Sunteți pe pagina 1din 26

WTO E-LEARNING

COPYRIGHT © 12

Detailed Presentation of the WTO and


Trade Economics: Theory and Policy

OBJECTIVE

 Provide some background knowledge on the basics of trade theory


and trade policy, in order to explain what are the gains from trade and
the costs associated with trade liberalization, as well as the motives to
join a trade agreement.

My Course series
I. INTRODUCTION

This is a multimedia course on The WTO and Trade Economics: Theory and Policy. The course
comprises this explanatory text, Frequently Asked Questions and self-assessment quizzes which
you can use to measure your understanding of their course. It is also supported by a video
presentation of this material entitled "The WTO: Economic Underpinnings".

Aim of this presentation

The aim of this multimedia presentation is to provide a theoretical background for


understanding the effects of trade liberalization and those of protection. We will try to
understand also why countries pursue polices of trade liberalization within the context of the
WTO, that is why countries negotiate with each other and commit to bound tariffs, for example,
rather than liberalizing unilaterally. The presentation is divided into four parts. In the first part I
will be providing some insights on what are the most important results of theoretical literature
on international economics on the effects of trade liberalization.

I. Gains from Trade

In particular, initially I will be looking at gains from trade in different setups, ranging from
situations where countries trade because they are different in their level of technology, to
situations where they are different because of their different endowment factors – different
endowments in capital, labour or land. And finally, two situations where countries trade even
when they are similar.

II. Income distribution Effects

In all these cases, I will explain that there are gains from trade, but that trade may, at the same
time, have income distribution effects. So that, within each country, there will be some groups
that make gains and some other groups that may lose. Trade liberalization also entails adjustment
costs. We will explain what does this mean and we will look at what governments can do to
minimize these adjustment costs.

III. Trade policy and development

In the third part, we will look at the evidence on the importance of trade liberalization for
development.

IV. Need of a multilateral commitment

2
In the last part, we will explain the rationale behind engaging in multilateral negotiations and
commit trade liberalization to international agreement.

3
II. GAINS FROM TRADE

II.A. THE THREE MOST IMPORTANT INSIGHTS FROM THE THEORY OF


INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Let's start with what the theory of international trade tells us about the effects of trade
liberalization.

1. There are gains from trade

The three most important results of international trade theory are: one, that there are gains from
trade; the second one is that when countries sell goods or services to each other, this exchange is
always beneficial; and the third, that two countries that trade will benefit from trade even if one
of them is more efficient than the other one at producing everything.

2. Trade is mutually beneficial

Therefore, not only are there gains, but there are gains for both countries. At the same time,
while nations generally gain in aggregate from international trade, it is quite possible that
international trade may hurt particular groups within a nation.

3. Trade has income distribution effects, but gains outweigh losses

Therefore there are income distribution effects, some groups, some people, will gain, some
people will loose and it is very likely that the loosing part of the society will put pressure on the
government to pursue protectionist policies, even if overall gains outweigh overall losses.

II.B. WHERE DO THESE GAINS COME FROM?

GAINS FROM BETTER UTILIZATION OF RESOURCES

Economic theory suggests that gains from trade can come from better utilization of resources.

... from specialization

What does trade do? Trade allows countries to specialize in the production of the goods that
they can produce relatively MORE efficiently and import the goods that they produce relatively
LESS efficiently. The exchange of these goods benefits both countries.

… from exploitation of economies of scale

4
Gains from better utilization of resources may also come from the fact that trade allows firms to
produce on a larger scale. When barriers to trade are eliminated, firms will face the demand of a
larger market. Therefore, firms will be able to choose to produce at a more efficient level of
production, and save costs. These lower costs will benefit the country as a whole.

5
Gains from specialization

Let's now turn to the analysis of the gains from specialization in a little bit more detail.
Everybody probably understands that if a country, which is very efficient in producing
computers, trades with another country which is very efficient in producing roses, then it is
probably to their benefit that the country more efficient in computers produces and exports
computers, while the other country produces and export roses.

But, what about a country that is more efficient in producing both – computers and roses –
trading with a country that is less efficient in the production of both? Is trade still beneficial? –
the important result from the theory is that there are GAINS from trade and that BOTH
countries gain from trade. These gains will arise from each country specializing in the production
of the good for which they have a comparative advantage.

 Comparative advantage (CA)

What does comparative advantage mean? Economists say that a country has a comparative
advantage in producing a certain good, if the opportunity costs of producing that good in terms
of other goods, is lower in that country than it is in the other country. Note that while defining
comparative advantage, we have introduced a new term: "opportunity cost".

 Opportunity cost

What is the opportunity cost? – The opportunity cost of a certain good, let's say roses, in terms
of another good, let's say computers, is the number of roses that could have been produced with
the resources used to produce a given number of computers. Opportunity costs differ across
countries because of differences in technologies.

 Theory of comparative advantage

The theory of comparative advantage states that when two countries specialize in producing the
good in which they have a comparative advantage, both economies gain from trade, even if one
country has an absolute advantage in both goods. In particular, each country will export the good
for which they have a comparative advantage.

1. Specialization from technological differences: the Ricardian Model

The best way to understand the idea of comparative advantage is through a specific example – a
model that demonstrates this. A model of comparative advantage that relies on differences of
labour productivity was first introduced in the early nineteenth century by an economist named

6
David Ricardo, and therefore it is also referred to as the Ricardian Model. In its simplest form
the Ricardian Model can be shown with the following example: Suppose that there are only two
countries in the world, Country A and Country B – and two sectors – roses and computers. A
worker employed in the roses sector would produce five million roses in Country A, and eight
million roses in Country B. Another worker employed in the computer sector would produce
200 computers in Country A and one thousand computers in Country B. In other words,
whatever the sector, one worker would produce more units of each good when employed in
Country B. In this case, Country B has an absolute advantage in the production of both goods.

Roses Computers

Country A 5 million 200

Country B 8 million 1,000

What about comparative advantages? Let's look at the opportunity costs for each country in terms of
roses, of giving up the production of a thousand computers. For Country B the opportunity
costs, in terms of roses, of producing one thousand computers less, is eight million roses.

What about Country A? If Country A had to produce one thousand computers, it would have to
employ five people in the computer sector, because each employee produces only two hundred
computers in Country A. In terms of roses, this would imply a cost of 25 million roses. To sum
up, while in Country B the opportunity costs of one thousand computers is eight million roses,
in Country A the opportunity costs of one thousand computers is 25 million roses. Since the
opportunity costs, in terms of roses, of producing computers are lower in Country B, Country B
has a comparative advantage in computers, while Country A has a comparative advantage in
roses. The theory of comparative advantage tells us that if Country A and B open up to trade,
then Country A will specialize in the production of roses and Country B will specialize in the
production of computers.

What will be the effect of specialization? …the Ricardian Model

7
Changes in output from specialization:

Roses Computers

Country A +10 million -400

Country B -8 million +1,000

TOTAL +2 millions +600

Specialization increases global production of both goods. All countries can gain from trade.

Suppose now that in Country A two workers are moved from the production of computers to
the production of roses. This implies that Country A would produce four hundred computers
less, and will produce ten million roses more. Suppose also that at the same time, Country B will
move one worker from the production of roses to the production of computers, therefore
Country B would produce eight million roses less and one thousand computers more. Overall
the global production of roses will increase by two million units. This is because there will be an
increase of ten million roses in Country A and a reduction of eight million in Country B.

In the computer sector there would be six hundred computers more produced globally. One
thousand computer more produced by Country B and four hundred computers less produced by
Country A. Since specialization increases the global production of both goods, all countries can
gain from trade. Trade makes available to each country a higher quantity of each of the goods.

Obviously the Ricardian Model is a very simple simplified model to explain all facts of
liberalization of trade. However, it provides two very powerful insights. One is that labour
productivity differences are very important in explaining patterns in trade and the other one is
that it is comparative advantage and not absolute advantage that is important for trade. In the
Ricardian Model there is only one factor of production: labour. Therefore, comparative
advantages only arise because of differences in labour productivity, which result from differences
in technology.

2. Specialization from differences in endowments: Factor Proportion Theory (the


Heckscher-Ohlin Model)

In reality, in the real world, trade is not just determined by technological differences, but it also
reflects differences in resources endowments across countries. Therefore, for example, Canada
exports forestry products to the United States not because its workers are more efficient in

8
forestry, but because Canada is more endowed with forests. To explain the importance of
resources in trade two economists, Heckscher and Ohlin, have developed a theory where trade is
determined by the interaction between the relative abundance of factors of production (such as
capital, labour or land) and the relative intensity with which these factors of production are used
in the production of different goods. Since in this theory, comparative advantages are
determined by the proportion of factors endowments and the proportion in which these factors
are used in the production of goods, the theory is known as the "factor proportion theory".

Comparative advantage depends on countries’ relative endowment of factors of production

According to the factor proportion theory, the country which is relatively abundant in labour will
have a comparative advantage in the production of relatively labour intensive goods. The nation
which is relatively capital abundant will have a comparative advantage in the production of the
relatively capital intensive goods. In particular, for example, Country A has a comparative
advantage in a capital intensive good relative to Country B, if its capital labour ratio is greater
than in Country B.

In a closed economy, the good that uses more intensively the relatively abundant factor will be cheaper

If a country is capital abundant, then the cost of capital will tend to be relatively low. As a
consequence, the cost of production of the capital intensive product, and its price, will tend to be
relatively low. The opposite will occur in a labour abundant country – wages will tend to be
relatively low and the cost of the labour intensive products will be relatively low. Differences in
relative prices of the two goods will lead to trade.

With trade:

 The prices of the traded goods will be the same across countries
When countries start to trade, the prices of the two goods, the labour intensive good (say,
the agricultural) and the capital intensive good (say, the manufacturing goods) will tend to
be the same in the two countries. Therefore, for example, the price of the labour intensive
good in the labour intensive country will tend to rise relative to the price of the capital
intensive good.

 The labour intensive country will export the labour intensive good
Both countries will produce more of the good, they have a comparative advantage for.
They will tend to specialize. The capital abundant country will tend to specialize in the
production of the capital intensive goods and export this product, while the labour

9
abundant country will tend to specialize in the labour intensive good and export that
product. Like in the case of the Ricardian Model, also in the H-O model, it is possible that
the global production of both goods may increase with trade. It is therefore possible for
both trading economies to consume more of both goods than in the absence of trade and
therefore both countries gain from trade.

III. INCOME DISTRIBUTION EFFECTS

Trade affects income disbribution

There is, however, a very important difference between the results of the Ricardian Model and
the results of Heckscher-Ohlin Model. In the Ricardian Model, labour is the only factor of
production in the model, it is assumed that labour within each country can move freely without
costs from one sector to another one. To the single individual, it does not make a difference
whether he is employed in one sector or another one. This implies that a simple Ricardian model
not only predicts that ALL countries gain from trade, but also within each country EVERY
INDIVIDUAL is better off as a result of international trade.

In the factor proportion theory, industries differ in the mix of the production factors they
require. In the simplest case, there are two production factors: capital and labour and two sectors
– one capital intensive and the other one labour intensive. The specialization in one of these two
sectors, say the specialization in the production of the capital intensive good, increases the
demand for one factor (capital in our example) while lowering demand for the other factor of
production (labour). In the H-O model, it is not necessarily true that each individual in each
country will gain from trade liberalization. Trade generates income redistribution effects, so that
there will be groups who will gain and groups who will lose.

Who gains and who loses? The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem

Who will gain and who will lose? The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem helps us to identify winners
and losers. Two economists, Stolper and Samuelson, showed that free trade raises the earnings
of the country's relatively abundant factor and lowers the earnings of the relatively scarce factor.
Let's consider the example of a capital abundant country: what will happen in this country after
liberalization? In the capital abundant country, trade induces a reallocation of resources towards
the capital intensive goods – therefore more capital will be demanded and this will increase the
domestic price of capital. Owners of the capital will therefore gain more because returns to
capital increase. What will happen to the demand of labour in this country? – This is the
relatively scarce factor, where the country hasn't got a comparative advantage. The demand for

10
labour will go down and wages will go down. To sum up, in the capital abundant country,
owners of capital will gain and owners of labour will lose.

In practice, there are costs to move from one sector to another one. Therefore, it is likely that
resources employed in the import-competing sector suffer the consequences of a restriction
shrinking of that sector. This explains why in industrialized countries at the moment where a
labour intensive sector, like the textiles sector, is liberalized both capital owners and workers in
that sector oppose free trade. The important result of the theory to bear in mind, though, is that
despite income distribution effects, the country overall gains – that is gains outweigh losses.
Costs of adjustment will be discussed in more detail later.

III.A. TRADE BETWEEN SIMILAR COUNTRIES

Similar countries trade similar goods: Intra-industry trade

An important point to bear in mind is that the Ricardian Model and the Heckscher-Ohlin Model
explain trade between different countries and different goods. In both models countries trade
because they are different – they are either different in terms of their technological level or in
terms of factor endowments. Countries specialize in the production of the good for which they
have a comparative advantage and export that product. However, in reality most of the trade
occurs between similar countries. And, between one quarter and one half of world trade is intra-
industry trade. That is trade between goods that fall in the same industrial classification. This is
particularly true, if one considers trade among developed countries and in particular trade in
manufacturing. In that case, intra-industry trade is most of the trade occurring. The Heckscher-
Ohlin and the Ricardian Model do not explain intra-industry trade.

Intra-industry trade relies on economies of scale

In order to explain intra-industry trade, we need to introduce economies of scale. In many


industries, the larger the scale of production, the more efficient the production. These industries
are characterized by increasing returns to scale, or economies of scale. This implies that by
doubling the input, like, for example, doubling the number of workers in the production of a
certain good, the output is more than doubled. Consider, for example, a company that produces
bicycles. And, suppose that the production of bicycles is characterized by economies of scale.
This implies, for example, that if 10 workers, say, produce in a day five bicycles, then twenty
workers will produce fifteen bicycles in the same time period. This is more than twice as much
as 10 workers can produce.

11
Gains from economies of scale

Without Trade With Trade

A B World A B World

Video cameras 10 10 20 25 0 25

Bicycles 5 5 10 0 15 15

Now suppose, there are two countries: Country A and Country B, and two goods: video cameras
and bicycles, for example. Suppose that both the production of video cameras and the
production of bicycles are subject to economies of scale, so that doubling the number of workers
employed in each sector, more than doubles the output of the sector. Suppose also that the two
countries are identical, that is they have the same technologies and same endowment of
resources. Assume also that labour is the only endowment. Initially Country A employs 10
workers in the video camera sector, and produces 10 video cameras, and employs 10 workers in
the production of bicycles and produces 5 bicycles. Assume that the situation is identical in
Country B – so that overall the world will produce 20 video cameras and 10 bicycles. Suppose
now that all production of video cameras gets concentrated in Country A, while that of bicycles
concentrates in Country B. Then, Country A will employ 20 workers in the production of video
cameras and Country B will employ 20 workers in the production of bicycles. Because of
economies of scales, the use of twice as many workers as before in the production of video
cameras will more than double the output of video cameras produced in Country A. Suppose,
for example, that the production of video cameras in Country A increases to 25. Similarly,
suppose that in Country B, the production of bicycles will rise to 15, say. Of course, given that
all workers have been moved to the other sector, no bicycles will be produced in Country A, and
no video cameras will be produced in Country B.

What happens to world production?

Overall the world will gain. There will be 25 video cameras available and 15 bicycles available.
Therefore, the potential exists for both countries to be better off with trade than without trade.

Gains from access to greater variety of goods and services

12
It is possible to generalize this example and assume that each industry is characterized by a
variety of goods. For instance, bicycles can be differentiated according to their style, colour,
comfortableness of their seats, and so on. Similarly, one can differentiate video cameras in terms
of their qualities, their memory power and so on.

 Trade liberalization may reduce the number of varieties produced by each country, but
consumers gain access to a greater variety of goods overall

In these circumstances trade allows each country to specialize in the production of a smaller
range of goods than it would produce in the absence of trade. However, overall the consumers
in each country will have available a wider choice of goods. This is because trade makes available
to the consumer in each country, not only the varieties of the goods produced domestically, but
also the varieties of goods produced in the other countries. Gains from trade in this case will
arise from the access to a greater variety of goods and services produced worldwide. Countries
will trade different varieties of the same good, thus leading to intra-industry trade.

 No income distribution effects

An important result of the intra-industry trade theory is that intra-industry trade gives raise to
very small income distribution effects. To the extent that trade is of an intra-industry type, trade
will not create social problems of income distribution.

Since intra-industry trade occurs mainly between similar countries, it follows that from a social
point of view, it is easier to liberalize trade among similar countries than among different
countries. This is because trade between different countries is mainly driven by comparative
advantage and generates income distribution effects, thus hurting some groups. These groups
may lobby against trade liberalization.

Gains from faster innovation and technology transfer

So far we have been looking at static gains from trade. There are also, however, dynamic gains
from trade.

Trade enhances the incentive to innovate through:

 Competitive effect - First of all, trade enhances the incentive to innovate. Innovation is
the basis of economic growth. Therefore, through fostering innovation, trade may have
positive effects on growth. Where does the incentive to innovate come from? – The
incentive to innovate is determined by what in economics is called "competitive threat".

13
That is, the difference between the profits that a firm would make if it innovates and the
profits that it would make if another firm innovates first. Trade increases competition
between countries, therefore it increases the losses a firm would face, if it fails to innovate,
while a competitive firms does it. This, in turn, increases the competitive threat and the
incentive to innovate.

 Scale effect - The second source of incentive to innovate is the scale effect. Trade, by
enlarging the size of the market, increases the profits of a firm, if it innovates, thus
increasing the incentive to innovate and invest in research and development.

Trade favours technology transfer through various channels:

A higher level of technology and productivity can also be due to the transfer of technology
coming from abroad. Trade is one of the channels through which technology can be transferred
across countries.

 Reverse engineering - A simple example is reverse engineering. Trade makes available


goods to a country. The mere fact of looking at a good, at its design, at its technology,
allows competitors to capture in part the knowledge embodied in the good. To the extent
that this knowledge is transferred to the importing country, the technology is transferred.

 Personal contacts - Technology is also transferred through personal contacts between


importers and exporters.

 Enhanced foreign direct investment (FDI) - Or, technology can potentially be transferred
through FDI. Trade also favours the inflow of foreign investments into the domestic
country. The presence of a foreign company, technologically more advanced, may not
only provide an incentive to existing domestic companies to update their technologies to
remain competitive, but may also directly contribute to the transfer of technology through
the training provided to local employees, or the quality standards required from local firms
that supply inputs to the production process of the foreign firm or distribute its output.
All this may trigger growth.

III.B. ADJUSTMENT COSTS

We have so far talked about gains from trade, but gains do not come without a cost. We have
highlighted that gains from trade are the consequence of a reallocation of resources towards the
relatively most efficient sectors. Specialization is the most important source of gains from trade.

14
There are costs associated with this reallocation. These costs, generally referred to as "adjustment
costs", are the costs incurred by displaced workers, those, for example, in the import-competing
sector, that have to look for another job. Adjustment costs are also the costs of a firm that needs
to invest in order to adjust to the new market conditions.

Although these costs are unavoidable, as they are a direct consequence of the reallocation effect
of trade liberalization, the size of these costs depends on a number of characteristics of the
domestic market.

Costs depend on:

 Functioning of credit market - The functioning of the credit markets and that of the
labour market, for example, have important implications for the size of the adjustment
costs. Clearly, if the credit markets works properly, displaced workers will find less
difficulties in funding their periods of low income, or zero income. At the same time,
firms would find more easily money for new investments.

 Functioning of the labour market - Similarly, the functioning of the labour market will
determine the duration of unemployment for a worker who is moving to a different sector
and looking for another job – the more efficient the labour market the more efficient will
be the supply of information about vacancies, and more easily wages will adapt to the
labour markets' conditions and more easily markets will tend to full employment.

 Quality of infrastructures and utilities - The quality of infrastructure and utilities is


extremely important in some of the sectors where for example the cost of
telecommunications has an important role.

 Credibility of the reform and quality of institutions - Important, is also the credibility of
the firms and the quality of institutions: the more credible the reforms are, the more likely
is that the market will react and respond quickly to the variations and a new equilibrium is
reached faster.

Since for developing countries credit markets, labour markets, quality of infrastructure are worse
than for developed countries, the size of the adjustment costs may be more relevant for
developing countries than developed countries. It is on the grounds of these higher adjustment
costs that developing countries benefit from longer implementation periods in the arrangements
for multilateral liberalization.

The role of national governments

15
In general there are a number of policies the national government can put in place in order to
minimize the size of these adjustment costs.

Implement policies to minimize the size of the costs

First of all, they can introduce policies to FACILITATE the adjustment. For example, they
could supply information on the availability of jobs and allow more flexible wage setting regimes,
or can provide credit guarantees during the adjustment phase. In addition, they can define an
appropriate pace for the reform, they can underpin trade reforms by international commitments
to increase the credibility of the reforms.

 Use export promotion schemes - Governments can also use export promotion schemes.
The use of active export promotion by governments can be economically justified because
of market failures. The adjustment process, in general, involves moving workers and
capital from the shrinking import sector to the expanding export sector. The expansion of
a new export activity, however, may require investments and investors may run into risks
that are unknown or difficult to measure. If financial markets are not sufficiently
developed or if they are inefficient, it may prove to be difficult for the exporter to get a
loan, or hedge for these risks. Under these circumstances, the inefficiency of the credit
market would be an obstacle to the expansion of the exporting sector, and an obstacle to
the process of adjustment. Therefore, there is a rationale for the government to put in
place export promotion policies to facilitate the adjustment process.

Implement policies to compensate those who lose

 Supplying social safety nets - The second set of policies that the government could put in
place to favour the adjustments process and, in so doing, lower the adjustment costs, is
compensation policies for those groups that lose out as a consequence of liberalization.
For example, the governments could identify those individuals or those groups that face
adjustment costs and, for example, supply social safety nets during the transition period to
alleviate their suffering.

Appropriate redistributive tax system

For long term losses, national governments can develop an appropriate redistributive tax system
that compensates individuals for their losses.

16
IV. TRADE POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT

So far, we have been looking at why countries trade, what determines the patterns of trade, and
what are the gains and the costs associated with trade liberalization. These are certainly
interesting questions, but what is more interesting to understand is what should a trade policy of
a country be, in order to foster development.

Trade liberalization and development

Development is a complex concept – it is a process in which people through their work –


investing and trading with other countries are able to secure their basic needs – education,
health, comfortable living standards and freedom. In order to obtain all this, people need
adequate economic forces. Therefore an adequate level of income is a basis for all this. Now we
have seen that trade liberalization can help countries to better utilize their resources through
specialization and through the exploitation of economies of scale. Trade also fosters the
incentive for innovation and the diffusion of technologies. It is a more efficient use of resources
that provides the potential for a higher level of income and therefore a higher level of
development.

There is a generally positive relationship between openness and income and the general picture is
that open and export oriented countries have succeeded in their development efforts, while
heavily protected and inward-looking countries have not.

Protectionist policies have been used as well to “favour” development

However, often a number of protectionist policies have been used as well to favour
development. We will now turn to the analysis of how protectionist policies work – what are the
instruments for protection – what are their effects and what is the rationale behind protectionist
policies. Moreover we will discuss some of the evidence of the results of these policies.

IV.A. WHAT ARE THE INSTRUMENTS OF TRADE POLICY?

Tariffs

What are the instruments of trade policy? The most well-known one is clearly the tariffs. Tariffs
can be specific tariffs or ad valorem tariffs. A specific tariff is a charge – a fixed charge for each
unit of the imported good. While an ad valorem tariff is a percentage tax on the value of the
imported good.

17
Quotas

The best known form of non-tariff barrier is a quota. This is the maximum quantity of some
good that may be imported.

Export subsidies

Export subsidies also represent an instrument of trade policy, as governments by providing


support to the export activity distort trade.

Any other policy-induced trade cost

In general, any policy-induced trade cost represents a barrier to trade. For example, non-tariff
barriers may be a particular type of standard that increases relative costs of production for
foreigner producers. Or, particularly time consuming customs clearance procedures that increase
overall transport costs. High transport costs due to anti-competitive behaviours or the low
quality of infrastructure may also be thought of as barriers to trade.

In all these cases the analysis of the impact of trade barriers are quite similar. For simplicity, in
the rest of the analysis we will look at the impact of import tariffs. But, please bear in mind that
the same comments are applicable to all other forms of barriers to trade.

IV.B. WHAT IS THE IMPACT OF AN IMPORT TARIFF?

Let's focus for simplicity on the impact of an import tariff on a certain economy, and let's
consider initially the case of a small country, where by small country we mean the case of a
country that cannot affect the world price of the imported good.

Case of a small country

Suppose initially that there are no tariffs. Then, consumers in this country pay the world price to
consume. Suppose that the government decides to levy a tariff on the imports of rice, for
example. The imposition of a tariff will, first of all, increase the domestic price of the imported
good. People who want to consume rice will now have to pay the world price plus the tariff.
Domestic consumers of rice will, therefore, be worse off, as they will have to pay more, if they
want to consume the same quantity of rice as before.

On the other hand domestic producers of rice will gain, because they will be able to sell rice at a
higher price. And the government will also gain, as it will be able to collect tariff revenue.

18
Overall, in the case of a small country, international trade theory shows that the country as a
whole will lose and national welfare will be reduced by the imposition of a tariff.

Case of a large country

Different is the case of a large country. Notice that here, by large country we do not mean a
country that is large in terms of its geographical size, but rather a country whose import demand
for a certain good is so large that it can affect the world price of the imported good.

What happens if a large country imposes a tariff on the import of a good, let's say rice? Like in
the case of a small country, first of all, the domestic price for rice will increase. This will reduce
the demand for imports of rice. But, now, in the case of a large country, the lower demand for
imports will lead to a reduction in the world price of rice.

In other words, by imposing a tariff on an imported good, a large country is able to affect the
price of the good to its own advantage! Economists refer to this gain as "terms of trade gain"
(TOT gain). This gain stems precisely from the ability of the country to affect the world price of
the imported good. It is because of the possibility of terms-of-trade gain that in the case of a
large country the impact of the imposition of a tariff on national welfare of a country is
ambiguous, i.e., it can be either positive or negative. What is important to highlight at this stage
is that terms-of-trade effects only occur in the case of a large country. In the case of a small
country, the imposition of a tariff is unambiguously welfare decreasing!

IV.C. WHY DO GOVERNMENTS IMPOSE IMPORT TARIFFS?

International trade theory clearly asserts the benefits of free trade and highlights the inefficiency
losses of imposing a tariff. In reality, very few countries have adopted total free trade. An
exception is probably the one of Hong Kong. There are various reasons for this.

The political economy justification

Often it is a question of political economy. Saying that there is a political economy justification
behind the imposition of a tariff means that protectionist policies are the consequence of the
lobbying activity of industries in the import-competing sectors that wish to be protected against
competition from the rest of the world.

There are also some theoretical arguments that can justify the use of protection from a national
welfare point of view.

19
Economic arguments for protection:

1. Terms-of-Trade argument

The first argument that we will look at is the terms-of-trade argument, according to which there
is an optimal level of tariff at which national welfare is maximized.

2. Infant industry argument

The second argument, we will look at, is the infant industry argument for protection. According
to this theory, there are circumstances where an industry may need temporary protection in
order for the country to develop a comparative advantage in that sector.

3. Strategic trade policy

The third argument for protection is the strategic trade theory argument. There might be
circumstances where a subsidy to a domestic firm may deter foreign companies from entering
into the market and competing with the domestic firm. In this case, the domestic firm will
benefit from monopoly profits and the country overall may gain.

4. Other arguments

The other arguments for prospection rely on the fact that import tariffs are a tool to raise
government fiscal revenue or they are a tool to redistribute income from the export sector to the
protected sector.

Let's now look at each of these arguments in turn.

IV.C.1. THE TERMS-OF-TRADE ARGUMENTS FOR PROTECTION

Theory

The terms-of-trade arguments follows directly from the cost and benefit analysis of the
imposition of a tariff. We have seen before, that when a large country introduces a tariff, there
may be positive terms-of-trade effects. The tariff reduces the demand for imports and this, in
turn, decreases the world price of the imported good. Economic theory shows that there is an
optimal tariff rate that is positive, for which the terms-of-trade gains must offset distortionary
effects of the imposition of a tariff.

BUT

20
Although theoretically valid, this argument presents very strong limitations, when applied to
actual policy making. First of all, the argument is valid only for the case of large countries. Small
countries are not able to affect foreign prices, therefore they cannot benefit from terms-of-trade
gains.

Second, even in the case of a large country, a trade policy that relies on terms-of-trade gains is a
beggar-thy-neighbour policy. This is because the gains to the large country come at the cost of
welfare losses in the foreign exporting countries that will receive a lower price for their exports.
A retaliation of foreign exporting countries may start a trade war that would leave all countries
worse off.

IV.C.2. INFANT INDUSTRY ARGUMENT FOR PROTECTION

The infant industry argument for protection relies on the arguments that temporary protection
might be needed for a country to develop a comparative advantage in a particular sector when
markets fail. For example, if there are inefficiencies in the financial market, it may happen that an
entrepreneur that wants to start a new business will not find the appropriate funding for his or
her activity, even if the activity is profitable. Inefficiencies in financial markets in developing
countries, for example, may stop resources from moving from the traditional agricultural sectors
to new manufacturing sectors. The simple reason might be that banks are too small, their
portfolios are not sufficiently diversified, or they lack information, and consequently they cannot
manage the risk connected with an investment in a new sector.

Evidence

Historically, many developing countries, in the aftermath of the Second World War, have
adopted an import-substitution strategy in the attempt to develop their manufacturing sector. In
many developing countries, the evidence has been that although the protected sector did
develop, the production stagnated for a long time and the sector needed continued government
intervention to stay in the market. In other words, import-substitution strategies did not lead to
the development of a competitive industry that eventually could face its competition in the
international market. That is to say that import-substitution strategies did not allow the
development of the comparative advantages they were meant to develop. A result that supports a
very strong argument against infant industry protection is that it is very difficult for governments
to identify industries of potential comparative advantage!

21
IV.C.3. STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY ARGUMENT

Let's now turn to the discussion on the strategic trade argument for protection.

Some markets may be characterized by imperfect competition so that there are only a
few big players and excess profits are made

Some markets are characterized by imperfect competition. It may occur that because of high
fixed costs, only a few companies can survive in a market and these companies are able to realize
above normal profits. Countries may decide to enter in competition to try to capture these
excessive profits. Let's take, for example, the case of the air transport industry. It might be the
case that, on specific routes, only one company can survive: If two companies (a domestic and a
foreign company, for example) were in the market, they would both realize losses; but if one
company survives, it will realize monopolistic profits.

A subsidy by government to a domestic firm can deter foreign company and raise the
profits of the domestic company by more than the subsidy

In these circumstances if the government of one country provides its domestic air transport
company with a sufficiently large subsidy, it may create for the company the incentive to enter in
the market independently of whether the foreign company enters or not in the market. On the
other hand, the foreign air-transport company, facing the competition of a subsidised company,
will decide not to enter in the market, because if it did, it would certainly realize losses.

In the end, only the subsidized company will stay in the market, and it will realize monopolistic
profits. To the extent that these profits are higher than the subsidy paid by the government, the
overall welfare of the country that has subsidized its domestic industry will increase.

Is this policy desirable?

At first sight, it might look quite a good idea, under these circumstances, to protect the domestic
industry and capture foreign profits. However, the desirability of such a policy depends on a
number of specific conditions. Firstly, it is necessary that the subsidy is sufficiently large to
actually deter the foreign firm from entering in the market. If it didn't and both companies
entered in the market, then the profits captured by the domestic firm may not cover the cost of
the subsidy and the country as a whole will be worse off.

22
In addition, a strategic trade policy is a beggar-thy-neighbour policy, because it is based on the
assumption of capturing foreign profits. As a consequence, strategic trade policy is subject to
retaliation and therefore entails the risk of a trade war that might leave everybody worse off.

IV.C.4. OTHER ARGUMENT FOR PROTECTION

Fiscal revenue argument

Among other arguments for protection, there is that of fiscal revenue. In many countries,
especially developing countries, income taxes are difficult to collect, while tariffs are easier to
collect: imported goods have to cross a border and therefore it is more difficult to hide them.
Countries, especially developing countries, have often used this argument to keep their tariffs
high. There is evidence, however, that in many countries the simplification of the tax and tariff
systems has led to an increase in the overall fiscal revenue, even when accompanied by a
reduction in the average tariff rate. This is because a simplified system is easier to control, people
understand it better and therefore it is less prone to evasion.

Income distribution

Finally, some countries have used protection as an instrument to redistribute income. We have
said that liberalization redistributes incomes. Trade liberalization increases the returns of the
relatively abundant factor and reduces the returns of the scarce factor. Maintaining protection is
therefore a way to avoid these adjustments. This is obviously true. However, trade policy is not
the only instrument to achieve redistributive goals. And economists argue that it is more efficient
to use fiscal policies than trade policy to achieve income redistribution targets.

V. NEED OF A MULTILATERAL COMMITMENT

V.A. IS THERE A REASON FOR COMMITTING TO MULTILATERAL


LIBERALIZATON?

Trade liberalization leads to gains also when it is unilateral. Yet, historically it has been
achieved through international negotiations

It is interesting to notice that historically tariffs were not reduced through a number of unilateral
decisions by individual countries, but rather through a number of rounds of international
negotiations. But, if countries can realize gains from trade by liberalizing unilaterally, why do they

23
engage in international negotiations and liberalize trade within a context of multilateral
commitments?

Theoretical reasons for coordinating liberalisation with others

There are at least three reasons why it is easier to remove tariffs at a multilateral level.

1. Reciprocal exchange of market access allows governments to mobilize export lobbies to counter-balance import
competing lobbies

First of all, we have seen that when a country liberalizes trade, some people gain and others lose.
We have seen, in particular, that the import competing sector is likely to lose from opening up to
trade, while the export sector is likely to gain. If a country liberalizes unilaterally, it is likely to
face the pressures of the import-competing sector that will mobilize and lobby against
liberalization. On the contrary, if a country is able to negotiate international liberalization, it will
be able to counteract the pressure of the lobbies of the import-competing sector by mobilizing
the exporters' lobbies to counterbalance the lobbies of the import-competing sector. From a
political economy point of view, it is much easier for a country to reduce tariffs if its trading
partners are doing the same.

2. International commitments avoid tit-for-tat trade restrictions

Another important reason why it is easier to reduce tariffs at the multilateral level is that by
coordinating liberalization with other countries, countries are able to avoid trade wars. If each
country set its trade policy independently, then the optimal policy for large countries would be to
set the "optimal tariff". Since this is beggar-thy-neighbour policy, it is subject to retaliations by
other countries. To avoid tit-for-tat trade restrictions, the best option is to cooperate to jointly
liberalize trade.

3. Enhances credibility of a trade policy and avoid time inconsistency problems

There is also a third important reason for underpinning a trade policy to a multilateral
commitment that is that a multilateral commitment enhances the credibility of a trade policy
itself and helps to avoid time inconsistency problems.

24
V.A.1. TIME INCONSISTENCY

Let's explain what time inconsistency means with an example.

Example: Interaction with financial sector

Suppose that a government wants to liberalize its financial sector. Suppose also that national
banks are inefficient and have accumulated non-performing credits. So they are in a very critical
situation. Assume that, at a certain point in time, the government announces that one year later,
it will open up the financial sector to foreign competition. What will banks do? There are two
possibilities: If the national banks believe the announcement, they will start to adjust their bad
credits and try somehow to become more efficient. However, if they don't believe the
announcement, they will not adjust. In this case, one year later, if the government does liberalize
the financial sector, there will be a financial crisis in the country. Therefore, if banks do not
adjust after the announcement, probably the government will not be implementing the policy
one year later.

Time inconsistency occurs when the announcement at time 2 is no longer an optimal


policy at time 4. Aware of time inconsistency problems, banks will decide not to adjust.

Time inconsistency occurs when the announcement, made at a certain time, is no longer an
optimal policy, at the time when it should be implemented. Aware of time inconsistency
problems, banks will decide not to adjust after the announcement of the government. As a
consequence, when the time of implementing the policy arrives, the government will be obliged
not to liberalize, otherwise it would risk a complete crisis in the financial sector.

International commitments solve the time inconsistency problems

The time inconsistency problem can be solved through international commitments. International
commitments will give credibility to the government announcement that it will liberalize the
financial sector, and banks will adjust.

V.A.2. OTHER REASONS FOR MULTILATERAL LIBERALIZATION

There are other reasons in favour of multilateral liberalization. One of these is to avoid the risk
of trade diversion due to the formation of regional trade agreements.

No risk of suffering from trade diverting effects of regional trade agreements

25
The policies we have described so far are non-discriminatory policies. This means that if two
countries decide to reduce their reciprocal tariffs, they will also apply these lower tariffs to the
rest of the world. It may happen as well that countries reduce their tariffs in a preferential way.
This means that a set of countries liberalize their intra-regional trade, but they keep their barriers
against the rest of the world. At the first sight, this might seem a good policy. We have said that
unilateral liberalization is good. We have said that multilateral liberalization is good, so one may
think that preferential liberalization should also be good. In contrast, when countries liberalize
in a preferential way, they may incur the risk of suffering from the consequences of what
economists call "trade diversion". Trade diversion occurs when the imports from a trading
partner of the regional agreement replaces imports from the rest of the world, although the
trading partner is not the globally most efficient producer of the good. Trade diversion has
clearly negative effects on the exporting countries outside the preferential area. What are the
consequences for the importing country member of the preferential area? On the one hand,
consumers gain, because they pay less to import the good from a regional partner, since there are
no import tariffs. On the other hand, the government loses tariff revenue. Since the trading
partner is not the most efficient producer of the good, this loss may be larger than the gain to
consumers. In other words, trade diversion may also have negative effects on the welfare of the
partners to the preferential agreement.

Transparency and predictability

Another advantage of committing liberalization to international agreements is that of enhancing


the transparency and predictability of conditions for the exchange of goods and services. For
example, this reduces the costs of getting information on the tariff rates applied on a certain
product by a certain country to another one and put countries on a level playing field.

26

S-ar putea să vă placă și