Sunteți pe pagina 1din 13

by W. V.

Harlow

Asset Allocation in a Downside-Risk


Framework
A downside-risk approachto investmentdecisionsuses intuitivemeasuresof riskthatfocus
on returndispersionsbelowa specifiedtargetor benchmark return.Downside-risk measures
areattractivenot only becausetheyareconsistentwith investors'perceptionof risk,butalso
becausethe theoreticalassumptionsrequiredto justify theiruse are very simple. Equally
important,a numberof well known risk measures,including the traditionalvariance
(standarddeviation)measure,are special cases of the downside-riskapproach.Asset
allocationin a downside-risk
framework thereforedeterminesan investmentopportunityset
for downside-averse investorsthatis at leastas efficientas thatderivedusing conventional
techniques.
A set of internationalasset allocationexamplesdemonstratesthe benefits of the
downside-risk framework.Specifically,optimizationsbasedon downsidemeasuresproduce
portfoliostrategieswith realizedreturnsthat haveless downsideriskexposurethan those
determinedusing variance.Thusinvestorsaverseto below-target returndispersionsachieve
a more attractiverisk-returntradeoffwithin this framework.Moreover,in the asset
allocationexamplesconsidered,the downside-risk approachproducesa significantlyhigher
averagebondallocationrelativeto stocks. This differencein asset compositionincreases
downsideprotectionwhileofferingthe sameor a greaterlevelof expectedreturn.

C ENTRAL
TOMODERNportfoliotheory overall magnitude of a loss, should one occur.
is the premise that investment decisions These seemingly disparate notions of risk, as
are made to achieve an optimal risk/ well as other possible definitions, serve as a
return tradeofffrom the availableopportunities. reminder that simple return variance (or stan-
In order to meet this objective, the portfolio dard deviation)-the traditional measure of
manager must first evaluate capital market in- risk-is sometimes deficient for dealing with the
formationand quantify ex antemeasures of both rich set of portfolio objectives and constraints
risk and expected return for the appropriateset that investment managers often formulate.
of assets. The next task is to isolate those This articlediscusses and demonstratesa gen-
combinations of assets that are the most "effi- eral approach to asset allocationbased on defi-
cient," in the sense of providing the lowest level nitions of risk that are attractivealternatives to
of risk for a desired level of expected return, and variance.1These alternativesall capture the ap-
then to select one combinationthat is consistent pealing notion of "downside risk" and provide
with the risk tolerance of the investor. a more robust approach to portfolio optimiza-
While the principle of identifying portfolios tion. Using an asymmetric measure of risk that
with the requiredrisk and return characteristics focuses on the returns below a specified target
is certainly clear, the appropriate definition of or benchmark return level, this framework in-
risk is more ambiguous. One manager might cludes as special cases such well known mea-
view risk as the probability of shortfall below sures as the probability of loss, expected loss
some benchmark level of return, for example,
while another may be more sensitive to the 1. Footnotes appear at end of article.

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 O 28

The CFA Institute


is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve, and extend access to
Financial Analysts Journal ®
www.jstor.org
mean-variancemeasures in the sense that the
Glossary selected portfolioshave less downside exposure
Asymmetric Measure of Risk: Any measure of
risk that focuses on a portion of the return
than those determined using variance. Thus
distributionratherthan the spread or dispersion investors averse to below-target return disper-
of the overall distribution. Downside-risk mea- sions achieve a more attractive risk/return
sures are asymmetric and isolate return devia- tradeoffwith a downside-riskframework.More-
tions in the left tail of the distributionthat fall over, in the asset allocation examples consid-
below a specified target rate. ered, the downside-risk approach produces a
Semivariance:An asymmetricmeasure of risk that significantly higher average bond allocation
focuses on squared return deviations below the than a traditional approach. This difference in
mean of the distribution.Targetsemivarianceis asset composition increases downside protec-
a similar but more general measure in which tion while offeringthe same or a greaterlevel of
return dispersions are considered below any
expected return.
arbitrarytarget or benchmarklevel of return.
Target Shortfall: A concept of downside risk that
In view of its appealing theoreticaland intui-
captures the severity of not achieving some tive features, the downside-risk framework
minimum target or benchmarkreturn. The tar- should provide a useful set of tools for portfolio
get shortfall represents the expected deviation managers considering a broad set of problems.
of returns falling below the target rate. Perhapsequally important,this approachcan be
Mean-VarianceFormulation:The traditionalfor- implemented in a manner similar to the stan-
mulation of the investment decision problem, dard asset allocation procedures currently in
stated in terms of the expected mean returnand place, with little added complexity.
variance of a portfolio of assets. In order to
achieve the most efficient portfolio, assets are Investment Risk
combined so as to minimize variancefor a given In his seminal contributionto modern portfolio
level of return.
Downside-Risk Optimization:An alternativefor-
theory, Harry M. Markowitz pointed out that
mulation of the investor's decision problem us- investors could reduce the overall risk of their
ing a downside measure of risk as opposed to investments by forming well diversified portfo-
the variance or standard deviation of asset re- lios.3 As a part of his analysis, he considered
turns. Thus, instead of minimizing variancefor various alternativerisk measures in addition to
a given level of return, a downside measure variance and concluded that the most theoreti-
such as target semivarianceis minimized. cally robust measure was semivariance (i.e., the
expected value of the squared negative devia-
tions about a specified "target"rate of return).
and semivariance.2 It also includes the tradi- Semivariance captures the notion of down-
tional variance measure as a special case, thus side risk and is an appropriatecharacterization
ensuring that the downside-risk approach de- of investment risk because investors are often
termines an efficient frontier for a downside- concerned about losses relative to a threshold
averse investor that is at least as optimal as that return level. It is important to note that, unlike
derived using existing techniques. the variance measure, semivariance does not
Although the concept of downside risk is increase with greater "upside potential." Up-
older than modern portfolio theory itself, the side potential is, rather, captured by the mean
theoretical development and extensions of this of the return distribution.
risk framework are relatively recent. Unfortu- Because of purported computational prob-
nately, empiricalinvestigations of this approach lems associated with calculating the semivari-
within the context of asset allocation remain ance statistic, Markowitz adopted variance as
somewhat limited. To obviate this deficiency, the risk measure in his analyses. As a result,
the present study examines the downside-risk much of the initial research in finance focused
frameworkby considering an internationalasset on the issues surrounding a simpler mean-
allocation example across 11 countries, using variance framework. Unfortunately, the theo-
returns that span the last decade. In addition, it retical assumptions necessary to support vari-
compares the downside-risk results with those ance as a risk measure (discussed below) are
derived using the mean-varianceapproach. somewhat restrictive.Moreover, varianceis not
We find that empiricaloptimizationsbased on consistent with investors' actual perception of
downside measures are more efficient than risk.

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 I 29


Figure A Downside Riskfor a TargetRateof Returnof 6 Per Cent

0% 6% 15%
Target Mean

As researchersin finance, economics and psy- where pp is the probability that return, Rp,
chology have noted over the past three decades, occurs.6The type of "moment," n, specified in
individuals view return dispersion in an asym- Equation (1) captures an investor's preferences
metric manner;that is, losses weigh more heav- by determining the manner in which the return
ily than gains.4 The examples of risk mentioned dispersion below the target is characterized.7
earlier-the probabilityof shortfall below some Figure A depicts a normal distributionwith a
benchmark level of return and the expected mean of 15 per cent and a standarddeviation of
magnitude of a loss-typify the concerns of 10 per cent. For a target rate of 6 per cent, the
portfolio managers. While these measures differ applicabledownside portion of the distribution
significantly,they both capturesome element of is representedby the shaded area. Forn = 0, the
downside risk. We focus our attentionon down- risk measure becomes a Oth-ordermoment (de-
side-risk measures in order to alleviate some of noted LPMO),with the term in brackets being
the shortcomings of variance and establish a
raised to the 0th power (i.e., equal to 1). Hence
more general approach to asset allocation.
the measure is simply the probabilityof falling
below the target rate. For this particularcase,
Downside-Risk Measures
Several classes of downside-risk measures are LPMoequals 0.184. In other words, there is an
18.4 per cent chance that the return perfor-
of particularinterest in finance. All involve the
tail of the relevant distributionof returns below mance will fall short of the desired minimum
some specific threshold level or target rate. level signified by the target rate.
These risk measures are referred to as "lower Forhigher-ordermoments, the shaded areain
partialmoments" (LPMs),because only the left- Figure A remains pertinent for the risk calcula-
hand tail of the returndistributionis used in the tion. However, for n = 1, LPM1becomes the
calculation.5 expected deviation of returns below the target,
Computationally, the LPM for an empirical or the target shortfall.8 LPM1for this example
(discrete) distribution of portfolio returns, Rp, equals 1.01 per cent. For n = 2, LPM2is analo-
with a target rate, i, is described by: goits to variance, in that it is a probability
weighting of squared deviations. Rather than
T computed around the mean of the distribution,
LPMn = > pp(t - Rp (1) however, the deviations are determined with
Ro = - xc respect to the target rate. LPM2 can thus be

1991El 30
FINANCIALANALYSTSJOURNAL/ SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER
referred to as a target semivariance. In our of portfolio optimization. The objective within
example, this measure equals 9.38 (or a 3.06 per this frameworkis essentially the same as in any
cent target semideviation, using the square root approach-i.e., select a portfolio of assets in
of the LPM2measure). some combinationso as to minimize risk subject
Many popular notions of risk are special cases to a specified level of expected return. In this
of the generalized LPMnmeasure. For example, case, however, LPMnis used as the appropriate
with n = 0 and a target rate equal to 0 per cent, characterizationof risk.
LPMois simply the probabilityof a loss. For n = Figure B illustrates this decision problem
2 and a target rate equal to the mean of the graphically.If Rp*is the investor's desired level
distribution, LPM2 becomes the traditional of return, then P* represents the portfolio that
semivariance measure. Furthermore, for nor- provides the lowest risk. For alternativevalues
mal, or symmetric, distributions, LPM2is ex- of Rp*,the resulting set of solutions trace out a
actly proportional to variance [LPM2(r = R) is convex mean-LPMnefficient frontier (denoted
equal to one-half of variance]. Using it as a risk MLPMn), reflecting the optimal risk/return
measure would be equivalent to using variance tradeoffs in exactly the same manner as the
and result in the same ordering of risky assets. traditionalmean-varianceapproach.
While the LPMnmeasure of risk has obvious Stated more formally, an investor who is
intuitive appeal, it is important to consider the averse to downside risk and who has a target
economic justificationfor its use and the general rate of return, r, must determine the allocation
conditions under which it is appropriate. The weight, Xj, for each relevant asset, j, to achieve
distinction between this framework and the an efficient point within the investment oppor-
traditional mean-variance approach lies in the tunity set. The nonlinear MLPMn optimization
assumptions regarding the distributionalprop- problem is represented by:
erties of returns and investor preferences. As
Select X to minimize: LPMn(T;X)
mentioned earlier, the use of variance as a
measure of risk requires a somewhat restrictive T

set of assumptions. Specifically, either returns = E


Pp(T - Rp)n (2)
must be normally distributed, or investors have Rp< T
to exhibit behavior describable by a quadratic
utility function.9 Within the LPMnframework, Subjectto: n = 1 or 2
distributions can be any one of a class charac-
{f;XPE(Rj)= Rp*}and
terized by a location and scale parameter(e.g.,
mean and standard deviation).10 In addition, {EjXj= 1, Xj > 0} without short sales or
the downside-risk framework makes only gen-
{NjXj= 1} with short sales,
eral assumptions regardinginvestor utility func-
tions (e.g., risk aversion and skewness prefer- where pp is the probabilityof portfolio return,
ence). Rp*.
The power and flexibilityof the downside-risk Once again, we note that the optimization
frameworkstem from the jointset of its assump- process uses the entire distribution of returns.
tions regarding investor preferences and asset Information contained in the right tail of the
return distributions. Unlike other frameworks, distribution (the returns above the target) does
which place restrictions on preferences or on not contribute to risk, but it is captured in the
distributions, the LPMnapproach uses a com- mean of the distribution.Thus, all things being
bined set of reasonable and less restrictive as- equal, two distributions with the same LPMn
sumptions. As a result, downside-risk analysis but differentmeans are not the same. In such a
is not only more attractivein terms of its con- case, the distributionwith the higher mean has
sistency with the way investors actually per- a greater degree of positive skewness.
ceive risk, but it is also valid under a broader One necessary restrictionon the optimization
range of conditions. in Equation (2) is that LPMn must be of first
order or higher (i.e., n must be greater than
Portfolio Optimization in a Downside- zero) if any form of risk aversion is to be
Risk Framework considered relevant in the decision-makingpro-
Having established a formaldefinition of down- cess. The probabilityof target shortfall, there-
side risk, we now consider its use in the context fore, cannot be used for the general purpose of

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 O 31


Figure B Downside-Risk(MLPMn)EfficientFrontier

E(R)
MLPMn Efficient Frontier

Rp* /

LPMn (Rp*;Target) LPMn

portfolio construction. The primary reason for target, thus establishing a level of aversion to
this is that the LPMomeasure does not differ- below-target exposure. This constraint inter-
entially weight the returns in the lower tail of sects or is tangent to the efficient frontier, indi-
the distributionbased on their "distance"from cating which portfolios are attractive to the
the target. In other words, the shortfall proba- investor. The probability of target shortfall,
bility is an incomplete measure of risk, because therefore, can be thought of as a risk-tolerance
it fails to provide any indication of how severe assessment tool when coupled with another
the shortfallwill be, should it occur. As such, it measure of risk. This is true whether the mea-
is inappropriateto use this measure directly to sure is variance or a downside-risk criterion
define an efficient frontier.11 such as LPM1or LPM2.
Note that, while the probability of target The appeal of the downside-risk frameworkis
shortfallis not a complete measure of risk, it can certainlynot diminished because target shortfall
be incorporated into the asset allocation deci- probabilitiescannot be used directly as a risk
sion. Specifically, LPMo provides a means of measure in a portfolio optimization problem.
isolating the segment of the investment oppor- Indeed, beyond LPMO,there exists a very large
tunity set most relevant to the investor. As class of theoreticallyattractiveand flexible risk
Leibowitz, Henriksson and Kogelman have measures. LPM1 (target shortfall) and LPM2
shown, the shortfallprobabilitycan be specified (targetsemivariance)provide an intuitive set of
as a constraint in a portfolio optimization prob- risk definitions that are more useful than tradi-
lem that utilizes some other measure of risk- tional approachesand are valid under a broader
for example, variance-to delineate the efficient set of economic conditions.
frontier.12This shortfall restriction essentially
provides information regarding the risk toler- Downside-Risk Optimization
ance of the investor. To appreciate the downside-risk framework
For the mean-variance formulation of Equa- more fully, it is useful to examine its implemen-
tion (2), the shortfall constraintis equivalent to tation under alternative formulations. As with
an upward-sloping line in Figure B, with an any asset allocation decision, the analysis can
intercept on the return axis representing the proceed in a variety of ways, based on the
investor's target rate and a slope tied to the manner in which informational inputs are de-
probability of falling below the target. The in- veloped. In particular,the optimizationproblem
vestor specifies both the probability and the stated in Equation (2) can be solved using ex-

FINANCIALANALYSTSJOURNAL/ SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER
1991 O 32
plicit return forecasts with probabilitiesof real- loss of initialcapitaland thus has a target rate of
ization derived through some independent return, r, equal to 0 per cent. These frontiersare
modeling process. Alternatively, the analysis computed using Equation (3) and 60 months of
can be accomplished using historical data as recent historical return data (i.e., T = 60) to
proxies for ex ante asset behavior. derive estimates of the LPMnrisk measure and
Equation (2) can be modified to utilize histor- expected asset returns. Panel A depicts the
ical returns, as follows: MLPM1(target shortfall)frontier, while Panel B
illustrates the MLPM2frontier using the same
Select X to minimize: LPMn(r;X) target rate of 0 per cent. In the latter case, the
T1 square root of the LPM2risk value is plotted to
provide a measure comparable to percentage
=E (r-R )n (3) return (i.e., target semideviation). Both panels
Rp T-
also indicate the risk and return of a global
Subject to: n=1 or 2 capitalization-weighted benchmark composed
of 60 per cent equity and 40 per cent fixed
{fjXjE(Rj)= Rp*}and income securities, based on the Salomon-
Russell Global Equity Index and the Salomon
11AX= 1, Xj> 0}, BrothersWorld Government Bond Index.13
where T is the number of return observations. In Panel A, the 60/40 benchmark has an
In other words, within the optimization pro- expected return of 13.5 per cent and a target
cess, LPMncan be computed by constructingan shortfall of 9.07 per cent. In other words, be-
empirical portfolio distribution given a set of cause the investor's target rate has been speci-
asset weights, X, and T previously observed fied as 0 per cent, the magnitude of the expected
returns. This value is then minimized subject to probability-weightedloss is 9.07 per cent. By
an expected returnconstraint,Rp*.The expected comparison, an MLPM1efficient portfolio deliv-
return for each asset, E(Rj),is determined using ering the same benchmark expected return of
its historicalmean risk premium in conjunction 13.5 per cent has only a 4.53 per cent expected
with the current risk-free rate of interest, Rfo. target shortfall. In Panel B, which uses target
That is, the asset's excess return at time t, Rjt- semideviation to define the frontier, the risk of
Rft, is first averaged over T observations. This the benchmark is estimated at 23.20 per cent,
value is then added to Rfoto obtain the expected while the risk of the comparable MLPM2effi-
return, so that E(Rj)= [NT (Rjt - Rft)/T] + Rfo. cient portfolio is projected at 12.40 per cent.
Keep in mind that, for purposes of this dis- Figure D indicates the effect that altering the
cussion, we are interested primarilyin evaluat- target rate of return, T, has on the magnitude of
ing the usefulness of an alternative portfolio the estimated risk. For ease of comparison, we
constructiontechnique, as opposed to a method have included the previous frontiers, with tar-
of producing return forecasts. As most asset get rates equal to 0 per cent as well as those
allocationprocedures rely to some extent on the constructed using target rates of 8 and 16 per
information contained in historical returns, the cent. Forthe lattertwo cases, the specificationof
problem formulated in Equation (3) is repre- risk is based on measures of dispersion that
sentative of typical implementationsand is thus capture underperformance relative to higher
the focus of our attention. benchmark target levels of return. While the
We consider a global asset allocationproblem investor with a target return equal to 0 per cent
relevant to many portfolio managers. We in- is concerned with the loss of any principal,
clude fully currency-hedged equity and fixed these higher targets represent the risk of return-
income markets in 11 countries-the United ing less than the risk-freeasset (r = 8%)or less
States, the United Kingdom, Japan, West Ger- than the market portfolio (r = 16%).
many, Switzerland, France, the Netherlands, Inspection of the figures indicates that, as the
Sweden, Australia, Canada and Hong Kong. target rate increases, both the MLPM1 and
The returns used in this analysis span the 11- MLPM2frontiers shift to the right. This occurs
year period from January 1980 to December because more of the distributionof returns falls
1990. below the specified target rate. The downside
Figure C presents actual MLPMn efficient component of returns thereforebecomes larger,
frontiers for an investor who defines risk as any increasing the numerical value of the risk mea-

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 133


Figure C Downside - RiskEfficientFrontiers

Panel A: Target Shortfall (MLPM1) Efficient Frontier


20

MLPM,Frontier
15
8 - (Target=0%)

Benchmark(60/40)

x; 10

5
0 5 10 15

LPM1 Target Shortfall (%)

Panel B: Target Semideviation (MLPM2) Efficient Frontier


20 -

15 MLPM2Frontier
(Target=0%) /
Benchmark(60/40)

a)
a.)
X 10

5 11 11 1 I 1 11 1 11 11il11llll
0 5 10 15 20 25 30

LPM2 Target Semideviation (%)

sure. Accompanying this shift is an increase in for example, the LPM1stock allocation is ap-
the allocation to stocks. This is certainly not an proximately10 per cent higher than that for the
intuitive result;rather,it represents the complex LPM2frontier (42.87 versus 32.83 per cent). In
interactionbetween the portfolio distributionof fact, the relative stock allocations for the LPM1
returns and the target rate of return. optimization are higher for all values of ex-
Another interesting result is that, for a given pected return, with the differences becoming
target rate and expected return, the LPM1and smaller toward each end of the frontiers.
LPM2allocationsdiffersubstantially.For T-equal This disparity highlights the importance of
to 0 per cent and a 15 per cent expected return, risk definition to the asset allocation decision.

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 O 34


Figure D Downside - RiskEfficientFrontiersfor AlternativeTargetRatesof Return

Panel A: Target Shortfall (MLPM1) Efficient Frontier


20
MLPM1EfficientFrontiers

Stocks:42.87%
Bonds:57.13%

154

av / / Stocks:43.72% S
x 10 Bonds:56.28% Bonds:53.59%

Target= 0% Target= 8% Target= 16%

5-
0 5 10 15
LPM1 Target Shortfall (%)

Panel B: Target Semideviation (MLPM2) Efficient Frontier


20 -
MLPM2EfficientFrontiers
Stocks:32.83%
Bonds:67.17%

Q) ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Stocks:
36.73%
Q) 10 ; / / / \ |Bonds: 63.27%
X 10

Target= 0%/ Target= 8% Target= 16% Stocks:35.01%


Bonds:64.99%

5-

5 10 15 20 25 30
LPM2 Target Semideviation (%)

Simply changing the focus of attention from variance setting must be determined empiri-
target shortfall to target semideviation dramati- cally. If return distributions are approximately
cally alters the composition of the investor's normally distributed, then variance is a suffi-
portfolio. Indeed, this choice has a much larger cient measure of risk, and differences between
effect on the allocation decision than the choice the two approaches will be small. But if returns
of a target rate for a specific type of risk mea- are not symmetrically distributed about the
sure. mean, but instead possess some degree of skew-
The actual benefits of the downside-risk ness, then the asset allocation decision reached
framework relative to the traditional mean- within the downside-risk framework can be

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 [ 35


Figure E Comparison of Downside-Risk and Mean-Variance Efficient Frontiers

PanelA: TargetShortfall(MLPM1)EfficientFrontier
20 -
- MLPM2Frontier(Target= 0%) .....*.

_ [ Stocks:32.83%
_ | Bonds:67.17%

Stocks:40.53%
Bonds:59.47%
;x J 10 Mean-Variance
Frontier

5-
5 10 15 20 25 30
LPM2TargetSemideviation(%)

significantly different from that obtained using normally distributed. The fact that they do not
mean-variancerelationships. It is to this poten- indicates the presence of skewness in the his-
tial distinction that we now turn our attention. torical return distribution. The variance risk
measure cannot capture the asymmetry in re-
Downside-Risk vs. Mean-Variance turns relative to the target rate.
Efficient Frontiers Figure E also indicates the stock/bond mix at
To make a fair comparison between the two the 15 per cent expected return level. For this
asset allocation frameworks, we use only the particularset of return data, the asset allocation
LPM2risk measure, because it, like variance, is under the MLPM2decision rule leads to a much
a second-order measure in which deviations higher bond allocation than that using the
from some return level are being squared. Fig- mean-varianceapproach(67.17 versus 59.47 per
ure E compares the MLPM2(r = 0%) efficient cent). The allocationdifferencesdiminish as the
frontier previously discussed with that com- frontiers converge toward each end. But at
puted using variance as the risk measure. (In intermediate return values, the two portfolio
order to display both frontiers on the same construction methodologies can lead to very
graph, we made LPM2 calculations for the differentasset allocation decisions.
mean-variance portfolios.) For both frontiers,
the square roots of the risk measures (i.e., target Downside-Risk vs. Mean-Variance
semideviation and standard deviation) are used Strategies
in order to reflect return-comparableunits. The differences between MLPM2and mean-
It is immediately apparent that the mean- variance portfolios, given a particular set of
variance frontier lies inside the MLPM2oppor- historicaldata, do not necessarily represent dif-
tunity set. Hence the MLPM2 portfolios are ferences in realized portfolio performance.It is
more efficient in that, for the same level of important to investigate the characteristicsof
expected return, they provide more downside these two alternative allocation strategies in
protectionthan those determined using a mean- terms of their ex post returns and risk.
variance decision rule. This holds over the en- To accomplish this task, we constructed port-
tire range of risk/return possibilities, with the folios using both optimization techniques. Be-
largest differences at intermediatevalues. ginning in January 1985, we used return data
Note that these frontierswould coincide if the over the preceding 60 months to develop the
historical returns used to construct them were required inputs. The return objective for both

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 O 36


strategies was the expected return on each of LO0 m w
O C m OC O O !
several global capitalization-weighted bench-
marks (e.g., a portfolio comprising 60 per cent
equity and 40 per cent fixed income securities).
In other words, for the MLPM2portfolio opti- nts O A S o o o t
mization in Equation (3), the expected return in \0 N N t

constraint, R *, was set equal to the global


benchmarkexpected return, and the downside-
risk measure was minimized. For the mean-
~
:3>~ io ~ ecnC,
tn t? cq t, c
variance strategy, the equivalent expected re-
turn constraintwas employed. Once again, only
c sM m m '.C
the LPM2target semideviation was considered s:ttt?N Ln

for purposes of direct comparison with the


mean-varianceapproach. tS-O N n mN p x r
XH
S Ce H~~~~H~H~~NNNen
To be consistent with the earlierexamples, we VCf

arbitrarilyset the target rate, r, equal to 0 per


cent. This represents an investor concerned
with the loss of any portion of initialinvestment 0, m mo nsoo t"Coo \D c

principal. This portfolio constructionprocedure


was applied each month, as the portfolios were
rebalanced over the next 72 months ending in a, nO t cn D ONa, " o
tt O O
t-,-
X
December 1990. In each case, the 60 months of N N s sN N, \0 \0 \?

return data immediately preceding the portfolio


formation month were used for the optimiza-
tions.
Table I summarizes the risk and return char-
acteristics of approximately1600 portfolio opti- 00 00 0 0 0 0 00000 N .C
mizations, using alternative benchmarks rang-
ing from 100 per cent fixed income to 100 per ON oo
tr>
qN
c>a
(3 a,\
en
cq
g

cent equities. It reports for each risk approach H ~ ~~~~~~


4Ua o,
6
t~ o,
a4 6 4 '6 0

the annualized geometric return, average


monthly return,standarddeviation, targetsemi- A t ~~~~U t- 00 0 C- , \c qo N t ?

deviation and minimum monthly return.


Columns (5) and (10) show that the MLPM2
approach outperforms the mean-variance ap- CZ 4o.1oq> Q)
proach in all cases by providing more downside
protection (as measured by smaller realized tar- :> 0! M
noNX~U ._rCN
get semideviation). Furthermore,in 10 of the 11 C E t b u: vo
un DNc t-s as Co<> o @,
cases, the minimum monthly return is smaller
for the downside-risk approach; this provides
an additional confirmationof risk reduction.
g E E AS g N eta t Na, t, 0 cv CDCD
Not only are the MLPM2portfolios less risky,
they also provide larger returns. A comparison
tVX m~~~~M
ooNN CI)9oo oo
NkOO o O

of columns (2) and (7) indicates that the annu-


alized MLPM2return is larger than the mean-
variancereturnfor all sets of portfolios, with the o~~~~~~~\
Q
St ,
t;-~~00
N cq cq O O00
00 a) r--
o" *m enC
c
N
N un
Cl
\C
N ,
Wv
difference ranging from 0.18 per cent (0/100
benchmark)to 1.58 per cent (100/0benchmark).
CZ
The average monthly returns, reported in col- tAn

umns (3) and (8), are also largerfor the MLPM2 S?SSSeE , =<
strategies. The higher ex post results for the \5 -
MLPM2approachappear to be an artifactof the n~~~~~~~~~c
U) m
t._ ,$CN
lower downside exposures of the MLPM2strat-
F
Q~~~4'
_ < s

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 0 37


Figure F Net PerformanceDifferenceBetween Downside-Riskand Mean-VarianceStrategies(1985-1990)

1.75 -
1.50 A
tJ~~~ A
> 1.25 -A
1.00-
A
0.75 -
0.50 - A
0.25 AA A
0.00
-0.25

1.4 -0.50
-0.75 -
-1.00 -
-1.25 -
-1.50
-1.75
-5.0 -4.0 -3.0 -2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0

RiskDifference(%)MLPM2vs MV

egies when compounded over multiple holding fixed income allocation, while column (9) pres-
periods. 4 ents a t-test of this value's significance.
As a separate evaluation of the differences In all cases, the average allocationto bonds is
between the MLPM2and mean-variance deci- higher for the MLPM2approach than for the
sion rules, the last two columns of Table I mean-variancemethodology and is significantly
summarize the below-targetreturns of both sets differentfrom zero. The differences range from
of portfolios. Specifically, column (12) indicates a low of 1.53 per cent (0/100 benchmark) to a
the percentage of times the MLPM2portfolios high of 2.68 per cent (90/10 benchmark). The
outperformed the mean-variance portfolios month-to-month differencesare as large as 9.49
when the latterportfolios returnedless than the per cent (90/10benchmarkin column (11)).
target. For all benchmarks,the MLPM2portfolio The MLPM2 approach's tendency to favor
returns exceed the mean-variancereturns in a bonds is also evident in the large percentage of
majorityof the 72 months. A t-test of this ratio, times in which the MLPM2fixed income alloca-
in column (13), shows that it is significantin six tion exceeds the mean-variance allocation (re-
of the 11 cases. ported in column (12) of the table). This per-
Figure F plots the annualized return differ- centage is in excess of 79 per cent for all
ence for each set of strategiesnoted in TableI, as benchmarks, reaching a high of 90.3 per cent
well as the reduction in target semideviation (20/80 benchmark). A t-test of this ratio, re-
obtained by using the downside-risk optimiza- ported in column (13), shows that it is signifi-
tion. Note that all observations fall in the north- cant for all sets of portfolios.
west quadrantof the figure, indicating the ben- These results, and those in Table I, suggest
efits of risk reduction and return enhancement that asset allocation in a downside-risk frame-
documented previously. work provides an attractive and powerful al-
Table II compares details of the asset mixes ternative to the traditional mean-variance
that generated the results reportedin TableI. In approach. The differences between the down-
particular,columns (2) through (7) indicate the side-risk and mean-variance approaches arise
mean fixed income allocation over the 72 because returns are not strictlynormallydistrib-
months, as well as the minimum and maximum uted. More important, the departuresfrom nor-
bond allocations for both strategies. Column (8) mality in past asset returns appear to contain
shows the average monthly difference in the informationuseful in ex anteportfolio decisions.

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 0 38


r- LO "o CA d H dS m O Ln The use of empirical asset distributions may
en Lf Lf .d
mt unL n Lf) o o) o
thus be beneficial in modeling risk in a down-
side-risk asset allocation framework. While all
~-
A) _q sO fin c O Nm n N C\ N x
these results do not necessarily generalize to
other asset classes or other periods of time, the
0 Aal x tn en czm N crN differences documented here indicate a poten-
tial benefit to be derived by closely examining
the methodology of portfolio construction and
the distributionsof returns used as inputs.
S: _ 00 00 enN00 O) ? CD t N
?,
ON
00 e
o N ao N r- ON LO) CP t Ln.

Conclusions
Downside risk is an intuitive measure of risk,
focusing on the asymmetry of returns about
< Q _
ocr
ec N rs N
oo a\cr o
et "D
\Cs N o oa, c\
ct CD \ N
L
some target level of return. The LPMn, as a
tn d I formal definition of downside risk, further en-
hances the appeal of this approach because of
u
the very simple theoretical assumptions re-
u u u Q
Q v
. U
l
U
q
U
f , U U
00 n 0
U
D
U U
:
.
quired to justify its use. Of equal import, a
broad set of well known risk measures, includ-
ing the traditionalvariance(standarddeviation)
> r ~~~~~~~~~~>
measure, are special cases of the LPMnframe-
work. Asset allocationin a downside-riskframe-
m x a,\ O H N 0 m 'IC N S
work, therefore, determines an investment op-
portunityset for downside-averse investors that
is at least as efficient as that derived using
conventional techniques.
o .E D ~~~~~N ri q \o \ q~o Ln o q More generally, the downside-risk approach
offers the potential for portfolios that are more
attractive than mean-variance portfolios. That
~~~~~~~aN ON ON aN ON (7 C?N x x x 00 o,
is, a downside-risk approach can lower risk
while maintaining or improving upon the level
of expected return offered by mean-variance
approaches.
u
4~~~~~~F t u o .
crtoN C: ooo o t, nH C
Beyond these appealing features, the down-
0 0 00~ ci t- lZ 1D 1D a? Cn tIn 0 b

>
side-risk approachallows the portfoliomanager
to define risk in a way appropriateto the objec-
W: S ~~~~
gC N 6 06 n ei 6 tf f- 0o UQ 14 -
tives and constraints of the portfolio. By being
able to specify a target rate of return and the
manner in which return deviations below this
target are considered, the manager can more
o~~~~~~~~~o
to - Ln 00 cn o, \0a fully appreciate the risk/returntradeoffs avail-
able from a given set of assets.'5 U
X~~~~~~~
C< C4 u6t C;L C;
Q e Wn ~~~N (OHNCN x x x x O O ;s
Footnotes
1. Extensionsof this frameworkto asset pricing are
discussed in W. V. Harlow and R. K. S. Rao,
"Asset Pricingin a GeneralizedMean-LowerPar-
X~~~~~~~~~~6L aL
, r
, 8L >t
tial Moment Framework,"Journalof Financialand
QuantitativeAnalysis, September 1989, and V.
co I t|t% Bawa and E. Lindenberg,"CapitalMarketEqui-
D
libriumin a Mean, Lower PartialMoment Frame-
U

work," Journalof FinancialEconomics,November


1977.
2. An alternativeapproachto returnshortfallrisk is
considered in M. L. Leibowitz and R. D. Hen-

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 [ 39


riksson, "Portfolio Optimization with Shortfall 9. Quadraticutility functions are unappealing, be-
Constraints: A Confidence-Limit Approach to cause they imply increasing absolute risk aver-
Managing Downside Risk," FinancialAnalysts sion. That is, investors with this type of utility
Journal,March/April1989 and M. L. Leibowitz functionrequirehigher risk premiums for a given
and S. Kogelman, "Asset Allocation Under investment as their wealth increases. This is
ShortfallConstraints,"Journalof PortfolioManage- contraryto both intuition and observed investor
ment,Winter 1991. behavior. See G. J. Alexander and J. C. Francis,
3. See H. M. Markowitz, PortfolioSelection(New PortfolioAnalysis(Englewood Cliffs, NJ:Prentice-
York:John Wiley, 1959). Hall, 1986).
4. For a comprehensive survey of the early litera- 10. These distributionsbelong to the two-parameter
ture, see R. Libby and P. Fishburn, "Behavioral location-scalefamilyand include normaldistribu-
Models of Risk Taking in Business Decisions: A
tions, Student t-distributionswith the same de-
Survey and Evaluation," Journalof Accounting
gree of freedom, and stable distributionswith the
Research,Autumn 1977. See also D. Kahneman
and A. Tversky, "ProspectTheory:An Analysis same characteristicexponent and skewness pa-
of Decision under Risk," Econometrica,March rameter (not necessarily zero).
1979. 11. The LPMoefficient frontier is not convex as de-
5. For details on LPM analysis, see V. S. Bawa, picted in Figure B, which makes portfolio selec-
"Optimal Rules for Ordering Uncertain Pros- tion difficult to generalize across a set of risk-
pects," Journalof FinancialEconomics, March1975, averse investors. As noted in footnote 7, the
and V. S. Bawa, "Safety First, Stochastic Domi- LPMorisk measure is consistent with all utility
nance and Optimal Portfolio Choice," Journalof functions for which the first derivativeis positive
Financialand QuantitativeAnalysis,June 1978. (u' > 0), and it makes no assumptions regarding
6. For a continuous distribution with probability the risk aversion of the individual. Thus risk
density function dF(R), the analogous form of aversion can only be captured by using LPMn
Equation(1) is: measures of first order or higher.
12. See Leibowitz and Henriksson, "PortfolioOpti-
rt mization," op. cit. and Leibowitz and Kogelman,
LPMn I!c (T- R)ndF(R).
"Asset Allocation,"op. cit.
7. the
Theoretically, order (n) of the LPMn measure 13. See "Salomon-RussellGlobal Equity Indices: In-
determines the type of utility function, u, consis- dex Construction and Methodology," Salomon
tent with that risk measure. LPMois appropriate BrothersInc, October1990, and "Introducingthe
for investors who prefermore to less wealth (u' > World Government Bond Index," Salomon
0), while LPM1is valid with all risk-aversefunc- BrothersInc, November 1986.
tions (u' > 0 and u" < 0). The LPM2 measure 14. All results are qualitatively identical when the
allows for all risk-averse functions that display October1987stock marketcrash is excluded from
skewness preference(u' > 0, u"< 0 and u"'> 0). the analysis.
8. The target shortfallis not the mean of the returns 15. I thank Keith Brown, Gary Gastineau, John
below the target (the mean of the shaded area in Howe, Stan Kogelman, Marty Leibowitz, Eric
FigureA is 0.099 per cent). Rather,it is the mean Lindenberg, Ramesh Rao and Gary Shkedy for
of the deviations from the target-i.e., T - Rp. their helpful comments.

FINANCIAL ANALYSTS JOURNAL / SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER1991 0 40

S-ar putea să vă placă și