Sunteți pe pagina 1din 11

World Development Vol. 38, No. 1, pp.

37–47, 2010
Ó 2009 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.06.001

Homogenization and Specialization Effects of International Trade:


Are Cultural Goods Exceptional?
JESSE CHU-SHORE *
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA, USA
Summary. — In contrast to the logic that international trade leads to greater specialization and differentiation of products, cultural
industries are often still protected from imports, in part, because of the worry that trade will lead instead to homogenization. Is this true
for cultural goods and if so, is this different from other goods? I consider the effects of homogenization on industrial development, pro-
pose a network-based method of identifying homogenization in global trade patterns, and test a range of industries. I find evidence of
homogenization in many industries, calling into question a major justification for free trade.
Ó 2009 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — global, world, international trade, cultural industries, homogenization, specialization

1. INTRODUCTION individual psychic and social life could be unduly shaped by


imports, resulting in a loss of local culture. From an economic
Free trade, by providing greater markets and greater compe- perspective, influence from imported goods could threaten the
tition, is supposed to engender specialization in those indus- unique endowment that a distinct local culture provides to lo-
tries or products in which a country has a particular cal cultural industries that could be developed and exported
endowment or competitive advantage. Free trade is thus for economic gain. The UNESCO convention also appeals
thought to lead to a greater variety and higher quality of to the sense that loss of cultural diversity would be a serious
goods available to consumers across the globe. Despite this, concern at the global scale, as well as for individual countries.
there is much debate as to whether cultural goods, such as This argument—that trade leads to homogenization in cul-
movies, books, and music, ought to be given special exemption tural industries—appears to contradict the most basic logic
from international trade agreements, in part because of the of international trade in other industries, that trade engenders
fear of homogenization. specialization. Specialization should support the production of
Since the Uruguay Round of trade talks that led to the cre- local cultural goods – products in which a given country has a
ation of the World Trade Organization (WTO), for example, comparative advantage – at least as a first approximation
‘‘audiovisual” products and services that ‘‘typically reflect based on the standard logic of trade.
the social and cultural characteristics of nations and their peo- My aims in this paper are twofold. First, I wish to evaluate
ples” (WTO Council for Trade in Services, 1998) have been this notion of the homogenizing effects of trade in the cultural
substantially omitted (even if not officially exempted) from industries. Cultural industries are not only socially important,
the standard free trade-oriented commitments made by but represent real economic development opportunity, and it
WTO member countries. The United Nations Educational, is essential to get trade and industrial policy right. In 1998,
Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) has adopted for example, global sales in recorded music were worth $38.6
a Convention on the Protection and Promotion of the Diver- billion, and world trade in cultural products in general was
sity of Cultural Expressions that enshrines in an official docu- estimated at $388 billion, an impressive sum, even taking def-
ment the rights of governments to protect domestic culture, initional and measurement difficulties into account (UNE-
cultural expressions, and significantly, cultural goods indus- SCO, 2006). International trade in cultural goods is
tries. Although this convention has no mechanism for enforce- important to developed countries that have thriving domestic
ment, it lends legitimacy to the protection of culture from the industries, but it is likely to be even more important to devel-
influence of foreign trade. Individual countries therefore have oping countries, for which cultural industries represent a po-
considerably more de facto leeway to practice direct protection tential leading export sector (e.g., Bourne & Allgrove, 1996;
or provide subsidies to cultural industries than they do with Kozul-Wright & Stanbury, 1998; Pratt, 2004; Scott, 2004).
other goods. Many developing countries that have weak manufacturing sec-
This special treatment, known as the ‘‘cultural exception” is tors and little prospect of becoming competitive in other rap-
a contentious issue. Countries that are already significant idly growing industrial sectors such as high tech goods
exporters of cultural goods, such as the United States, have ar-
gued that special treatment is unwarranted. Supporting special
treatment are countries such as France and Canada, which * Sincere thanks are due to Alice H. Amsden, Michael J. Piore, Frank Levy,
have expressed concern over the likely loss of their domestic Pol Antras, and Christopher Wheat for many helpful comments on earlier
cultures and cultural products due to the influence of imported drafts of this paper. Many thanks also to Tom Snijders for his help with
goods. implementation of the statistical method. Special thanks to four
An important theme in this debate is this concern that inter- anonymous reviewers for substantial insights and suggestions which greatly
national trade would lead to homogenization of local cultures. improved the paper. All errors and inaccuracies are my own. This research
For individual countries, the meanings, expressions, and val- was completed while the author was on a National Science Foundation
ues that are conveyed through cultural goods and that shape Graduate Research Fellowship. Final revision accepted: June 8, 2009.
37
38 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

nonetheless have thriving musical and literary cultures, with tion. Fu (2006) shows that in the feature film industry, the
abundant human capital and productive ‘‘technology.” It United States and the United Kingdom have been increasing
would therefore be a lost opportunity of immense proportions their shares of international trade in movies, while other coun-
to suppress rather than support nascent cultural industries in tries have been steadily declining. Inquiries into such global
developing countries because of wrong-headed trade policy. market dominance could be classified into three broad catego-
My second aim is to evaluate this notion that the cultural ries: imperialistic, purely economic, and diffusion based.
industries are exceptional. If trade has a homogenizing effect Explanations based on media imperialism (e.g., Mattelart &
on cultural goods, it may have a homogenizing effect on other Polan, 1978; Schiller, 1976) emphasize the active role that eco-
goods as well. Specialization implies that everyone gains from nomic actors in developed countries play in creating and main-
trade. A finding of homogenization would not have such an taining international trade arrangements that benefit
implication and raises some serious concerns about the effects themselves at the expense of those in developing countries.
of trade on the development of industry in developing coun- American firms have lobbied for media infrastructure and reg-
tries. If trade has a homogenizing effect on domestic cultural ulation in trade partner countries that benefits or is compatible
industries, there are strong arguments to be made for support with the type of output that they produce, for example (Lee,
or protection of domestic producers and products. The welfare 1980). In these accounts, homogenization is a negative and
of the world’s poorest has been entrusted to this notion of spe- intrinsic consequence of international hegemony.
cialization; if there is another side of the effects of trade, it Purely economic explanations (e.g., Dupagne & Waterman,
must be understood so that it can be brought into policy deci- 1998; Lee & Waterman, 2007; Wildman & Siwek, 1988) are
sions to the benefit of all. based on the size of an exporter’s home market. A large home
Although the approach of this paper involves an analysis of market is an advantage for exporters of cultural goods in part
the pattern of trade, it is less a trade study than an inquiry into because of economies of scale in distribution of these goods
the premises upon which arguments about development are and services. For example, in the production of feature films,
built. I am not seeking to understand the determinants of most of the cost of production occurs up front in the process
who exports which products or how much is exported, but of creating the original cut of the film: actor’s and crew mem-
rather an aspect of the complementary issue of the effects of ber’s wages, equipment, location rentals, editing, scoring, mas-
trade on domestic industries. Finally, although the questions tering, and so on. Once the original has been produced, unit
addressed in this paper are inspired by aspects of the ‘‘cultural reproduction costs (i.e., the cost of creating a playable copy
exception,” this paper is not directly concerned with the full from that original) are very low. The more sunk costs of pro-
scope of that debate. Rather, I take it as a starting point for duction can be spread over many units, the cheaper each unit
an investigation into the possible homogenizing effects of trade can be sold or leased for. Furthermore, the larger the home
on industrial development more generally. market, the more specific steps in the production process can
The plan of the rest of the paper is as follows. In Section 2 I be carried out by specialized external contractors, increasing
review literature on and related to the idea of a homogenizing the overall efficiency of the production process. Therefore,
effect of trade, and how it might affect the development of the prices of cultural goods originating in large home markets
domestic industries. In Section 3, I propose a method of distin- are likely to be lower than the prices of goods from smaller
guishing between homogenization and specialization effects by markets. This implies an international division of labor in
looking at the overall pattern of world trade in individual which, ceteris paribus, the countries with the largest home mar-
goods as networks and comparing their characteristic topolo- kets (roughly the large, rich countries) specialize in the pro-
gies. I argue that certain topological characteristics in cross duction and export of cultural goods.
section are likely to have resulted from a process of homoge- The role of cultural homogenization is more central in diffu-
nization, while others are likely to have resulted from a pro- sion-based accounts of trade in cultural goods. In this tradi-
cess of specialization. I evaluate two cultural goods and two tion, the influence of imported goods on local culture is
uniform commodities and compare the results, finding that assumed, but the authors emphasize the agency and indepen-
the two cultural goods show strong evidence of homogeniza- dence of consumers in importing countries. People select,
tion effects from trade, while the two uniform commodities adapt, and give new contexts and meanings to the cultural
show strong evidence of specialization. I go on to test a range goods they import. The foreign culture does not necessarily
of manufactures that are neither uniform commodities nor overwhelm or displace the local culture as in the imperialistic
goods that are exempted from trade agreements on ‘‘cultural” or home-market based accounts, but rather enriches and in-
grounds. The results from analyzing trade patterns for these forms it, as homogenization co-exists with a process of differ-
goods describe a spectrum between the extremes represented entiation. These authors (e.g., Falkenheim, 2000; Pool, 1977),
by the two cultural goods and the two undifferentiated com- see the emergence of non-US subcenters of television produc-
modities, with most showing significant evidence of trade lead- tion and export (Telenovelas from Mexico, for example) as
ing to homogenization. Section 4 examines alternative evidence supporting this perspective.
explanations for the patterns of trade found in Section 3. Fi-
nally, Section 5 discusses the implications for policy and fur- (b) Homogenization and innovation
ther research.
Moving beyond accounts of trade in cultural goods, the lit-
erature on innovation more generally is consistent with a pro-
2. DOES TRADE LEAD TO HOMOGENIZATION? cess of homogenization due to trade. Most product
innovations occur as incremental changes to an existing set
(a) Homogenization in the cultural industries of knowledge. This is to say that innovations in new products
depend on older products, or that technological change (or
It has been observed that in cultural industries, such as tele- change in the characteristics of goods) is path dependent
vision (Lee, 1980) and feature films (Fu, 2006), exports dispro- (e.g., Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). If imports serve as reference
portionately originate in a few countries. And in the film points for innovation, it would imply a convergence of domes-
industry at least, there is a trend toward increasing concentra- tic and global technological trajectories.
HOMOGENIZATION AND SPECIALIZATION EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 39

Likewise for consumers, it could be said that taste for cur- to the export led-growth of the East Asian Economies (e.g.,
rent products is shaped in large part by what products each Amsden, 1979; Amsden, 2001). Among the major themes of
consumer has been exposed to in the past. The diffusion of this literature is that technological knowledge is not easily
innovations literature shows that the more similar new prod- gained, even if consumers can adapt and come to like new
ucts are to what is already known, the more rapidly and exten- products easily. If trade changes what is demanded by con-
sively they are adopted in the aggregate (Di Benedetto, sumers faster than domestic industry can accumulate new pro-
Calantone, & Zhang, 2003; Haveman, 1993; Rogers, 1995, ductive knowledge, then trade in new products puts foreign
and references therein). Consumers who have common expe- producers (who already produce these products) ahead of
riences in consumption of a given type of industrial product the producers in the importing country. Therefore, developing
therefore have a common set of reference points to which fu- countries would be wise to implement policies to protect un-
ture products can be related. Each individual’s positive or neg- ique goods or capabilities in the context of foreign trade.
ative impression of any given reference point is of course a There is also the possibility that homogenization could pre-
personal matter and not necessarily illuminating for analysis vent countries from developing their own, unique products
at the social level. The sharing of common reference points which they could go on to export for economic gain, without
within an aggregate population of consumers is enough to sug- having to play industrial catch-up. Differences between the
gest that new products related to those reference points have products of one nation and those of another could occur by
an increased probability of diffusing widely through that pop- specializing in relation to shared reference points, or it could
ulation, that is, that there is a large potential market for such occur due to a difference in reference points in the first place.
related goods. Homogenization implies that the latter type of differentiation
Trade between two countries in a given industry generates would not occur, and thus would prevent one way in which
common experience in relation to which new products are cre- a country could develop a novel endowment in a given indus-
ated and consumed. This is my interpretation of the finding of try.
the homogenizing effect of trade. Homogenization does not Admittedly for many industries, another word for homoge-
mean that exactly the same products are produced in multiple nization could be ‘‘standardization.” One could also think of
places, but rather that the product reference points that shape homogenization as an analog to standardization in the domain
future rounds of production converge over time for countries of tacit, rather than explicit knowledge. The impact of a for-
engaged in trade with each other. Homogenization also im- eign standard on domestic development is complex. On the
plies that not only does the extent of the market affect the pos- one hand, the arrival of a foreign standard requires the domes-
sibilities for trade, but trade itself affects the extent of the tic industry to catch up with the technological capabilities of
market. the country which exports the goods to which the standard ap-
Specialization, on the other hand, could only meaningfully plies. Investments in technologies which do not conform to the
be said to occur among countries that already share product new standard may be rendered valueless in the transition
reference points to some degree, in other words, among mar- (Farrell & Saloner, 1986; Katz & Shapiro, 1992). However,
kets with consistent definitions of what is demanded. Special- the flip side of the necessity to catch up and keep pace with
ization implies that given a set of reference points, the foreign standards is the increased opportunity for technological
products of one country relate to those reference points in a learning from abroad. Standards can allow for easier interna-
particular way that is of value to domestic and foreign con- tional technological transfer and partnerships. The impact of
sumers and is different from products exported by other coun- foreign standards on developing countries depends therefore
tries. Specialization is sustainable when the specializing on the competitive assets of domestic firms relative to the glo-
country has some particular advantage in producing that vari- bal market (Ratanawaraha, 2006). While explicit standards
ety of product. can be negotiated with foreign actors by firms and govern-
ments to maximize developmental benefits (learning) and min-
(c) Is homogenization good or bad? imize costs (loss of non-conforming sunk investments), tacit
homogenization of technology and products is more difficult.
In effect, the idea of free trade assumes a homogenous world The implication is that for countries with significant techno-
in which the potential export market for any given good is the logical assets, for example, in cultural or other consumer
set of countries with consumers able to afford that good. In goods, homogenization could put domestic industries into an
this assumption, there is no theoretical place for a process of inferior position relative to global competitors.
homogenization. However, the results of this study provide At the global scale, standardization could have a beneficial
evidence of such a process, which must therefore be accounted effect on economic growth if it allows innovations in different
for in industrial policy. For industries such as books and mu- countries to be complementary to each other, rather than
sic recordings, there are obvious arguments to be made about redundant or mutually irrelevant. However, standardization
why countries may wish to protect local industries by limiting taken to the extreme could theoretically lead to technological,
the imports of foreign products. However, even for industries organizational, or institutional ‘‘lock-in,” in which innovation
which are not obviously ‘‘cultural” there are nonetheless rea- is limited by overinvestment in existing standards and/or
sons to think that homogenization may not necessarily be homogeneity of perspectives and experience on the part of
good. innovators and firms (Olson, 1982). Limiting innovation
There have been many challenges to the idea that free trade would almost certainly limit possibilities for future economic
is universally beneficial. The traditions of dependency and growth. This is to say that whether or not standardization
world systems theory argue that trade forces industries in or homogenization is good for any particular country or set
developing countries to assume peripheral and dependent roles of countries, it could be a negative for all countries if it pro-
relative to the markets of developed countries. (Amin, 1974; gresses too far at the global scale.
Wallerstein, 1975). This peripheral role strictly limits the de- A process of homogenization implies a tension between po-
gree to which such countries can capture the gains from trade. sitive and negative economic consequences: homogenization
An alternative view, suggests that the integration of domestic could prevent a country from developing unique technology
industries with the demands of foreign markets was essential or products, and yet could open up potential export markets
40 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

by aligning domestic products with what is demanded in for- by countries forming a number of transitive triads. It is there-
eign markets. As these consequences rely on technological fore necessary to control for exogenous sources of similarity
change over time, they would invite dynamic, rather than sta- before making inferences about the effects of trade itself.
tic policy responses. In existing accounts of trade, however, Taken alone, of course, a finding of a significant transitivity
homogenization is either assumed or assumed away. The sta- effect in trade patterns cannot be attributed to similarity in
tus of this assumption dictates to a large extent the type of pol- technology and/or taste, however plausible that seems. A more
icy conclusions that can be drawn from the research. To my credible test would involve a comparison between industries in
knowledge, the literature lacks a broad-based empirical test which we a priori believe trade to be shaped by similarities and
of this critical assumption. differences in technology and taste, that is, cultural industries,
against industries in which we firmly believe technology and
taste are irrelevant to trade, such as uniform commodities. If
3. METHODS, DATA, AND TESTS trade patterns for cultural goods exhibit a significant tendency
to transitivity after controlling for exogenous factors, whereas
(a) Testing for homogenization and specialization effects uniform commodities do not show this tendency, we can pro-
visionally see evidence of similarity in technology and/or taste
(i) Testing for homogenization effects as the factor which leads to this outcome.
To test the hypothesis that trade has a homogenizing effect, I will therefore examine patterns of trade for two cultural
it must first be made operational. To that end, I begin by ask- goods, books and sound recordings, and two uniform com-
ing what we would expect to observe if trade had a homoge- modities, anthracite and unmilled corn. The testable versions
nizing effect. If imports influence domestic technology and/ of the first hypothesis are therefore:
or taste, then the result would be that countries that traded H1a: World trade patterns in books and sound recordings
with each other would become more similar in these dimen- exhibit a transitivity effect.
sions for the good being traded. H1b: World trade patterns in anthracite and unmilled corn
I assume for now that for a trade tie to exist, what is pro- exhibit a transitivity effect.
duced and exported by the exporting country (roughly, the I expect to find support for H1a, and not for H1b.
technology) must be somehow compatible with what is ex-
pected or demanded by the importing country (the taste). It (ii) Testing for specialization effects
cannot be inferred from the pattern of trade ties what is being Unlike cultural goods, which could be described heuristi-
produced, of course, so the meaning of ‘‘similar” here is only cally as highly varied and constantly changing, ordinary goods
that there is some correspondence between product and mar- are well-defined commodities, in which any country might
ket across the countries in question. Two countries engaged trade under standard market assumptions. I therefore expect
in bilateral trade are in this broad sense ‘‘similar,” but could to see exports of ordinary goods originating in a relatively
be producing very different goods that are nonetheless com- small number of countries that specialize in production of
patible with each other’s markets. A lack of a trade tie does each good because of some sort of advantage or endowment.
not necessarily imply dissimilarity, however, unless other bar- In terms of trade network structure, this would be described
riers to trade such as geographic distance are accounted for. by the variable representing ‘‘out-stars” such as the right-hand
Looking beyond bilateral trade to larger patterns suggests a side of Figure 1. The estimated parameter for the out-star var-
method of testing for homogenizing effects of trade. Let i, j, iable captures the degree to which the origins of export flows
and k represent three arbitrary countries selected from the are concentrated in relatively few countries. An insignificant
set of countries that engages in international trade in a given out-star parameter would indicate that there is no such ten-
good. If i exports to j, then i and j must be somewhat similar. dency beyond that explained by other variables.
If j also exports to k, then j and k must be similar. If i is similar H1c: World trade patterns in books and sound recordings
to j, which is similar in turn to k, then i ought to be similar to exhibit an ‘‘out-star” effect.
k. I therefore expect to observe a greater than random preva- H1d: World trade patterns in anthracite and unmilled corn
lence of links (i, k), given the existence of links (i, j) and (j, k). exhibit an ‘‘out-star” effect.
In other words, I expect to observe transitive triads such as the I expect to find support for H1d, and not for H1c.
left side of Figure 1.
Similarities in other dimensions than technology and taste (iii) Testing for homogenization in other goods
could also lead to a finding of transitive triads in trade pat- There were a priori reasons to believe that trade flows of
terns. In the presence of transportation costs, geographically obviously cultural goods, such as music, would exhibit transi-
similar (i.e., proximate) countries are more likely to trade with tivity. But which other goods would this kind of logic apply
each other and less likely to trade with distant countries. At to? So far I have described cultural goods as having technol-
the network level, this could result in trade flows among near- ogy and taste characteristics which vary across countries and
which cannot be evaluated with objective quality measures.
Contrasting with this is the purely utilitarian, readily measur-
able quality characteristics and global market viability of or-
dinary goods such as, say, coal. But between these extremes
there must be goods with a mix of cultural and utilitarian
qualities. Allen Scott, a veteran analyst of cultural industries,
describes an ‘‘unbroken continuum of sectors” from the cul-
tural to the utilitarian (Scott, 2004). I therefore expect to reject
the hypothesis implicit in free trade agreements:
H1e: Other goods do not exhibit transitivity effects.
I test hypothesis H1e in the analyses of the networks defined
by international trade flows in furniture, sound recordings,
Figure 1. Structures hypothesized to occur at a greater than random rate in
sewing machines, cutlery, passenger vehicles, shoes (leather,
trade in cultural goods (left) and ordinary goods (right).
HOMOGENIZATION AND SPECIALIZATION EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 41

rubber, or plastic sole), wine, color TVs, butter, unmilled corn, The papers by Anderson, Wasserman, and Crouch (1999)
gas generators, and parts thereof, anthracite, cargo ships and Robins, Pattison, Kalish, and Lusher (2007) are good
(excluding tankers), and iron and steel bars and ingots. introductions to this analytic method, and the following over-
Examining differentiated goods raises the issue of intra- view is largely a summary of the salient points from these two
industry trade, which is described by the ‘‘new” trade theory sources that are important for the present context. The basic
(Krugman, 1980). Both old and new trade theories should pre- premise of the approach is that the observed network (of trade
dict a finding of out-stars characterizing network structure. In ties, in this case) is one realization of a stochastic process,
old trade theory, countries specialize in producing and export- which is to be modeled. The same stochastic process could
ing those goods in which they have a comparative advantage have generated a different pattern of ties, but any such in-
or endowment, and other countries import them. In new trade stance of the generating process would have structural charac-
theory, countries might specialize in producing an individual teristics in common, even if the exact pattern of ties differed.
variety of a good. In this case, a given country might be both This set of possible networks is described as a probability dis-
an exporter and an importer of goods in a certain industry. tribution, with the exact probability of a given configuration
But each exporting country would likely export its specialized of ties depending on the parameters in the model that de-
output to a number of other countries. At the network level, scribes the stochastic process. The maximum likelihood ap-
this would amount to a structural tendency to out-stars as proach to estimating the parameters of the stochastic process
well, with the only difference being that these exporting coun- results in a model in which the observed network has the high-
tries also have incoming trade flows. est probability of occurring.
These models consist of a family of probability functions,
(b) Exponential random graph model (ERGM) analysis in P h fY ¼ yg ¼ expðh0 uðyÞ  wðhÞÞ ð1Þ
StOCNET

(i) The model where y is the observed set of ties defining an adjacency matrix
The hypothesis tests that I propose are not so much about representing the network being modeled, h is a vector of
the level of trade or even which countries are exporters so parameters, u(y) is a vector of sufficient statistics of the graph
much as the structure of the larger patterns of trade. That or digraph, and w(h) is a normalizing constant, ensuring that
is, the hypotheses describe network-level effects and thus must the probabilities of all possible graph configurations sum to
be tested with network-based tools, rather than the standard one (Snijders et al., 2006).
approach to studying bilateral international trade, which is Estimation of structural parameters—those that involve
the gravity model. The gravity model’s history of empirical dependencies between one random variable (one tie between
success does provide some guidance in terms of explanatory two nodes, or in terms of the present paper, a trade flow from
variables to include in a network-based investigation, how- one country to another) and the state of other random
ever. The standard version of the model relates the level of variables (trade flows) involves complications unfamiliar in or-
bilateral trade to the combined economic ‘‘masses” (GDPs) dinary regression models. Early approaches (Frank & Strauss,
of a pair of countries, and a term representing ‘‘gravity” by 1986; Wasserman & Pattison, 1996) were based on a pseudo-
the inverse of the great circle distances separating them. It is loglikelihood approach. Although models constructed in this
also customary to include dummies for common language, fashion could be practically estimated using any logistic
colonial past, and contiguity of borders. regression software after preparing the data appropriately,
Because the observations are hypotheses concern larger the statistical properties of the resulting estimator are not well
structures than bilateral relationships, candidate models are understood for random graph models, and the value of its
essentially limited to those from drawn from the network anal- standard errors is questionable (Snijders, 2002).
ysis literature. Among these, the most appropriate set of tools Snijders (2002) therefore elaborated a Monte Carlo simula-
in network analysis for testing hypotheses about structural ef- tion method of arriving at maximum likelihood parameter
fects are the exponential random graph models (ERGMs), estimates, with the corresponding well-understood t-statistics.
also known as p* models. These have been developed in the Snijders’ method has been implemented in the computer pro-
context of social network analysis to estimate structural statis- gram SIENA, which is a component of the network analysis
tics for networks without the independence assumption that is platform StOCNET (Snijders, Steglich, Schweinberger, &
a principal feature of standard statistical approaches (Frank & Huisman, 2007). In addition to the structural parameters, SIE-
Strauss, 1986; Pattison & Wasserman, 1999; Snijders, 2002; NA can accommodate independent variables in the form of
Snijders, Pattison, Robins, & Handcock, 2006; Wasserman attributes of individual nodes and dyadic covariates.
& Pattison, 1996). Indeed the hypotheses I wish to test are pre- A technical difficulty with the estimation of ERGMs is that
mised on the idea that individual observations (the presence or for many specifications, much of the parameter space can be
absence of a trade tie) are actually dependent in some way or degenerate—that is, producing simulated networks that are
ways on certain other observed ties. either empty or maximally connected. This can prevent con-
This method grew out of the literature on the social networks vergence of the estimation algorithm. This is a particular prob-
of individuals, and most empirical applications have been in re- lem in estimating a parameter for transitive triads, which we
lated settings. For example, Thurner and Binder (2008) apply it are especially interested in.
to an analysis of the influence of informal networks on formal For example, in a simulated network, if the presence of a gi-
networks in the context of international relationships among ven tie would lead to the completion of three transitive triads,
political actors. However, its use is indicated in any setting in then the log-odds of that tie being present increases by three
which the units of analysis are relationships among actors times the estimated parameter. The presence of this tie further
(such as the trade flows between countries), when there is rea- increases the number of transitive triads that would be com-
son to believe that the relationships are dependent on each pleted by other ties as the simulation process continues, leading
other. As a statistical method, it has been applied beyond so- to a large increase in the likelihood of their inclusion in the sim-
cial networks as well Guo, Fu, and Xing (2007) study networks ulated network, and so on until all possible ties are predicted.
of gene expressions in fruit flies, for example. One tactic is to estimate models conditional on the total
42 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

number of ties in the observed network. This can lead to great- approach would not allow the subtraction of re-exports, which
er success in parameter estimation, but there are still many data I deemed to be the more significant distortion of the data for
sets for which satisfactory estimates cannot be obtained. There- the present study. Weight data are not reported by some coun-
fore Snijders et al. (2006) have developed alternative statistics tries and were therefore not an option for this analysis.
for estimating these models. The basic idea is that geometri- I define the presence of a directed trade flow dichoto-
cally decreasing weights are put on larger numbers of triads mously—a flow is coded with a one if it is present or a zero
that would be completed by a given tie. This has the effect of if it is absent or extremely small. Trade flows from exporting
attenuating the tendency to cascade into a maximally con- countries are added to the network and coded as existing in
nected network and reduce the degenerate areas of the param- the descending order of total value. Starting with the largest
eter space. Several structural effects are better estimated with reported flow, trade flows are added to the network until
this type of specification. All these are denoted (for reasons ex- 95% of the global total of reported trade has been represented
plained in Snijders et al. (2006)) by the prefix ‘‘Alternating.” in the network. The smallest trade flows, which are large in
number, but together total less than five percent of total re-
(ii) Model parameters ported world trade in that commodity are omitted from the
The principal structural parameters of interest are those for network. This has the analytical value of omitting the ‘‘long
transitivity, denoted by ‘‘alternating k-triangles” and the com- tail” of the distribution of trade flow magnitudes and focuses
peting tendency for exports to originate in a few countries, de- on those flows that are of significant size.
noted by ‘‘alternating out-stars.” Three other effects were Dichotomous coding strips the dependent variable of some
added to the model as structural control variables. The reci- information. However, for goods that are traded in part in
procity effect captures the increased tendency for i to export the form of designs or licenses, rather than physical products,
to j conditional on j exporting to i. The ‘‘alternating in-star” the reported level of trade may be quite inaccurate in any case.
effect represents the tendency for certain countries to import Dichotomous coding thus allows for easier comparisons
from a large number of other countries. The ‘‘alternating across goods.
two-path” effect represents a pattern of exporting from one To further achieve comparability across various commodi-
country to a second, and the second to the third. As such it ties, I used the same reference set of 156 countries for each
could be thought of as a ‘‘precondition” to transitivity (Snij- trade network. This has the advantage of defining a popula-
ders et al., 2007), or a tendency to a directed, hierarchical net- tion of countries under study that may or may not be engaged
work structure. in trade in a given commodity. However, for most goods, there
The parameter estimate for reciprocity may seem like an- are a large number of countries that do not engage in trade.
other variable of interest for studying homogenizing effects Including non-trading countries introduces many zeros into
in trade. However, it depends on reciprocal market demand the data matrix representing the trade network, and results
and the presence of a developed industry capable of exporting in much greater computing time for each network under
in both countries. It may even in certain circumstances capture study—anywhere from a few hours to a few days per network.
information about the different status characteristics of both Goods for which the top 95% of trade is concentrated in an
countries’ exports. In other words, a deeper substantive inter- especially small number of trade flows could not be analyzed
pretation of the reciprocity parameter in this context is prob- because the iterative estimation algorithm could not converge
ably unwarranted without further study. on stable parameter estimates. With a smaller reference group
Independent covariates included in the model are the prod- of countries, such as the industrialized countries, these omitted
uct of GDPs, inverse of great circle distances between national goods could be studied in the same manner.
capitals, the presence of a common language spoken by great- Non-structural independent variables are implemented as
er than 9% of both countries’ populations, a present or past dyadic covariates, with one value for each pair of countries.
colonial relation, and contiguity of borders. To control for For historical reasons, the StOCNET platform only accepts
non-homothetic preferences, I also included effects for GDP integer values between 0 and 255 for dyadic covariates. The
per capita in the exporting and importing countries, but be- original data were thus normalized to a maximum value of
cause they did not substantively affect outcomes, they were 255, and rounded to the nearest integer to accommodate this
ultimately excluded from the final model. limitation. Because the dependent variable is dichotomous,
however, it is extremely unlikely that this transformation af-
(c) Data and data preparation fected the analysis in any significant way. Finally, dyadic
covariates are centered by subtracting the mean.
I use reports of the values of exports in the year 2005 from
the United Nations Commodity Trade Database (COM- (d) Results
TRADE). For these data, the value of an export flow is re-
ported by each exporting country in United States dollars in The estimated magnitudes of the parameters for the transi-
free on board (FOB) terms, which includes costs of the ex- tivity effect and the out-star effect are plotted in Figure 2. A
ported goods and the costs incurred in getting them to the full table of estimated parameters, t-statistics, and effect mag-
country’s border, but excludes shipping and insurance costs in- nitudes for all model effects is reported in Appendix. Effect
curred in transporting them to the destination country. Re-ex- magnitudes represent the increased likelihood of observing a
ports, which are goods that merely pass through a country’s tie in the presence of a one unit increase in dummy and struc-
jurisdiction without having being produced there, are typically tural variables, or a two-standard deviation increase for con-
reported as part of exports. However, because my aim is to tinuous explanatory variables.
study domestic production and technology, I have subtracted As expected, there are very large transitivity effects for the
re-exports from exports wherever they have been reported to two cultural goods and very small ones for the two commod-
arrive at a figure for net exports, which includes only goods ities. I therefore reject H1b. Conversely, there are very large
originally shipped from the origin country. Other authors have out-star effects for the two commodities and very small ones
tended to prefer to use imports, rather than exports as the for the two cultural industries. I therefore reject H1c. For
source of data on trade flows for reasons of accuracy, but this the range of other goods, we see a continuum between the high
HOMOGENIZATION AND SPECIALIZATION EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 43

each model. Although the other variables do produce a con-


siderable incidental transitivity effect, it is much lower than
the actual trade patterns exhibit.

(c) Controlling for omitted exogenous sources of similarity

Having found that there is more transitivity in patterns of


trade than can be accounted for by the independent variables
in the model, it nonetheless remains possible that this excess
transitivity could be due to some omitted exogenous explana-
tory variable. Although it is impractical and inadvisable to test
a large number of explanatory variables for which we have no
prior reason to include in the model, we can still seek evidence
of omitted variables in general. If there is some important exog-
enous source of similarity in technology and taste, then it ought
Figure 2. Trade network Structure, various commodities. to affect trade in more than one narrowly defined industry. If
this is the case, there should be correspondence between spe-
cific ties that form transitive triads in multiple industries. If
specialization uniform commodities and the high-transitivity there is no such correspondence, then we must conclude that
cultural goods. In other words, although trade policy treats either each specific has a unique, unobserved, exogenous
manufactures in the same way as uniform commodities, their source of similarity (not a very plausible story), or that the
patterns of trade are not necessarily similar. I reject H1e and source of similarity is endogenous to the process of trade.
find evidence a mismatch between policy and empirical reality Although questionable as a true model of trade, we could use
for trade in a wide range of ordinary goods: trade leads to one trade network as a control variable in a model of another
homogenization. trade network. In practice, this means including an indepen-
dent dyadic covariate matrix, coded as ‘‘1” for all ties present
in the ‘‘control” network and ‘‘0” otherwise. For example, in
4. IS TRANSITIVITY ENDOGENOUS TO THE TRADE an analysis of trade in sound recordings, we could include
NETWORK? the trade network defined by the sum of trade in all goods in
the COMTRADE database as a test of dimensions of similarity
(a) Hypotheses not captured by the control variables already in the model. We
could also posit that an unobserved exogenous socio-cultural
To support the idea that trade leads to homogenization of similarity between countries is more likely to affect trade in cul-
technology and taste, it remains to be shown that the transitiv- tural goods than in other goods. To test this possibility, we
ity effect of section II is endogenous to the network and not could include the trade network of one cultural good as a con-
the result of some other process. In other words, we must dis- trol variable to proxy for such an unobserved similarity in the
tinguish between the following hypotheses: analysis of another. Returning to music, we could include trade
Exogenous hypothesis: in books as such a control variable (Table 2).
H2a: the observed tendency to transitivity is a result of sim- In both cases, the parameter for transitivity is moderately
ilarities between countries that are exogenous to the process of lower than that in the original model, more so for the imple-
trade. mentation of books as a proxy for exogenous difference than
Endogenous hypothesis: for the use of the total trade network. This suggests that there
H2b: the observed tendency to transitivity is a result of sim- is some unobserved factor which is correlated with the transi-
ilarities between countries that are caused by trade itself. tivity parameter. Still, even after controlling for unobserved
In this section, I provide several exhibits that support an variables, the magnitude of the transitivity effect is statistically
endogenous explanation of transitivity in trade networks. significant and very high compared to, say, the original esti-
mates for coal, corn, or cargo ships. I therefore maintain a
(b) Specification test high level of suspicion that transitivity is in large part due to
an endogenous process of trade itself.
The variables in the original model which derive from the
standard specification for gravity models capture directly or
are proxies for the most obvious explanations for exogenous (d) An exceptional case: antiques
similarities that could produce transitive trade patterns. The
variables for colonial ties and common language capture signif- Intuitively, I would expect antiques to fall on the cultural
icant historical sources of cultural similarities, as well as the goods side of the spectrum, because they are extremely differ-
resultant present day ease or frequency of international ex- entiated and their value does not stem from universally held
change. The gravity and contiguity variables capture spatial functional criteria. However, they are an interesting test case
similarity, and the product of GDPs captures, to an extent, eco- because the technology used to produce them could not be
nomic similarity. It is conceivable, therefore, that the transitiv- influenced by present-day imports because the producers are
ity parameter is spuriously picking up transitivity that should all dead. They are thus unconcerned by changes in fashion
have been explained by the exogenous explanatory variables. and also immune from subconscious influences. Still, if the
I re-ran the estimation process with the transitivity parameter exogenous hypothesis for explaining transitivity in trade pat-
fixed to zero and subsequently compared the resulting model terns were correct, we would expect trade in antiques to
to the observed network to evaluate if this was the case. exhibit transitivity strongly. It does not. In fact, this is the
Table 1 reports the result of modeling trade in music with- only good I analyzed, other than iron and steel puddled bars
out the alternating k-triangles parameter. Observed values and ingots, that had an insignificant estimate for the
are compared with a distribution of simulated networks for transitivity parameter. Interestingly, trade in antiques also
44 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. Effect of fixing transitivity parameter to zero


Structural measure Observed data Original model Fixing transitivity parameter to zero
Mean of sim. networks t-stat. for fit Mean of sim. networks t-stat. for fit
Number of mutuals 131 129.16 0.285 131.95 0.129
Alternating Out Stars 893.2 894.45 0.154 891.16 0.277
Alternating In Stars 780.02 779.14 0.073 779.07 0.088
Alternating k-triangles 904.89 905.02 0.009 784.12 4.1568
Alternating 2-paths 3696.57 3677.66 0.123 3703.63 0.0528
Number of ties  gravity 4345.25 4131.23 0.327 4299.48 0.075
Number of ties  colony 46.46 46.57 0.026 46.23 0.044
Number of ties  common language 50.98 49.32 0.098 53.67 0.21
Number of ties  contiguous 57.81 56.09 0.23 57.75 0.009
Number of ties  GDP product 4640.99 4631.85 0.077 4626.67 0.107

Table 2. Using other trade networks to control for omitted exogenous


sources of transitivity on trade in music plained by the dominant perspective that trade leads to
Parameter Estimate S.E. Estimate S.E.
economic gains through specialization, but it is consistent with
the idea that trade leads to homogenization of technology
Trade in books 2.0702 0.1533 and/or taste. For countries which produce distinctive or un-
All trade 2.2321 0.2109 ique goods, but are not already international leaders in export-
Reciprocity 0.7826 0.2178 0.7864 0.2087 ing these goods, this finding supports the idea that policies
A. Out stars 0.9865 0.2023 0.7991 0.2012 must be enacted to counter the homogenizing effect of trade.
A. In stars 0.1081 0.1909 0.431 0.197 What form these policies should take is a matter for future re-
A. k-triangles 1.1718 0.1656 1.3423 0.1723 search. The other major empirical finding of the present study
A. 2-paths 0.002 0.0097 0.011 0.0097 is that patterns of trade for individual industries range dra-
Gravity 0.0166 0.0037 0.022 0.0033 matically from extremes defined by cultural goods on the
Colony 0.1789 0.2849 0.4849 0.244
one hand to uniform commodities on the other hand. The
Language 0.3202 0.1489 0.8725 0.1289
broader implication of these findings is that international
Contiguous 0.0562 0.2605 0.0253 0.2409
trade policy is based on an incomplete theory of the effects
Product of GDPs 0.0867 0.0158 0.0556 0.0133
of trade. In this final section, I discuss the findings and specu-
late on their implications, with the intention of suggesting
exhibits the strongest tendency to out-stars of any good propositions to be examined in future research.
analyzed (Figure 3).
In sum, while it is not possible to conclusively reject the (b) Transitivity is a feature of trade networks
exogenous hypothesis for the origin of transitivity in trade net-
works, I have endeavored to show in this section with these Higher degrees of transitivity characterize those goods that
three tests that the most plausible story is the endogenous one. we a priori consider to be ‘‘cultural.” But every good exam-
ined, except for antiques (a special case) and iron and steel
bars and ingots, exhibited a significant tendency to transitivity.
5. DISCUSSION AND IMPLICATIONS FOR FURTHER The interpretation of this is not so much that cultural goods
RESEARCH are like ordinary goods, but rather that we should systemati-
cally revise our picture of all industries to include effects we
(a) Summary only expected in cultural goods. To take a small example,
the gravity model is the empirical benchmark for explaining
The principal empirical finding of this paper is that transitiv- trade, but it does not account for structures of interdepen-
ity is a feature of international trade patterns. This is not ex- dency within the trade network. Rather, it makes the standard
assumption that all variables with explanatory power are
exogenous to the trade network. The results presented here
suggest that endogenous effects—probably through channels
of technology and taste—may in fact be extremely important
to modeling trade—not only in cultural goods industries, but
in most other industries as well.

(c) The cultural industries as a model

The cultural industries have been considered difficult to ana-


lyze with traditional economic methods. Perhaps this is be-
cause, with their high semiotic content, they are the furthest
away from the classical origins of economic analysis: uniform,
mass produced goods. Indeed, this paper began by asking if
the cultural industries were an exception to the basic theory
of international trade and finished by using them as an
example for the types of questions that could be asked
Figure 3. An exceptional case: network structure for trade in antiques. more generally. Cultural industries bring to the fore issues of
HOMOGENIZATION AND SPECIALIZATION EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 45

consumption, prior reference points, definitions of, and con- for exempting them from free trade commitments. Perhaps
ventions structuring what is demanded that vary across social more fundamentally, I found that cultural goods are not
units of analysis. To better understand them it becomes neces- exceptional in this way, and that many other ordinary goods
sary to consider large-scale patterns of human interaction reveal this sort of ‘‘cultural” pattern of trade by demonstrating
explicitly, an analytical approach that is likely to serve us well evidence of a strong homogenization effect. The presence of
in studying other phenomena in today’s increasingly con- such an effect implies that trade liberalization is not necessarily
nected world. I believe that in this era of knowledge- and good for everyone, and that there are winners and losers.
information-based economic development rather than being Admittedly, the findings here beg for much additional research
considered the most irregular, the cultural industries could in- before we can fully understand the implications of homogeni-
stead become a new best example and an alternative pole to zation from trade on development. For now, however, I will
uniform commodities in development studies, which could say that at the least, if products and technologies that are un-
illuminate many obscure and complex mysteries of the devel- ique to a given country are of any value, then that country
opment of economies in general. should seek to support and protect them from the homogeniz-
ing influence of trade, even where there is no ‘‘infant industry”
(d) Conclusion justification for such protection.

I have found strong evidence that trade has a homogenizing


effect for cultural goods and therefore empirical justification

REFERENCES

Anderson, C. J., Wasserman, S., & Crouch, B. (1999). A p* primer: Logit study of the home market effect. Journal of Media Economics, 20(3),
models for social networks. Social Networks, 21(1), 37–66. 167–188.
Amin, S. (1974). Accumulation and development: A theoretical model. Mattelart, A., & Polan, D. B. (1978). The nature of communications
Review of African Political Economy, 1(1), 9–26. practice in a dependent society. Latin American Perspectives, 5(1),
Amsden, A. H. (1979). Taiwan’s Economic History: A case of etatisme 13–34.
and a challenge to dependency theory. Modern China, 5(3), 341–379. Olson, Mancur (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth,
Amsden, A. H. (2001). The rise of the rest: Challenges to the west from late- stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.
industrializing economies. New York: Oxford University Press. Pattison, P., & Wasserman, S. (1999). Logit models and logistic
Bourne, C., & Allgrove, S. M. (1996). Prospects for exports of entertain- regressions for social networks: II. Multivariate relations. British
ment services for the English-speaking Caribbean: The case of music. Journal of Mathematical and Statistical Psychology, 52(2), 169–193.
World Bank Informatics and Telecommunications Division, Working Pool, I. de Sola (1977). The changing flow of television. Journal of
Paper. Communication, 27(2), 139–149.
Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new Pratt, A. (2004). The music industry in Senegal: The potential for economic
perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quar- development. UNCTAD.
terly, 35(1), 128–152. Ratanawaraha, A. (2006). Late standardization and technological catch-up.
Di Benedetto, C., Calantone, R. J., & Zhang, C. (2003). International Unpublished dissertation, MIT Department of Urban Studies and
technology transfer: Model and exploratory study in the People’s Planning <http://dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/37674>.
Republic of China. International Marketing Review, 20(4), 446–462. Robins, G., Pattison, P., Kalish, Y., & Lusher, D. (2007). An introduction
Dupagne, Michael, & Waterman, David (1998). Determinants of U.S. to exponential random graph (p*) models for social networks. Social
television fiction imports in Western Europe. Journal of Broadcasting Networks, 29(2), 173–191.
and Electronic Media, 42(2), 208–220. Rogers, EverettM (1995). The diffusion of innovations. The Free Press: New
Falkenheim, B. J. C. (2000). Asymmetries reconfigured: South American York.
television flows in the 1990s. Canadian Journal of Communication, Schiller, H. I. (1976). Communication and cultural domination white plains.
25(2). International Arts and Sciences Press.
Farrell, J., & Saloner, G. (1986). Installed base and compatibility: Scott, A. J. (2004). Cultural-products industries and urban economic
Innovation, product preannouncements, and predation. The American development: Prospects for growth and market contestation in global
Economic Review, 76(5), 940–955. context. Urban Affairs Review, 39(4), 461–490.
Frank, O., & Strauss, D. (1986). Markov graphs. Journal of the American Snijders, T. A. B. (2002). Markov Chain Monte Carlo estimation of
Statistical Association, 81(395), 832–842. random graph models. Journal of Social Structure, 3(2).
Fu, W. W. (2006). Concentration and homogenization of international Snijders, T. A. B., Pattison, P. E., Robins, G. L., & Handcock, M. S.
movie sources: Examining foreign film import profiles. Journal of (2006). New specifications for exponential random graph models.
Communication, 56(4), 813–835. Sociological Methodology, 36(1), 99–153.
Guo, F., Hanneke, S., Wenjie Fu, Xing, E. P. (2007). Recovering Snijders, T. A. B., Steglich, C. E.G., Schweinberger, M., & Huisman, M.
temporally rewiring networks: A model-based approach. In Proceed- (2007). Manual for SIENA version 3. University of Groningen, ICS,
ings of the 24th international conference on machine learning http:// Groningen. University of Oxford, Department of Statistics, Oxford.
doi.acm.org/10.1145/1273496.1273537. <http://stat.gamma.rug.nl/stocnet>.
Haveman, Heather A. (1993). Follow the leader: Mimetic isomorphism Thurner, P. W., & Binder, M. (2008). European Union transgovernmental
and entry into new markets. Administrative Science Quarterly, 38(4), networks: The emergence of a new political space beyond the nation-
593–627. state?. European Journal of Political Research, 48(1), 80–106.
Katz, M. L., & Shapiro, C. (1992). Product introduction with network UNESCO. (2006) http://www.unesco.org/culture/industries/trade/
externalities. Journal of Industrial Economics, 40(1), 55–83. html_eng/question.shtml Accessed 10.25.06.
Kozul-Wright, Z., & Stanbury, L. (1998). Becoming a globally competitive Wallerstein, I. (Ed.) (1975). World Inequality. Quebec: Black Rose.
player: The case of the music industry in Jamaica. UCTAD discussion Wasserman, S., & Pattison, P. (1996). Logit models and logistic
paper no. 138. http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/dp_138.en.pdf. regressions for social networks: I. An introduction to Markov random
Krugman, P. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation, and the graphs and p*. Psychometrika, 61(3), 401–426.
pattern of trade. American Economic Review, 70(5), 950–959. Wildman, S. S., & Siwek, S. (1988). International trade in films and
Lee, Chin-Chuan (1980). Media imperialism reconsidered: The homogeniz- television programs. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
ing of television culture. Beverly Hills: Sage. WTO Council for Trade in Services. (1998) AUDIOVISUAL SERVICES;
Lee, Sang-Woo, & Waterman, D. (2007). Theatrical feature film trade in Background note by the Secretariat. WTO document 98-2437
the United States, Europe, and Japan since the 1950s: An empirical www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/serv_e/w40.doc.
46 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

APPENDIX A
ESTIMATED PARAMETERS FOR ERGM TRANSITIVITY ANALYSIS—VARIOUS GOODS

Reciprocity A. Out A. In A. A. Gravity Colony Language Contiguous Product


stars stars k-triangles 2-paths of GDPs
Books
Parameter estimates 1.0843 1.0122 0.6058 1.7624 0.0005 0.0177 1.9752 0.6261 1.2174 0.1322
Standard errors 0.1931 0.1690 0.1376 0.1331 0.0051 0.0026 0.1872 0.0606 0.1608 0.0162
t ratios 5.6152 5.9893 4.4026 13.2412 0.0980 6.8077 10.5513 10.3317 7.5709 8.1605
Size of effect 2.9574 2.7516 0.5456 5.8264 1.3043 7.2081 1.8703 3.3784 2.8233
Furniture
Parameter estimates 0.2347 0.7962 0.0837 1.7430 0.0050 0.0148 0.5793 0.2476 1.1388 0.0650
Standard errors 0.1863 0.1715 0.1537 0.1535 0.0100 0.0031 0.2054 0.1464 0.1799 0.0095
t ratios 1.2598 4.6426 0.5446 11.3550 0.5000 4.7742 2.8204 1.6913 6.3302 6.8421
Size of effect 2.2171 5.7145 1.2487 1.7848 3.1230 1.6658
Sound recordings
Parameter estimates 0.9572 0.9672 0.1846 1.6535 0.0048 0.0189 0.8173 0.4775 0.6195 0.1154
Standard Errors 0.1955 0.1862 0.1663 0.1624 0.0086 0.0026 0.2292 0.0853 0.2360 0.0144
t ratios 4.8962 5.1944 1.1100 10.1817 0.5581 7.2692 3.5659 5.5979 2.6250 8.0139
Size of effect 2.6044 2.6306 5.2252 1.3280 2.2644 1.6120 1.8580 2.4744
Sewing machines
Parameter estimates 1.0266 1.0908 0.3897 1.5885 0.0234 0.0101 0.3479 0.2998 1.3704 0.0399
Standard errors 0.2815 0.1518 0.1237 0.1234 0.0121 0.0030 0.2923 0.1167 0.2125 0.0071
t ratios 3.6469 7.1858 3.1504 12.8728 1.9339 3.3667 1.1902 2.5690 6.4489 5.6197
Size of effect 0.3582 2.9767 0.6773 4.8964 1.1637 1.3496 3.9369 1.3679
Cutlery
Parameter estimates 0.0624 1.1691 0.3414 1.5470 0.0028 0.0109 0.4102 0.3648 1.5511 0.0938
Standard errors 0.2105 0.1692 0.1328 0.1233 0.0080 0.0025 0.2088 0.0860 0.1832 0.0131
t ratios 0.2964 6.9096 2.5708 12.5466 0.3500 4.3600 1.9646 4.2419 8.4667 7.1603
Size of effect 3.2191 0.7108 4.6974 1.1777 1.4402 4.7167 2.0885
Passenger vehicles
Parameter estimates 0.6300 1.2888 0.0338 1.4557 0.0147 0.0095 0.2260 0.0685 0.8566 0.0393
Standard errors 0.2232 0.1991 0.1676 0.1618 0.0165 0.0028 0.3155 0.1375 0.1927 0.0067
t ratios 2.8226 6.4731 0.2017 8.9969 0.8909 3.3929 0.7163 0.4982 4.4453 5.8657
Size of effect 1.8776 3.6284 4.2875 1.1533 2.3551 1.3614
Shoes-leather, rubber or plastic sole
Parameter estimates 0.1486 0.9843 0.1808 1.3999 0.0118 0.0079 0.3048 0.2895 1.3185 0.0226
Standard errors 0.2109 0.1631 0.1522 0.1343 0.0149 0.0024 0.2522 0.0767 0.1694 0.0049
t ratios 0.7046 6.0349 1.1879 10.4237 0.7919 3.2917 1.2086 3.7744 7.7834 4.6122
Size of effect 2.6759 4.0548 1.1259 1.3358 3.7378 1.1941
Women’s dresses all fabrics
Parameter estimates 0.0067 0.9189 0.3408 1.2094 0.0287 0.0102 0.8024 0.2581 0.8987 0.0404
Standard errors 0.2094 0.1393 0.1315 0.1118 0.0124 0.0025 0.2357 0.0863 0.1892 0.0072
t ratios 0.0320 6.5966 2.5916 10.8175 2.3145 4.0800 3.4043 2.9907 4.7500 5.6111
Size of effect 2.5065 1.4061 3.3515 0.9717 1.1654 2.2309 1.2945 2.4564 1.3733
Wine
Parameter estimates 0.8317 1.5596 0.5402 1.0614 0.0730 0.0060 1.0429 0.3818 1.5609 0.0242
Standard errors 0.3133 0.1730 0.1469 0.1142 0.0178 0.0026 0.2788 0.0769 0.2154 0.0052
t ratios 2.6546 9.0150 3.6773 9.2942 4.1011 2.3077 3.7407 4.9649 7.2465 4.6538
Size of effect 0.4353 4.7569 1.7164 2.8904 0.9296 1.0942 2.8374 1.4649 4.7631 1.2092
Color TVs
Parameter estimates 0.5083 1.7848 0.1842 1.0479 0.1574 0.0069 0.1590 0.1378 1.5311 0.0305
Standard errors 0.2146 0.1643 0.1290 0.0962 0.0133 0.0029 0.3398 0.1377 0.2219 0.0062
t ratios 2.3686 10.8631 1.4279 10.8929 11.8346 2.3793 0.4679 1.0007 6.9000 4.9194
Size of effect 1.6625 5.9584 2.8517 0.8544 1.1091 4.6233 1.2706
HOMOGENIZATION AND SPECIALIZATION EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 47

APPENDIX A—Continued
Reciprocity A. Out A. In A. A. Gravity Colony Language Contiguous Product
stars stars k-triangles 2-paths of GDPs
Books
Butter
Parameter estimates 0.3740 1.6104 0.2979 1.0307 0.0894 0.0059 0.7483 0.2126 1.1023 0.0079
Standard errors 0.2702 0.1441 0.1182 0.0798 0.0129 0.0023 0.2066 0.0842 0.1770 0.0026
t ratios 1.3842 11.1756 2.5203 12.9160 6.9302 2.5652 3.6220 2.5249 6.2277 3.0385
Size of effect 5.0048 1.3470 2.8030 0.9145 1.0926 2.1134 1.2369 3.0111 1.0640
Corn, unmilled
Parameter estimates 0.2374 2.0981 0.5355 0.6693 -0.0776 0.0045 -0.2584 0.1551 1.9361 0.0157
Standard errors 0.5700 0.1637 0.1569 0.1206 0.0271 0.0039 0.4169 0.1402 0.2812 0.0030
t ratios 0.4165 12.8167 3.4130 5.5498 -2.8635 1.1538 -0.6198 1.1063 6.8851 5.2333
Size of effect 8.1507 1.7083 1.9529 0.9253 6.9317 1.1312
Gas generators and parts thereof
Parameter estimates 0.1938 1.7512 0.5054 0.6344 0.0350 0.0084 0.9333 0.2406 1.0062 0.0320
Standard errors 0.3209 0.1628 0.1527 0.1049 0.0149 0.0032 0.2301 0.1115 0.2398 0.0075
t ratios 0.6039 10.7568 3.3098 6.0477 2.3490 2.6250 4.0561 2.1578 4.1960 4.2667
Size of effect 5.7615 1.6576 1.8859 1.0356 1.1344 2.5429 1.2720 2.7352 1.2856
Anthracite
Parameter estimates -1.0620 2.4325 1.2643 0.6663 -0.1183 0.0057 0.5576 0.2112 1.9251 0.0148
Standard errors 1.2104 0.2291 0.2276 0.2641 0.0729 0.0067 0.5194 0.2659 0.4018 0.0046
t ratios -0.8774 10.6176 5.5549 2.5229 -1.6228 0.8507 1.0735 0.7943 4.7912 3.2174
Size of effect 11.3873 3.5406 1.9470 6.8558 1.1232
Cargo ships (excl. tankers)
Parameter estimates 0.0879 1.9417 1.3910 0.5857 0.0715 0.0047 0.1185 0.2637 0.6668 0.0085
Standard errors 0.6330 0.1756 0.1633 0.1310 0.0333 0.0038 0.4496 0.2711 0.3752 0.0027
t ratios 0.1389 11.0575 8.5181 4.4710 2.1471 1.2368 0.2636 0.9727 1.7772 3.1481
Size of effect 6.9706 4.0189 1.7962 0.9310 1.0690
Iron and steel bars and ingots
Parameter estimates 1.3974 1.5624 1.0941 0.2563 0.0184 0.0061 0.3685 0.1981 1.5954 0.0221
Standard errors 0.4621 0.1702 0.1727 0.1334 0.0332 0.0037 0.3193 0.1621 0.2688 0.0047
t ratios 3.0240 9.1798 6.3353 1.9213 0.5542 1.6486 1.1541 1.2221 5.9353 4.7021
Size of effect 4.0447 4.7703 2.9865 4.9303 1.1895
Antiques
Parameter estimates 1.0971 2.7326 2.0313 0.0129 0.1675 0.0142 0.9492 0.5956 1.0775 0.0299
Standard errors 0.5419 0.6187 0.6017 0.3754 0.0465 0.0078 0.4023 0.2577 0.4556 0.0076
t ratios 2.0245 4.4166 3.3759 0.0343 3.6021 1.8205 2.3594 2.3112 2.3650 3.9342
Size of effect 2.9954 15.3728 7.6239 1.1823 2.5836 1.8141 2.9373 1.2645
Note: effect magnitudes are only reported for parameters with t ratios greater than 2.
Effect magnitudes are calculated for an increase of two standard deviations in the independent variable for gravity and GDP product, and for a one unit
change for dummy and structural variables.

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

S-ar putea să vă placă și