (Mansbridge 2003). But what if Similarly, Pereira, Singh, and Mueller (2011) argue effec-
principals feel an overbearing president supersedes their tive democratic governance requires a delicate balance
agents actions? Liberal representative democracy is between resoluteness and adaptability. Both logics align
meant to grant citizens a voice, a measure of self-rule, with our proposition regarding the value of a happy
and mechanisms for accountability (Dahl 1971; Powell medium of executive authority vis--vis the legislature.
2000). If perceptions of representation and responsive- Behavioral evidence also indicates that citizens would
ness powerfully influence democratic attitudes (Almond prefer to strike a middle ground of presidential power.
6 Political Research Quarterly 68(1)

Saiegh (2011) finds violent riots are most frequent when as to the direction of such reformswhether they moder-
executives pass either a very low (<15%) or very high ate power or push it to strong or weak extremeswhich is
(>80%) percentage of their bills, and least frequent when not obvious a priori. Nevertheless, we discuss some of
they pass roughly half (see also Machado, Scartascini, these reforms in more detail and empirically analyze the
and Tommasi 2011; Przeworski 2010). If violent political possibility of reverse causality below and in the
protests correspond to presidential policy prowess in a Supplemental Materials (http://prq.sagepub.com/supple-
nonlinear manner, democratic attitudes might reasonably mental/). We find no evidence that mass regime support
be expected to do so as well. precipitates institutional restructuring or changes in presi-
While we expect moderate presidential powers are dential prerogative and prowess within countries.
ideal for cultivating support for democratic regimes, there
are several reasons why this might not be the case. One is
that citizens may respect and desire a powerful, decisive
Data, Measurement, and
figure at the helm. Presidentialism creates a unique aura Methodology
and self-image around a leader (Linz 1990, 53), and Dependent Variables
some citizens are drawn to dominant authoritative figures
(Pratto, Sidanius, and Levin 2006). Moreover, Latin Our theory links presidential power to regime support,
Americans who are pleased with political and economic part of the broader concept of political support, which also
performance are often willing to grant presidents wide includes support for the political community and support
unilateral powers with the potential to undermine checks for authorities (Easton 1975). Dalton (1999, 2004) theo-
and balances (Carlin and Singer 2011). Second, it is pos- rizes that regime support is directed at three main objects
sible that, independent of their actual powers, citizens principles, performance, and institutionsand citizens
generally perceive presidents to be quite powerful. Voters can hold affective and instrumental orientations to each.
may reward or punish presidents for outcomes for which We expect presidential power and prowess to shape instru-
they are not necessarily responsible (e.g., Achen and mental support for regime (democratic) principles and
Bartels 2004). Still, although baseline perceived presi- performance in line with the principalagent problems
dential powers may be high, we expect variation in actual and dilemmas inherent in the extreme (weak or strong)
presidential powers and lawmaking prowess to alter citi- models of presidentialism outlined above.
zens perceptions around this baseline and, in turn, their To measure these two dimensions of regime support,
regime support. we select indicators from the Latinobarometer, a widely
A third concern is that the causal arrow may run the used source of regional survey data (e.g., Alcaiz and
other direction: regime support may influence presidential Hellwig 2011; Cramer and Kaufman 2011; Fernandez
power and prowess. Yet the theoretical grounds for this and Kuenzi 2010; Sarsfield and Echegaray 2006).2
proposition are not well established. Across Latin America, Instrumental support for regime principles is mea-
presidents formal legislative powers and prerogatives sured with the classic Linzian item:
were reshaped by new constitutions or major institutional
reforms at the outset of democratic transitions. Thereafter, With which of the following statements do you most agree?
governability challenges prompted further reforms in a
host of countries. Prevailing theories of institutional A.
Democracy is preferable to any other kind of
government.
choice, however, suggest a disconnect between the crisis
that precipitates constitutional change and nature of the
B.Under some circumstances, an authoritarian government
eventual amendments or reforms adopted.
can be preferable to a democratic one.
According to Negrettos (2013) study of third wave
Latin American democracies, constitutional change takes C.For people like me, it does not matter whether we have
place when institutions fail to meet a cooperative goal a democratic or a nondemocratic regime.
outcomes such as political order, stable government,
effective decision-making, and citizen inclusion and par- From these responses, we create a dichotomous vari-
ticipation (e.g., Jillson and Eubanks 1984; McGuire 1988). able coded 1 for respondents who selected option A and
Although all actors agree that reforms are needed, they coded 0 for those who chose B or C. Instrumental support
typically disagree about, or do not know, which are most for regime performance is gauged with a common mea-
appropriate. Moreover, institutional designers invariably sure of democratic satisfaction:
seek to adopt rules to their political advantage. Thus, a
correlation could plausibly exist between levels of regime In general, would you say that you are very satisfied, fairly
support and reforms to alter presidential powers. But satisfied, not very satisfied, or not at all satisfied with the
determining reverse causality requires a clear expectation way democracy works in (country)?
Singh and Carlin 7

From these responses, we code an ordinal variable that powers, decree authority, budgetary powers, whether the
assigns a 4 to respondents who are very satisfied, a 3 to president can convene Congress at will, and whether a
those who are fairly satisfied, a 2 to those not very satis- president can call a referendum on a bill. Theoretically,
fied, and a 1 to those not at all satisfied. Nonresponses are his Legislative Powers index captures the proactive tools
coded as missing. Figures A1 and A2 of the Supplemental presidents can use to enact their agendas. Because it is
Materials illustrate the mean values of both dependent derived via principal component analysis, Legislative
variables across the countries in our sample. Powers overcomes the limitations of extant additive
Under Daltons (1999, 58, Table 3.1) taxonomy, the indexes, which assume that each particular power con-
Linzian item taps instrumental evaluations of regime tributes equally to a presidents overall power (Negretto
principles and satisfaction with democracy taps instru- 2009, 12728). The measure has a theoretical range of 1
mental evaluations of regime performance. This distinc- to 100, with higher values indicating greater legislative
tion matches Torcal and Moncagattas (2011) conceptual powers of the presidency. In contrast to the alternative
review, aligns with Linde and Ekmans (2003) critical operationalizations of presidential lawmaking power
appraisal of these two measures, and is consistent with described below, Negrettos index is not relational, mean-
evidence that mass support for regime principles and per- ing it does not capture the presidents power vis--vis
formance, measured with these and similar indicators, other political players and, thus, the constraints he or she
retains an instrumental, utilitarian flavor in Latin America faces in the policymaking arena.
(Booth and Seligson 2009; Carlin and Singer 2011;
Sarsfield and Echegaray 2006). Political constraints. As noted above, presidents also derive
While these measures are commonly employed in the power from their partisan support within and between
literature, they are imperfect. Both may suffer problems of lawmaking branches. Veto players preferences across
comparability related to how respondents define democ- these branches must align for policy to change, and depar-
racy (Canache 2012). Finding that satisfaction with tures from the status quo are less likely where veto players
democracy correlates with support for regime principles, are numerous and the ideal points of different veto players
institutions, and political authorities, Canache, Mondak, diverse (Tsebelis 2002, 2). Employing the veto players
and Seligson (2001) conclude it fails to measure any dimen- concept, Henisz (2000) creates a measure of political con-
sion of political support. A more sanguine reading of their straints gauging the likelihood of changing the policy sta-
evidence is that satisfaction with democracy measures tus quo if the presidents preferences change. The measure
regime performance and is somewhere in between specific accounts for the number of independent branches of gov-
support and institutional confidence (Anderson 2001, 11). ernment and the preferences of these branches, based on
Principal component analysis3 supports this basic intu- party composition. For example, if the presidents party
ition. Satisfaction with democracy (regime performance has large majority in the legislature, the variable will
evaluations) loads moderately on both of the first two decrease. Alternatively, if the president must rely on a
components, which together capture 64 percent of the fractionalized coalition in the legislature, the variable will
variance; Linzian support (regime principles evaluations) increase. So whereas Negrettos Legislative Powers index
is unrelated to the first component but strongly related to reflects the presidents constitutional powers, Heniszs
the second. Furthermore, institutional trust measures Political Constraints accounts for changing political land-
(Congress, parties, judiciary, president, government) are scapes. Its theoretical range is from 0 to 1. As Political
unrelated to the second component and strongly related to Constraints approaches 0, it indicates that the executive
the first. Still, our two regime support measures are weakly faces an increasingly veto-free policymaking environ-
related (polychoric correlation = 0.29), and we acknowl- ment. Alternatively, as it approaches 1, it indicates that
edge the imperfection with which they can be separated. changing the status quo becomes increasingly difficult.4

Legislative Box Score. Finally, we use a measure of presi-


Explanatory Variables dents realized legislative success. The Box Score, as
Our key explanatory variables, outlined below, were col- calculated by Saiegh (2009, 2011), is the percentage of
lected across each country for each available year in bills initiated by the president that were approved by the
which the Latinobarometer survey was conducted. legislature in the year under study. A low Box Score indi-
cates the presidents agenda has met resistance in the leg-
Legislative powers of the president. As a de jure measure, islature; a high Box Score suggests the president has little
we use Negrettos (2009, see his Appendix A) Compara- trouble implementing his agenda by statute.
tive Index of Legislative Powers, which records cross-
national and over-time variation in the following Our models include both the raw and squared versions
constitutional powers of Latin American presidents: veto of each measure of presidential legislative power and
8 Political Research Quarterly 68(1)

prowessLegislative Powers, Political Constraints, and are only eighteen observations at Level 3, modeling the
Legislative Box Scoreto determine whether they exhibit country-level effects in a multilevel framework is poten-
an inverted-U-shaped association with instrumental tially inadvisable (cf. Heck and Thomas 2000; Hox 2002;
regime support, as our theory predicts. Specifically, we Stegmueller 2013). Yet Wells and Krieckhaus (2006)
expect regime support to be lowest at the extremes of show the importance of accounting for hierarchical data
Legislative Powers than at more judicious degrees of structures in cross-national models of democratic atti-
power. Similarly, we expect lower levels of regime sup- tudes. To do so, we use multilevel models that estimate a
port when presidents face either very many or very few random intercept for each survey within each country.
Political Constraints and greater support in moderately While this does not explicitly account for country-level
constrained contexts. Regarding Legislative Box Score, effects, it does model unobserved variance due to survey-
again we also expect that, up to a point, evaluations of level effects and characteristics attributable to the envel-
democratic principles and performance should rise with oping country. Furthermore, to examine the robustness of
the presidents ability to implement his or her legislative our findings, we estimated our models in a full three-level
agenda, only to fall once the legislature begins to function framework with both maximum likelihood and Bayesian
as a rubber stamp for presidential initiatives. estimation techniques. The results are robust to these
In the Supplemental Materials, Figures A3 to A6 dis- approaches (see Tables A7A10 in the Supplemental
play the means of each presidential power index across Materials).
the countries in our sample. Furthermore, Figure A7 illus- Our general model is illustrated with following
trates that there are no strong linear dependencies among equation:
the indices of presidential power and prowess. This sug-
yij = j + xij + ij ,
gests our analyses are not exact replicas of one another
but rather can be considered separate tests of the relation-
ships between democratic regime support and presiden- where j = j + j .
tial authority. Finally, Figures A8 to A13 plot the values Each individuals (i) score on the dependent variable
of the presidential powers and prowess measures and the in a given survey (j) is denoted as yij. Individual-level
mean levels of support for democratic regime principles variables are contained in xij and survey-level variables
and performance over time across all eighteen countries. are contained in j. The coefficients associated with xij are
contained in vector , and coefficients associated with j
are contained in vector . The j term captures variation
Control Variables around the survey-specific intercepts, j, and ij cap-
We control for a host of factors previously linked to tures the random error for each individual. This approach
regime support. In the interest of space, we discuss the also permits an estimation of = var(j) / [var(j) +
theoretical bases for the inclusion of each control variable var(ij)], the proportion of unmodeled individually held
and their measurement in the Supplemental Materials. At variance in the dependent variable due to unobserved sur-
the survey level, we control for wealth, economic growth, vey- or country-level effects. This value ranges roughly 4
and age of democracy. At the individual level, we control and 7 percent across each model, indicating that unex-
for age, gender, education, retrospective economic evalu- plained variance in regime support at the survey and
ations, political interest, ideological proximity to the country levels exists even after we account for multiple
president, and crime victimization. Level 2 factors.7
Data on each of our variables is available across 142 For the dichotomous dependent variable tapping
surveys of a total of 107,330 individuals in eighteen instrumental support for regime principlesthe Linzian
countries for the years 19951998, 2000, 2001, and democracy is best measurewe use a logistic link to
20032005,5 with the exception of Legislative Box Score, map from the covariates to the outcome; these results are
which is available for only thirteen of the eighteen coun- presented in Table 1. For the ordinal-dependent variable
tries in the sample.6 As such, models employing this mea- gauging instrumental evaluations of regime perfor-
sure include just 71 surveys and 54,541 individuals. All mancesatisfaction with democracywe use an ordinal
variables are summarized in Table A1 of the Supplemental logistic link; results are presented in Table 2.
Materials.
Results
Methodology As expected, each model is consistent with our claim that
The data are observed at three levels, with individuals instrumental evaluations of regime support initially rise
(Level 1) clustered within surveys (Level 2), which them- as presidential powers and prowess rise, but at a certain
selves are clustered within countries (Level 3). As there point, further increases in presidential strength lower
Singh and Carlin 9

Table 1. Linzian Support for Democracy and Presidential Powers.

Dependent variable: Democracy is best

Model 1: Legislative powers Model 2: Political Model 3: Legislative Box


of president constraints Score

Variable Coefficient p value Coefficient p value Coefficient p value


Survey level
Legislative powers 0.043 <.001
Legislative powers2 0.0004 <.001
Political constraints 3.464 <.001
Political constraints2 3.332 <.001
Box score 0.090 <.001
Box score2 0.001 <.001
Wealth 0.212 <.001 0.011 .704 0.476 .008
Growth 0.001 .645 0.036 <.001 0.005 .781
Duration of democratic regime 0.015 <.001 0.016 <.001 0.011 .001
Individual level
Age 0.007 <.001 0.007 <.001 0.006 <.001
Education 0.305 <.001 0.304 <.001 0.322 <.001
Female 0.092 <.001 0.092 <.001 0.101 <.001
Economic evaluations 0.031 <.001 0.033 <.001 0.014 .071
Political interest 0.191 <.001 0.192 <.001 0.211 <.001
Ideological proximity 0.041 <.001 0.043 <.001 0.067 <.001
Crime victimization 0.053 <.001 0.049 <.001 0.077 <.001
Model statistics
Constant 3.483 1.553 7.283
var(ij) 3.290 3.290 3.290
var(j) 0.129 0.143 0.229
0.038 0.042 0.065
Prob. > 2 <.001 <.001 <.001
Number of individuals 107,330 107,330 54,541
Number of surveys 142 142 71

p values are two-sided. Results are from multilevel logistic regressions.

instrumental regime support. Figure 1 charts the relation- Contrast this with Argentina since 1994, which scores
ships. The y-axes in the left-hand side panels capture the 67.2, about one standard deviation above the observed
predicted probability that a respondent feels democracy is mean (54.1) of the Legislative Powers index. According
the best form of government (support for regime princi- to our model, if Argentina were to strengthen the presi-
ples). The y-axes in the right-hand side panels illustrate dents formal lawmaking power by one standard devia-
the predicted probability that a respondent is either fairly tion, the likelihood of the average respondent viewing
or very satisfied with democracy (support for regime democracy as the best form of government is predicted to
performance).8 decrease by roughly 15 percentage points. In other words,
The upper-left panel of Figure 1 helps visualize the instrumental evaluations of regime principles could be
key result from Model 1. It shows that the likelihood of a expected to fall if the Argentine president were to gain
respondent agreeing that democracy is the best form of additional power.
government builds with formal constitutional presidential The middle-left panel of Figure 1 depicts the parabolic
powers (Legislative Powers) up to a score of about 54 relationship between the presidents partisan powers and
before quickly deteriorating. At the sample minimum for Linzian democratic support estimated in Model 2.
the Legislative Powers index (21.4, Mexico 1917pres- Respondents are more likely to view democracy as the
ent), a standard deviation ( = 24.3) increase in the index best form of government as Political Constraints increase;
is associated with about a 7 percentage point increase in that is, presidents lose partisan power. But the returns to
the likelihood of Linzian support for regime principles. instrumental support for regime principles begin to taper
10 Political Research Quarterly 68(1)

Table 2. Satisfaction with Democracy and Presidential Powers.

Dependent variable: Satisfaction with democracy

Model 4: Legislative Model 5: Political Model 6: Legislative Box


powers of president constraints Score

Variable Coefficients p value Coefficients p value Coefficients p value


Survey level
Legislative powers 0.057 <.001
Legislative powers2 0.001 <.001
Political constraints 3.576 <.001
Political constraints2 3.687 <.001
Box score 0.072 <.001
Box score2 0.001 <.001
Wealth 0.187 <.001 0.093 <.001 0.749 <.001
Growth 0.105 <.001 0.023 <.001 0.022 <.001
Duration of democratic regime 0.019 <.001 0.019 <.001 0.023 <.001
Individual level
Age 0.004 <.001 0.004 <.001 0.005 <.001
Education 0.090 <.001 0.079 <.001 0.027 .312
Female 0.010 .369 0.011 .341 0.009 .564
Economic evaluations 0.211 <.001 0.211 <.001 0.187 <.001
Political interest 0.189 <.001 0.191 <.001 0.202 <.001
Ideological proximity 0.079 <.001 0.076 <.001 0.093 <.001
Crime victimization 0.203 <.001 0.206 <.001 0.185 <.001
Model statistics
1 not satisfied|not very satisfied 3.294 2.181 9.129
2 not very satisfied|fairly satisfied 5.553 4.440 11.387
3 fairly satisfied|very satisfied 7.385 6.272 13.327
var(ij) 3.290 3.290 3.290
var(j) 0.181 0.174 0.189
0.052 0.050 0.054
Prob. > 2 <.001 <.001 <.001
Number of individuals 107,330 107,330 54,541
Number of surveys 142 142 71

p values are two-sided. Results are from multilevel ordered logistic regressions.

beyond their peak score at 0.52Perus score from 2002 2001). This finding mirrors a pattern observed in the pre-
through 2006as partisan support collapses. Based on vious two analyses: positive instrumental evaluations of
these results, then, too much partisan support, and the democratic regime principles are more difficult to gener-
associated lack of political constraint, is actually worse ate at higher levels of presidential power than at lower
for mass support for democracy than too little. levels. A happy medium of power and prowess, however,
When it comes to legislative prowess, as Model 3 and strikes the optimal balance for generating citizen support
the bottom-left panel of Figure 1 show, instrumental sup- for a regime that poses them with two thorny principal
port for democracy as the best form of government is agent problemscontrolling the president and delegating
most likely where the president enjoys moderate levels of legislators to represent their interests.
statutory success and least likely where the president Comparing panels in Figure 1 from left to right shows
implements either very little or very much of his or her the relationships between the presidential powers and
agenda. Ceteris paribus, this likelihood peaks at a passage prowess and instrumental support for regime perfor-
rate of roughly 59 percent. In our sample, Argentina in mance (satisfaction with democracy) are remarkably
2003 comes closest to hitting this mark. But the chances similar to those observed for Linzian instrumental sup-
of a respondent expressing Linzian democratic support port for regime principles. Levels of democratic satisfac-
are much lower at the sample maximum (Mexico in 1995 tion initially increase as formal constitutional powers
and 1996) than at the sample minimum (Argentina in (Legislative Powers, Model 4), partisan powers (Political
Singh and Carlin 11

.8

.4
Pr(Satisfied with Democracy)
Pr(Democracy is Best)

.35
.7

.3
.6

.25
.5

.2
.4

.15
20 40 60 80 100 20 40 60 80 100
Legislative Powers Legislative Powers
.8

.4
Pr(Satisfied with Democracy)
Pr(Democracy is Best)

.35
.7

.3
.6

.25
.5

.2
.4

.15

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Political Constraints Political Constraints
.8

.4
Pr(Satisfied with Democracy)
Pr(Democracy is Best)

.35
.7

.3
.6

.25
.5

.2
.4

.15

20 40 60 80 100 20 40 60 80 100
Legislative Box Score Legislative Box Score

Figure 1. Democratic support and presidential powers.


Left-hand side panels created from results of Models 13 in Table 1. Right-hand side panels created from results of Models 46 in Table 2. Shaded
areas represent 95 percent confidence intervals.
12 Political Research Quarterly 68(1)

Constraints, Models 5), and statutory success (Legislative (Tables A3 and A4). The models indicate no consistent
Box Score, Model 6) increase, but at certain points, fur- conditioning impact of economic performance on the
ther increases are associated with lower levels of satisfac- influence of presidential powers for instrumental support
tion. And the same asymmetry emerges: very strong and either for regime principles or performance.
weak presidents both generate lower levels of instrumen- Next, though we theorize less regime support where
tal regime support than presidents with a happy medium very strong presidents dominate policymaking, citizens
of power, but both Linzian support for democratic prin- may plausibly express more support under vast presi-
ciples and satisfaction with regime performance are lower dential powers if they greatly trust the president. To test
under very strong presidents than they are under very this proposition, we interact the presidential powers
weak ones. indices with trust in the presidency and trust in Congress
Rather than going through each model and graph in (Tables A5 and A6). Again, we find no conditioning
detail again, we flesh out the general pattern with the effect of trust on the relationship between presidential
example of statutory success as measured by Legislative powers and instrumental support for regime principles
Box Score (bottom-right panel of Figure 1). Consider a or performance.
president whose passage rate is just 33 percent, like Finally, we consider the observable implications of
Colombian president Ernesto Samper in 1996. Our theory reverse causality. As discussed above, all eighteen Latin
predicts that where the president implements so little of American countries began their post-authoritarian peri-
his or her agenda, the public will desire a more effectual ods with new or heavily amended constitutions stipulat-
president. As such, instrumental support for regime per- ing, and often revising, formal presidential powers. In
formance will respond positively to increases in the presi- many cases, these rules were considered temporary or
dents legislative success. Indeed, starting at a Legislative expedient and were thus subsequently changed. If reverse
Box Score of 33, a standard deviation ( = 18.2) increase causality is at work, comparatively low levels of regime
in the passage rate is associated with about a 7 percentage support should precede reforms that pushed presidential
point increase in the likelihood that a respondent reports powers toward the extremes (high and low), and com-
being either fairly or very satisfied with democracy. paratively high regime support should precede reforms
Compare this to a president with twice the success rate that moderated powers. Of the three cases we can use to
(66%), such as Honduran president Carlos Roberto Reina test this proposition, only Ecuador in 1998 is partially
in 1996. In this case, we expect citizens will be satisfied consistent with the notion of reverse causality; the other
with the moderate, but not overwhelming, legislative suc- two cases (Uruguay in 1996 and Brazil in 2001) are not.9
cess of the president but will become less satisfied if the Ecuadors Constitution of 1998 heavily bolstered the
president further imposes his agenda. Illustrating this presidents lawmaking powers. It granted presidents
dynamic, at a Legislative Box Score of 66, a standard exclusive initiative in the areas of taxes and public spend-
deviation increase in passage rates is associated with ing and limited Congresss ability to raise total spending
about a 10 percentage point decrease in the likelihood of above the level authorized by the president. It also rein-
a respondent expressing satisfaction with democracy. forced presidents agenda-setting powers by granting
Across Models 1 to 6, likelihood ratio tests indicate them the authority to further modify such bills via amen-
that introducing the squared terms to nested linear models datory observations and to promulgate nonvetoed parts of
significantly improves model fit and a clear pattern them in the case of partial observations.10 These new con-
emerges: citizens give democracy the best marks where stitutional features raised Ecuadorian presidents legisla-
their president is neither impotent nor omnipotent but tive power from middling, by regional standards, to one
instead possesses a moderate amount of authority and is of the regions strongestnearly doubling on the legisla-
thus able to successfully pass legislation with the consent tive powers index from 42.2 to 82.2 (Negretto 2009, 139).
of other political actors. In December 1997seven months before the constitu-
In the Supplemental Materials, we probe potential tions text was adoptedEcuadorians instrumental sup-
extensions of our theoretical framework. We first con- port for democratic principles (preference for democracy)
sider whether economic performance might condition the was more than a standard deviation below the sample
effects of presidential powers on democratic support. mean (see Figure A8) and, thus, in line with the reverse
Citizens may appreciate a powerful president when the causality hypothesis. Instrumental support for regime
economy is robust but turn skeptical if the economy per- performance (satisfaction), however, is quite close to the
forms poorly (cf. Carlin and Singer 2011). If this is the mean, which augurs against reverse causality (see Figure
case, the curvilinear relationships between presidential A9). Taken together, evidence of reverse causality is
powers and satisfaction should change shape as economic clearly mixed in this case.
conditions worsen or improve. We test this by interacting While the bulk of Uruguays 1996 constitutional
each presidential powers index with economic growth reforms were electoral, some raised the presidents
Singh and Carlin 13

already formidable formal powers in two ways.11 First, democracy for fostering these outcomes, the advantages
they shortened how long Congress has before it must take and disadvantages of the varieties of presidentialism for
action on bills the president sends for urgent consider- ensuring regime support have nevertheless received little
ation. Second, they facilitated the presidents formation attention. This study tests whether executive lawmaking
of legislative blocs to prevent vetoes from being overrid- power and prowess affect citizen support for democratic
den. In July of 1996, five months before these reforms, regimes across Latin Americas presidential systems.
support for democratic principles and performance were The basic theoretical proposition advanced here is that
well above the mean level in Latin America (see Figures the relationship between presidential lawmaking power
A8 and A9). Hence, the Uruguayan case presents no evi- and regime support is best represented by an inverted-U-
dence that low levels of regime support spurred reforms shaped parabola. Our findings are consistent with the
to strengthen the presidents lawmaking powers, as the hypothesis that citizens are happiest with, that is, most
reverse causality hypothesis holds. supportive of and satisfied with, democracy where presi-
In Brazil, formal presidential legislative power tapered dents enjoy a happy medium of lawmaking power. They
somewhat (though remained high) when President also suggest that although presidents with vast formal
Fernando Henrique Cardoso and Congress agreed to powers and/or broad majorities in the legislature can
amend constitutional Article 62 governing the use of avoid gridlock and fluidly implement their agendas, they
provisional measures (medidas provisrias) in in the process fuel discontent with democracy and under-
September 2001. While not stripping presidents of their mine its legitimacy. The same is true, but to a lesser
ability to legislate by decree, the amendment doubled extent, if the presidents every attempt to effect legisla-
from thirty to sixty days, the period by which these tion is thwarted. Instead, Latin American citizens express
decrees must be converted into law before lapsing, the greatest regime support where presidents reside in a
allowed presidents to reissue a lapsed decree only once happy medium between ineffectual and almighty
rather than indefinitely, and declared a host of issue areas lawmakers.
off-limits to decrees.12 If this moderation in power was These results reveal a striking embrace of the messy
(reverse) caused by attitudes in the public, it would have politics of separation of powers systems in a region often
been preceded by high levels of regime support. But this assumed to harbor a cultural preference for the swift, top-
was not the case. The percentage of Brazilians that down rule of despots, strongmen, technocrats, and caudi-
believed democracy was the best form of government in llos (Lagos 1997; Lewis 2006; Vliz 1980; Wiarda 2003).
the quarter preceding the amendment was nearly two They also point to an appreciation for the intricacies of
standard deviations below the sample mean (see Figure liberal representative democracy that belies the typically
A8). At the same time, a low-to-middling percentage of simple and, at times, empty and even pejorative ways in
Brazilian respondents were satisfied with how democ- which Latin Americans define democracy (Canache 2012;
racy was functioning (see Figure A9). Carrin 2008; Dalton, Shin, and Jou 2007). In this sense,
In all, any evidence across these three cases that is the present study is optimistic about the prospects for the
consistent with the reverse causality hypothesis is over- attitudinal consolidation of democracy in Latin America.
whelmed by evidence consistent with the null hypothesis It also supports the more general conclusion that minimiz-
of no reverse causality. To more systematically examine ing the risk involved in the principalagent relationships
whether regime support affects presidential powers, we that arise in representative democracy, particularly under
construct time-series cross-sectional models of our three presidentialism, is more critical to mass support for demo-
powers and prowess variables as a function of the average cratic politics than any particular amount of power the
level of support for, and satisfaction with, democracy in executive enjoys vis--vis the legislature. Citizens are
the preceding year. The results reported in Tables A11 to contented with presidential democracy when it grants both
A13 again show no evidence of the reverse causality presidents and legislators the power to respond to and pro-
dynamic in our data. tect their interests in the spirit of compromise.
Our study also warns that machinations by Latin
American presidents to strengthen their lawmaking pow-
Conclusion
ers could undercut democracys fragile but strengthening
A long theoretical tradition stretching from Weber, Dahl, legitimacy in the region. As presidential powers continue
Lipset, Easton, and Linz to more recent empirical work to swellwhether via new constitutional provisions,
posits political systems that legitimize themselves to their shifting political alignments, deliberately stripping power
citizens, both through the outcomes they produce and the from other branches, or other circumstancesany ini-
inputs they use to produce them, have greater long-run tially positive gains in democratic regime support may
stability and quality. While scholars have debated at eventually turn into losses. Considering that both
length the relative merits of competing models of immense presidential powers and low levels of public
14 Political Research Quarterly 68(1)

support can theoretically accelerate the erosion of democ- analysis.


racy, the finding that the two factors are interlinked is par- 4. An alternative measure of policy constraints is Checks
ticularly disconcerting for the long-term stability of from the World Banks Database of Political Institutions
democracy in those parts of the region in which presi- (Beck et al. 2001). Replacing Political Constraints with
Checks in our models returns very similar results (see
dents actively seek to strengthen their hand. At the same
Table A2 in the Supplemental Materials, http://prq.sage-
time, however, it cautions against institutional designs
pub.com/supple-mental/).
that leave the presidency completely bereft of power. 5. Coverage in 1995 was limited to eight countries total and
On a final note, the idea of a happy medium of presi- the Dominican Republic was surveyed starting in 2004.
dential power and prowess did not escape the framers of There were no surveys in 1999. The ideological proximity
the U.S. Constitution. For example, while Alexander control variable is unavailable for Uruguay and Venezuela
Hamilton recognizes the importance of energy in the in 1995 and for Nicaragua in 2003. The Latinobarometers
executive (Federalist Paper No. 70), James Madison under- political interest question, which is used to formulate one
scores the importance of checks and balances for effective of our control variables, was not asked in 2002, 2006, or
government (Federalist Paper No. 51). As Madison 2008. The retrospective economic evaluations question
famously wrote in No. 51, Ambition must be made to was not asked in 2007. The Checks measure (see Note 4) is
not available for Peru in 1995.
counteract ambition. As contemporary political commen-
6. Saiegh calculated Legislative Box Scores for the follow-
tators continue to debate whether presidentialism in the
ing countryyears: Argentina, 19952003; Bolivia, 1996
United States embodies Madisons recommendation, con- 2000; Brazil, 19952006; Chile, 19952005; Colombia,
stitutional framers in todays more tumultuous nascent 19961998; Costa Rica, 19962003; Ecuador, 19962001;
presidential and semi-presidential democracies, such as Honduras, 1996; Mexico, 19952002; Panama, 19962001;
Egypt, Pakistan, and Russia, may consider the benefits of Paraguay, 19952002; Peru, 19952002; and Uruguay,
moderately powerful presidents for mass regime support. 19952002. Not included were El Salvador, Dominican
Republic, Guatemala, Nicaragua, and Venezuela.
Acknowledgment 7. In plainer terms, there is something about being in Chile in
2004, for example, that affects democratic support differ-
The authors would like to thank Gabriel L. Negretto, Sebastian
ently than being in Chile in 2001 or Bolivia in 1998 (or any
M. Saiegh, Matthew M. Singer, and Heather Stoll for helpful
other countryyear pairing). These effects are captured in
comments.
the random intercepts of the multilevel models. Likelihood
ratio tests indicate that the variance in these random inter-
Authors Note cepts is significantly different from zero across the models,
Replication data for this article can be viewed at www.shaneps- further justifying our multilevel approach.
ingh.com. 8. All predicted values are calculated with the covariates held
at their means.
Declaration of Conflicting Interests 9. Venezuelas 1999 constitutional change also falls within
our samples domain. But because the closest data point
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with is twelve months prior (December 1998) to the December
respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this 1999 adoption of the language and constitution, we exclude
article. it from the analysis. Incidentally, middling levels of both
measures of regime support militate against the reverse
Funding causality hypothesis.
The author(s) received no financial support for the research, 10. For a fuller treatment, see Negretto (2013, chap. 7).
authorship, and/or publication of this article. 11. See Forteza et al. (2003) for fuller treatment.
12. For discussion, see Pereira, Power, and Renn (2005, 184).
Notes The text of the amendment is available at http://www.plan-
alto.gov.br/ccivil_03/Constituicao/Emendas/Emc/emc32.
1. Presidents nonlegislative powers vary far less across the
htm.
region and, taken alone, we find no significant associations
between them and regime support.
2. While the AmericasBarometer also surveys residents References
of Latin America, practical reasons limit its usefulness. Achen, Christopher H., and Larry M. Bartels. 2004. Blind
Namely, data on our primary country-level independent Retrospection: Electoral Response to Drought, Flu, and
variables exist through 2009, but the AmericasBarometer Shark Attacks. Working Paper 199. Center for Advanced
only encompasses the eighteen Latin American countries Study in the Social Sciences, Juan March Institute, Madrid,
from 2008. Thus, using AmericasBarometer would restrict Spain.
the scope of our analyses considerably. Alcaiz, Isabella, and Timothy Hellwig. 2011. Whos to
3. As our measures of interest are dichotomous and ordinal, Blame? The Distribution of Responsibility in Developing
we calculated tetrachoric and polychoric correlations in Democracies. British Journal of Political Science 41:
the correlation matrix input into the principal component 389411.
Singh and Carlin 15

Alemn, Eduardo, and Ernesto Calvo. 2010. Unified Morgenstern and B. Nacif, 44668. Cambridge, UK:
Government, Bill Approval, and the Legislative Weight Cambridge University Press.
of the President. Comparative Political Studies 43: Cramer, Brian D., and Robert R. Kaufman. 2011. Views of
51134. Economic Inequality in Latin America. Comparative
Alemn, Eduardo, and Patricio Navia. 2009. Institutions and Political Studies 44:120637.
the Legislative Success of Strong Presidents: An Analysis Dahl, R. Alan. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition.
of Government Bills in Chile. Journal of Legislative New Haven: Yale University Press.
Studies 15:40119. Dalton, Russell J. 1999. Political Support in Advanced
Almond, Gabriel Abraham, and Sidney Verba. 1963. The Industrial Democracies. In Critical Citizens: Global
Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Support for Democratic Government, edited by P. Norris,
Nations. Newbury Park: SAGE. 5777. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Altman, David, and Anbal Prez-Lin. 2002. Assessing Dalton, Russell J. 2004. Democratic Challenges, Democratic
the Quality of Democracy: Freedom, Competitiveness Choices: The Erosion of Political Support in Advanced
and Participation in Eighteen Latin American Countries. Industrial Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University
Democratization 9:85100. Press.
Anderson, Christopher J. 2001. Good Questions, Dubious Dalton, Russell J., and Christopher J. Anderson. 2011.
Inferences, and Bad Solutions: Some Further Thoughts Citizens, Context, and Choice. In Citizens, Context, and
on Satisfaction with Democracy. Working Paper No. Choice: How Context Shapes Citizens Electoral Choices,
116. Center on Democratic Performance, Department of edited by R. J. Dalton and C. J. Anderson, 332. Oxford:
Political Science, Binghampton University. Oxford University Press.
Anderson, Christopher J., Andr Blais, Shaun Bowler, Todd Dalton, Russell J., Doh C. Shin, and Willy Jou. 2007.
Donovan, and Ola Listhaug. 2005. Losers Consent: Understanding Democracy: Data from Unlikely Places.
Elections and Democratic Legitimacy. New York: Oxford Journal of Democracy 18:14256.
University Press. Diamond, L. Jay. 1999. Developing Democracy: Toward
Anderson, Christopher J., and Christine A. Guillory. 1997. Consolidation. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Political Institutions and Satisfaction with Democracy: Easton, David. 1975. A Re-assessment of the Concept of
A Cross-National Analysis of Consensus and Majoritarian Political Support. British Journal of Political Science
Systems. American Political Science Review 91:6681. 5:43557.
Beck, Thorsten, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer, Fernandez, Kenneth E., and Michelle Kuenzi. 2010. Crime
and Patrick Walsh. 2001. New Tools in Comparative and Support for Democracy in Africa and Latin America.
Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions. Political Studies 58:45071.
World Bank Economic Review 15:16576. Forteza, Alvaro, Daniel Buquet, Mario Ibarburu, Jorge Lanzaro,
Booth, John A., and Mitchell A. Seligson. 2009. The Andrs Pereyra, Eduardo Siandra, and Marcel Vaillant.
Legitimacy Puzzle in Latin America: Public Support and 2003. Understanding Reform: The Uruguayan Case.
Democracy in Eight Nations. New York: Cambridge http://ideas.repec.org/p/ude/wpaper/0603.html.
University Press. Heck, Ronald H., and Scott L. Thomas. 2000. An Introduction
Canache, Damarys. 2012. Citizens Conceptualizations of to Multilevel Modelling Techniques. Mahwah: Lawrence
Democracy: Structural Complexity, Substantive Content, Erlbaum.
and Political Significance. Comparative Political Studies Henisz, Witold J. 2000. The Institutional Environment for
45:113258. Economic Growth. Economics & Politics 12:131.
Canache, Damarys, Jeffery J. Mondak, and Mitchell A. Hox, Joop J. 2002. Multilevel Analysis: Techniques and
Seligson. 2001. Meaning and Measurement in Cross- Applications. Mahwah: Lawrence Erlbaum.
National Research on Satisfaction with Democracy. Jillson, Calvin C., and Cecil L. Eubanks. 1984. The Political
Public Opinion Quarterly 65:50628. Structure of Constitution Making: The Federal Convention
Carlin, Ryan E., and Matthew M. Singer. 2011. Support for of 1787. American Journal of Political Science 28:
Polyarchy in the Americas. Comparative Political Studies 43558.
44:150026. Lagos, Marta. 1997. Latin Americas Smiling Mask. Journal
Carrin, Julio. 2008. The Persistent Attraction of Populism of Democracy 8:12538.
in the Andes. In Latin American Democracy: Emergent Lagos, Marta. 2003. World Opinion: Support for and
Reality or Endangered Species? edited by R. Millet, J. Satisfaction with Democracy. International Journal of
Holmes, and O. Prez, 233-51. New York: Routledge. Public Opinion Research 15:47187.
Cox, Gary W., and Mathew D. McCubbins. 2001. The Lewis, Paul H. 2006. Authoritarian Regimes in Latin America:
Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy Outcomes. Dictators, Despots, and Tyrants. Lanham: Rowman &
In Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy, edited by S. Littlefield.
Haggard and M. D. McCubbins, 2163. Cambridge, UK: Lijphart, Arend. 2012. Patterns of Democracy: Government
Cambridge University Press. Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. 2nd ed.
Cox, Gary W., and Scott Morgenstern. 2002. Epilogue: Latin New Haven: Yale University Press.
Americas Reactive Assemblies and Proactive Presidents. Linde, Jonas, and Joakim Ekman. 2003. Satisfaction with
In Legislative Politics in Latin America, edited by S. Democracy: A Note on a Frequently Used Indicator in
16 Political Research Quarterly 68(1)

Comparative Politics. European Journal of Political Powell, G. Bingham. 2000. Elections as Instruments of
Research 42:391408. Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions. New
Linz, Juan J. 1990. Perils of Presidentialism. Journal of Haven: Yale University Press.
Democracy 1:5169. Powell, G. Bingham, and Guy D. Whitten. 1993. A Cross-
Linz, Juan J. 1994. Presidential or Parliamentary Democracy: National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account
Does It Make a Difference? In The Failure of Presidential of the Political Context. American Journal of Political
Democracy: Comparative Perspectives, edited by J. J. Science 37:391414.
Linz and A. Valenzuela, 390. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Pratto, Felicia, Jim Sidanius, and Shana Levin. 2006. Social
University Press. Dominance Theory and the Dynamics of Intergroup
Linz, Juan J., and Alfred C. Stepan. 1996. Problems of Relations: Taking Stock and Looking Forward. European
Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern Review of Social Psychology 17:271320.
Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe. Przeworski, Adam. 2010. Democracy and the Limits of Self-
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Government. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Machado, Fabiana, Carlos Scartascini, and Mariano Tommasi. Saiegh, Sebastian M. 2009. Political Prowess or Lady Luck?
2011. Political Institutions and Street Protests in Latin Evaluating Chief Executives Legislative Success Rates.
America. Journal of Conflict Resolution 55:34065. Journal of Politics 71:134256.
Mainwaring, Scott. 1993. Presidentialism, Multipartism, and Saiegh, Sebastian M. 2011. Ruling by Statute: How Uncertainty
Democracy: The Difficult Combination. Comparative and Vote-Buying Shape Lawmaking. New York: Cambridge
Political Studies 26:198228. University Press.
Mainwaring, Scott, and Matthew S. Shugart, eds. 1997. Samuels, David. 2004. Presidentialism and Accountability
Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin America. New for the Economy in Comparative Perspective. American
York: Cambridge University Press. Political Science Review 98:42536.
Mansbridge, Jane J. 2003. Rethinking Representation. Sarsfield, Rodolfo, and Fabin Echegaray. 2006. Opening
American Political Science Review 97:51528. the Black Box: How Satisfaction with Democracy and
McGuire, Robert A. 1988. Constitution Making: A Rational Its Perceived Efficacy Affect Regime Preference in
Choice Model of the Federal Convention of 1787. Latin America. International Journal of Public Opinion
American Journal of Political Science 32:483522. Research 18:15373.
Melo, Marcus A. 2009. Strong Presidents, Robust Democracies? Shugart, Matthew S., and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents
Separation of Powers and Rule of Law in Latin America. and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral
Brazilian Political Science Review 3:3059. Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Miller, Arthur H. 1974. Political Issues and Trust in Shugart, Matthew S., and Scott Mainwaring. 1997. Presidentialism
Government: 1964-1970. American Political Science and Democracy in Latin America: Rethinking the Terms
Review 68:95172. of the Debate. In Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin
Negretto, Gabriel. 2004. Government Capacities and Policy America, edited by S. Mainwaring and M. S. Shugart, 12-54.
Making by Decree in Latin America: The Cases of Brazil New York: Cambridge University Press.
and Argentina. Comparative Political Studies 37: Singh, Shane P. 2014. Not All Election Winners Are Equal:
53162. Satisfaction with Democracy and the Nature of the Vote.
Negretto, Gabriel. 2009. Political Parties and Institutional European Journal of Political Research 53:30827.
Design: Explaining Constitutional Choice in Latin Stegmueller, Daniel. 2013. How Many Countries for
America. British Journal of Political Science 39:11739. Multilevel Modeling? A Comparison of Frequentist and
Negretto, Gabriel. 2013. Making Constitutions. Presidents, Bayesian Approaches. American Journal of Political
Parties and Institutional Design in Latin America. New Science 57:74861.
York: Cambridge University Press. Stepan, Alfred, and Cindy Skach. 1993. Constitutional
Norris, Pippa. 1999. Critical Citizens: Global Support for Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation: Parliamentari-
Democratic Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press. anism versus Presidentialism. World Politics 46:122.
Pereira, Carlos, and Marcus Andr Melo. 2012. The Torcal, Mariano, and Paolo Moncagatta. 2011. Political
Unexpected Success of Multiparty Presidential Regimes. Support. In International Encyclopedia of Political
Journal of Democracy 23:15670. Science, edited by B. Badie, D. Berg-Schlosser, and L.
Pereira, Carlos, Timothy J. Power, and Lucio Renn. 2005. Morlino, 2563-66. London: SAGE.
Under What Conditions Do Presidents Resort to Decree Torcal, Mariano, and Jos R. Montero. 2006. Political
Power? Theory and Evidence from the Brazilian Case. Disaffection in Comparative Perspective. In Political
Journal of Politics 67:178200. Disaffection in Contemporary Democracies: Social
Pereira, Carlos, Shane P. Singh, and Bernardo Mueller. 2011. Capital, Institutions, and Politics, edited by M. Torcal and
Political Institutions, Policymaking, and Policy Stability R. Montero, 2-19. New York: Routledge.
in Latin America. Latin American Politics and Society Tsebelis, George. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions
53:5989. Work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Prez-Lin, Anbal. 2007. Presidential Impeachment and the Vairo, Daniela. 2012. El Consenso De Los Perdedores Y La
New Political Instability in Latin America. Cambridge, Legitimidad De La Democracia En Amrica Del Sur.
UK: Cambridge University Press. Poltica y Gobierno 19:4169.
Singh and Carlin 17

Vliz, Claudio. 1980. The Centralist Tradition in Latin America. Wiarda, Howard J. 2003. The Soul of Latin America: The
Princeton: Princeton University Press. Cultural and Political Tradition. New Haven: Yale
Wells, Jason M., and Jonathan Krieckhaus. 2006. Does National University Press.
Context Influence Democratic Satisfaction? A Multi-level Young, Joseph K., and Laura Dugan. 2011. Veto Players and
Analysis. Political Research Quarterly 59:56978. Terror. Journal of Peace Research 48:1933.

S-ar putea să vă placă și