Sunteți pe pagina 1din 14

William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 143

Social Determinants
of Productivity:
Demographics,
Human Capital and
Social Diversity
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 144
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 145

Population Aging,
Productivity and
Living Standards
William Scarth
145

THE REVIEW OF ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE AND SOCIAL PROGRESS | 2002


INTRODUCTION In the remainder of this introduction I
describe more fully the basis for the concern

T
he productivity challenge is gaining about aging. Then, in three separate sections,
attention among policy-makers. One I summarize research that focuses on why it
reason for this is that the deficit has is reasonable to argue that our economy pos-
been “defeated.” The new finance minister sesses mechanisms that insulate living stan-
can afford to shift the focus to other initia- dards (at least to some extent) from the
tives that address the same long-run objec- adverse effects of an aging population. In the
tive — to increase the living standards of first section I consider how an aging popula-
Canadians over time. A second reason is the tion affects society’s incentive to invest in
warning issued by demographers. For exam- physical capital accumulation. The focus then
ple, Denton and Spencer (1998) note that shifts to an open-economy setting, where vari-
the rate of growth of per capita GDP is cer- ations in the level of foreign indebtedness are
tain to fall significantly over the coming just as important as changes in the capital
decades unless either the immigration rate stock. Finally, I consider how aging affects
or the productivity growth rate increases investment in human capital. A brief appen-
rather dramatically. It is the aging of dix provides a fuller explanation of some of
Canada’s population that lies behind this the material in the last section.
concern. The purpose of this paper is to eval- Demographers certainly do predict that
uate some of the economic analyses that have there will be dramatic growth in Canada’s
attempted to put the concern about aging elderly dependency ratio — the number of
into perspective. As we shall see, it is possi- individuals over 65 years of age divided by
ble that aging will lead to increases in pro- the number between 15 and 64 years of age.
ductivity growth — even if no policy This ratio will essentially double, from 19.2
initiative is taken. In other words, popula- percent in 1996 to 38.5 percent in 2040. The
tion aging may create both a problem and most common reaction to this development
the solution to that problem. is that, with so few workers trying to support
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 146

William Scarth

so many dependants, it is obvious that our grams for the elderly — despite some savings
living standards will have to fall. Indeed, on other programs. Since adequate health is
many studies (such as a World Bank 1994 needed for people to enjoy consumption
report) have referred to this development as goods, and since an aging population requires
a “crisis.” Other studies (see, e.g., Emery and a shifting of resources away from the produc-
Rongve 1999; Mérette 2002) reach much tion of consumption goods and towards the
more optimistic conclusions, sometimes health sector, there may well be grounds for
referring to the aging-population phenome- concern about average living standards.
non as “much ado about nothing.” How are Despite these estimates, optimists
non-specialists to react when there is such a draw attention to several factors. First, with
dispersion of views in the field? increased life expectancy and growing accept-
First, it should be noted that Canadians ance of flexible working arrangements (such
146 have already experienced an overall dependen- as job sharing), baby boomers may choose to
cy ratio that was just as high as the level to remain in the work force to a more advanced
which overall dependency will rise in the age than their predecessors. In addition,
coming decades. In the 1950s, when the baby Canadian immigration rates may rise. Both
boom generation was too young to work, the of these developments may limit the pre-
youth dependency ratio was extremely high. dicted labour shortage. Second, even if these
But that overall dependency ratio was pulled developments do not occur, and labour does
down by the fact that there were relatively become scarce, that scarcity should cause the
few older Canadians. With the passage of price of labour to rise. After all, with each
time, and given the dramatic drop in birth scarce worker having more capital to work
rates (the so-called baby bust), things have with, her productivity will be higher. The
been in the process of switching. The youth resulting increase in pre-tax wages may make
dependency ratio has been falling while the it possible for governments to tax the gener-
old-age dependency ratio has been rising. The ation that follows the baby boomers more (to
overall dependency ratio fell as the baby cover the extra health and pension costs for
boomers entered their working years, and the boomers) and still leave the young better
now it is rising again as the boomers begin to off. The next section explains how econo-
retire. We managed to cope quite well with mists evaluate this possibility.
the high overall dependency ratio before.
Optimists presume that we can do so again.
Less optimistic individuals stress the AGING, RELATIVE FACTOR PRICES
fact that it costs a lot more to provide health AND INVESTMENT IN
care to the elderly than to provide education CAPITAL
for the young. Numerous studies (such as
Office of the Auditor General of Canada 1998 Economists use models of overlapping
and Robson 2001) have estimated that, when generations to estimate the effects of demo-
the baby boomers retire, Canadian govern- graphic changes on living standards. The sim-
ments will need another 3 percentage points plest framework (Diamond 1965) involves just
of GDP in revenue to finance existing pro- two generations living at any point in time,
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 147

Population Aging, Productivity


and Living Standards

the “young” and the “old.” The young work late the aging population, we need a base for
with the existing stock of capital to produce comparison. Initially, therefore, the model
output, and they decide how much of their economy is in equilibrium, with each genera-
income to consume during their working tion the same size as all the others. Then a larg-
years (and how much to save so that they can er cohort arrives, the baby boomers, so that the
supplement the public pension benefits they economy comprises more young than old for an
will receive in their old age). Saving takes the entire generation. The post-boomer cohort is
form of capital accumulation, and the decision the same size as the pre-boomer cohorts, so
to save is affected by the after-tax return that when the baby boomers become the old gener-
the individual can expect when the capital is ation the model economy goes through condi-
employed during retirement. tions that are designed to be representative of
To derive numerical predictions from what Canadians will confront in the next few
a model of this sort, economists need to spec- decades. What are the results? 147
ify how individuals make their consumption- When the baby boomers are young,
savings choice and how firms make their their large numbers push down both pre-tax
labour-capital choice when producing goods. wages and the tax rates faced by each person.
Household decisions depend on how impa- In most simulations, the former effect domi-
tient people are, how constrained they are in nates the latter, so living standards for this
their attempts to borrow, and how accurate- cohort fall somewhat. The pre-baby boom
ly they can predict future wages and interest generation is better off, however. Since they
rates (the yield on capital). Decisions made own the capital that has become relatively
by firms depend on how easily labour can be scarce when they are old, and since they also
substituted for capital in production process- benefit from lower tax rates, their incomes
es, how rapidly capital depreciates, and the and living standards rise. Overall, consump-
degree of competition among firms. Standard tion of the average person rises by close to 2
practice is to consult the empirical studies on percent. This analysis is consistent with what
all of these issues and, using the results of we observed in Canada from the mid-1970s
those studies as a guide, select representative to the mid-1990s, when baby boomers flood-
parameter values for the model economy. The ed the labour market and contributed to very
model economy is then used to simulate var- slow growth in wages, and older Canadians
ious developments, and numerical estimates enjoyed very high interest income.
of what will occur are calculated. When the baby boomers constitute the
Many economists have constructed model old generation in the model economy, capi-
economies of this sort and reported simulation tal is the relatively abundant factor of pro-
results. I summarize the results of one such study duction, so interest rates fall and wage rates
here, that by Scarth and Souare (2002). This rise. As a result, the old suffer a drop in their
study is relatively easy to understand since it uses living standards, while the young — the
the simplest, baseline version of the overlapping post-boomers — enjoy an increase in con-
model to examine the aging phenomenon. sumption. The model confirms the proposi-
Fortunately, its results are representative of tion that the wages of the young rise more
many of the more involved studies. To simu- than their taxes, so they should welcome the
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 148

William Scarth

aging of the generation that has preceded ification difference such as the existence (or not)
them. Nevertheless, we should not make too of tax-sheltered savings plans.
much of this result, since — considering
both young and old as one group — it turns
out that average living standards fall by AGING AND FOREIGN
about 2 percent. Furthermore, when the baby INDEBTEDNESS
boomers are retired they constitute the
majority of the population and thus have the Other, rather different, versions of the
political power to increase the benefits paid overlapping-generations model support the
to the old. In this way, part of the drop in general conclusion reported above. In some
their living standards can be passed on to the specifications, there are many generations
post-boomer generation. Overall, then, the alive at the same time. Instead of just two
148 main outcome is that average living stan- cohorts, the young and the old, with the
dards fall by about 2 percent. period of analysis covering an entire genera-
This set of results is surprisingly unaf- tion (roughly 30 years), there are dozens of
fected when major changes in the model econ- cohorts co-existing at each point in time
omy are considered: whether households are (with a new cohort born every year). Scarth
liquidity-constrained, whether individuals and Jackson (1998) use this version of the
within the model accurately anticipate demo- model economy to investigate an alternative
graphic changes and their effects, and whether way of increasing the old-age dependency
governments offer favourable tax treatment for ratio. Instead of a temporary, but long, peri-
household saving. This latter issue has been od involving an older population (as dis-
stressed in the literature (especially by Mérette cussed above), they consider a permanent
2002). As the baby boom generation ages, the reduction in the average retirement age. In
RRSP system shifts from being an arrangement this scenario, the aging population occurs
that can limit government revenue (when the because the average person spends a greater
majority of the population is working and portion of her life in retirement. Another
receiving tax breaks by contributing to retire- important feature of this analysis is that it is
ment savings plans) to one that can increase designed to represent a small, open economy.
government revenue (when the majority of the The model economy discussed in the
population is retired and paying tax on the previous section assumes that the ratio of the
income generated by those savings). But the wage rate to the interest rate is determined
model economy has two important features: by the relative scarcity of labour and physi-
both government debt and per capita govern- cal capital. There is no constraint that factor
ment spending are fixed. Thus, when govern- prices bear any relationship to what labour
ment revenue would otherwise be affected by and capital earn elsewhere in the world. For
variations in the proportions of the population this reason, that model is best applied to the
that are paying into and receiving payments entire North American economy. Since the
from their RRSPs, tax rates are adjusted. This Canadian and American old-age dependency
is one of the reasons why the predictions of the ratios are increasing at roughly the same rate,
model economy are unaffected by a major spec- this is a natural application of the model.
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 149

Population Aging, Productivity


and Living Standards

If we want to consider an analysis that its pre-existing foreign debt. Since higher sav-
applies exclusively to Canada, we must recog- ings mean less consumption for a while, there
nize that there are serious limits on how much is “short-term pain.” Eventually, though, with
the factor prices of any one small country can smaller interest-payment obligations to for-
depart from what is observed elsewhere. In the eigners, individuals can consume more and
modern, “globalized” world, capital is very there is “long-term gain.” This gain counter-
mobile internationally. Indeed, many studies acts — at least partially — the drop in living
assume that the option of moving capital standards that occurs when there is less labour
elsewhere makes it impossible for domestic available to produce consumption goods. Living
interest rates to depart, in any lasting way, standards fall by 3 percent if an aging popula-
from the yield available in the rest of the tion occurs in the domestic economy only. The
world. With the most common specification additional 1 percent drop occurs if there is an
for the input-output process, the fact that the equivalent increase in the dependency ratio in 149
interest rate is determined in the rest of the the rest of the world (an event that causes the
world is sufficient to make the wage level of domestic interest rate to fall). Some readers may
the domestic economy determined in the rest find this last outcome surprising, since it is usu-
of the world as well. Within this framework, ally assumed that lower interest rates are “good”
then, it is possible to break the effect of a ris- for the economy.
ing old-age dependency ratio on average liv- It is true that lower borrowing costs make
ing standards into two components, one that it profitable for firms to hire more capital, and
occurs because the domestic population is more capital to work with makes labour more
aging and one that occurs because the popu- productive. But this favourable effect on domes-
lation in the rest of the world is aging. Only tic incomes competes with an unfavourable
the second of these developments changes rel- effect. With lower interest rates, individuals
ative factor prices in the domestic economy. choose to save less. As a result, foreign debt (and
An older population brings down the liv- the associated level of interest-payment obliga-
ing standards, but — as with the simpler, tions) is higher. In short, GDP is higher but the
closed-economy overlapping-generations spec- ratio of GNP to GDP is lower. Since domestic
ification discussed in the previous section — income is GNP, not GDP, this unfavourable
living standards decrease by a smaller percent- effect cannot be ignored. It turns out that the
age than does the labour force. In this setting, unfavourable effect dominates.
the cushion is provided partly by a change in Before ending this section, I touch on
factor prices and partly by a change in the econ- two issues. The first is that aging will affect
omy’s foreign indebtedness. In simulations the economy in ways other than by raising
using Scarth and Jackson’s specification, living the dependency ratio. The second is that
standards are reduced by a little over 4 percent other important developments, such as gov-
if the retirement age falls sufficiently to increase ernment debt reduction, will likely continue
the dependency ratio by what we anticipate for as aging proceeds. Also, we indicate how esti-
the several decades after 2030. Faced with the mates of one-time effects on the level of living
prospect of a longer retirement, individuals save standards can be converted to equivalent
more. As a result, the country pays off some of changes in the productivity growth rate.
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 150

William Scarth

One of the reasons for an aging popula- the poor lose. Thus — as long as the rich and
tion is increasing life expectancy. The models the poor are given equal weight, and the econ-
discussed above have been used to examine this omist’s standard rule for evaluating alternatives,
aspect of aging, and favourable effects have the hypothetical compensation criterion, is
emerged. People who live longer have an applied — the analysis supports the proposi-
increased incentive to save. Individuals acquire tion that lower population growth is “good.”
more capital and achieve lower foreign indebt- So, the lower-population-growth dimen-
edness as a result, and (other things being equal) sion of the aging population is cause for opti-
these developments raise living standards. mism regarding how average living standards
An additional feature of an aging pop- will fare as the population ages. Nevertheless,
ulation is a falling birth rate, since a popula- the incomes of those who are dependent on
tion with a large proportion of old people has government transfers will be squeezed slight-
150 a correspondingly smaller proportion of indi- ly, and income redistribution may become
viduals in the child-bearing phase of life. As increasingly difficult in a global economy
a result, Canada’s population growth rate is where mobile “rich” individuals can escape
expected to fall. taxes that exceed international norms.
According to standard growth theory, Furthermore, since skilled-biased technical
low population growth is associated with high change will likely continue to increase the
living standards — since less of each year’s out- inequality of pre-tax-and-transfer incomes, it
put must be withheld from consumption and would be imprudent to give too much weight
used to provide each worker with an adequate to this consideration. In short, in the face of
supply of capital. There is tension between this rising demands for governments to address
proposition and recent discussions of our aging growing inequality, both within Canada and
population. For example, the Office of the throughout the world, policy-makers may feel
Auditor General of Canada (1998) predicts a constrained to increase immigration rates by
large drop in government revenue (and there- enough to avoid a significant drop in overall
fore in the living standards of those who are population growth.
dependent on government transfers) when There is a big difference between the
lower population growth causes GDP growth model-economy simulations that have been
to fall. Scarth (2001) examines these compet- discussed and Canada’s future economy. The
ing effects using a small, open-economy version simulations assume that the aging population
of a standard growth model — with overlap- is the only shock to hit the economy, but other
ping generations, lifecycle features, and both significant developments will very likely be
forward-looking and liquidity-constrained con- occurring simultaneously as Canada’s popula-
sumers — and finds that the “rich” are better tion ages. One such development is govern-
off with lower population growth (as predicted ment debt reduction. Many studies (such as
by standard theory), while the “poor” are worse Scarth and Jackson) have found that if the fed-
off (as predicted by analysts such as the Auditor eral debt-to-GDP ratio continues its down-
General). The model permits us to calculate the ward trend and reaches its post-war low of
present value of all gains and losses. The con- about 20 percent, we can expect average liv-
clusion is that the rich gain much more than ing standards to increase by some 3 percent.
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 151

Population Aging, Productivity


and Living Standards

This is roughly what is needed to allow AGING AND INVESTMENT IN


Canadians to shift resources from the produc- HUMAN CAPITAL
tion of consumer goods to the provision of
health care for the elderly — a requirement The economic analyses discussed in
that is not included in the simulations. Thus, previous sections have one particularly lim-
the two excluded considerations essentially iting feature. They assume that labour pro-
cancel off one another. Debt reduction can ductivity can be increased only if labour has
give governments just the room their budgets more physical capital with which to work.
need to cope with rising health-care costs. But recent advances in growth theory have
Nevertheless, the mechanisms that insu- stressed the fact that individuals can and do
late living standards from the aging phenome- invest in education and training, so that their
non are still incomplete. We are left with productivity is higher even if they work with
something like a 3 percent reduction in aver- no additional amount of physical capital. If 151
age living standards (since this is the average of labour is expected to be the relatively scarce
the 2 percent estimate discussed in the preced- input as the population ages, we can expect
ing section and the 4 percent estimate discussed that the return to investment in human cap-
in this section, and since all of the simulations ital will rise. Thus, by excluding this option
exclude the two effects that cancel off). for increasing labour productivity, the sim-
We close this section by indicating how ulations have overestimated the threat to our
one-time level effects on the standard of living living standards that is posed by aging. In
can be converted to equivalent rate of growth this section I will attempt to explain how
effects. The following calculation might put economists have tried to estimate the mag-
the finding of a 3 percent one-time reduction nitude of this overestimate.
into a productivity-growth-rate perspective. Unfortunately, the studies that focus on
Growth in real per capita income of 2.1 per- aging and human-capital investment are based
cent per year for 30 years results in a rise in on model economies that are more complicat-
living standards by a factor of 1.865. Growth ed than those discussed above. No study has
at one-tenth of one percentage point less (that applied the simplest version of the human-cap-
is, by 2 percent per year) for the same period ital, endogenous-productivity growth-rate
results in living standards that are higher by model (the textbook model) to the aging-pop-
a factor of 1.811 — an outcome that is 3 per- ulation question. In the appendix, I show how
cent lower than achieved with the higher this can be done; only the essence of the
growth rate. Thus, one way of summarizing approach and the results are described here in
the simulation results is to say that the aging the body of the paper.
population can be expected to reduce the The analysis is an extension of the
annual growth rate in living standards by many-overlapping-generations framework.
one-tenth of one percentage point. Many Households continue to save for their retire-
Canadians may regard this loss as fairly mod- ment; the main difference is that they have
est, especially considering that it will be even two options for investing their savings — in
smaller if it is assumed that immigration rates physical capital and in human capital. There
will not be increased. are two sectors of the economy: the goods-
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 152

William Scarth

producing sector, which produces both con- > An increase in life expectancy. This devel-
sumption goods and physical capital, as before; opment induces competing effects as
and the education sector, which produces well, but the specifics are different. The
knowledge (human capital, which raises each incentive for increased saving is more
individual’s productivity). The education sec- pronounced, so there is, on balance, a
tor uses human capital more intensively in the noticeable increase in the annual pro-
production of knowledge than the manufac- ductivity growth rate — roughly an
turing sector uses human capital in the pro- additional one-tenth of one percentage
duction of goods. In the simplest version of point in the annual growth rate, for an
the analysis, physical capital is not needed at increase in life expectancy of four years.
all in the education sector, so it is employed > A decrease in the population growth rate.
only in the manufacturing sector. It is the fact Just as favourable income-level effects
152 that knowledge is a man-made input in the accompany this dimension of aging in
production process, in this extended analysis, the models that abstract from human
that makes the nation’s productivity growth capital, favourable productivity growth
rate dependent upon both demographic events rate effects accompany it when invest-
and government policy. ment in human capital is highlighted.
The details concerning the structure A drop of one percentage point in
and empirical calibration of this model econ- annual population growth yields an
omy are provided in the appendix. Since we increase of about one-third of one per-
continue to assume that government debt centage point in the annual productiv-
reduction will make room, in government ity growth rate.
budgets, for rising health-care expenditures, Do these results call for a modification
we limit the reported experiments to the fol- of the conclusions reached in the previous sec-
lowing three: tions? In one sense, no modification is required.
> An increase in the old-age dependency ratio. There is additional support for the proposition
Since individuals plan to spend more that the falling-population-growth-rate dimen-
time in retirement, this development sion of an aging population is good news for
induces each person to save more and to average living standards. Nevertheless, there is
re-evaluate how much of her time she still the concern that governments will have
spends in training. These responses at the difficulty meeting the likely rising demand for
individual level have a positive effect on income redistribution in a global setting.
the growth of living standards. However, Since lower population growth hurts those
there is a reduction in aggregate human who are dependent on government transfers
capital, since more individuals are retired, — even though it raises the average income
and this has a negative effect. The simu- level rather dramatically — governments may
lations show that these competing influ- want to override this dimension of the aging
ences almost exactly cancel off. The net population by increasing immigration quotas.
effect on the growth rate of per capita Thus, as argued in the previous section, it is
consumption is positive, but is too small prudent to identify, but not to count on, this
to be relevant. good-news dimension of an aging population.
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 153

Population Aging, Productivity


and Living Standards

Nevertheless, there is one reason why a lower annual consumption by this much. What
modified conclusion is called for. In this analy- would be the payoff? This reallocation is equiv-
sis of human capital, rising life expectancy can alent to society annually buying an equity that
be expected to have a positive effect on a pro- pays a dividend of 10 percent. If the initial
ductivity growth rate that is small, yet large year’s GDP value is unity, the present value of
enough to compensate for the unfavourable the first “equity purchase” is (.01)(.10)(1/(r-n)),
one-time level effect of aging seen in previous where r and n denote the discount rate and the
sections. Overall, then, a rather benign view GDP growth rate respectively. Since this per-
of aging is supported. If it is assumed that manent shift of resources involves the equiva-
policy-makers will adjust immigration rates lent of buying such an equity every year, the
to keep population growth roughly constant, total benefit is (0.1)(.10)(1/(r-n)2). The present
there are likely to be neither large negative nor value of the cost is (.01)(1/(r-n)), so the net one-
large positive effects on growth in productiv- time percentage increase in living standards is 153
ity or in average living standards. If it is (.01)[(.10/(r-n))-1], which equals 0.04 if r=.04
assumed that population growth will fall, we and n=.02.
can expect to see an increase in the growth rate In Canada, public expenditure on educa-
of living standards. tion is about 5 percent of GDP, so an increase
Before concluding this section, it is worth of one percentage point is a significant initia-
considering how we might develop confidence tive. Roughly speaking, the reasoning in the
regarding the finding that a focus on human above paragraph suggests that the net benefit
capital investment does not affect the results is equivalent to a one-time increase in con-
dramatically. This is particularly worthwhile sumption of 4 percent. What increase in the
since there is disagreement on this finding in annual growth rate brings the same one-time
the literature. On the one hand, Devereux and equivalent benefit? If the interest rate is 4 per-
Love’s (1994) simulation results concerning tax cent, the answer is an increase in n from 0.02
changes are consistent with the small effects to 0.02078. I therefore conclude that a signif-
reported here for changes in the dependency icant investment in education can be expect-
ratio. On the other hand, Fougère and ed to generate an increase in the growth rate
Mérette’s (2000) simulations involve large of the economy of about one-thirteenth of one
effects accompanying both demographic and percentage point. It would seem that scepti-
tax changes. A full evaluation of these alter- cism is warranted whenever formal growth
native specifications of training and education models show more than a modest growth-rate
is beyond the scope of this paper. Thus, I pro- effect following from variations in the size of
vide perspective in another way — by consid- the education sector.
ering the following “back of the envelope”
calculations (which are discussed in more
detail in Scarth 2000, 259). CONCLUSIONS
Consider shifting resources away from
current consumption and into education. I have summarized several approaches
Assume that the rate of return on education is used by economists to analyze how an aging
10 percent; a shift of 1 percent of GDP would population might affect the growth rate of per
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 154

William Scarth

capita consumption. I have focused on basic used by firms as additional capital in future
versions of each approach so that non-special- periods. The second sector involves just
ists can better appreciate why there are com- labour; it is the education sector that pro-
peting effects. A second reason for highlighting duces human capital. Individuals are more
the simulation results from several simple productive in the goods sector when they
model economies is so that our comparison of have more human capital. The production
the numerical results can be interpreted as a processes are a Cobb-Douglas function in
bold test of the robustness of some conclusions. the goods sector (with capital’s share equal
It is noteworthy that from this approach a fair- to a) and a linear function in the training
ly general conclusion has emerged. It appears sector. Net of depreciation, the increase in
that the aging population will probably lead human capital equals B times the amount
to rather modest changes in the growth rate of of human capital, H, that is employed in
154 our living standards, and that the net effect that sector. Parameters b, p and f are the
could even be a favourable one. fraction of non-retired individuals who are
employed in the manufacturing sector, the
annual death probability faced by each indi-
APPENDIX vidual and the retirement age. As a result,
the fraction of the population that is work-
To highlight the role of training in the ing in the training sector is (1-b)(1-e-pf).
growth process, I follow Uzawa (1965) and Long-run equilibrium exists when the
Lucas (1988), and focus on a simple model growth rate for all per capita variables is the
economy with two sectors. I start with the same — that is, when per capita consumption,
simplified treatment in Barro and Sala-i- per capita output, per capita physical capital
Martin (1995) and Turnovsky (1995), and and per capita human capital all grow at one
extend it to overlapping generations by using rate, n, which I use to denote the growth rate
Nielsen’s (1994) extension of Blanchard’s in living standards. The model is used to
(1985) analysis of household savings behav- determine how a reduction in the retirement
iour. As long as household utility depends on age, f, an increase in life expectancy (a fall in p)
private consumption and government-pro- and a reduction in the population growth rate,
vided goods in a separable fashion, private z, affect the growth rate in living standards, n.
consumption is proportional to broadly Parameter B indicates the gross yield on
defined wealth (the sum of physical and human capital, since it indicates how much
human capital). The factor of proportionality “output” follows from employing one unit of
is the sum of each individual’s rate of impa- “input” in the training sector. It is assumed
tience, m, and the (constant) probability of that both physical and human capital wear out
death, p. More than one newborn appears to with the passage of time at the same depreci-
replace each individual as she dies, so the ation rate, d. Thus, the net return on human
overall population grows (at rate z). capital is r*=B-d. Equilibrium requires that
One sector uses physical capital and the pre-tax return on physical capital, r, gen-
labour to produce goods, and these goods erate the same net return, r*=r(1-t), where t is
can be either consumed by households or the tax rate. With firms in the manufacturing
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 155

Population Aging, Productivity


and Living Standards

sector hiring physical capital so that its mar- 0.27 and 0.18. Physical capital’s share of out-
ginal product is just equal to its rental cost, put in the manufacturing sector is 0.33; capi-
we have (Y/K)=(r+d)/a, where Y and K denote tal’s depreciation rate is 0.04; the net-of-tax
manufacturing output and physical capital. yield on capital is 6 percent; and the initial
The full-equilibrium version of the growth rate of the population and per capita
human capital accumulation identity is: living standards is 0.02 (n=z=0.02). All other
n+z+d=B(1-b)(1-e-pf) (1) parameter values are determined by the equa-
The physical capital accumulation tions of the model. The numerical results are
identity, when combined with the resource reported in the body of the paper.
constraint (that output equals the sum of pri-
vate consumption, C, government programs
and investment in physical capital), the gov- NOTE
ernment budget constraint (that government 155
spending equals tY), and the (Y/K) expres- Without implication, I thank participants at the
CSLS-IRPP workshop, in particular Marcel Mérette,
sion given above, implies: Andrew Sharpe, Daniel Schwanen, and Malick Souare
z+x+n-d(1-t)(1-a)/a=r*/a (2) for helpful comments. Also, the able research
assistance of Krishna Sen Gupta and financial
where x=C/K. Finally, as derived in Nielsen support from the SEDAP research program are
(1994), the full-equilibrium version of the gratefully acknowledged.
consumption function is
n=r*-m-[(p+z)(p+m)]/x+q(Y/K)/x (3)
where REFERENCES
q=[p(p+m)(1-a)(1-t)(1-e-r*f)]/[r*(e pf -1)] (4)
Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth.
The total differential of these four equa-
New York: McGraw-Hill.
tions, along with the definitions of r, r* and the Blanchard, O. 1985. “Debt, Deficits, and Finite Horizons.”
expression for (Y/K) given in the previous Journal of Political Economy 93(2):223-247.
paragraph, are used to determine the changes Denton, F., and B. Spencer. 1998. “Population, Labour
in n, x, r, r*, b, q and Y/K that result when Force and Long-Term Economic Growth.” Policy
Options: 19(1): 3-9.
changes in life expectancy (1/p), the population
Devereux, M., and D. Love. 1994. “The Effects of Factor
growth rate (z) and the retirement age (f ) are Taxation in a Two-Sector Model of Economic
specified. Growth.” Canadian Journal of Economics 27(3):509-536.
The model ensures that the discussion of Diamond, P. 1965. “National Debt in a Neoclassical
these issues is internally consistent. While it is Growth Model.” American Economic Review
55(5):1126-1150.
deliberately simplified, the model can be used
Emery, H., and I. Rongve. 1999. “Much Ado About
to illustrate the quantitative effects of these Nothing? Demographic Bulges, the Productivity
developments. For this purpose, representative Puzzle, and CPP Reform.” Contemporary Economic
Policy 17:68-78.
parameter values that are suitable if each peri-
Fougère, M., and M. Mérette. 2000. “Population Aging,
od is interpreted as one year have been select- Intergenerational Equity and Growth: An Analysis
ed. The initial values for private consumption, With an Endogenous Growth Overlapping
government spending and investment in phys- Generations Model.” In Using Dynamic General
Equilibrium Models for Policy Analysis, ed. G.
ical capital (as proportions of measured [manu- Harrison, S. Jensen, L. Pedersen and T. Rutherford.
factured goods] output) are assumed to be 0.55, Amsterdam: North Holland.
William Scarth text 11/27/02 2:17 PM Page 156

William Scarth

Lucas, R. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Development ——. 2001. “Population Growth and Average Living
Planning.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22(1):3-42. Standards.” (mimeo).
Mérette, M. 2002. “The Bright Side: A Positive View on Scarth, W., and H. Jackson. 1998. “The Target Debt-to-GDP
the Economics of Aging.” Choices 8(1). Montreal: Ratio: How Big Should It Be? And How Quickly Should
Institute for Research on Public Policy. We Approach It?” In Fiscal Targets and Economic Growth,
Nielsen, S. 1994. “Social Security and Foreign ed. T. Courchene and T. Wilson. Kingston, ON: John
Indebtedness in a Small Open Economy.” Open Deutsch Institute for the Study of Economic Policy.
Economies Review 5:47-63. Scarth, W., and M. Souare. 2002. “Baby-Boom Aging and
Office of the Auditor General of Canada. 1998. Average Living Standards.” SEDAP Research Paper
“Population Aging and Information for Parliament: No. 68. Hamilton, ON: SEDAP (Social and
Understanding the Choices.” Report of the Auditor Economic Dimensions of an Aging Population),
General to the House of Commons – 1998. Available at McMaster University.
www.oag-bvg.gc.ca/domino/reports.nsf/html/ Turnovsky, S. 1995. Methods of Macroeconomic Dynamics.
98menu_e.html Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Robson, W.B.P. 2001. “Will the Baby Boomers Bust the Uzawa, H. 1965. “Optimal Technical Change in an
156 Health Budget? Demographic Change and Health Aggregative Model of Economic Growth.”
Care Financing Reform.” Commentary no. 148. International Economic Review 6:18-31.
Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute. World Bank. 1994. Averting the Old Age Crisis: Policies to
Scarth, W. 2000. Economics: The Essentials. Toronto: Protect the Old and Promote Growth. Oxford: Oxford
Harcourt. University Press.

S-ar putea să vă placă și