Sunteți pe pagina 1din 13

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/273400808

A behavioral model of collective action in


artisanal and small-scale gold mining

Article in Ecological Economics April 2015


Impact Factor: 2.72 DOI: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.02.002

READS

42

3 authors, including:

Adrian Saldarriaga Clara Villegas-Palacio


National University of Colombia National University of Colombia
13 PUBLICATIONS 26 CITATIONS 15 PUBLICATIONS 30 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

All in-text references underlined in blue are linked to publications on ResearchGate, Available from: Clara Villegas-Palacio
letting you access and read them immediately. Retrieved on: 16 April 2016
Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Ecological Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

Analysis

A behavioral model of collective action in artisanal and small-scale


gold mining
Adrin Saldarriaga-Isaza a, Santiago Arango b,, Clara Villegas-Palacio c
a
Department of Economics, Universidad Nacional de Colombia Sede Medelln, Calle 59A No. 63-20, Bloque 43, Medelln, Colombia
b
Department of Computing and Decision Sciences, Universidad Nacional de Colombia Sede Medelln, Carrera 80 No. 65-223, Bloque M8A, Medelln, Colombia
c
Department of Geosciences and the Environment, Universidad Nacional de Colombia Sede Medelln, Carrera 80 No. 65-223, Bloque M3, Medelln, Colombia

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: There is a rising global concern about mercury use in small-scale gold mining because of its harmful effects on
Received 29 August 2014 ecosystems and human health. Associative entrepreneurship has been promoted as a way of accessing alternative
Received in revised form 30 December 2014 techniques to address this concern. By associative entrepreneurship, in this paper we mean the creation of local
Accepted 4 February 2015
associations between small-scale gold miners in order to acquire more environmentally-friendly technologies.
Available online xxxx
We built a behavioral simulation model to assess the feasibility of associative entrepreneurship in the context
Keywords:
of the public-good dilemma that gold mining communities face. The model construction is based on results
Small-scale gold mining from eld economic experiments, and properly replicates the observed behavioral patterns; thus, it reveals
Public-good dilemma that sustained collective action is possible when miners completely understand the social dilemma they face,
Collective action but that self-organization is not possible. Features such as reciprocity and temptation to free ride partially explain
Behavioral simulation model why self-organization fails. In such a case, external intervention has a key role in promoting programs that im-
Economic experiment prove the understanding of the social dilemma faced by artisanal and small-scale gold miners.
2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction stead (Ostrom, 1998). When everybody in the community follows this
type of strategy, the public good is underprovided or not provided at
In the design and implementation of support policies for communi- all, while pollution increases. However, the entire community might
ties involved in artisanal and small-scale gold mining (ASGM), several be better off if everyone contributes to the provision of the public
scholars have stressed the importance of having a good understanding good (Ostrom, 1998). In an ASGM context, cleaner technologies for
of the social dynamics of these communities (Hilson, 2006; Sinding, gold recovery could be accessed under an association scheme that in-
2005; Spiegel, 2009). Poor performance of some projects aimed at reg- volves entrepreneurial activities (associative entrepreneurship);
ularizing and providing assistance to ASGM has been said to be, in i.e., through collective action. Nevertheless, some incentives and per-
part, due to an insufcient understanding of the dynamics of target sonality traits might hinder the emergence of such pro-social behavior.
communities (Hilson, 2007). There is a kind of policy aiming to reduce mercury pollution in
Communities involved in ASGM face a social dilemma that is found in ASGM, which is the promotion of miners' organization via entrepre-
the way gold is recovered. In the gold recovery (ore beneciation) pro- neurship (Saldarriaga-Isaza et al., 2013). By associative entrepreneur-
cess, a miner usually employs the apparently cheapest and traditionally ship it is meant the creation of local associations between small-scale
available technique mercury amalgamation to gain the maximum gold miners in order to acquire more environmentally-friendly technol-
short-run benet for himself. However, the entire community is worse ogies, in order to overcome the social dilemma that is present in the
off than if a cleaner and more productive technology were used. This so- gold recovery process. In addition, it is also expected to improve the re-
cial dilemma can be classied as a public-good dilemma and it concerns lationship with the state, and thus associative entrepreneurship would
the control of pollution resulting from this process.1 enable miners to accumulate the nancial capital required to obtain
In a public-good dilemma people nd it costly to contribute to the cleaner and more productive technologies that are beyond the budget
provision of the public good and prefer others to pay for its provision in- of most miner families (Hinton et al., 2003; Ghose and Roy, 2007;
Spiegel, 2009). This nancial capital is difcult to obtain from the nan-
Corresponding author. cial system, which perceives small-scale mining as a risky activity
E-mail addresses: casaldarriagai@unal.edu.co (A. Saldarriaga-Isaza), (Chaparro, 2003). This fact, added to the low tendency of miners
saarango@unal.edu.co (S. Arango), civilleg@unal.edu.co (C. Villegas-Palacio).
1
Public-good and common-pool resource dilemmas are similar in that there is no ex-
to save money for investing (Saldarriaga-Isaza et al., 2013), makes asso-
clusion in the access to the resource or good. They differ in the degree of rivalry; in ciative entrepreneurship an option for small-scale miners to increase
public-goods this is much lower or simply do not exist. the nancial capabilities.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.02.002
0921-8009/ 2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109 99

Fig. 1. The core relationships of collective action.


Source: Reproduced from Ostrom (1998).

In an effort to assess the feasibility of associative entrepreneurship face-to-face communication (cheap-talk) is another factor that affects
and collective action in the context of this public-good dilemma, in the individual attributes that nally shape behavior in a social dilemma
this paper we propose a behavioral simulation model. This approach situation (Ledyard, 1995; Ostrom, 1998; Anderies et al., 2011). Such indi-
goes beyond the analysis done so far by some scholars who, through vi- vidual attributes are trust, reciprocity and reputation (Ostrom, 1998,
sual models, have integrated, for instance, the most relevant factors that 2000), which positively reinforce each other and affect the level of coop-
explain poverty-traps in ASGM (see Heemskerk, 2001; Hilson and eration (extraction effort in a common-pool resource, or contributions to
Pardie, 2006; Spiegel, 2009). Even though these models represent the a public good). Such a level of cooperation nally determines the benets
core relationships that drive poverty-traps in ASGM, it is still not clear that individuals earn from their social interactions (see Fig. 1).
from these visual models, for instance, which are the attributes that Laboratory experiments concerning public-goods provide empirical
would prevent the use of cleaner technologies, in a way that allows the evidence of Ostrom's theory. For instance, Czap and Czap (2010) show
design of strategies for overcoming resistance to technological change. that the level of trust in others that someone has may positively deter-
Modeling, in general, has been established as a useful tool in the pro- mine the concern the subject has for the provision of the public good,
cess of creating scientic explanations of how systems work, and also in and therefore his levels of donations to the provision of the good.
assessing alternatives for transforming systems (Morecroft, 2007). Ostrom (2000) and Fischbacher et al. (2001) report that a certain type
Modeling by simulation has become an important methodology for of player, a conditional cooperator, may lead to relatively high levels
theory development in the literature about organizations, and for of contributions in public-good games. A conditional cooperator is some-
explaining social phenomena (Vzquez et al., 1996; Bowles, 2004; one who is willing to initiate cooperative action when he estimates that
Davis et al., 2007). The use of simulation has been previously employed others will reciprocate, and to repeat these actions as long as a sufcient
in the analysis of situations that imply a social dilemma. Using the Sys- proportion of the others involved do reciprocate (Ostrom, 2000). Howev-
tem Dynamics simulation method, Castillo and Saysel (2005) explained er, Fischbacher and Gchter (2010) found that players in a public-good
the behavior arising from individual decision rules of communities game are not complete, but rather imperfect conditional cooperators,
whose livelihood depends upon the extraction of common-pool sher- and this feature explains the decline in contributions to nitely repeated
ies, and where a common-pool resource dilemma is implied. The model linear public-good games.
that we propose builds on the mode and analysis created in Castillo and When cooperators reciprocate in their decisions, there is an incen-
Saysel (2005) which is modied in its structure for the public-good tive to acquire a reputation for keeping promises and performing ac-
dilemma that we study in this paper. tions with short-term costs but long-term net benets (Ostrom,
The paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we provide a 1998, p. 12). Additionally, in cases where the relation between individ-
brief discussion of the theory of collective action and our approach to uals is recurrent, and they have the opportunity of retaliation against
modeling individual decision rules of artisanal gold miners, considering those who defect, cooperation is more likely to occur (Bowles, 2004).
the aforementioned public-good dilemma. Thereafter, the behavioral sim- In addition to the effect of the structural variables on collective action
ulation model and some issues on model validity are presented, followed mentioned by Ostrom (1998), a key ingredient for explaining the success
by the simulation results and policy analysis. We use simulation methods or failure of a community in solving a social dilemma is the context. Differ-
to explain the endogenous causes of behavior of individuals involved in ent kinds of broader contextual variables, such as the resource system
ASGM, in situations that involve a public-good dilemma and in which col- (Ostrom, 2007), market conditions (Castillo et al., 2011), and historical
lective action is a challenge. In the nal section, we conclude with a dis- and ecological settings (Prediger et al., 2011) generate differences in the
cussion of this model and provide some insights for future work. behavioral patterns and decision-making processes of resource users.
Finally, another driver of decision-making in social dilemmas is the
homo-economicus or rational prot maximizer from neoclassical eco-
2. Collective Action in Social Dilemmas
nomics. In this regard, Castillo and Saysel (2005) pointed out that
some aspects of human behavior, such as temptation to free-ride and
Extensive eldwork has established that under some circumstances
prot maximization, are important drivers of individual decision-
individuals do voluntarily organize themselves to, for example, protect
making in situations involving a common-pool resource dilemma.
natural resources (see, e.g., Ostrom, 2000, 2010; Anderies et al., 2011).
In the next section we propose a model of individual decision rules of
Ostrom (1998) pointed out that some of the structural variables that af-
artisanal gold miners, which considers the aforementioned aspects of col-
fect individuals' decisions in situations involving social dilemmas are the
lective action in social dilemmas. The model is expected to improve the
size and heterogeneity of the group of participants, discount rates, and
understanding of the societal dynamics of ASGM communities. Although
the level of information available to participants. Besides these variables,
there are certainly other mechanisms that would explain the poverty-trap
in this sector (see, e.g., Hilson and Pardie, 2006), we focus our attention on
Table 1
the social (public-good) dilemma as it relates to the technology trap that
Number of subjects by treatment.
causes pollution from the gold recovery process to persist.
Treatment Students Miners

Baseline (control) 50 10 3. Modeling Approach for Decision Making in ASGM


Exclusion 45 30
Co-management 45 20 The behavioral simulation model that we develop is based on the
Exclusion & co-management 45 25
methods of System Dynamics. These methods allow the description
100 A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109

Nash Strategy

- - Relative
Group's Contribution
Cooperation +
+
R3
Group's + Group's
Reputation Contribution +
- B Awareness of the
+ (Relative Contribution)
Difference + + Dilemma
Free-riding Payoff / (Relative Payoff)
- - -
+
Temtaption to R2
Individual +
+ Free-ride - Relative Payoff
Contribution Profit
Trust + + -
Threshold + Maximization
-
R1 Desired Payoff
Profit Maximizing
Reciprocity Effect

+
Willingness to
Cooperate Awarness of
Dilemma Effect +

Fig. 2. Dynamic hypothesis of the behavioral model for ASGM.

and analysis of how complex social systems work (Sterman, 2000; address this complexity, the model structure is theoretically based on
Morecroft, 2007; Davis et al., 2007). In this particular case the social be- the core relationships of collective action proposed in Ostrom's (1998)
havior of ASGM can be endogenously explained with a model that con- theory of collective action (see previous section), and the simulation
siders the public-good dilemma studied of this social system. model proposed by Castillo and Saysel (2005). Moreover, we enriched
With simulation, one can represent the tendency that economic the model, with empirical data from the outcomes of two economic
agents sometimes have underestimating delays and misperceiving non- experiments that we conducted both in the lab with university students
linearities (Sterman, 1989; Moxnes, 2004). Nonlinearities can even be in Medelln, Colombia, and in the eld with small-scale gold miners in
found in the social relationships of human communities. For instance, Segovia, Colombia, between October and November of 2012.
for the public-good dilemma observed in ASGM, these nonlinearities The economic experiment that supports the construction of the
are found in aspects such as the relationship between a group's trust- model considers an ASGM framework where a cleaner and more pro-
worthiness (i.e., trust between members within a group) and the will- ductive technology for the gold recovery process could be accessed
ingness to cooperate (Castillo and Saysel, 2005). Furthermore, there under a scheme of associative entrepreneurship. The essential condition
might be other instances of these nonlinearities; in issues such as in- that governs this kind of association is the contribution to a common
vestment decisions or the perception of the unhealthy effects fund in order to raise the minimum nancial capital to cover the cost
of pollution, the temporal difference between cause and effect can of the technology. However, some subjects might be tempted to free-
be huge (Hilson, 2006). Such delays lead to the making of decisions that ride; i.e., not to contribute but to enjoy the benets of both a better
do not consider these effects, or that consider them but only when it is environmental quality and the higher efciency of the new technology
too late. Overall, these misperceptions lead to decisions that imply mis- in the recovery process. Under the conditions of non-exclusion and
management of natural resources and the environment (Moxnes, 2004). non-rivalry in the positive externalities derived from the adopted
In general, the complexity underlying most socio-ecological systems technology, a threshold public-good game was carried out. In the
is composed of personal, social, economic, political and natural game, subjects must raise a minimum amount of money (T) to cover
elements that are permanently interacting (Dudley, 2008). In order to the cost of the alternative technology. The experimental framework

Willingness to Cooperate Temptaon to Free Ride


1.4
1.2 1.4

1
1.2
0.8
0.6 1
0.4
0.8
0.2
0 0.6
0 0.5 1 1.5 2 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1
Trust in them (i - T)/T

Prot Maximizaon Social Dilemma Awareness


1.55
1.26

1.45 1.24
1.22
1.35 1.2
1.18
1.25
1.16

1.15 1.14
0.53 0.58 0.63 0.68 0.73 0.78 0.83 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6
Payo / Max. Payo Relave Contribuon / Relave Payo

Fig. 3. Graph functions for calculation of individual contribution.


A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109 101

Table 2 that even when a player trusts other subjects, an extremely high temp-
Tests for model structure validation. tation to free-ride should lead him to decide to contribute nothing. At
Source: The author based on Forrester and Senge (1980), Sterman (2000) and Morecroft
(2007).
the same time, in the formulation, each variable that has effects on the
individual contribution variable can depend nonlinearly on other vari-
Test Description ables (Sterman, 2000), as shown below. This decision for the individual
Boundary adequacy This test asks whether the model includes all the i is formulated as follows:
relevant concepts for addressing the problem.
Structure verication Model structure must be consistent with the knowledge Contributioni Reference contribution  Willingness to cooperatei
we have about the real system.  Temptation to free ridei  Profit maximizing effect i
Parameter conrmation Parameters must have a meaning or a counterpart in
=Social dilemma awarenessi :
the real world.
Dimensional consistency All equations in the model must be dimensionally 2
consistent, and this dimensionality must correspond
to the real system.
In the reciprocity loop (R1), we follow Ostrom (1998, p. 14) who de-
Extreme conditions This test entails assigning extreme values to selected
parameters, and assessing the plausibility of nes reciprocity as the norms individuals learn from socialization and
model-generated behavior against what it is life's experiences. In this loop, individual's contribution (ci) increases
theoretically anticipated. group's contribution (i); i.e., the total investment of the group or com-
Sensitivity analysis Sensitivity of results to changes in the assumptions munity in a cleaner technology which positively affects group's coopera-
about how people make decisions.
tion. The latter is dened as the total amount of donations in the group
minus the symmetric free-riding equilibrium, which in this game is to
was the same for both students and miners. Table 1 reports the number contribute zero tokens (Cadsby and Maynes, 1999). In other words, the
of subjects by treatment in both subject pools. higher the amount of contributions to the common fund, the more the
In the baseline experiment, each of the ve participants of a group group cooperates. In practice, the investment that each miner does in
had to choose how much (ci) of his endowment (E) of 25 tokens, to con- cleaner techniques benets everyone in the mining community. By the
tribute within a group account which in the context of the study refers same token, it may positively affect the willingness of each miner to
to each miner's investment in cleaner technologies. This endowment reduce mercury pollution by investing on a cleaner technology.
was assigned at the beginning of each of the 17 periods of the game. If Additionally, for each individual i, the group's reputation for cooperating
T (60 tokens) was not reached in the round, the individual's payoff is affected by past actions (contributions) of the group. This variable is
was his own endowment. However, when the summation of the group's modeled as exponential smoothing process, and is formulated consider-
contributions was equal to or greater than the cost of the alternative ing others' contributions (j i) in the past, together with a normal
technology T, everyone in the group received a reward of 24 tokens, (average) level of contribution by others that in this case is assumed to
which represents the benets of both an improved environmental qual- be an equitable donation:
ity (R) and higher productivity (), benets that were not excludable in X
0
this base case.2 Individual's payoff (Ui) in the base case is summarized in group s reputationit ci;t1 =48; for i; j 1; 2; 3; 4; and 5: 3
i j
the following function:
X
n There is a belief that everybody has on other's reliability to undertake
If ci b T; then U i E; actions; which lead to overcoming the social dilemma as an important
i1
1 component of the reinforcing mechanisms that shape human behavior
X
n
in this kind of situation (Ostrom, 2009). The belief of the likely behavior
If ci T; then U i Eci R :
of other miners to be trustworthy reciprocators and adopt cleaner tech-
i1
niques is based on information available to each miner. In the model, the
Considering this public-good dilemma, Fig. 2 illustrates the causal level of trust the individual has in the group is altered by group's reputa-
structure or dynamic hypothesis of the model. The feedback loop dia- tion taking into account past decisions. This variable trust accumu-
gram shows the cause-and-effect relations between the variables that lates the group's past reputation for cooperation, as follows:
explain behavior in the public-good dilemma we study. In this gure, Z t
 0 
the arrows indicate the causal connection between pairs of variables. trust it group s reputations ds trust i0 : 4
0
When the arrow has a positive (negative) sign, it means that a change
in the variable in which the link starts, generates a change in the same This level of trust nally affects the individual's willingness to cooperate
(opposite) direction in the other variable (ceteris paribus). Small paral- (contribute) in a positive way. The relationship between trust and willing-
lel lines crossing some of the arrows in the diagram denote delays. The ness to cooperate is represented as a nonlinear formulation in Fig. 3.4 In
dynamic hypothesis consists of four causal loops, three reinforcing loops this formulation, we assume that when the levels of trust are high, the
or positive feedbacks (denoted by R1, R2, and R3 in the center of the player reciprocates by increasing contributions to the common fund. As
loop), and one balancing loop or negative feedback (denoted by B in trust decreases, player's contributions decrease. In this nonlinear formula-
the center of the loop).3 Each of these loops is described below. tion, the player is assumed to be highly responsive to inferior levels of
The contribution decision is modeled for ve representative subjects trust but this response slows down as trust moves toward its maximum
who make private decisions. This decision rule for individual contribu- possible value. Moreover, player's willingness to cooperate saturates at
tion can be formulated with either a multiplicative or an additive certain levels for minimum and maximum levels of trust.
approximation. Either of these approximations can take into account Fig. 2 also portrays a free-riding loop (B). In this balancing loop, the
the nonlinear dependence of the contribution decision on each of the player takes into account the behavior of the difference between group's
aspects included in the dynamic hypothesis. The additive formulation contribution and the cost of the alternative technology or threshold (T).
assumes strong separability whereas the multiplicative formulation al- This difference is perceived by the player with a time delay; i.e., it corre-
lows for an extreme value of any variable to dominate the effects of sponds to the information the player receives in the current period on
other variables (Sterman, 2000). For instance, in our model, we expect
4
Models in System Dynamics involve the use of nonlinear functions that are usually
2
We invite the reader to see Saldarriaga-Isaza (2013) for a complete description of the specied analytically by using table or graph functions. This kind of function species
economic experiment. the relationship between values of the independent and the dependent variables. See
3
See Sterman (2000) for a further explanation. Sterman (2000) for further explanation.
102 A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109

20

18

16

14

12
Tokens
10

0
01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Period

Fig. 4. Extreme condition test for the initial value of trust.

75
Group Contribuons (Tokens)

70
65
60
55
Miners
50
Students
45
40
35
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17
Period

Fig. 5. Average group contributions in the baseline of the framed experiments with miners and students.

what this difference was in the previous period. If this information reaching the threshold and therefore of obtaining prots from the group
indicates that the difference was positive, the player has the incentive to account. However, as the ratio of average perceived payoff to the maxi-
free ride on others by decreasing his contribution in the current decision mum payoff rises, the effect disappears and the player would contribute
period. Nonetheless, when total contributions drop below the threshold, approximately the same level of tokens in the next period of the game.
the temptation disappears and the individual's payoff is just his endow- As time goes by, it is also expected that each player learns about the
ment. In such a case, the player would be encouraged to contribute to dilemma in which he is involved. In the awareness loop, the player gains
reach the threshold and obtain benets from the group account. In the awareness of the public-good dilemma for higher values of the ratio of
model, the difference between group's contribution and T is normalized,
taking into account the possible maximum values this difference can Table 3
take according to the expression (i T)/T. The relationship between Characteristics of students and miners in the simulation.
temptation to free ride and this difference is modeled as the graph Player Initial level Initial level of Willingness Temptation Prot
(table) function that is shown in Fig. 3. In practice, free-riding behavior of trust free-riding to cooperate to free ride maximization
in ASGM may emerge when some miners are, to some extent, aware of Students
the impact of mercury pollution, but do not want to share the costs of A Medium High Common Low Common
overcoming the dilemma. B Medium Medium High Low Common
We also take into consideration that in this decision-making process C Low Low Low Low Common
D High Medium Medium Common Common
subjects want to make prots. This prot maximizing or prot making be-
E Medium Medium Common Common Common
havior is represented in the reinforcing loop, R2, in Fig. 2. According to this
loop, the individual compares the average earned payoff from the previ- Miners
A High High High Mediuma Lowb
ous period with the maximum payoff he could earn in a single period
B Medium Medium Common Common Low
(49 tokens). This is modeled with a function that represents the effect C Medium High Common Common Low
of this reasoning on individual contributions, which is represented in D Medium Medium Common Common Low
Fig. 3. In this function, when the average earned payoff is about the min- E Medium High Common Common Low
imum that can be earned, the player would be willing to contribute more. a
Inverse sigmoid function.
Under this situation, contributing more would increase the chance of b
Convex function.
A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109 103

Miners Students
75 70

Group Contribuons (Tokens)

Group Contribuons (Tokens)


70 65
65 60
60
55
55
50
50
45 45 Experiment
Experiment
40 40
Simulaon Simulaon
35 35
30 30
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17
Period Period

Fig. 6. Comparison of model behavior and average group contributions in the control treatment of the economic experiments (pooled data).

70 18
Group Contribuons (Tokens)

Individual Contribuons
65 16
60 14

(Tokens)
55 12
50 10
45 Miners 8 Miners

40 Students 6 Students

35 4
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17
Period Period

Fig. 7. Average behavior in the co-management treatment of miners and students.

perceived relative contributions and the perceived relative payoff: model behavior are commonly applied to assess the adequacy of the be-
havior generated by the structure of the model (Forrester and Senge,
ci X
1980; Morecroft, 2007). In this sub-section we present and discuss the
ci
. : 5 results of the tests we applied to our behavioral model.
Payoff
Max:Payoff
3.1.1. Tests of Model Structure
Some of the most commonly employed tests for structural validation
When this ratio takes high values (close to 0.6), the player recog-
are discussed in Forrester and Senge (1980) and Sterman (2000). A
nizes that by contributing few tokens relative to what other players con-
brief description of these tests is presented in Table 2. With regard to
tribute (ci/ci is low) is not being protable enough; i.e., Payoff
the boundary adequacy and structure verication tests, the major vari-
Max.Payoff is low. This perception causes the individual to increase
ables of the causal loop (see Fig. 2) are endogenously generated by the
the contribution to the common fund. The social dilemma awareness,
model: individual and group contributions, trust, and individual payoffs.
however, is better distinguished when the difference between the per-
This structure adheres to Ostrom's (1998) theory of collective action, al-
ceived payoff and the maximum payoff is wide (i.e., when the ratio is
ready described in the section Collective action in social dilemmas,
lower than 0.7). The learning effect decreases at an accelerated rate as
more specically to Ostrom's core relationships of collective action
the perceived payoff gets closer to the maximum possible payoff.
(see Fig. 1), which is also supported by the results of the economic exper-
Most of the factors just described are nonlinear functions represent-
iments reported in Saldarriaga-Isaza (2013).6 Accordingly, in those exper-
ed in Fig. 3. The reference contribution in Eq. (4) is a parameter that was
imental results the statistical signicance of dynamic variables in
set at 12. This is the intermediate value between a completely selsh
explaining individual contributions leads to the conclusion that partici-
donation level (0 tokens) and the maximum level the individual may
pants in the experiment did reciprocate. Moreover, in the experiments,
donate (25 tokens).
trust in others positively affected the contributions subjects made to the
common fund.
3.1. Validation of the Model5
Dimensional consistency was directly tested using the tool available
in the Powersim Studio software. There is no numerical data to verify
All models are wrong, but some are useful (Box and Draper, 1987,
the value of the parameters employed in the model. Instead, the param-
p. 424). In general, we cannot expect that a single system dynamics
eters and functions of the model were calibrated taking into account the
model replicates reality; however, models and their simplications are
experimental results reported in Saldarriaga-Isaza (2013).
useful to learn about complex dynamic systems (Sterman, 2000). In
To test the model response to extreme conditions, we rst look at
general, the validation of a system dynamics model involves both struc-
how the model behaves under extreme conditions of initial levels of
ture and behavior (Barlas, 1996; Qudrat-Ullah and Seong, 2010), in
trust. On the one hand, the most likely behavior for very low initial
which model validity is essentially seen as a condence-building pro-
levels of trust is that players will try to follow the inefcient Nash
cess (Forrester and Senge, 1980) that involves a variety of tests to as-
sess the quality of both the model and the model building process 6
In the literature about human behavior, there are other theories of collective action in
(Morecroft, 2007, p. 377). Besides tests for model structure, tests of
which other concepts and variables are proposed as drivers of collective action in social di-
lemmas (see, e.g., Lange et al., 2013, for a recent discussion from psychology). However,
5
The model, built in Powersim Studio, and its complete description are available upon this discussion is beyond of the scope of this paper and therefore a boundary test that in-
request. cludes other concepts is not done in this paper.
104 A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109

Eect of Co-management
11

1
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
Relave Contribuon / Relave Payo
Fig. 8. Effect of co-management of awareness of the social dilemma.

strategy and make contributions near to zero tokens. In fact, Fig. 4 players (players A and B) strongly resist the temptation to free ride on
shows that when the players initially distrust others they put very few others (the temptation to free ride function is concave), while the other
tokens in the group account. As the game goes on, players learn about three players are given a common temptation to free ride function
the dilemma and try to increase their contributions to the common (see Fig. A.2 in the Appendix A). In this case, players A and B would do-
fund, but the provision point is never reached. On the other hand, nate more tokens than his partners, from the very beginning. The rest of
when players fully trust in the actions of each of the group members, the players take advantage of this behavior and contribute less than the
contributions start high, although not at its maximum. In a threshold cost-sharing donation. The threshold is, however, always reached and
public-good game, group contributions beyond the provision point are the public good provided. In another scenario, where player A is charac-
welfare reducing (Marks and Croson, 1998). Therefore, contributions terized by a high temptation to free ride, the contributions of this player
are not expected to be much higher than a certain level, which in this are quite low throughout. Other players' contributions keep close to the
case is the efcient cost-sharing contribution of 12 tokens that maxi- cost-sharing donation. However, their cooperative efforts are eroded by
mizes social welfare. Other behavioral driving forces such as prot max- the elevated opportunistic behavior of player A, and the public good is
imization would prevent players from wasting their available resources, hardly ever provided.
inducing them to provide collectively acceptable donations.
The results of the simulation model can be sensitive to the assump-
3.1.2. Tests of Model Behavior
tions about the way people make decisions (Sterman, 2000) or how
The aim of testing model behavior is to assess the t of a simulation to
they react to certain impulses. These assumptions are modeled as
observed data (Morecroft, 2007). In this section, we discuss the model
graph functions, described in Fig. 3 of the previous sub-section. Such re-
behavior compared with the average behavior of miners and students
lationships that are likely to be inuential on the behavioral patterns are
in the framed economic experiments reported in Saldarriaga-Isaza
willingness to cooperate and temptation to free ride (Castillo and Saysel,
(2013). Firstly, there is an oscillating pattern around the efcient Nash
2005). Here, we present an analysis of the sensitivity of the model to
outcome equilibrium (60 tokens) that is usually observed in other
changes in the shape of these two graph functions.
threshold public-good games (Croson and Marks, 2000); it can be detect-
In Fig. A.1 in the Appendix A we show how the results of the model
ed in the baseline of the framed experiments undertaken with miners
change for different possibilities of the functional forms that dene the
and students. However, the amplitude of the oscillation of group contri-
willingness to cooperate, and different initial values of trust. When the
butions in students is different than the behavioral pattern observed in
willingness to cooperate is low, the system is not able to reach an appro-
the experiments with miners. Fig. 5 portrays those differences.
priate level of individual donations that leads to the provision of the pub-
To reproduce the behavioral patterns coming from the experiments,
lic good. This happens even when the initial level of trust is high. In
we modied the following characteristics of each player in the model: ini-
contrast, players are always prone to contribute enough tokens when
tial levels of trust and temptation to free-ride, and the functional forms of
the willingness to cooperate is high, even when players have a low initial
willingness to cooperate, temptation to free ride and prot maximization.
level of trust (i.e., the individual is altruistic). In this case, individual
Table 3 shows the characteristics of each of the ve players in both groups
contributions tend to increase from the beginning and stabilize in the
(students and miners). Fig. 6 portrays the best t between the simulations
nal rounds at values close to the cost-sharing equilibrium (12 tokens).
and average group contributions in the control treatment of the economic
Assuming a moderate function of willingness to cooperate, the sys-
experiments. The general impression from these results is that students
tem moves toward an inefcient equilibrium of individual contribu-
act more like homo-economicus (prot maximizers) than miners, and
tions. Conversely, in the common case, i.e., for the graph function
try to adjust their contributions to the efcient contribution level.
showed in Fig. 3, neither the cost-sharing equilibrium nor the provision
point is always reached, although it is more likely to be reached when
players start the game with high trust. In general, the behavior of the 4. Policy Analysis
model in this sensitivity analysis is as expected.
Some individuals can resist the temptation to free ride while others This analysis is aimed at simulating and assessing the response of the
cannot (Skatova and Ferguson, 2013). These individual behavioral dif- system to a policy that has been tried, or to create new strategies, in
ferences affect the opportunistic behavior that players have, and order to improve the performance of the real system (Forrester and
hence the results of the game. For instance, let us assume that two Senge, 1980; Barlas, 1996; Sterman, 2000; Morecroft, 2007).
A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109 105

80

Group contributions (tokens)


70

60

50

40 Baseline Co-management

30

20
01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Period

Fig. 9. Model behavior for co-management treatment.

The data gathered in the economic experiments, both with miners the awareness loop that starts having effects from period 9. The function
and university students, show that individuals do not succeed in self- accelerates the rate at which each individual becomes aware of the
establishing a sustained collective action (see Fig. 5). In the base case of public-good dilemma. As shown in Fig. 8, the effect of co-management
the experiment, subjects can afford the cost of the technology, but this is especially high when the ratio of relative contribution to relative pay-
happens only sporadically; the rates of successful provision for both sub- off is low. In other words, when an individual himself does not perceive
jects' pools are slightly above 50% (see Saldarriaga-Isaza, 2013). In a real the dilemma, communication with an external party and with other
world situation, contributions to the common fund are required not only group members triggers the individual's awareness of the dilemma.
to buy the equipment but also to maintain it. Therefore, strategies to im- The general behavioral pattern obtained from the simulation model
prove these performance patterns are required. To have individuals under this treatment is portrayed in Fig. 9.
whose commitment to provide enough funds to the association is not Spiegel (2009) points out the links that exist between technological
permanent could have a deterrent effect on a group's contributions. development, environmental health awareness, and trust-building in
In the last two decades, external organizations have presented tech- ASGM. From the sensitivity analysis of the previous section, we see
nical mining alternatives (Chouinard and Veiga, 2008) and persuaded that high initial levels of trust lead to cooperation, no matter the coop-
artisanal gold miners to organize themselves into associative entrepre- erative trait of the subject (see Fig. A.1 in the Appendix A). Moreover,
neurship groupings. This scheme would help to enable miners to accu- our simulations show that the experimental results are partially
mulate the nancial capital required to obtain cleaner and more explained by medium or low levels of trust that individuals have at
productive technologies (Ghose and Roy, 2007; Spiegel, 2009). the beginning of the game (see Table 3 above). Therefore, from a policy
In this policy context, one of the institutional arrangements that was viewpoint, it is important to improve the channels of communication in
examined in the economic experiments developed by Saldarriaga-Isaza these communities. Better communication leads to a strengthening of
(2013) was co-management. Conceptually, this mechanism is under- the levels of trust, commitment, and social capital which, according to
stood as the interaction between internal communication among com- Zeffane et al. (2011), are key elements within any organization. More
munity members and an external non-coercive party. The role of the trust and commitment, combined with the support of external agencies
external party was to persuade miners to invest in the new technology, that increase education and provide technical assistance, guide ASGM
with the aim of reducing the emissions of mercury and avoiding the communities to improve the gold recovery process that, in the long-
harmful effects of mercury pollution. In addition to this persuasion, run, may translate into greater well-being.
each ve-person group had 5 min to converse among themselves. The Finally, another mechanism that was tested in the experiments of
average results of this treatment, both in miners and students, are Saldarriaga-Isaza (2013) is the exclusion from the private benets that
shown in Fig. 7. In this gure, the rst eight periods correspond to the a miner may obtain from the alternative technology if the miner does
baseline; thereafter, when players communicate and interact with the not contribute to the purchase of the technology. These private benets
external advisor, we observe that they try to coordinate their actions correspond to the higher efciency or greater productivity in the gold
in order to reach the efcient outcome (60 tokens). Moreover, subjects recovery process if the alternative technology is obtained and used.
tend to get closer to the cost-sharing equilibrium by contributing 12 to- This kind of economic incentive did not have any effect on the behavior
kens. See for instance Fig. 7, which portrays the average of individual miners showed in the experiment. However, by doing some simulations
decisions of students and miners in one of the sessions where the co- we can discern a certain design of the economic incentive in order to
management treatment was applied. make it effective in terms of the objectives of the policy.
The kind of behavior observed under this treatment is explained by In the exclusion treatment of the experiment, the level of minimum
the awareness of the dilemma loop, from Fig. 2. Communication among contribution to avoid exclusion was chosen to be simply above zero.
group members and the external advisor triggers commitment and These results change if we consider a tougher minimum individual con-
trust inside the group, and additionally helps make subjects more tribution in this exclusion case; e.g., a donation level that is at least as
aware of the public-good dilemma. During the experiments, for in- high as the cost-sharing contribution of 12 tokens. If we keep the char-
stance, Saldarriaga-Isaza (2013) observed that one or two miners with- acteristics of miners that were shown in Table 3, the simulation results
in the group played the role of leaders. These leaders pointed out the show that by making this coercive requirement after period 8, contribu-
features of the social dilemma and suggested the way of dealing with it. tions tend to increase such that in almost all of the second stage of the
To simulate the effect of this institutional arrangement on contribu- game the threshold is reached, although with total contributions that
tions at the set-up of the experiment, we introduced a graph function in are welfare-decreasing (above 60), as shown in Fig. 10. We should
106 A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109

80

Total Contri buti ons (Tokens )


70

60

50

40

30
01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Period

Fig. 10. Simulation of the effect of a tougher economic incentive.

note that we did not obtain a signicant effect when we increased the dilemma. Also important is to set up strategies (e.g., education programs)
amount of the private benets. Therefore, there is room for further re- to improve social capital and strengthen the skills that are required to at-
search about the role of economic incentives in cooperation in ASGM. tain an enduring association.
Lokhorst et al. (2013) pointed out the effectiveness of different
commitment-inducing strategies in altering environmental behavior.
5. Discussion and Concluding Remarks Nonetheless, these authors admit the ignorance that exists in the litera-
ture about the mechanisms by which it may happen. From our behav-
Previous literature has proved the usefulness of simulation methods ioral model, however, we argue that by making people more aware of
environmental decision making problems (e.g. Decker, 1994; Grant and the social dilemma, external interventions could lead miners to commit
Thompson, 1997). This literature includes models developed to analyze themselves to socially responsible mining practices. Moreover, experi-
the management of natural resources that entails social dilemmas mental evidence shows that decision makers with more awareness
(Castillo and Saysel, 2005; Touza et al., 2013), and to support the design of interdependence in the dilemma (interdependence information)
of policies focused on ASGM (Andriamasinoro and Angel, 2012). Based can increase cooperation (see, e.g., Gonzalez et al., 2014). Economic
on Ostrom's (1998) theory of collective action in social dilemmas and incentives that alter the private benets the individuals earn from the
analogous to Castillo and Saysel's (2005) approach, in this paper we recovery process also work in this direction.
propose a behavioral simulation model to explain why communities en- We observe the importance of education and capacitation. In the eco-
gaged in ASGM often fail to establish a sustained association in the gold nomic experiments, university students performed better than miners. In
recovery process. Features such as reciprocity and temptation to free general, students achieved more efcient outcomes than miners did (see
ride partially explain this failure. Nonetheless, our simulations reveal Saldarriaga-Isaza, 2013). From simulation results, we argue that a possible
that, where they are involved, sustained collective action is feasible explanation of this behavioral discrepancy is found in the differences in
when miners increase their understanding of their social dilemma. education levels. Better skills enable the individual to understand particu-
The better understanding can be gained, for instance, with education lar situations better, in this case of the game, and estimate the conse-
campaigns and interventions that foster social capital through the im- quences of their actions when considered together with others' actions.
provement of the channels of communication. Finally, in this paper we showed the usefulness that simulation
We are aiming to contribute to the understanding of social dilemmas models can have in the design and support of policies targeted at
faced by users of natural resources. For the specic case of ASGM, natural-resource-based communities, thereby adding to the existing liter-
our paper goes beyond the analysis with visual models done, so far, ature (see, e.g., Castillo and Saysel, 2005; Andriamasinoro and Angel,
by scholars such as Heemskerk (2001), Hilson and Pardie (2006) and 2012). In ASGM, further applications could be in the analysis of other
Spiegel (2009). Through a simulation model, we explored how an institu- aspects that explain, or mechanisms to address, poverty-traps in this sec-
tional arrangement inuences associative entrepreneurship among tor. Besides the technology trap that has been analyzed in this paper,
artisanal gold miners in a manner that improves the well-being of these other social and economic components that call for analysis are the deci-
communities. sions that entail low levels of education, and of savings. Moreover, simu-
The design of effective policies to address environmental problems re- lation methods and experimental economics are potential tools to be
quires the setting up of interventions that consider the peculiarities of jointly employed in the design of mechanisms, including economic incen-
each problem, as well as the kind of pro-environmental behavior that pol- tives, to overcome mercury pollution and change certain behavioral pat-
icy makers wish to induce (Osbaldiston and Schott, 2012). In fact, for sit- terns that are welfare-reducing in ASGM.
uations in which individuals must cope with a social dilemma, several
scholars have highlighted the positive effects that face-to-face communi-
cation has on collective action (see, e.g., Ledyard, 1995; Ostrom, 2010). Acknowledgments
Nonetheless, weak communication channels may actually prevent the
self-organization or collective action that might otherwise emerge as a so- We acknowledge the nancial support from Universidad Nacional
lution to those social dilemmas. In those cases, ASGM being one of them, de Colombia to carry out this work. We thank Pablo Londoo for his
external intervention is needed. For the specic case of ASGM, we show very helpful and efcient research assistance. We are grateful to Yris
that external parties (governments, NGOs, etc.) have a key role by pro- Olaya and two anonymous referees for their insightful and constructive
moting programs that improve the miners' understanding of their social for comments.
A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109 107

Appendix A

Function Individual Contributions

High Willingness to Cooperate


1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0 0.5 1 1.5 2
Trust in them

Low Willingness to Cooperate


1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0 0.5 1 1.5 2
Trust in them

Medium Willingness to Cooperate


1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0 0.5 1 1.5 2
Trust in them

Common Willingness to Cooperate


1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0 0.5 1 1.5 2
Trust in them

Fig. A.1. Sensitivity analysis of willingness to cooperate function and trust.


108 A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109

Concave function Convex function


1.6 1.6

1.4 1.4

1.2 1.2

1 1

0.8 0.8

0.6 0.6

0.4 0.4
-1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1
(i - T)/T (i - T)/T

Individual Contributions Individual Contributions


20

18

16

14

12

Tokens
10

4
Others Players A & B Others Player A
2

0
01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Period

Group Contributions Group Contributions


80 80
Total Contri buti ons (Tokens )
Total Contri buti ons (Tokens )

70 70

60 60

50 50

01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Period Period

Fig. A.2. Sensitivity analysis of temptation to free ride function.

References Castillo, D., Bousquet, F., Janssen, M.A., Worrapimphong, K., Cardenas, J.C., 2011. Context
matters to explain eld experiments: results from Colombian and Thai shing vil-
Anderies, J., Janssen, M., Bousquet, F., Cardenas, J., Castillo, D., Lopez, M.C., Tobias, R., lages. Ecol. Econ. 70, 16091620.
Vollan, B., Wutich, A., 2011. The challenge of understanding decisions in experimental Chaparro, E., 2003. Small-scale mining, a new entrepreneurial approach. Serie Recursos
studies of common pool resource governance. Ecol. Econ. 70, 15711579. Naturales e Infraestructura 9. CEPAL, Santiago, Chile.
Andriamasinoro, F., Angel, J.-M., 2012. Artisanal and small-scale gold mining in Burkina Chouinard, R., Veiga, M., 2008. Results of the awareness campaign and technology
Faso: suggestion of multi-agent methodology as a complementary support in elabo- demonstration for artisanal gold miners. Summary Report. UNIDO, Vienna.
rating a policy. Resour. Policy 37, 385396. Croson, R., Marks, M., 2000. Step returns in threshold public goods: a meta- and experi-
Barlas, Y., 1996. Formal aspects of model validity and validation in system dynamics. Syst. mental analysis. Exp. Econ. 2 (3), 239259.
Dyn. Rev. 12, 183210. Czap, H.J., Czap, N.V., 2010. An experimental investigation of revealed environmental
Bowles, S., 2004. Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. Princeton Uni- concern. Ecol. Econ. 69, 20332041.
versity Press, Princeton, NJ. Davis, J., Eisenhardt, K., Bingham, C., 2007. Developing theory through simulation
Box, G.E.P., Draper, N.R., 1987. Empirical Model-Building and Response Surfaces. Wiley, UK. methods. Acad. Manag. Rev. 32, 480499.
Cadsby, C., Maynes, E., 1999. Voluntary provision of threshold public goods with continu- Decker, J., 1994. The validation of computer simulations for design guideline dispute
ous contributions: experimental evidence. J. Public Econ. 71, 5373. resolution. Environ. Behav. 26, 421443.
Castillo, D., Saysel, A.K., 2005. Simulation of common pool resource eld experiments: a Dudley, R., 2008. A basis for understanding shery management dynamics. Syst. Dyn. Rev.
behavioral model of collective action. Ecol. Econ. 55, 420436. 24, 129.
A. Saldarriaga-Isaza et al. / Ecological Economics 112 (2015) 98109 109

Fischbacher, U., Gchter, S., 2010. Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free Ostrom, E., 2000. Collective action and the evolution of social norms. J. Econ. Perspect. 14
riding in public good experiments. Am. Econ. Rev. 100, 541556. (3), 137158.
Fischbacher, U., Gchter, S., Fehr, E., 2001. Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence Ostrom, E., 2007. A diagnostic approach for going beyond panaceas. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci.
from a public goods experiment. Econ. Lett. 71, 397404. 104, 1518115187.
Forrester, J.W., Senge, P., 1980. Tests for building condence in system dynamics models. Ostrom, E., 2009. Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Eco-
In: Legasto, A., Forrester, J.W., Lyneis, J. (Eds.), TIMS Studies in Management Sciences nomic Systems. Nobel Prize Lecture (accessed 11/13/2014, http://www.nobelprize.
vol. 14. North Holland, New York, pp. 209228. org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2009/ostrom-lecture.htmlN).
Ghose, M., Roy, S., 2007. Contribution of small-scale mining to employment, development Ostrom, E., 2010. Revising theory in light of experimental ndings. J. Econ. Behav. Organ.
and sustainability an Indian scenario. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 9, 283303. 73, 6872.
Gonzalez, C., Ben-Asher, N., Martin, J., Dutt, V., 2014. A cognitive model of dynamic Prediger, S., Vollan, B., Frlich, M., 2011. The impact of culture and ecology on cooperation
cooperation with varied interdependency information. Cogn. Sci. http://dx.doi.org/ in a common-pool resource experiment. Ecol. Econ. 70, 15991608.
10.1111/cogs.12170. Qudrat-Ullah, H., Seong, B., 2010. How to do structural validity of a system dynamics type
Grant, W.E., Thompson, P.B., 1997. Integrated ecological models: simulation of socio- simulation model: the case of an energy policy model. Energy Policy 38, 22162224.
cultural constraints on ecological dynamics. Ecol. Model. 100, 4359. Saldarriaga-Isaza, A., 2013. The Tragedy of the Commons in Artisanal Gold Mining: Eval-
Heemskerk, M., 2001. Do international commodity prices drive natural resource booms? An uation of Mechanisms of Cooperation with Simulation and Economic Experiments.
empirical analysis of small-scale gold mining in Suriname. Ecol. Econ. 39, 295308. (PhD thesis), Universidad Nacional de Colombia Sede Medelln ([accessed 11/13/
Hilson, G., 2006. Abatement of mercury pollution in the small-scale gold mining industry: 2014, bhttp://www.bdigital.unal.edu.co/10297N]. [accessed 3/3/2011, http://www.
restructuring the policy and research agendas. Sci. Total Environ. 362, 114. nytimes.com/2011/03/04/world/americas/04colombia.htmlS]).
Hilson, G., 2007. What is wrong with the Global Support Facility for small-scale mining? Saldarriaga-Isaza, A., Villegas-Palacio, C., Arango, S., 2013. The public good dilemma of a
Prog. Dev. Stud. 7, 235249. non-renewable common resource: a look at the facts of artisanal gold mining. Resour.
Hilson, G., Pardie, S., 2006. Mercury: an agent of poverty in Ghana's small-scale gold- Policy 38, 224232.
mining sector? Resour. Policy 31, 106116. Sinding, K., 2005. The dynamics of artisanal and small-scale gold mining reform. Nat. Res.
Hinton, J., Veiga, M., Veiga, A., 2003. Clean artisanal gold mining, a utopian approach? Forum 29, 243252.
J. Clean. Prod. 11, 99115. Skatova, A., Ferguson, E., 2013. Individual differences in behavioural inhibition explain
Lange, P.A.M., Joireman, J., Parks, C.D., Van Dick, E., 2013. The psychology of social di- free riding in public good games when punishment is expected but not implemented.
lemmas: a review. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 120, 125141. Behav. Brain Funct. 9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1186/1744-9081-9-3.
Ledyard, J., 1995. Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In: Roth, A., Kagel, J. Spiegel, S., 2009. Socioeconomic dimensions of mercury pollution abatement: engaging
(Eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, artisanal mining communities in Sub-Saharan Africa. Ecol. Econ. 68, 30723083.
pp. 111194. Sterman, J.D., 1989. Modeling managerial behavior: misperceptions of feedback in a dy-
Lokhorst, A.M., Werner, C., Staats, H., van Dijk, E., Gale, J., 2013. Commitment and behavior namic decision making experiment. Manag. Sci. 35, 321339.
change: a meta-analysis and critical review of commitment-making strategies in en- Sterman, J.D., 2000. Business Dynamics: System Thinking and Modeling for a Complex
vironmental research. Environ. Behav. 45, 334. World. Irwin McGraw-Hill, Homewood, IL.
Marks, M., Croson, R., 1998. Alternative rebate rules in the provision of a threshold public Touza, J., Drechslera, M., Smart, J., Termansen, M., 2013. Emergence of cooperative behav-
good: an experimental investigation. J. Public Econ. 67, 195220. iours in the management of mobile ecological resources. Environ. Model Softw. 45,
Morecroft, J., 2007. Strategic Modeling and Business Dynamics. John Wiley & Sons Ltd., 5263.
West Sussex, England. Vzquez, M., Liz, M., Aracil, J., 1996. Knowledge and reality: some conceptual issues in sys-
Moxnes, E., 2004. Misperceptions of basic dynamics: the case of renewable resource man- tem dynamics modeling. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 12, 2137.
agement. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 20, 139162. Zeffane, R., Tipu, S., Ryan, J., 2011. Communication, commitment & trust: exploring the
Osbaldiston, R., Schott, J.P., 2012. Environmental sustainability and behavioral science: meta- triad. Int. J. Bus. Manage. 6, 7787.
analysis of proenvironmental behavior experiments. Environ. Behav. 44 (2), 257299.
Ostrom, E., 1998. A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action.
Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 92, 122.

S-ar putea să vă placă și