Sunteți pe pagina 1din 20

Strategic Management Journal

Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)


Published online EarlyView 6 October 2016 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2554
Received 11 October 2014; Final revision received 2 May 2016

ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO RECONFIGURATION


FOLLOWING A TECHNOLOGICAL DISCONTINUITY
NAVID ASGARI,1,* KULWANT SINGH,2 and WILL MITCHELL3
1
Gabelli School of Business, Fordham University, New York, New York, U.S.A.
2
NUS Business School, National University of Singapore, Singapore
3
Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto, Toronto, Ontario, Canada

Research summary: We study how technological discontinuities generate first- and second-order
effects on alliance formation and termination, leading to reconfiguration of firms’ alliance
portfolios. Following technological shocks, we argue that firms often seek alliances that provide
new resources while also having incentives to form alliances for reinforced and challenged
resources that complement the new resources. In parallel, alliance terminations, even involving
resources otherwise unaffected by the discontinuity, increase due to limits in firms’ alliance
carrying capacity. We study biopharmaceutical firms between 1990 and 2000, which faced a
technological discontinuity in 1995 in the form of combinatorial chemistry and high-throughput
screening. We improve understanding of how technological discontinuities affect the value of
resources and how firms reconfigure alliance portfolios in response.
Managerial summary: When firms form alliances to gain new resources during technological
discontinuities that disrupt their industry, they cannot consider only the focal new partnerships.
Instead, new alliances create complementarity and substitution pressures that lead to broader
reconfiguration of the firms’ alliance portfolios: (1) complementarity creates incentives to also
form alliances for resources that the technological discontinuity reinforces or challenges in order
to improve the collective value of co-specialized assets; (2) substitution creates incentives to
terminate existing alliances, even if their value is otherwise unaffected by the discontinuity, in
order to create carrying capacity for new alliances. Thus, one new alliance can generate a cascade
of reconfiguration that challenges the balance between the benefits of stability and the need for
change in an alliance portfolio. Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

INTRODUCTION is a set of partnerships that the firm manages


collectively (Hoffmann, 2007; Lavie, 2007; Ozcan
When technological discontinuities disrupt markets and Eisenhardt, 2009; Wassmer, 2010). Yet, adding
(Dosi, 1982; Pavitt, 1998; Tushman and Ander- to an alliance portfolio often creates the need
son, 1986), firms have incentives to form alliances for complementary investments and/or termination
in order to gain access to relevant new resources of existing relationships; to date, we have lim-
(Lavie and Singh, 2012). Such alliances for new ited understanding of the pressures to reconfig-
resources add to a firm’s alliance portfolio, which ure alliance portfolios that arise when firms form
new alliances. This article focuses on how different
forms of changes in the value of resources follow-
Keywords: alliance portfolio reconfiguration; technolog- ing an exogenous technological discontinuity lead
ical discontinuities; firm’s resources; biopharmaceutical to formations and terminations within an alliance
industry portfolio.
*Correspondence to: Navid Asgari, Gabelli School of Business,
45 Columbus Avenue, New York, New York 10023. E-mail: We frame our arguments using studies of
nasgari@fordham.edu technological discontinuities (Dosi, 1982; Pavitt,

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.


Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1063
1998), resource-based theory (Barney, 1991; Helfat (Dosi, 1982; Pavitt, 1998), which Tushman and
et al., 2007; Siggelkow, 2001; Sirmon et al., 2011; Anderson (1986), and Lavie (2006) argue can
Wernerfelt, 1984), and alliance portfolios (Lavie, enhance or destroy the value of resources. Building
2007; Lavie and Singh, 2012; Wassmer, 2010). Our on the idea in resource-based theory that firms
core argument is that technological discontinuities generate value from combining diverse resources
generate first- and second-order incentives for into co-specialized assets (Karim, 2006; Teece,
firms to reconfigure their alliance portfolios. A 1986), it is useful to extend the basic compe-
technological discontinuity is a “technical advance tence enhancing-destroying framework into a
so significant that no increase in scale, efficiency, somewhat more fine-grained set of categories.
or design can make older technologies competitive Table 1 and Figure 1 summarize our typology
with the new technology” (Tushman and Anderson, of five categories based on how technologi-
1986: 441). We argue that technological discon- cal discontinuities affects resource value: new,
tinuities create demand for new resources, while reinforced, unaffected, challenged, and obsolete
having a range of effects on existing resources, resources.
including reinforcing, challenging, leaving unaf- The emergence of combinatorial chemistry for
fected, and obsolescence. Some firms will form drug discovery that arose in the biopharmaceuti-
alliances to access new resources required by the cal industry in the mid-1990s illustrates the tech-
discontinuity. In turn, the new alliances create com- nological discontinuity categories. Combinatorial
plementarity and substitution effects that lead to chemistry involved computer-aided generation of
second-order reconfiguration of the firms’ alliance vast libraries of chemical compounds to iden-
portfolios: (1) complementarity leads to forming tify possible lead candidates for drug develop-
alliances for reinforced and challenged resources ment. These compounds were then tested through
that improve the collective value of firms’ bundle high-throughput screening (Persidis, 1997, 1998;
of co-specialized assets; and (2) substitution leads Thomke and Kuemmerle, 2002).
to terminating otherwise unaffected alliances in Combinatorial chemistry was a major change
order to create carrying capacity for new alliances. from organic synthesis and testing of chemicals.
We test these ideas on a longitudinal sample of New resources: The discontinuity required firms to
285 biopharmaceutical firms with 5,699 alliances develop new resources in the form of information
between 1990 and 2000; the industry experienced technology (IT) and other combinatorial platforms
a technological discontinuity with the emergence and screening tools to facilitate rapid evaluation
of combinatorial chemistry and high-throughput and management of large volumes of complex data.
screening (hereafter, combinatorial chemistry) Without these new resources, firms would not be
in 1995. able to adopt or gain from the new technology. Rein-
We advance conceptual understanding of how forced resources: To gain from the new resources,
firms reconfigure their alliance portfolios in firms also invested in complementary areas such as
response to technological shocks that change the artificial intelligence and mathematical modelling,
nature of competition in their industries. We first which could be applied to instrumentation and
develop a more fine-grained categorization of how robotic testing for rapid screening of compounds.
technological discontinuities affect the value of The discontinuity reinforced the value of such
resources. We then focus on how the changes resources. Challenged resources: The value of
in resource value affect first- and second-order other complementary resources was challenged by
incentives to form and/or terminate alliances, such the technological discontinuity. These resources
that one new alliance can generate a cascade of needed to be transformed through changes to their
reconfiguration. technical or functional bases to co-specialized
assets that support new resources. For example,
traditional bioinformatics resources could not
BACKGROUND
process the vast and complex data for combinato-
rial chemistry methods; nonetheless, firms could
Technological discontinuities and resources
potentially preserve the value of such challenged
Technological discontinuities typically occur resources by investing in improving their capa-
through sudden, major advances in the scien- bilities. Unaffected and obsolete resources: Other
tific or technical fundamentals of technologies resources were unaffected by the discontinuity, and
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
1064 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell
Table 1. Changes in the value of resources following a technological discontinuity

Impact of technological Fit with Tushman and


Type of resource discontinuity on value of resource Anderson (1986)

New: A resource made valuable From zero to positive New competence


in a particular market context
by the discontinuity. The
resource was not required
before the discontinuity, and
therefore, had limited value
in the relevant context,
although it may have existed
in other contexts

Reinforced: A resource whose From positive to more positive as a Competence enhancing


value increases following the complement to the new resource
discontinuity

Challenged: A resource whose From positive to (1) less positive if Toward competence destroying if
value declines following the not transformed, (2) equally or untransformed; toward
discontinuity. This value may even more positive if competence enhancing if
be retrieved through transformed to complement the transformed
transformation new resource This is the major extension of the
competency enhancement-
destruction framework,
highlighting the idea that firm
agency in the form of investment
decisions can shape the nature of
a technological discontinuity

Obsolete: A resource whose From positive to zero Competence destroying


value is reduced to zero
following the discontinuity

Unaffected: A resource that is Remains positive Outside the context of the


unaffected by the technological discontinuity, yet
discontinuity, so that its pre- may be relevant for firm carrying
and post-discontinuity values capacity
are unchanged

therefore, retained their value, while others were governance and operating structures, mitigating
made obsolete. negative reputation, and finding alternate sources
of resources (Gulati and Singh, 1998; Park and
Ungson, 2001). A second constraint arises from
Alliance portfolio reconfiguration
the need to maintain the collective properties of
Despite incentives to form and terminate alliances an alliance portfolio. Firms face the challenge of
in response to changes in the value of resources, forming a new alliance while maintaining needed
alliance portfolio reconfiguration following a legal and operational separation across alliances
technological discontinuity faces three constraints. (Lavie, 2007) and integrating resources across
First, reconfiguration is costly. Forming alliances multiple relationships (Vasudeva and Anand,
requires searching for and evaluating partners, 2011). Third, technological discontinuities create
achieving agreement, managing relationships, uncertainty about the nature and impact of change
and developing alliance-specific assets (Dyer and (Anderson and Tushman, 1990; Milliken, 1987);
Singh, 1998; Reuer and Ariño, 2007; Singh the uncertainty will hinder firms’ decisions about
and Mitchell, 1996; Williamson, 1991). Termi- the need for resources and the need to reconfigure
nation, meanwhile, incurs costs in dismantling the portfolio.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1065

Figure 1. Change in the value of resources following a technological discontinuity.


Notes: V1: value of new resources before the discontinuity. V2: value of new resources after the discontinuity. V3: value
of reinforced resources before the discontinuity. V4: value trajectory of reinforced resources after the discontinuity. V5:
value of unaffected resources before the discontinuity. V6: value of unaffected resources after the discontinuity. V7: value
of challenged resources before the discontinuity. V8: value trajectory of challenged resources after the discontinuity. V9:
value trajectory of challenged resources after the discontinuity, with transformation. V10: value of obsolete resources
before the discontinuity. V11: value of obsolete resources after the discontinuity

Nonetheless, the need for resources will drive evaluate the value of their existing alliances; a sec-
some firms to form new alliances following a ond indirect effect of the discontinuity is to create
technological discontinuity. In doing so, firms substitution among alliances, where the capacity to
have incentives to form alliances for complemen- form alliances requires termination of others.
tary resources while terminating less valuable
alliances to create capacity for new partnerships. Hypothesis 1: alliance formation
Our arguments follow from the idea that firms
manage the collective benefits and costs of their Figure 2 summarizes possible courses of action
partnerships as alliance portfolios, rather than as for a firm facing a technological discontinuity. We
independent ties. argue that many firms that react to the discontinuity
will form alliances for new resources (choice A in
Figure 2), which are particularly attractive during
HYPOTHESES the uncertainty following a discontinuity (Mitchell
and Singh, 1992). We focus on the formation of
Our argument about how technological discontinu- at least one alliance for new resources as a key
ities affect alliance portfolio reconfiguration relies indication of responding to a discontinuity; this
on four conceptual building blocks. (1) Techno- is a sharp, observable event that triggers changes
logical discontinuities create the need for new in a firm’s resource bundle. In contrast, firms
resources; firms that react to a discontinuity by that choose not to react to the discontinuity (B),
introducing new resources into their resource bases possibly because of uncertainty or because they
will often also need to integrate complementary lack the capabilities to react (King and Tucci, 2002;
resources. (2) Some firms will use alliances as their Milliken, 1987; Mitchell, 1991), or use some other
resource sourcing mode; a direct effect of the dis- mode to react, such as acquisitions or internal devel-
continuity is to increase the formation of alliances opment, will not form alliances for new resources
for new resources (other options for responding and will undertake limited alliance portfolio
to a discontinuity, such as acquisitions, fall out- restructuring.
side the scope of our discussion, although we Now consider the incentives for further recon-
address them empirically). (3) Forming alliances for figuration of alliance portfolios of firms that create
new resources often triggers formation of alliances alliances for new resources versus those that do not.
for other resources, including reinforced and chal- Firms that respond to the discontinuity by forming
lenged resources; therefore, an indirect effect of the alliances for new resources will need to decide
discontinuity involves complementary alliance for- whether to transform complementary resources,
mation. (4) Formation of alliances leads firms to including reinforced and challenged resources.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
1066 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell

React to technological
discontinuity?

B: Do not modify resource base or use


A: Modify resource base alternative modes to react
Form at least one alliance for new Do not form alliances for new resources
resources
Little alliance portfolio reconfiguration

A1: A2:
A1a. Reinforced resources: Invest A2a. Reinforced resources: Invest
A1b. Challenged resources: Invest A2b. Challenged resources: Do not invest
A1c. Unaffected resources: May or may A2c. Unaffected resources: May or may
not invest not invest

Figure 2. Alliance decisions following a technological discontinuity

First, consider reinforced resources. Having com- (A2b). Thus, firms that form alliances for new
mitted to developing new resources required by resources will be more likely to form alliances
the discontinuity, these firms are likely to invest for challenged resources relative to firms that
in reinforced resources. Firms that possess the do not form alliances for new resources (A1b
reinforced resources due to previous investments versus B), but with a lesser tendency toward for-
(Barney, 1991; Dierickx and Cool, 1989) will be mation of alliances for reinforced resources (A2b
attractive alliance partners for firms seeking those versus A1b).
resources. We therefore expect firms that form In summary, when firms respond to a dis-
alliances for new resources to be more likely to continuity by forming at least one alliance for
form alliances for reinforced resources (A1a and new resources, they will also tend to form more
A2a) than firms that do not form alliances for new alliances for reinforced resources and for chal-
resources (B). lenged resources relative to firms that do not
Second, consider challenged resources. Firms respond to the discontinuity. In turn, firms that
face a greater dilemma with challenged resources form alliances for new resources are more likely to
as investments are required to transform these form alliances for reinforced than for challenged
resources to their pre-discontinuity value. Nonethe- resources (we do not make predictions about for-
less, some firms that form alliances for new mation of alliances for unaffected resources [A1c
resources will invest in and form alliances for and A2c] because their value is not affected by the
challenged resources (A1b); this will complement discontinuity).
their investments in new and reinforced resources,
while ensuring their resource bases are compatible Hypothesis 1 (complementarity of reinforced and
with and co-specialized to post-discontinuity challenged resources with new resources [H1]):
technology. However, resource constraints together Following a technological discontinuity, firms
with the cost and uncertainty of recovering the that form alliances for new resources will form
value of challenged resources will inhibit oth- more alliances for reinforced (H1a) and chal-
ers from forming alliances for these resources lenged resources (H1b) than firms that do not
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1067
form alliances for new resources, with stronger resources. Because the value of unaffected
impact on alliances for reinforced than for chal- resources is unchanged, firms may continue to use
lenged resources (H1c). these resources. However, carrying capacity limits
may lead firms to terminate alliances for unaffected
resources in order to focus on the alliances for new
Hypotheses 2 and 3: termination of alliances
resources. Again, then, as firms undertake alliances
The second means of portfolio reconfiguration is for new resources, they will be more likely to
termination, which takes place through two mecha- terminate alliances for unaffected resources in
nisms. First, firms can terminate alliances to reflect comparison with termination of alliances for
reduction in the value of particular resources, which reinforced resources.
we term a resource-value mechanism. Second, firms
can drop alliances from their portfolios in order Hypothesis 2 (substitution of challenged and
to reduce the cost of managing multiple alliances, unaffected versus reinforced resources when
which is a carrying-capacity mechanism (Singh and firms form alliances for new resources [H2]):
Mitchell, 1996). Following a technological discontinuity, the
We are particularly interested in the more alliances firms form for new resources,
carrying-capacity mechanism as an incentive the more alliances for challenged (H2a) and
for alliance portfolio reconfiguration. Firms that unaffected resources (H2b) they will terminate
form alliances for new resources face incentives relative to alliances for reinforced resources.
to terminate existing alliances in order to free
carrying capacity within their alliance portfolio. The potential that the resource-value mecha-
The more such new-resource alliances a firm nism will lead firms to form new alliances for
forms, the stronger the incentives to terminate reinforced and/or challenged resources, as com-
other partnerships. The question we are concerned plements to the technological discontinuity, raises
with is the relative incentives to terminate existing a further issue with termination of alliances for
alliances for reinforced, challenged, and unaffected unaffected resources. The new formations create a
resources. carrying-capacity challenge for the alliance portfo-
We start with a base case of reinforced resources. lio. We expect a substitution effect in which the
Since the value of reinforced resources increases more alliances firms form for challenged and rein-
after the discontinuity, firms with existing alliances forced resources, the more alliances they will termi-
for reinforced resources are likely to maintain nate for unaffected resources.
them as complements to their alliances for new
resources (A1a and A2a). Indeed, there may
Hypothesis 3 (substitution of unaffected
well be a positive complementarity effect via the
resources when firms form alliances for
resource-value mechanism, in which the more
reinforced and challenged resources [H3]):
new-resource alliances that a firm forms, the fewer
Following a technological discontinuity, the
existing alliances for reinforced resources that it
more alliances for reinforced resources (H3a)
terminates.
and challenged resources (H3b) that firms form,
For challenged resources, the question of whether
the more alliances for unaffected resources they
to terminate existing alliances is more mixed. Some
will terminate.
firms that undertake alliances for new resources will
also invest in complementary challenged resources
(A1b) and so are unlikely to terminate existing
DATA AND METHODS
alliances for those resources. Other firms, though,
may lack the time or expertise needed to invest in
Empirical setting
transforming challenged resources (A2b) and may
well terminate existing alliances for them. Thus, The setting for this study is the global biophar-
firms that invest in alliances for new resources maceutical industry. The industry experiences
are more likely to terminate existing alliances for high rates of change through frequent scientific
challenged resources than for reinforced resources. discoveries and technological revolutions, some of
Now consider termination of unaffected which strike as technological discontinuities. Firms
resources (A1c and A2c) relative to reinforced commonly use alliance portfolios to address
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
1068 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell
technological and resource challenges in the industry executives as well as through reviews of
industry (Rothaermel and Boeker, 2008; Vassolo, industry and scientific material.
Anand, and Folta, 2004).
As we noted above, the industry experienced a
Data
major technological discontinuity in 1995 through
the introduction of combinatorial chemistry and Our initial sample comprised the 519 firms listed in
high-throughput screening. These technologies the Osiris database between 1990 and 2000 with the
were partly based in IT and robotics, and originated primary NAICS (North American Industrial Clas-
mainly from academic research laboratories; sification System) codes for biopharmaceuticals.
hence, the discontinuity largely emerged exoge- We restricted our analysis to 1990–2000 as this
nously from the biopharmaceutical industry. Firms period was long enough to permit alliance formation
required new resources that differed from those and termination around the discontinuity in 1995.
for traditional chemical and manual processes. We also ended the study period before the human
At the same time, firms relied on conventional genome mapping discontinuity in the early 2000s
bioinformatics and testing resources to develop to avoid confounding effects.
and deal with the new molecular diversity that the We collected alliance data from the Recap
discontinuity produced. Though some firms with database (www.recap.com), a reliable source
experience in conventional methods hesitated to of biopharmaceutical alliance data (Schilling,
shift because of challenges and uncertainty, the 2009). We screened all 519 firms in our initial
potential benefits offset concerns and led many sample to identify those that had at least one
firms to experiment with the new technology in the alliance between 1990 and 2000; incorporating
1990s (Persidis, 1998; Thomke and Kuemmerle, firms without alliances would have biased results
2002). These technologies quickly revolutionized against termination and formation of alliances.
the early stages of the drug discovery process, sub- Some alliances formed before 1990 would have
stantially reducing the cost and time for developing continued and may have influenced the formation
candidates for drugs. A chemist using traditional and termination of ties during the study period.
chemistry could screen four compounds per month, Therefore, we searched the Recap database back to
with average cost of $7,500 per compound; by con- 1986 for alliances formed by the sample firms.
trast, combinatorial chemistry allowed screening of We then screened the ties reported by Recap and
3,300 compounds per month, with average cost of excluded those that were not alliances, but instead
$12 (Persidis, 1997). Hence, combinatorial chem- exchanges of letters of intent, warrants, and other
istry was a technological discontinuity that altered contractual arrangements. We also excluded firms
the value of resources, increasing the value of some that exited the industry before 1995 or entered
resources while reducing the value of others. after this year because they did not experience the
Trends in publication data reported by Thomke technological discontinuity.
and Kuemmerle (2002) suggest that the techno- Our final sample consists of 285 firms with
logical discontinuity centered sharply on 1995. 5,699 alliances, comprising 5,269 formed between
Publication began in 1986 and grew gradually to 1990 and 2000 as well as 430 formed between
163 publications in 1994; publications then jumped 1986 and 1989 that were in existence at the start
drastically to 1,179 in 1995, 1,386 in 1996, and of our study period in 1990. Geographically, the
1,459 in 1997, then fell to 666 in 1998 (Appendix 1 firms were distributed as follows: 75 percent United
in File S1 depicts the trends). The surge in the States, 5 percent United Kingdom, 4 percent Japan,
number of scientific papers on these two technolo- 2 percent Germany, 2 percent Sweden, 2 percent
gies in 1995 is consistent with exponential patterns France, and 10 percent from 14 other countries.
indicating discontinuities reported in studies of Firms remained in the sample throughout the period
technology diffusion (Bass, 1969). According to unless they exited the industry or were acquired; we
Swanson (2002), 1995 marked the first application treated exits and acquisitions as censored cases.
of information systems and computer sciences
to compound library design, an issue of great
Dependent variables
importance for these technologies. Therefore,
we treated 1995 as the year of the technological The dependent variables for Hypothesis 1 are
discontinuity. We confirmed this conclusion with the number of alliances for reinforced resources
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1069
formed (H1a) and the number of alliances for after the acquisition. These alliances constituted
challenged resources formed (H1b). Hypothesis 7.3 percent of our sample.
1c compares the coefficients for these dependent The next step in building the variables was
variables. The dependent variables for Hypoth- to identify how the technological discontinuity
esis 2 are number of alliances for reinforced, affected the value of the resources provided by each
challenged, and unaffected resources terminated. alliance. Recap indicates the primary technological
Hypothesis 2a compares the coefficients for resources exchanged for each alliance, using a
reinforced resources and challenged resources, classification of 53 technology areas. We used the
while Hypothesis 2b compares the coefficients technology areas as indicators of the resources
for reinforced resources and unaffected resources. exchanged in each alliance. Two of these areas
For Hypothesis 3, the dependent variable is the were combinatorial chemistry and high-throughput
number of alliances for unaffected resources screening, which we treated as requiring new
terminated. resources. We consulted industry experts as well
Although Recap reliably reports alliance for- as industry and scientific material on the emer-
mation, it reported termination dates for only gence of combinatorial chemistry to classify each
303 (5.3% of 5,699) alliances during the study of the other 51 technology areas as reinforced,
period (1990–2000) because most firms do not challenged, or unaffected by the discontinuity. We
publicly disclose the termination of alliances did not classify any category as obsolete because
(Schilling, 2009). We performed an extensive Recap continued to report on every category after
search of alliances in our dataset to establish the discontinuity.
whether they continued to exist up to the year We used this categorization and Recap’s alliance
2000. We searched Factiva (www.dowjones.com/ information to classify each alliance as focused
factiva) for press releases using partners’ names on new, reinforced, challenged, or unaffected
and other alliance characteristics. This identified resources. Some alliances exchange more than one
press releases that discussed alliance termination type of resource; we recorded separate alliances
for 433 alliances (7.6%), which we adopted as the for each type exchanged. We computed the various
date of termination. dependent variables by counting the number of
For the remaining alliances, we followed the alliances formed or terminated within each cate-
stream of press releases and recorded the last year gory for each year. Appendix 2 in File S1 lists the
in which there was a press release referring to classifications.
an alliance as its termination year. The process
estimated termination dates for another 1,324
Explanatory variables
(23.2%) alliances between 1990 and 2000. This is
a reasonable approximation of termination because Our treatment indicator for Hypothesis 1 is a
alliances in the biopharmaceutical industry are dummy variable reporting if a firm formed an
closely tracked by media and industry analysts, and alliance for new resources between 1996 and 2000
capital markets are sensitive to alliance announce- to distinguish firms that reacted to the technological
ments (Kale, Dyer, and Singh, 2002). Alliances discontinuity from those that did not. The explana-
are important for biopharmaceutical firms, which tory variable for Hypotheses 2a and 2b is the num-
often provide public updates on their progress. ber of alliances for new resources formed in a year.
This procedure provides a more reliable estimate The explanatory variables for Hypothesis 3 are the
of alliance termination than the common approach number of alliances for reinforced resources formed
of assuming that alliances exist for fixed periods (H3a) and the number of alliances for challenged
of between three and five years. In total, we estab- resources formed (H3b).
lished that 2,060 alliances (36.1% of 5,699) were
terminated during the study period. We treated the
Controls
remaining 3,639 alliances as continuing at the end
of our study period. We addressed three sets of firm-level factors
We used Recap and Factiva to identify mergers that may influence portfolio reconfiguration:
and acquisitions (M&As). For each M&A, we alliance experience (Number of alliances formed
traced the acquired firms’ alliances to establish if before 1995; Alliance familiarity), resources for
they were inherited by the acquirer in the years internal adaptation (Debt-equity ratio; Return
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
1070 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell
Table 2. Control variables

Variable Measure Purpose

Alliance experience: Cumulative number of alliances formed by Notes firms’ propensity to ally and their
Number of alliances each firm from 1986 to 1994, measured likelihood of being accepted as partners
formed before 1995 at the end of each year (Gulati, 1998)

Alliance experience: Alliance familiarityit = Controls the extent to which a firm’s new
Alliance familiarity T=t
∑ alliances were with previous partners,
(familiar partners)iT to indicate preference and lower costs
T=1986 of allying with familiar partners
Familiar partners: Alliances that firm i (Gulati, 1995)
formed in year t with firms it partnered at
least once between 1986 and year t – 1
Alliance familiarity in year t : Cumulative
familiar partners from 1986 to year t

Internal adaptation: Total liabilities/shareholders’ equity Controls organizational slack, which may
Debt-equity ratio allow firms to absorb discontinuities or
buffer their technical core from external
influences (Bourgeois, 1981)

Internal adaptation: Net income/shareholders’ equity Controls firm profitability, which may
Return on equity provide resources for internal
adaptation

Technological resources: Count of technology areas of cooperation Broader resource access may provide
Number of technology for a firm’s current alliances stronger capabilities for exploration and
areas dealing with resource diversity
(Mitchell and Singh, 1992; Sorenson
et al., 2006)

Technological resources: Count data from the U.S. National Institute Controls involvement in drug discovery
Number of clinical trials of Health (NIH) (http://clinicaltrials
.gov/) and Recap, which together
provided clinical trials information from
1960

Technological resources: Annual counts of applications Controls possession of innovation


Number of patents capabilities

Technological resources: R&D expenditure as a proportion of sales Controls innovation capabilities


R&D intensity (Rothaermel and Hill, 2005)
Number of M&As Count of prior acquisitions Acquisitions may substitute for alliances
(Dyer, Kale, and Singh, 2004)
Sales (log) Annual revenue Resource availability
Firm age Years since founding Firm experience (Rothaermel and Boeker,
2008)
Primary NAIC Six-digit level coding Industry segment effects
Country of origin Location of headquarters National specialization

on equity), and technological resources (Number Table 3 presents descriptive statistics. High cor-
of technology areas; Number of clinical trials; relations among the alliance measures reinforce
Number of patents; R&D intensity). We also the argument that firms do not form or terminate
controlled other firm-level factors: Number of alliances independently, but treat them as portfolio
M&As, Firm sales, Firm age, Primary NAIC, decisions. The correlations do not hinder our anal-
and Country of origin. Table 2 describes the ysis because these variables are used in separate
controls. models.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Table 3. Descriptive statistics (N = 1,425)

Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17) (18) (19) (20) (21) (22)

1. Number alliances for new 1


resources formed
2. Number of alliances for 0.28 1
challenged resources formed
3. Number of alliances for 0.4 0.35 1
reinforced resources formed
4. Number of alliances for 0.16 0.26 0.16 1
challenged resources
terminated

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.


5. Number of alliances for 0.27 0.33 0.52 0.35 1
reinforced resources
terminated
6. Number of alliances for 0.28 0.31 0.45 0.24 0.57 1
unaffected resources
terminated
7. Number of alliances formed 0.39 0.3 0.56 0.17 0.5 0.59 1
before 1995
8. Alliance familiarity 0.37 0.21 0.45 0.12 0.29 0.38 0.52 1
9. Debt-equity ratio 0 −0.01 −0.01 0.01 0.03 −0.01 0 −0.01 1
10. Return on equity 0.15 0.08 0.17 0.05 0.09 0.11 0.11 0.1 0.01 1
11. Number of technology areas 0.64 0.49 0.78 0.21 0.52 0.61 0.66 0.56 −0.01 0.16 1
12. Number of clinical trials 0.28 0.28 0.34 0.25 0.46 0.34 0.45 0.42 0 0.11 0.42 1
13. Number of patents 0.49 0.38 0.54 0.22 0.48 0.51 0.62 0.57 0.01 0.16 0.66 0.53 1
14. R&D intensity −0.05 −0.03 −0.05 −0.02 −0.05 −0.06 −0.07 −0.05 −0.01 −0.09 −0.07 −0.03 −0.05 1
15. Number of M&As 0.2 0.2 0.35 0.16 0.28 0.29 0.27 0.25 −0.01 0.11 0.36 0.27 0.33 −0.04 1
16. Sales (log) 0.28 0.21 0.4 0.15 0.34 0.34 0.4 0.29 0.02 0.43 0.42 0.29 0.45 −0.32 0.31 1
17. Firm age 0.21 0.23 0.36 0.1 0.28 0.24 0.3 0.18 0 0.23 0.33 0.18 0.38 −0.08 0.25 0.53 1
18. Familiar and diverse 0.06 0.07 0.06 0.04 0.05 0.07 0.06 0.05 −0.04 0 0.09 0.06 0.07 0 0.06 0 0 1
knowledge recombination
19. Novel and distant knowledge 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.04 0.06 0.05 0.04 −0.03 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.07 −0.06 0.04 0.15 0.26 −0.13 1
recombination
20. Number of reciprocal 0.63 0.4 0.63 0.21 0.47 0.56 0.58 0.52 0 0.15 0.84 0.4 0.6 −0.07 0.34 0.38 0.3 0.06 0.05 1
alliances
21. Number of sequential 0.48 0.42 0.79 0.2 0.51 0.55 0.64 0.53 −0.01 0.17 0.89 0.42 0.62 −0.07 0.4 0.43 0.35 0.08 0.05 0.65 1
alliances
22. Number of pooled alliances 0.06 0.08 0.24 0.06 0.14 0.18 0.19 0.17 0 0.07 0.21 0.1 0.17 −0.02 0.09 0.15 0.19 0 0 0.17 0.22 1
Mean 0.28 0.05 0.7 0.03 0.34 0.65 4.59 0.21 2.21 −52.68 2.72 0.69 8.22 162.1 0.23 9.29 23.58 0.52 0.07 0.7 1.51 0.01
S.D. 0.97 0.31 1.55 0.2 0.9 1.54 7.51 0.6 37.75 99.02 5.09 2.84 34.42 970.08 0.66 3.58 34.24 0.19 0.16 1.53 2.5 0.1
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities

Minimum 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 −171.9 −974.95 0 0 0 0 0 2.3 2 0 0 0 0 0


Maximum 12 6 16 4 11 15 47 7 1013.5 141.33 40 58 203 10076.29 8 17.51 332 0.91 1 12 19 1

All correlations greater than |0.05| are significant (p < 0.05).

Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)


DOI: 10.1002/smj
1071
1072 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell
Methods reinforced [H1a] and challenged [H1b] resources),
measured across two groups (treated versus con-
We use two approaches to test the hypothe-
trolled) and two time periods (post-discontinuity
ses: difference-in-difference (DiD) analysis to
versus pre-discontinuity).
test Hypothesis 1 and two-stage least squares
The control observations are weighted using
fixed-effect models to test Hypotheses 2 and 3. All
kernel-based matching with weights calculated by
independent variables in the two-stage least squares
the following function:
fixed effect models were lagged by one year.
( p −p )
j i
k h
Difference-in-difference models w (i, j) = .
n0 ( )
∑ p −p
Our intent in Hypotheses 1a and 1b is to compare k jh i
firms that responded to the discontinuity by forming j=1
alliances for new resources and those that did not.
We employed difference-in-difference analysis In this function, pi and pj are the propensity scores
using propensity score (Rosenbaum and Rubin, of the treatment and control observations, respec-
1983) and kernel-based matching (Heckman, tively, and h is the bandwidth (we used the default
Ichimura, and Todd, 1998) to compare the control h = 0.06). Appendix 3 in File S1 describes the
group (those that did not form an alliance for new matching process in more detail.
resources) with the treatment group (those that This procedure accounts for differences among
formed one or more alliances for new resources). firms in terms of their pre-discontinuity propensi-
We do not have a shock of the form commonly ties to form alliances for reinforced (H1a) and chal-
employed with DiD analyses. However, the for- lenged (H1b) resources. We used “diff” in Stata for
mation of at least one alliance for new resources this analysis (Villa, 2011). For Hypothesis 1c, we
distinguished firms that reacted to the discontinuity compare the coefficients of interest in Hypotheses
from those that did not; the failure to react may 1a and 1b.
suggest that these firms were not directly affected
by the discontinuity. Differences in the formation
of alliances for reinforced and challenged resources Two-stage least squares models
between firms that formed alliances for new The explanatory variables in Hypotheses 2 and 3
resources and those that did not provide evidence may be influenced by an unobservable variable that
of how the discontinuity affects alliance portfolio may also influence alliance termination, leading to
reconfiguration. We assigned firms to the treatment biased estimates. To address possible endogeneity,
group if they formed at least one alliance for new we employed two-stage least squares fixed-effect
resources between 1996 and 2000, and to the models with estimators that are robust to autocor-
control group otherwise. The treatment and control relation and heteroskedasticity (Newey and West,
groups comprised 82 (28.8%) and 203 (71.2%) 1987), using “xtivreg2” in Stata.
firms. The larger number of firms in the control
group improves matching with the treatment group.
DiD analysis calculates the “average treatment Instrumental variables
effect on the treated” (ATET) for the outcome The independent variables in Hypotheses 2 and 3
variable of interest using the following formula: are the number of alliances formed for different
[ ] types of resources. We used two sets of instruments
1 ∑ treated ∑ control on how firms recombine knowledge (familiar and
ATET = ypost − w (i, j) ypost
n diverse knowledge recombination; novel and dis-
j
[ ] tant knowledge recombination) and on focal firms’
1 ∑ treated ∑ control
task interdependence with their allies (recipro-
− ypre − w (i, j) ypre . cal interdependence; sequential interdependence;
n j pooled interdependence).
Familiar and diverse knowledge recombination
In this formula, Y is the average of the out- used backward patent citations to indicate how
come variable of interest (Number of alliances for firms recombine knowledge. For each patent, we
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1073
calculated the diversity of backward cited classes have any impact on the number of specific types of
j=n
∑ alliances terminated, as termination is mainly driven
2
using the formula 1 − Spj 2
, where Spj is the by the alliance resource-value and carrying capacity
j=1 mechanisms.
proportion of backward citations in patent p that had The second set of instrumental variables proxy
been cited by the firm in the previous five years in how firms exchange resources with their partners,
technology class j. We averaged the measure across which may indicate the propensity and capabil-
all patents firm i applied for in year t to estimate the ity for resource sharing and alliance formation
firm’s propensity to recombine familiar and diverse (Gulati and Singh, 1998), affecting our potentially
knowledge in that year. endogenous independent variables. As our measure
The variable novel and distant knowledge recom- captures how partners share their resources and not
bination was measured as follows: For each patent how interdependent the partners are, consistent with
belonging to a firm, we measured the proportion of the logic of Puranam, Raveendran, and Knudsen
its backward citations to new patents that the firm (2012), these instruments are unlikely to directly
had not cited in the past five years from technology correlate with the determinants of alliance termi-
classes the firm had not filed any patents in over the nation. As we argued above, alliance termination
past five years. We averaged this proportion across is mainly shaped by changes in resource value and
all patents the firm applied for in a year to calculate the number of alliances the focal firm maintains
the extent of this recombination in that year. (carrying capacity). We further confirmed that the
The second set of instrumental variables measure instruments satisfied key statistical criteria, as we
task interdependence between the focal firm and its report below.
portfolio partners: The variables reciprocal interde-
pendence, sequential interdependence, and pooled
interdependence counted the number of alliances RESULTS
within a portfolio characterized by each form of
interdependence, drawing from Thompson (1967). We first estimated a probit selection model for the
We followed Gulati and Singh (1998), who pro- propensity to form alliances for new resources.
posed that the logic for value creation in an alliance This likelihood permits matching firms that did
leads partners to share their resources in certain or did not form alliances for new resources on
ways, which in turn, creates task interdependence. observed covariates, allowing estimation of the
Appendix 4a in File S1 presents our adaptation of effects of alliance formation for new resources on
the Gulati and Singh (1998) value creation logics formation of alliances for reinforced and challenged
and assignments to the three types of interdepen- resources (H1a and H1b). We use the same set of
dencies. We used Recap’s contract descriptions to control variables in the first stage as in our main
define the value creation logic of each alliance, models.
and then assigned each type of contract to a cate- The results reported in Appendix 5 in File S1
gory of interdependence (Appendix 4b in File S1). provide insights about how the discontinuity
If an alliance involved more than one contract affected formation of alliances for new resources.
with different degrees of task interdependence, we Firms are more likely to establish alliances with
assigned the greatest degree of interdependence to familiar partners. Number of patents is significant.
the alliance. We chose these instruments as they are The marginal effect of one more patent was to
likely to correlate with our potentially endogenous increase the probability of establishing at least one
independent variables while not correlating with alliance for new resources by 0.02, a relatively
other determinants of the outcome variable (Angrist small effect for firms with limited patent activity,
and Pischke, 2009). but relevant for established pharmaceutical compa-
The first set of instrumental variables address nies that have extensive patent portfolios. Another
how firms recombine knowledge, an indication of indicator of capabilities, the number of clinical
the tendency to explore and respond to changes in trials, is significant. The marginal effect indicates
the environment, which may signal willingness to that conducting one more clinical trial increases
form alliances for new, challenged, and reinforced the probability of forming at least one alliance for
resources (Vasudeva and Anand, 2011). At the same new resources by 0.32, also a material effect. Most
time, how firms recombine knowledge is unlikely to generally, then, the firms that formed alliances
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
1074 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell
for the new resources were more innovative firms (b = -0.74; p = 0.00). This result is consistent with
and/or firms with relevant partnership experience. complementarity between new and reinforced
Table 4 presents the DiD tests of Hypothesis resources (Arora and Gambardella, 1990). Model
1. Model 1a shows that control and treatment 2, then, shows that forming more alliances for new
groups differed significantly before and after the resources has little effect on terminating alliances
discontinuity. The test of Hypothesis 1a (Model for challenged resources (b = 0.02; p = 0.51). The
1a: b = 0.76; p = 0.00) shows that firms that nonsignificance of this result may reflect the oppos-
form alliances for new resources form 0.76 more ing effects of firms that invest in new resources both
alliances for reinforced resources following the dis- investing (path A1b in Figure 2) and not investing
continuity than before the discontinuity, relative to (A2b) in challenged resources, which will impact
firms that do not form alliances for new resources. termination of alliances for these resources.
This supports Hypothesis 1a. Hypothesis 2a proposes that firms will termi-
Model 1b shows that the control and treatment nate fewer alliances for reinforced than challenged
groups did not differ in the formation of alliances resources. The difference in the coefficients of num-
for challenged resources prior to the discontinu- ber of alliances for new resources formed across
ity but differed significantly following the discon- Models 1 and 2 is statistically significant (b = -0.76;
tinuity (b = 0.13; p = 0.00). The DiD result between p = 0.00), supporting Hypothesis 2a.
the two groups is significant (b = 0.11; p = 0.00) Next, Hypothesis 2b proposes that following the
and supports Hypothesis 1b: following the tech- discontinuity, the more alliances firms form for
nological discontinuity, firms that formed alliances new resources, the fewer alliances they terminate
for new resources formed 0.11 more alliances for for reinforced resources relative to alliances for
challenged resources than firms that did not form unaffected resources. The difference in the coeffi-
alliances for new resources. cients of the number of alliances for new resources
As well as being significant, these effects are formed in Model 1 (b = −0.74; p = 0.00) and Model
material. On average, treatment group firms formed 3 (b = −0.70; p = 0.00) is significant (b = −0.04;
1.49 reinforced alliances and 0.50 challenged p = 0.00), supporting Hypothesis 2b. This result
alliances after the discontinuity. In turn, the results suggests that new resources may have stronger com-
in Model 1c show that formation of alliances for plementarity with reinforced resources than with
new resources led firms to form more alliances for unaffected resources, so that resource constraints
reinforced resources than for challenged resources lead firms to terminate alliances for unaffected
(b = 0.65; p = 0.00). This comparison is consistent resources ahead of those for resources directly
with Hypothesis 1c. impacted by the discontinuity.
Appendix 6 in File S1 presents the results of the Models 4 and 5 test Hypotheses 3a and 3b. Model
first stage of the two-stage models for Hypotheses 4 (b = 0.88, p = 0.00) supports Hypothesis 3a both
2 and 3. It proved to be difficult to identify one set statistically and materially, showing that forming
of instruments that was valid across models. As a one more alliance for reinforced resources increases
result, we tested different lags of the instruments as termination of alliances for unaffected resources by
well as different combinations of the instruments 0.88. Model 5 (b = 2.30, p = 0.03) supports Hypoth-
across models. Though it would be parsimonious esis 3b and shows that forming one more alliance
to use the same instruments across models, using for challenged resources increases termination of
different instruments for models testing different alliances for unaffected resources by 2.3. These
hypotheses does not create bias. The F tests of also are material effects; the mean number of ter-
excluded instruments support the validity of the minated alliances for unaffected resources is 0.65.
instruments. These results suggest that when firms invest in
Table 5 presents the second-stage models for challenged or reinforced resources (A1a, A1b, and
Hypotheses 2 and 3. Hypothesis 2a proposes that A2a in Figure 2), carrying capacity constraints cre-
the more alliances firms form for new resources, ate incentives to terminate alliances for unaffected
the fewer alliances they terminate for reinforced resources.
resources relative to termination of alliances for Further exploratory tests show that the coeffi-
challenged resources. Model 1 shows that as cient in Model 5 (from formation of challenged
firms form more alliances for new resources, they resource alliances) is significantly greater than
terminate fewer alliances for reinforced resources that in Model 4 (formation of reinforced resource
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Table 4. Difference-in-difference (DiD) tests of Hypotheses 1a and 1b

Period 1 (P1): 1990–1994 Period 2 (P2): 1996–2000 P2 vs. P1

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.


Control (no Treated
Outcome new-resource (new-resource
variable alliances) alliances) Difference Control Treated Difference Difference-in-difference

Model 1a Number of alliances for 0.26 0.56 0.29 0.43 1.49 1.06 0.76
H1a (+) reinforced resources (0.05/0.00) (0.08/0.00) (0.10/0.00) (0.07/0.00) (0.23/0.00) (0.24/0.00) (0.26/0.00)
formed
N 178 82 178 82
Model 1b Number of alliances for 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.14 0.13 0.11
H1b (+) challenged resources (0.01/0.26) (0.01/0.08) (0.02/0.28) (0.01/0.14) (0.03/0.00) (0.03/0.00) (0.04/0.00)
formed
N 178 82 178 82
Model 1c Difference in formation 0.65 (p = 0.00)
H1c coefficient of alliances for
for H1a > H1b reinforced and
challenged resources

The first number in parentheses is robust standard errors; the second number is p > |t|.
For Hypotheses 1a and 1b, treatment group: Firms that formed at least one alliance for new resources after 1995; control group: Firms that did not form any alliances for new resources after
1995. Treatment and control groups were matched using the following variables: number of alliance formed before 1995, alliance familiarity, debt-to-equity ratio, return on equity, number
of technology areas, number of clinical trials, number of patents, R&D intensity, number of M&As, sales (log), firm age, country, and NAIC.
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities

Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)


DOI: 10.1002/smj
1075
Table 5. Fixed-effect 2SLS estimates of the effects of formation of alliances on alliance termination following the discontinuity (H2 and H3)
1076

Model 1 Model 2: H2a Model 3: H2b Model 4: H3a Model 5: H3b


Number of alliances Number of alliances Number of alliances Number of alliances Number of alliances
for reinforced for challenged for unaffected for unaffected for unaffected
Variables resources terminated resources terminated resources terminated resources terminated resources terminated

Number alliances for new resources formed −0.74 0.02 −0.70


(0.14/0.00) (0.03/0.51) (0.21/0.00)
Number of alliances for reinforced resources 0.88
formed (0.25/0.00)

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.


Number of alliances for challenged resources 2.3
formed (1.04/0.03)
Alliance familiarity −0.04 −0.02 −0.27 −0.36 −0.29
(0.06/0.51) (0.01/0.23) (0.08/0.00) (0.10/0.00) (0.09/0.00)
Debt-equity ratio −0.00 −0.00 0.00 0.00 −0.00
(0.00/0.82) (0.00/0.83) (0.00/0.96) (0.00/0.71) (0.00/0.97)
Return on equity 0.00 0.00 −0.00 −0.00 −0.00
(0.00/0.64) (0.00/0.43) (0.00/0.73) (0.00/0.88) (0.00/0.70)
N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell

Number of technology areas 0.14 0.00 0.22 −0.05 0.08


(0.02/0.00) (0.01/0.56) (0.03/0.00) (0.05/0.34) (0.03/0.00)
Number of clinical trials 0.03 0.00 0.08 0.08 0.09
(0.01/0.01) (0.00/0.24) (0.02/0.00) (0.02/0.00) (0.02/0.00)
Number of patents 0.00 −0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00
(0.00/0.54) (0.00/0.39) (0.00/0.90) (0.00/0.03) (0.00/0.26)
R&D intensity −0.00 0.00 −0.00 −0.00 0.00
(0.00/0.87) (0.00/0.97) (0.00/0.66) (0.00/0.97) (0.00/0.92)
Number of M&As 0.25 0.06 0.027 0.15 0.18
(0.05/0.00) (0.01/0.00) (0.07/0.00) (0.09/0.08) (0.08/0.03)
Sales (log) 0.01 −0.00 −0.01 −0.02 0.02
(0.02/0.57) (0.01/0.86) (0.03/0.72) (0.04/0.52) (0.04/0.66)
N 1,425 1,425 1,425 1,425 1,425
F 7.50 4.48 10.92 8.51 9.60
Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic 80.14 80.14 80.14 43.68 22.81
Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic 28.58 28.58 28.58 22.45 5.75
Sargan statistic 1.97 0.00 0.73 0.02 1.33

First number in parentheses is standard errors; the second is p > |z|. Standard errors and covariance matrices are heteroskedastic and autocorrelation consistent (HAC). Year dummies are
included in all models. Variables number of alliances formed before 1995 and firms age were dropped due to multicollinearity. For all models, the Kleibergen-Paap rk LM test rejects the
null hypothesis of under-identification. The Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic exceeds the Stock and Yogo (2005) critical values for weak identification. The Sargan statistics fails to reject
the joint null hypothesis that the instruments are uncorrelated with the error term and that they are correctly excluded from the second stage.

Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)


DOI: 10.1002/smj
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1077
Table 6. Test of parallel-paths assumption

S=1 S=2 S=3 H0: q = q – 1 H0: s = s – 1

A: Unconditional fully flexible model for the number of alliances formed for reinforced resources
Alliances for reinforced resources q = 1 0.18 0.46 0.54 1.41
(0.30/0.53) (0.32/0.15) (0.33/0.10) [0.84]
q=2 −0.06 −0.03 −0.21 0.25 2.46
(0.43/0.88) (0.62/0.96) (0.81/0.80) [0.22]a [0.65]
B: Unconditional fully flexible model for the number of alliances formed for challenged resources
Alliances for challenged resources q = 1 0.03 0.05 0.16 5.60
(0.04/0.04) (0.04/0.28) (0.06/0.01) [0.23]
q=2 0.03 0.04 0.15 0.00 4.59
(0.06/0.64) (0.10/0.69) (0.14/0.29) [0.92]b [0.33]

a N = 2,265. This sample includes pre-discontinuity data to allow testing of the parallel path assumption. The first number in parentheses

is robust standard errors; the second number is p > |z|. P-values in brackets. The null hypothesis is for parallel paths. The results do not
reject this hypothesis, supporting the validity of the DiD analysis: common pre-discontinuity dynamics = 1.53 (p-value = 0.22).
b
N = 2,265. This sample includes pre-discontinuity data to allow testing of the parallel path assumption. The first number in parentheses
is robust standard errors; the second number is p > |z|. P-values in brackets. The null hypothesis is for parallel paths. The results do not
reject this hypothesis, supporting the validity of the DiD analysis: common pre-discontinuity dynamics = 0.01 (p-value = 0.92).

alliances) (b = 1.42; p = 0.00). The implication here variable for both treated and control groups are
is that investment in challenged resources (A1b) and similar in the absence of treatment (Mora and Reg-
the consequent complementarity with reinforced gio, 2012). If this assumption does not hold, the sec-
resources create particularly strong pressures on ond differencing that compares groups before and
alliance portfolios, increasing the carrying capac- after the discontinuity will contain pre-treatment
ity need to create space by terminating alliances for diverging trends. An effective control group is one
unaffected resources. whose pre-discontinuity plot is parallel to the treat-
The controls offer insights. Firms were less likely ment group’s plot. We assess this assumption by
to disband alliances for unaffected resources with graphing the values of outcome variables across the
familiar partners; by contrast, alliance familiarity treated and controlled groups. In Panels A and B
did not affect termination of alliances for chal- of Appendix 7 in File S1, the control and treatment
lenged or reinforced resources. One interpretation groups for reinforced and challenged resources have
is that resource needs dominate when firms use similar paths prior to the 1995 discontinuity; they
alliances to serve new tasks, such as investing diverge strikingly after the discontinuity.
in challenged or reinforced resources. However, We use Stata procedure “dqd” (Mora and
partner familiarity is important when deciding to Reggio, 2014) to assess the plots. Our panel data
maintain alliances that focus on on-going tasks, structure allows a stringent test of the parallel path
such as providing unaffected resources. Firms with assumption and of the more demanding parallel
greater competencies, as reflected in the number of growth assumption, which also requires similarity
technology areas they operate in and the number in the patterns of growth for treated and control
of clinical trials they conducted, were more likely groups. Panels A and B in Table 6 show the results
to terminate alliances, though not in the case of of unconditional fully flexible models. The null
alliances for challenged resources. The number hypotheses of parallel paths cannot be rejected
of patents had limited impact on termination. for the two plots, supporting the validity of the
M&As were associated with greater termination assumption of parallel paths.
of all types of alliances, consistent with their being The DiD estimates in Table 4 may be sensitive
partial substitutes for alliances (Dyer et al., 2004). to the choice of the kernel-function for matching
treatment and control observations. We repeated the
DiD analysis with Gaussian, uniform, biweight, and
Robustness tests
triweight kernel functions, finding similar results,
The parallel paths assumption in DiD analysis except that the effect of the formation of alliances
requires that the average change in the outcome for new resources on formation of alliances for
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
1078 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell
reinforced resources was not significant in one DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS
test. We tested the robustness of the probit-based
propensity scores in Appendix 5 in File S1 with We examined how firms reconfigure their alliance
logit analysis, finding similar results to those pre- portfolios following a technological discontinu-
sented. ity. We used a quasi-natural experiment to test
Next, we tested Hypotheses 1a and 1b with a how an exogenous event disrupted the value of
Heckman two-stage regression model (Heckman, resources, and triggered the formation and termi-
1979) to deal with the selection of being part of the nation of alliances that provided access to these
treatment versus control group. The results did not resources. The results support our prediction that
change materially from the DiD analysis. firms that use alliances to obtain new resources
To ensure that results were not confounded have incentives to undertake broader reconfigura-
by alliances that terminated according to a pre- tion of their alliance portfolios: adding comple-
determined schedule rather than because of the mentary alliances for reinforced and challenged
technological discontinuity, we identified alliances resources, while terminating substitute alliances,
whose termination dates coincided with the expiry even involving resources otherwise unaffected by
dates specified in the initial agreements. Sensitivity the discontinuity, in order to free carrying capac-
analyses removed these alliances, finding similar ity for the new alliances. The interaction of the
results. incentives makes alliance portfolio reconfiguration
For alliances involving more than one type of a complex process in which changes in resource
resource, our research design recorded separate values lead to the formation of alliances for new
alliances. It is possible, though, that firms viewed resources, which triggers the formation and termi-
these as single alliances. We tested possible bias by nation of alliances for other resources.
dropping all such multi-resource alliances, finding The study contributes to the literature on alliance
equivalent results. portfolios and technological discontinuities in three
If firms manage their alliances as portfolios, ways. First, we improve theoretical understanding
it is possible that the total formation or termi- of technological discontinuities and how they affect
nation of alliances, including for resources not the value of resources. Disaggregating the effects
affected by the discontinuity, will confound the of discontinuities in terms of new, reinforced,
formation and termination of alliances affected challenged, unaffected, and obsolete resources
by the discontinuity. We tested this possibility allows more nuanced evaluation of how they affect
by introducing two variables in all models: total firms and their alliance portfolios. The concept
alliances formed and total alliances terminated by of challenged resources is particularly important
each firm in the previous one and two years. The because it highlights the idea that firm agency
results remained unchanged for Hypotheses 2 and in the form of decisions of whether to invest in
3 when we included formation and termination transforming resources can shape the nature of a
variables for the previous one year. When we discontinuity. The results reinforce the importance
included formation and termination variables for of studying discontinuities in terms of complemen-
the previous two years, the results remained the tarity and substitution among firm-level resources
same for Hypothesis 2, but lost significance for rather than as shocks that uniformly affect industries
Hypothesis 3. or economies (Gatignon et al., 2002; Lavie, 2006).
Finally, we replaced instrumental variable Second, we show that firms actively reconfigure
estimators with Generalized Method of Moment their alliance portfolios to meet resource needs
(GMM) estimators that are suitable for nonlinear that arise from exogenous changes. Our focus on
models (Cameron and Trivedi, 2010) for testing how changes in resource values influence changes
Hypotheses 2 and 3; the results were similar, in inter-firm relationships aligns with perspectives
except that the effect of formation of alliances that attribute firm-level exchange relationships
for new resources on termination of alliances for to micro attributes of transactions (Williamson,
reinforced resources was not statistically different 1991). The results support the importance of firm
from the effect of formation of alliances for new agency in the management of alliance portfolios.
resources on termination of alliances for unaffected This finding is important in balancing the view
resources (H2b). that the evolution of alliances tends to be driven
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1079
by path-dependency, repeated interaction, or life reconfiguration, in the presence of an unam-
cycles (Gulati, 1995; Uzzi, 1996). biguous technological discontinuity that created
Third, we contribute to empirical research by reconfiguration incentives. We were able to assess
demonstrating a rigorous approach to establishing detailed data about alliances and resources that the
alliance termination. The paucity of data on ter- discontinuity affected in different ways. In doing
mination of alliances is an obstacle to research on so, we demonstrate strong interactions among
the evolution of alliances, alliance portfolios, and firms’ decisions to form and terminate alliances
networks (Schilling, 2009). The study provides a associated with the resources. The study highlights
reliable alternative to assuming fixed durations for opportunities to investigate how firms reconfigure
alliances. alliance portfolios as well as improves theoretical
More broadly, this study has implications for the and empirical understanding of technological
literature on asset orchestration and business recon- change and how firms respond to the change.
figuration (Helfat et al., 2007; Karim and Capron,
2016; Siggelkow, 2001; Sirmon et al., 2011). When
firms add a new resource, they commonly need to ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
tranform other components within their bundle of
resources to ensure fit. The evolution of alliance We thank Benjamin Cole, Annapoornima Subra-
portfolios is a key element of firms’ ongoing recon- manian, Falguni Sen, Gautam Ahuja, Ishtiaq Mah-
figuration in response to changes in their techno- mood, and Editor Alfonso Gambardella for their
logical environments. Combining insights from the many valuable inputs.
asset orchestration, business reconfiguration, and Navid Asgari thanks the Strategy Research Foun-
alliance portfolio literatures offers new areas for dation (SRF) program for Dissertation Research
investigation. Grant DP 12-82, which supported this study.
Limitations of the study point to six opportuni- Kulwant Singh acknowledges support from NUS
ties for future research. First, research can examine Research Grant R-313-000-098-112.
settings with different forms of discontinuities. Sec-
ond, future studies could attempt to observe changes
in values at the resource-level as well as the direct REFERENCES
costs of forming and terminating alliances. Third,
Anderson P, Tushman ML. 1990. Technological discon-
further studies could examine how reconfiguration tinuities and dominant designs: a cyclical model of
is affected by the architecture of portfolios, which technological change. Administrative Science Quar-
influence interdependence and integration among terly 35(4): 604–633.
firms. Fourth, alliance portfolios often overlap with Angrist JD, Pischke JS. 2009. Mostly Harmless Economet-
networks of competitors, incorporating firms that rics: An Empiricist’s Companion. Princeton University
Press: Princeton, NJ.
compete within the portfolio. Evaluating how net- Arora A, Gambardella A. 1990. Complementarity and
works of competitors influence firms’ formation or external linkages: the strategies of the large firms in
termination of alliances will provide understand- biotechnology. Journal of Industrial Economics 38(4):
ing of another dimension of influence on alliance 361–379.
portfolio reconfiguration. Fifth, it would be useful Barney J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive
advantage. Journal of Management 17(1): 99–120.
to evaluate the performance implications of port- Bass FM. 1969. A new product growth for model consumer
folio reconfiguration, particularly in determining durables. Management Science 15(5): 215–227.
the boundaries on the benefits of reconfiguration. Bourgeois LJ. 1981. On the measurement of organizational
Sixth, further research can identify shocks that more slack. Academy of Management Review 6(1): 29–39.
clearly discriminate treated and control firms for Cameron AC, Trivedi PK. 2010. Microeconometrics Using
Stata. Stata Press: College Station, TX.
DiD-type analysis. We recognize that some read- Dierickx I, Cool K. 1989. Asset stock accumulation and
ers may prefer to interpret our results as corre- sustainability of competitive advantage. Management
lations rather than causal influences; nonetheless, Science 35(12): 1504–1511.
we believe that the correlations involving highly Dosi G. 1982. Technological paradigms and technological
detailed data highlight important patterns in the trajectories: a suggested interpretation of the determi-
nants and directions of technical change. Research Pol-
reconfiguration of alliance portfolios. icy 11(3): 147–162.
In sum, the article addresses an important Dyer JH, Kale P, Singh H. 2004. When to ally and when to
phenomenon in the form of alliance portfolio acquire. Harvard Business Review 82(7/8): 109–115.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
1080 N. Asgari, K. Singh, and W. Mitchell
Dyer JH, Singh H. 1998. The relational view: cooperative Mitchell W. 1991. Dual clocks: entry order influences on
strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive incumbent and newcomer market share and survival
advantage. Academy of Management Review 23(4): when specialized assets retain their value. Strategic
660–679. Management Journal 12(2): 85–100.
Gatignon H, Tushman ML, Smith W, Anderson P. 2002. A Mitchell W, Singh K. 1992. Incumbents’ use of pre-entry
structural approach to assessing innovation: construct alliances before expansion into new technical subfields
development of innovation locus, type, and characteris- of an industry. Journal of Economic Behavior and
tics. Management Science 48(9): 1103–1122. Organization 18(3): 347–372.
Gulati R. 1995. Social structure and alliance formation pat- Mora R, Reggio I. 2012. Treatment effect identification
terns: a longitudinal analysis. Administrative Science using alternative parallel assumptions. Working paper
Quarterly 40(4): 619–652. 12-33, Department of Economics, Universidad Carlos
Gulati R. 1998. Alliances and networks. Strategic Manage- III de Madrid, Getafe, Madrid, Spain.
ment Journal 19(4): 293–317. Mora R, Reggio I. 2014. dqd: a command for treatment
Gulati R, Singh H. 1998. The architecture of coopera- effect estimation under alternative assumptions. Work-
tion: managing coordination costs and appropriation ing paper 14-07, Department of Economics, Universi-
concerns in strategic alliances. Administrative Science dad Carlos III de Madrid, Getafe, Madrid, Spain.
Quarterly 43(4): 781–814. Newey WK, West KD. 1987. A simple, positive
Heckman J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation
error. Econometrica 47(1): 153–161. consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55(3):
Heckman J, Ichimura H, Todd P. 1998. Matching as an 703–708.
econometric evaluation estimator. Review of Economic Ozcan P, Eisenhardt KM. 2009. Origin of alliance
Studies 65(2): 261–294. portfolios: entrepreneurs, network strategies, and firm
Helfat CE, Finkelstein S, Mitchell W, Peteraf M, Singh performance. Academy of Management Journal 52(2):
H, Teece D, Winter SG. 2007. Dynamic Capabilities: 246–279.
Understanding Strategic Change in Organizations. Park SH, Ungson GR. 2001. Interfirm rivalry and man-
Blackwell: Oxford, UK. agerial complexity: a conceptual framework of alliance
Hoffmann WH. 2007. Strategies for managing a portfo- failure. Organization Science 12(1): 37–53.
lio of alliances. Strategic Management Journal 28(8): Pavitt K. 1998. Technologies, products and organization
827–856. in the innovating firm: what Adam Smith tells us and
Kale P, Dyer JH, Singh H. 2002. Alliance capability, stock Joseph Schumpeter doesn’t. Industrial and Corporate
market response, and long-term alliance success: the Change 7(3): 433–452.
role of the alliance function. Strategic Management Persidis A. 1997. Combinatorial chemistry. Nature
Journal 23(8): 747–767. Biotechnology 15(4): 391–392.
Karim S. 2006. Modularity in organizational structure: the Persidis A. 1998. High-throughput screening. Nature
reconfiguration of internally developed and acquired Biotechnology 16(5): 488–489.
business units. Strategic Management Journal 27(9): Puranam P, Raveendran M, Knudsen T. 2012. Organiza-
799–823. tion design: the epistemic interdependence perspective.
Karim S, Capron L. 2016. Reconfiguration: adding, Academy of Management Review 37(3): 419–440.
redeploying, recombining, and divesting resources Reuer JJ, Ariño A. 2007. Strategic alliance contracts:
and business units. Strategic Management Journal, dimensions and determinants of contractual complex-
Virtual Special Issue. Available at: http://onlinelibrary ity. Strategic Management Journal 28(3): 313–330.
.wiley.com/journal/10.1002/%28ISSN%291097-0266/ Rosenbaum PR, Rubin DB. 1983. The central role of the
homepage/reconfiguration_vsi_introduction.htm. propensity score in observational studies for causal
King AA, Tucci CL. 2002. Incumbent entry into new mar- effects. Biometrika 70(1): 41–55.
ket niches: the role of experience and managerial choice Rothaermel FT, Boeker W. 2008. Old technology meets
in the creation of dynamic capabilities. Management new technology: complementarities, similarities, and
Science 48(2): 171–186. alliance formation. Strategic Management Journal
Lavie D. 2006. Capability reconfiguration: an analysis of 29(1): 47–77.
incumbent responses to technological change. Academy Rothaermel FT, Hill CW. 2005. Technological discontinu-
of Management Review 31(1): 153–174. ities and complementary assets: a longitudinal study of
Lavie D. 2007. Alliance portfolios and firm performance: industry and firm performance. Organization Science
a study of value creation and appropriation in the 16(1): 52–70.
U.S. software industry. Strategic Management Journal Schilling MA. 2009. Understanding the alliance data.
28(12): 1187–1212. Strategic Management Journal 30(3): 233–260.
Lavie D, Singh H. 2012. The evolution of alliance port- Siggelkow N. 2001. Change in the presence of fit: the rise,
folios: the case of Unisys. Industrial and Corporate the fall, and the renaissance of Liz Claiborne. Academy
Change 21(3): 763–809. of Management Journal 44(4): 838–857.
Milliken FJ. 1987. Three types of perceived uncertainty Singh K, Mitchell W. 1996. Precarious collaboration:
about the environment: state, effect, and response business survival after partners shut down or form new
uncertainty. Academy of Management Review 12(1): partnerships. Strategic Management Journal 17(S1):
133–143. 99–115.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj
Alliance Portfolio Reconfiguration and Discontinuities 1081
Sirmon DG, Hitt MA, Ireland RD, Gilbert BA. 2011. Vassolo RS, Anand J, Folta TB. 2004. Non-additivity
Resource orchestration to create competitive advantage. in portfolios of exploration activities: a real
Journal of Management 37(5): 1390–1412. options-based analysis of equity alliances in biotech-
Sorenson O, McEvily S, Ren CR, Roy R. 2006. Niche nology. Strategic Management Journal 25(11):
width revisited: organizational scope, behavior and 1045–1061.
performance. Strategic Management Journal 27(10): Vasudeva G, Anand J. 2011. Unpacking absorptive capac-
915–936. ity: a study of knowledge utilization from alliance
Stock JH, Yogo M. 2005. Testing for weak instruments portfolios. Academy of Management Journal 54(3):
in linear IV regression. NBER Working paper 284, 611–623.
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Villa JM. 2011. DIFF: stata module to perform differences
MA. in differences estimation. In Statistical Software Com-
Swanson RP. 2002. The entrance of informatics into ponents. Boston College Department of Economics:
combinatorial chemistry. In The History and Heritage Chestnut Hill, MA.
of Scientific and Technological Information Systems, Wassmer U. 2010. Alliance portfolios: a review and
Rayward WB, Bowden ME (eds). Information Today. research agenda. Journal of Management 36(1):
ASIS & T: Medford, NJ; 203–211. 141–171.
Teece DJ. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: Wernerfelt B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm.
implications for integration, collaboration, licensing Strategic Management Journal 5(2): 171–180.
and public policy. Research Policy 15(6): 285–305. Williamson OE. 1991. Comparative economic organiza-
Thomke S, Kuemmerle W. 2002. Asset accumulation, tion: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives.
interdependence and technological change: evidence Administrative Science Quarterly 36(2): 269–296.
from pharmaceutical drug discovery. Strategic Man-
agement Journal 23(7): 619–635.
Thompson JD. 1967. Organizations in Action: Social
Science Bases of Administrative Theory. McGraw-Hill: SUPPORTING INFORMATION
New York, NY.
Tushman ML, Anderson P. 1986. Technological Additional supporting information may be found
discontinuities and organizational environments. in the online version of this article:
Administrative Science Quarterly 31(3): 439–465.
Uzzi B. 1996. The sources and consequences of embedded- File S1. Alliance portfolio reconfiguration follow-
ness for the economic performance of organizations: ing a technological discontinuity.
the network effect. American Sociological Review
61(4): 674–698.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1062–1081 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

S-ar putea să vă placă și