Sunteți pe pagina 1din 11

IFC Economics Notes

Note 1
The impact of infrastructure on growth
in developing countries
Antonio Estache and Grégoire Garsous
April 2012

Since Aschauer’s seminal work (1989a) on linear,…), data stationarity issues and
the USA, there has been almost 25 years of untreated endogeneity (i.e. how certain are
academic research on the impact of we that the model accounted for the two-
infrastructure on growth.1 Understanding way causality between growth and
these long lasting debates is essential to infrastructure). Part of the challenge, when
have a balanced quantitative view on the interpreting this literature, is to make sure
relevance of infrastructure for growth. Some that results are really comparable.
of the issues have indeed been settled, The upshot is that it is easy to
others not quite yet. understand why there still are so many
That infrastructure matters to growth is debates as to the level of the impact of
now relatively well recognized and widely infrastructure on the level of GDP and its
understood among practioners and policy longer term impact on the growth potential
makers. There is, indeed, a plethora of of the economy. Among the many debates,
anecdotal and more technical evidence that the discussions on the specific definition of
better quantity and quality of infrastructure infrastructure may matter the more directly
can directly raise the productivity of human to practioners.
and physical capital and hence growth (e.g. In general, infrastructure is defined as
by providing access, roads can: (i) improve electricity, gas, telecoms, transport and
education and markets for farmers’ outputs water supply, sanitation and sewerage.
and others by cutting costs, (ii) facilitate However, because data on the physical
private investment, (iii) improve jobs and stocks of these sectors, or their valuation,
income levels for many). tends to be scarce, authors have often relied
How much, specifically, and which on stocks of public capital or specific
infrastructure matters when to output subsectors as proxies for infrastructure.
levels and their growth in developing and Public capital seems to be attractive
transition economies is not as clearly because it is somewhat easier to identify in
settled. The research available on these many countries. But it is a broader concept
questions is the main focus of this note. that is itself quite unclear. For instance, it
can include all public buildings, including
(Settled?) Academic debates on how
often hospitals, schools or public housing
much infrastructure matters
and office stocks, or police and fire stations.
Debates on the proper econometric Thus the extent of its relevance to assess
modeling have tended to dominate the the impact of infrastructure on growth is at
disagreements among academics and other best unclear. It is in fact worsening since,
researchers on how much infrastructure pointed out by Straub (2011), the relative
matters. The discussion covered poor importance of the private sector in
choice of explained variable (GDP level, or infrastructure has increased a lot more than
growth, measured in physical or in in other activities.
monetary terms,…), functional forms (Cobb- For the reader convinced that public
Douglas, translog, log, linear, or log- capital is a reasonable proxy, two recent
surveys show that it has a positive effect on
1 This note represents the views of the authors and these growth. Romp & de Haan (2007) conclude
should not be attributed to any of the organizations we are that "there is more consensus than in the
affiliated with, nor to IFC, the World Bank or any of its past that public capital positively affects
members countries or agencies. Any mistake or
misinterpretation is ours and ours only. economic growth, but the impact seems to
be lower than previously thought." Bom & For SSA, according the research
Lighthart (2009) also point out that early conducted collectively by the donors’
estimates had the right (positive) sign but community, the estimated spending needs
may have been to optimistic. Focusing on are $93 billion a year or 15% of the
research on the output elasticity of public region’s GDP, about 10% in investment
capital, they conduct a meta-analysis of all and 5% in operation and maintenance.2
comparable studies and find it to average The spending needs in the poorest
across studies at around 0.08—i.e. a 1% countries are as high as 25% of their GDP,
increase in the stock of public capital would even more for fragile states. Over 40% of
lead to a 0.08% increase in GDP, keeping in the expenditure needed is in the power
mind that this is an average that hides much sector—to finance the 7,000 megawatts of
higher sector specific payoffs achieved in new generation capacity needed each year
some of the subsectors, in particular in just to keep pace with demand. Slightly
infrastructure as seen in the appendix; the more than 20% is needed for water supply
appendix table shows that for a few key and sanitation and a further 20% for the
representative studies focusing on transport sector to achieve a reasonable
infrastructure only, the elasticity of growth level of regional, national, rural, and urban
is 2.5 times what it averages out to be for connectivity and to maintain existing
total public capital. assets. The rest is for irrigation and
For anyone interested more specifically telecommunicatons.
on infrastructure, it is easy to argue that the Asia needs annually about US$750
impact of public capital on growth billion in infrastructure investment to 2020,
underestimates the impact of around 68% for new investments and the
infrastructure. This is what Straub (2008) rest for maintenance or replacement of
argues. His case is a bit technical but it existing assets. This implies an annual
implies that the use of public capital commitment of about 6.5% of its GDP. Of
underestimates the statistical strength of the total, about half is for energy
the evidence on the real GDP and growth infrastructure, a third for transport, 13%
payoffs of infrastructure. The evidence for ITC, and 3% for W&S (Bhattacharyay
seems to validate this view. When the data (2010)). East and Southeast Asia together
allows a measure of infrastructure, the account for more than 50% of the total
impact of asset expansion in the sector on required investment. In Central, East and
both GDP and growth is indeed statistically Southeast Asia, investment needs are the
more significant. However, somewhat highest in the electricity sector whereas in
surprisingly, the order of magnitude South Asia the highest need is in transport.
remains similar. It is simply statistically
more credible. This is also the conclusion For Latin America, annual needs are
reached by Estache and Garsous (2011). around 4% of GDP to support most growth
scenarios—from conservative to optimists.
Calderon et al. (2011) provide an (Kolhi and Basil (2011)). This is also the
additional insight that reinforces the sense working order of magnitude used by the
of robustness of the impact of main donors. In this region, however, many
infrastructure. Focusing on elasticity of GDP governments have also released their own
per worker with respect to a synthetic estimates and they tend to be 1-2% higher
infrastructure index leads to a similar than the estimates based on multi-country
elasticity level similar to those focusing on assessments.
GDP per se.
For MENA, these needs are around 3%
All this research can be translated into
of GDP but roughly an extra 4% is needed
an assessment of the infrastructure
for operations and maintenance (Yepes and
investment requirements to achieve the
Estache (2011)). This adds up to around
growth needed to reach the reductions in
US$106 billion/year. There is however a
poverty demanded by the MDGs. How
much infrastructure depends on each
region. 2 www.infrastructureafrica.org/

2
huge variance in the region, with oil major bottleneck or introducing a major
exporting countries needing to spend technological improvement. Yet, empirical
around 11%, about the double of what oil research so far has not really provided a
importing and GCC countries need to spend. definitive answer. For instance, Calderon et
Energy and transport each need around al. (2011), relying on very aggregate
40% and ICT around 10% of the total approach, find that the stage of
needs. development does not seem to matter.
For ECA, the total needs are around However, Garsous (2012) points out
6.6%. What stands out in this region is that that their conclusion has to be qualified.
the highway interconnections are poor and Indeed, the answer to the question depends
sources of bottlenecks. This is why road on the weight of developing countries in the
transport (2.7% of GDP) is the subsector sample analyzed. The larger the number of
with the highest needs, followed by energy developing countries in the sample, the
(2%). ICT comes third with needs of around more likely a positive impact of
0.9% of GDP (Estache (2011)) infrastructure on output/growth is likely to
be observed. This would allow the
conclusion that the less developed the
Ongoing debates on “which country, the more likely infrastructure to
infrastructure matters when”? matter. The more developed a country is,
the more other dimensions such as
While there is a reasonable agreement on bottlenecks, diseconomies of scale, network
how much infrastructure matters to effects, or technological lags tend to matter
growth, there is much less convergence on more than the aggregate infrastructure
which infrastructure subsector matters the stock.
most under which circumstance. This can
Estache and Wren-Lewis (2011) add
be seen in the differences in estimates of
that large supranational energy or
investment needs across regions and within
transport projects can have very significant
regions. The challenge is thus to sort the
payoffs at all stages of development.
drivers of these differences.
Investments in these sectors can thus make
One way of organizing the assessment a significant impact in terms of connecting
of the drivers of infrastructure priorities is markets. Ignoring this may underestimate
suggested by Estache and Garsous (2011). the payoffs from infrastructure or some
Infrastructure could depend on: countries.
 the development stage of the countries The case for such projects is just as
covered by the sample analyzed, strong in Europe as it can be in Africa, Asia
 the time period over which the impact is or Latin America. This point was already
assessed, and made at the US level where spillover effects
 the type of infrastructure. across states can be important. Fernald
(1999) showed a difference in the U.S.
Building on that suggestion, Garsous (2012) interstate highway network productivity
conducts a meta-analysis of studies focused before and after its completion. In
exclusively on infrastructure rather than on particular, the massive road-building of the
public capital. His synthesis and a few 1950’s and 1960’s seem to have offered a
related papers offer the insights one-time boost productivity. Fernald
summarized next. (1999) actually argues that Aschauer
(1989) high productivity assessments were
a. On the stage of development biased by this one-time increase in
Intuitively, it should make sense to productivity. A much broader conclusion is
assume that the more developed a country that relying only on past productivity gains
is, the higher its infrastructure stock and from “local or national” investments may
hence the lower the payoff from additional underestimate the gains from investing in
investment, unless it aims at addressing a larger networks for some countries, in

3
particular when these investments have c. On the type of infrastructure 3
huge international network externalities.
Any modern textbook on industrial
b. On the time dimension economics or industrial organization will
As too often in economic research, the point out that for industries that enjoy
importance of very basic facts and network externalities, the social rate of
assumptions for the extent to which a return has to be higher than the private rate
conclusion can be generalized tends to be of return in these projects—assuming that
underestimated. One such characteristic is the regulation does not allow the network
the relevance of the time period analyzed. externality to be turned into a private rent.
The older the studies on a given country or In other words, their impact on GDP and its
regions, the more like they are to cover time growth should be high.
periods in which the stock of infrastructure This explains for instance why the
was lower and hence any improvement growth impact of the telecoms sector so
would have a higher payoff. This is the case often come out to be high. But for specific
for Spain or the US for instance (Estache- countries or regions, this could also be true
Fay (2010)). But this is just another way of for transport or electricity. In general,
validating the point that the stage of however, all infrastructure subsectors can
development matters. Indeed, be good examples of sectors in which such
infrastructure mattered a lot more to Spain network externalities can matter. Their
in the 60s when it was simply trying to social return will however evolve with time,
catch with the more advanced parts of with stock size and with market size. This
Europe. This is what the old studies picked section reviews the main lessons available
up. More recent studies, include time on each subsector on the growth impact of
periods as of which, the gap has closed and each infrastructure subsector.
the payoffs to additional infrastructure are
still positive, but simply lower. i. Energy
Estache (2011) provide a somewhat The importance of access to electricity
more subtle argument to explain the to human development has been
relevance of time. Ceteris paribus, studies documented in a large number of case
covering a longer period are more likely to studies and cross-country econometric
find a positive impact of infrastructure on studies across regions. It is a recurring item
output or growth. This result should not be in all studies on the impediments to the
surprising. Infrastructure has an unusual business environment. (see Dethier et al.
cash flow profile, with high short-term costs (2008 et al.) for instance). Among these
and slow but long income flows. Therefore, studies, those focusing on developing
for a given project and discount rate, the countries all find a positive impact of
longer the analysis, the more likely a energy infrastructure on output/growth. In
positive impact assessed on GDP, growth fact, in his survey, Garsous (2012) finds
and, in facts, jobs. that, ceteris paribus, studies focusing on the
Even if these arguments seem robust, energy sector are more likely to find a
the hard evidence continues to raise robust positive impact than any other
questions. It is intriguing that many of the infrastructure sector. In other words,
studies covering the fifties and eighties investing in the energy sector may be the
were more likely to find a positive impact of safest bet to achieve a high social rate of
infrastructure. The opposite is true for return. This should not be a surprise,
many of the studies covering the sixties and energy is indeed an input into any of the
the seventies. Clearly, other factors matter other infrastructure subsectors—for
as well. For instance, Albala-Bertrand and instance, water is often pumped thanks to
Mamatzakis (2004) show for Chile that electric pumps.
infrastructure impact became higher after
liberalization (see Note 2 for more details). 3 The few sub-Sector specific elasticities results available
from cross country studies are reported in the appendix.

4
ii. Water and Sanitation This is quite obvious in the recent
The water and sanitation sector may be growing research on the importance of the
the infrastructure subsector for which the access to internet to increase competition in
econometric evidence of an impact is the the sector and from there increase the
less well documented. This reflects the fact social return to expansions in the sector.
that the link with growth is a lot more Poor regulation hurts the growth payoffs
indirect that for the other subsectors. because even when investment takes place,
Although water drives health which in turn quality does not necessarily follow. We
drives labor productivity and labor know for instance that the faster the access
productivity, itself, drives growth, the link to high speed internet, the stronger the
between water and growth does not seem payoff. Yet many countries fail to manage
to spring to mind to most researchers or at this, contributing to explain the differences
least not as strongly as for the other sectors. in the macroeconomic and social returns to
It is noteworthy that Calderon and Serven, investment in the sector.
the World Bank based researchers who may The orders of magnitude of the gains
have spent the most time on assessing the vary across regions and across countries.
impact of infrastructure on growth have left But the average payoffs are quite
out the water sector of their analysis. impressive—they are usually among the
Among the few studies to have analyzed highest when the payoffs to infrastructure
this contribution in developing countries, are unbundled into its components. For
the evidence is mixed. Binswanger et al. Africa for instance, this is one of the reasons
(1992) for instance find that the why supranational investments on the
contribution of canal irrigation backbones are so important.
infrastructure to crop output is null from a
panel districts in India. Estache et al. (2005) iv. Transports
find the contribution of water and sanitary For developed countries, the estimated
infrastructure to be positive from a panel of growth effects of transport investments
sub-Saharan countries. have not been very strong. This has been a
common finding in research over the last 20
iii. Telecommunications years or so. This is not surprising since
The impact of telecoms for growth may their transport stocks are mature. The main
be the best documented impact. To a large impact at advanced stages of development
extent, it is because telecoms data is has to come from quality, from addressing
relatively easy to access, including for bottlenecks or from capturing new network
developing countries. Zhan-Wei Qiang and or suprational effects which have not been
Pitt (2009) and Chakraborty and Nandi internalized in older designs of the
(2011), more recently, survey this transport networks.
literature. But it continues to grow.4 Most For developing countries, the picture
studies find a positive impact of looks quite different. Whatever the GDP
telecommunication infrastructure on GDP, growth related focus, most cross-country
on growth—and also on labor productivity. studies find a positive impact. For
As with other infrastructures, there is a instance, roads are needed for Africa to
debate on the precise magnitude of its catch with the rest of the world (Buys et
contribution. But this is quite normal, the al. (2006). Roads are essential to reduce
interdependency between fixed and mobile differences across regions within
telephony for instance still requires a countries (Estache–Fay (2010)). Port
significant amount of regulation of access. quality is central to the evidence collected
Its effectiveness strongly drives the social on the gains from trade facilitation for
return of return for the sector. instance. In the case of APEC countries,
Wilson et. Al (2003) for instance found
4 The IMF has produced a few working papers on the topic. that increasing port capacity for countries
The latest one is by Andrianaivo and Kpodar (2011)
focusing on the growth effect of ICT in Africa and it below capacity average could increase
features a interesting focus on the impact of mobile APEC average per capita GDP by 4.3%.
telephony and financial inclusion.

5
It is however important to point out argue that, at different stages of
that for country specific studies, the development, different kinds of
overall results are not always as clear cut. infrastructure are important to maintain
A possible explanation, of course, could be growth and productivity at levels high
is that econometric methodologies cannot enough to allow countries to catch up with
easily fully capture the gains from the countries with the highest growth rates.
marginal, or sometimes more significant, At a given level of development, however,
redesigns of the transport networks to the growth and productivity payoffs of
fully internalize network externalities. 5 sector specific investment will not be the
Similarly, these methodologies seldom same across regions.
pick up fully properly at the country level
There is a lot of ongoing research
the gains from intermodal interactions
showing that differences in institutional
from increased competition or improved
quality matters to growth and hence to the
integration.
growth payoffs of sectoral investment
decisions (Rodrik (2008), Acemoglu and
iv. So, in which subsector to invest?
Robinson (2012)). There is also sound
There is no simple answer to any question and increasingly popular research on the
trying to lead to a ranking of sectoral importance of identifying bottlenecks
investments. The best standard way to deal when deciding where to allocate scarce
with these sorts of questions is still to resources (using firm-level surveys
conduct a good cost-benefit analysis at the critically—recognizing that complaints are
project level and to add up the results for all not the same as real constraints).
projects to generate the aggregate Hausman and various co-authors at
investment profile for the country. No Harvard have conducted many such
country really does it like that. Some do it diagnostics—see Hausman et at. (2005)
within sectors (the UK, Australia or Finland for the intuition and Hausman et al (2008)
for instance). Chile is probably the country for a “manual”. This is the research that is
that comes the closest to following this starting to provide useful answers to the
rational approach. question “where should investment take
When trying to see ex-post which sector place?”. In a nutshell, it all starts with a
has tended to help the most, one alternative tedious but much needed growth
approach is to look at comparative impact diagnostic.
assessments from econometric studies. The
approach raises lots of issues, but it seems Main messages to remember?
to suggest quite systematically that energy Improvements in econometric techniques,
is the more productive sub-sector in most and sometimes in data sources, have
country specific assessments. However, in steadily improved the precision and
general, these papers do not include ICT reliability of our collective understanding
infrastructure, in particular all the modern and assessment of the contribution of
developments allowed by the constant public capital/infrastructure to growth. Our
technological improvements in the sector. knowledge is still far from perfect as the
Although there is no precise answer to data available on the sector is still
the macro-ranking question in the problematic. However, the improvement in
literature, the best general answer is the quality of macroeconomic research in
offered by Hulten and Isaksson (2007) the field has generated a few reasonably
when trying to trying to explain differences robust messages for practitioners. They can
in income and productivity levels for 112 be summarized as follows:
countries between 1970 and 2000. They
 Infrastructure matters to growth and
its impact is easy to underestimate;
5It is quite widely recognized that the current African
networks reflect designs largely inherited from colonial to avoid underestimating its impact:
powers and mostly aimed at exporting raw materials to o distinguish between infrastructure
Europe. This reflects of concept of mobility quite far from and public capital, as public capital
the current internal needs of the continent.

6
tends to underestimate the impact  And finally, payoffs are slow to show
of infrastructure on growth up in infrastructure—roads are often
o take into account the national built on traffic forecast with over 30
payoffs that can be achieved from years of lead time.
supranational projects, if needed.
 Infrastructure investment needs to Bibliography
support growth vary across regions:
o For SSA, they average 10% of GDP Acemoglu, D. and J.A. Robinson (2012), Why
(over 40% for energy and 20% each Nations Fail: The origins of power,
for water and sanitation and prosperity and poverty, Crown Publishers.
transport) and can reach over 25%
for the poorest of the region; Albala-Bertrand, J. M., and E. C. Mamatzakis
o Asia and Latin America needs (2004): “The Impact of Public
around 4-5% of their GDP for new Infrastructure on the Productivity of the
investment only; Chilean Economy,” Review of Development
o The needs in MENA are around 3% Economics, 8(2), 266-278.
but are more than double that Albala-Bertrand, J. M., and E. C. Mamatzakis
amount in oil exporting countries; (2007): “The Impact of Disaggregated
o The needs in ECA are closer to 6.5% Infrastructure Capital on the Productivity
including large rehabilitation and Growth of the Chilean Economy,” The
replacement needs Manchester School, Vol. 75, No. 2, 258-273.
 Subsectoral needs vary across
Andrianaivo, M. and K. Kodar (2011), “ICT,
regions;
Financial Inclusion, and Growth: Evidence
o Across regions, energy is where the
from African Countries”, IMF working
largest infrastructure gaps are
papers, WP/11/73, Washington, DC
found (around 40-60% of the
investment needs, depending on the Aschauer, D. A. (1989a), “Is Public
country) followed transport— Expenditure Productive?,” Journal of
except in ECA and South Asia where Monetary Economics, 23, 177-200.
the transport needs are the highest Baltagi, B. H., and N. Pinnoi (1995): “Public
 On average, the operation and Capital Stock and State Productivity
maintenance of the assets adds the Growth: Further Evidence from an Error
equivalent of at least 50% of the Components Model,” Empirical Economics,
investment needs (more in MENA)6 20, 351-359.
 Access to physical infrastructure Bhattacharyay, B. (2010), “Estimating
does not drive GDP, growth or the Demand for Infrastructure in Energy,
social returns alone. Transport, Telecommunications, Water and
o The poorer a country, the more Sanitation in Asia and the Pacific”, 2010–
infrastructure matters on average 2020. ADBI Working Paper No. 248.
o The weaker the institutions (i.e. September. Tokyo.
more corruption, fewer skills, …), Canning D, and E Bennathan (2000), “The
the lower the growth payoff social rate of return on infrastructure
o The more competitive the investments”, World Bank research
environment, the higher the payoff project , RPO 680-89, Washington, D.C.
o The more balanced the residual
regulation, the higher the payoffs Binswanger H. P., S. R. Khandker and M. R.
Rosenzweig (1993): “How Infrastructure
and Financial Institutions Affect
6 This is based on the information provided by sector Agricultural Output and Investment in
specific engineers on how much it costs to operate and India,” Journal of Development Economics,
maintain a standardized assets. This costs is assessed as a
percentage of the per unit value of the asset. This is the
41, 337-366.
foundation of most recent studies of investment and Boarnet, M. G. (1998): “Spillovers and the
matching operating and maintenance costs.

7
Locational Effects of Public Infrastructure,” Working Paper, 4792, Washington, DC,
Journal of Regional Science, 38, 381-400. World Bank
Bom, P. R. D., and J. E. Lighthart (2009): Ding, L. and K. Haynes (2006): “The Role of
“How Productive is Public Capital? A Meta- Telecommunications Infrastructure in
Analysis”, Georgia State University, Andrew Regional Economic Growth in China,”
Young School of Policy Studies, Australasian Journal of Regional Studies,
International Studies Program Working Vol. 12, No. 3.
Paper 09-12 Eisner, R. (1991): “Infrastructure and
Bougheas, S., P. O. Demetriades, and T. P. Regional Economic Performance:
Mamuneas (2000): “Infrastructure, Comment,” New England Economic Review,
Specialization, and Economic Growth,” September/October, 47-58.
Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 33, No. Egert, B., T. Kozluk, and D. Sutherland
2. (2009): “Infrastructure and Growth:
Buys, P., U. Deichmann and D. Wheeler Empirical Evidence,” William Davidson
(2006), “Road Network Upgrading and Institute Working Paper Number 957, April,
Overland Trade Expansion in Sub-Saharan University of Michigan.
Africa”, World Bank Policy Research Esfahani, S. H., and M. T. Ramirez (2002):
Working Paper No. 4097. “Institution, Infrastructure and Eco- nomic
Calderón, C., E. Moral-Benito, and L. Servén Growth,” Journal of Development
(2011): “Is Infrastructure Capital Economics Volume 70, Issue 2, April 2003,
Productive? A Dynamic Heterogeneous Pages 443-477.
Approach,” Banco de España, Documentos Estache, A. (2008): “Infrastructure and
de Trabajo N° 1103. Development: A Survey of Recent and
Canning, D. (1999): “Infrastructure Upcoming Issues,” Annual World Bank
Contribution to Aggregate Output,” World Conference on Development Economics –
Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. Global 2007: Rethinking Infrastructure for
2246. Development, pp 47-82.
Canning, D., and E. Bennathan (2000): “The Estache, A. and L. Wren-Lewis (2009):
Social Rate on Return of Infrastructure “Toward a Theory of Regulation for
Investment,” World Bank Policy Research Developing Countries: Following Jean-
Working Paper No. 2390. Jacques Laffont’s Lead,” Journal of
Chakraborty, C. and B. Nandi (2011), Economic Literature, 47:3, 730-771.
“’Mainline’ telecommunications Estache, A. and M. Fay (2010): “Current
infrastructure, levels of development and Debates on Infrastructure Policy,” in
economimc growth: Evidence from a panel Globalization and Growth: Implications for
of developing countries”, a Post-Crisis World, Commission on Growth
Telecommunications Policy, 35,441-449 and Development, Edited by Michael
Datta, A., and S. Agarwald (2004): Spence and Danny Leipziger, 151-193.
“Telecommunications and Economic Estache, A., B. Speciale, and D. Veredas
Growth: A Panel Data Approach,” Applied (2005): “How much does infrastructure
Economics, 36, 1649-1654. matter to growth in Sub-Saharan Africa,”
Démurger, S. (2001): “Infrastructure European Center for Advanced Research in
Development and Economic Growth: An Economics Working Paper, Universite Libre
Explanation for Regional Disparities in de Bruxelles.
China?,” Journal of Comparative Economics Evans, P., and G. Karras (1994): “Are
29, 95-117. Government Activities Productive?
Dethier, J.J, M. Hirn and S. Straub (2008), Evidence from a Panel of US States,” Review
“Explaining Enterprise Performance in of Economics and Statistics, 76, 1-11.
Developing Countries with Business Feddreke, J. W. and Z. Bogetic (2009):
Climate Survey Data”, Policy Research “Infrastructure and Growth in South Africa:

8
Direct and Indirect Productivity Impacts of Hulten, C. and A. Isakson (2007), “why
19 Infrastructure Measures,” World development levels differ: differential
Development Vol. 37, No. 9, pp. 1522-1539. growth n a panel of highand low income
Fernald, J. G. (1999): “Roads to Prosperity? countries”, NBER, Working Paper,
Assessing the Link between Public Capital No.13469, Cambridge, MA.
and Productivity,” The American Economic IFC, Information and Communication for
Review, Vol. 89, No. 3, pp. 619-638. Development 2009 (IC4D09): Extending
Garcia-Mila, T., T. J. McGuire, and R. H. Reach and Increasing Impact.
Porter (1996): “The Effects of Public Capital Kelejian, H. H. and D. P. Robinson (1997):
in State Level Production Functions “Infrastructure Productivity Estimation and
Reconsidered,” Review of Economics and its Underlying Econometric Specifications: a
Statistics, 78, 177-180. Sensitivity Analysis,” The Journal of the
Garsous, G. (2012): “How Productive is RSAI, 76, 1, 115-131.
Infrastructure? A Quantitative Survey,” Kocherlakota, N. R., and K. M. Yi (1996): “A
ECARES Working Paper, Université libre de Simple Time Series Test of Endoge- nous vs.
Bruxelles. Exogenous Growth Models: An Application
Hardy, A. (1980): “The Role of the to the United States,” The Review of
Telephone in Economic Development,” Economics and Statistics, Vol. 78, No. 1,
Telecommunications Policy, 4(4), 278-286. 126-134.

Hausmann, R., D. Rodrik, and A. Velasco Kohli, H.L. and P. Basil (2011),
(2005). ‘Growth Diagnostics’. In The ”Requirements for Infrastructure
Washington Consensus Reconsidered: Investment in Latin America Under
Towards a New Global Governance, (eds) J. Alternate Growth Scenarios 2011–2040”,
Stiglitz and N. Serra. New York: Oxford Global Journal of Emerging Market
University Press. Economies, January 2011; vol. 3, 1: pp. 59-
110
Hausman, R., B. Klinger and R. Wagner Lee, S. H., J. Levendis and L. Gutierrez
(2008), “Doing Growth Diagnostics in (2009): “Telecommunications and
Practice: A ‘Mindbook’”, CID Working Paper, Economic Growth: An Empirical Analysis of
No 177, September Sub-Saharan Africa”, Universidad del
Hulten, C., and A. Isaksson (2007). Why Rosario, Serie Documentos de Trabajo, No.
Development Levels Differ: The Sources of 64.
Differential Economic Growth in a Panel of Madden, G., and S. J. Savage, (2000):
High and Low Income Countries. NBER “Telecommunications and economic
Working Paper No. 13469. Cambridge, MA: growth,” International Journal of Social
National Bureau of Economic Research Economics, 27, 893-906.
Hulten, C. R., and R. M. Schwab (1991): Munnell, A. H. (1990): “Why Has
“Public Capital Formation and the Growth Productivity Growth Declined? Productivity
of the Regional Manufacturing Industries,” and Public Investment,” New England
National Tax Journal, 40, 121-134. Economic Review, January/February, 2-22.
Hurlin, C. (2006): “Network Effects of the Munnell, A. H. (1993): “An Assessment of
Productivity of Infrastructure in Developing Trends in and Economic Impacts of In-
Countries,” World Bank Policy Research frastructure Investment,” in Infrastructure
Working Paper 3808. Policies for the 1990s. OECD, Paris.
Holtz-Eakin, D., and A. E. Schwartz (1995b): Nagaraj, R., A. Varoudakis and M.-A.
“Spatial Productivity Spillovers from Public Véganzonès (2000): “Long-Run Growth
Infrastructure: Evidence from State Trends and Convergence across Indian
Highways,” International Tax and Public States,” Journal of International
Finance, 2, 459-468. Development, 12, pp. 45-70.
Norton, Seth W. “Transaction Costs,

9
Telecommunications, and the Straub, S. (2011): “ Infrastructure and
Microeconomics of Macroeconomic Development: a Critical Appraisal of the
Growth,” Economic Development and Macro-level Literature,” The Journal of
Cultural Change, October 1992, 41(1), pp. Development Studies, Vol. 47, 5, 683-708.
175-96. Yamarik, S. (2000): “The Effect of Public
Rodrik, D. (2008), One Economics, Many Infrastructure on Private Production
Recipes: Globalization, Institutions, and During 1977-96,” mimeo, University of
Economic Growth. Princeton University Akron, Akron, Ohio.
Press, Princeton, NJ. Yepes, T. (2007), Infrastructure investment
Roller, L-H. and L. Waverman, (2001): needs, The World Bank mimeo
“Telecommunications Infrastructure and Yepes, T. and A. Estache (2011),
Economic Development: A Simultaneous “Investment Needs for Infrastructure 2011-
Approach,” American Economic Review 91, 2020” , Background Note prepared for a
909-23. Labor Market Study, Middle East and North
Romp, W., and J. De Haan (2007): “Public Africa Region, The World Bank
Capital and Economic Growth: A Critical Waverman, L., M. Meschi and M. Fuss
Survey,” Perspektiven der (2005): “The Impact of Telecoms on
Wirtschaftspolitik, 8, 6-52. Economic Growth in Developing Countries”,
Seethepalli, K., M. C. Bramat, and D. Veredas The Vodafone Policy Paper Series, 2, 03, pp
(2008): “How Relevant Is Infrastructure to 10-24.
Growth in East Asia?,” The World Bank Wilson,John S. & Mann, Catherine L. &
Policy Research Working Paper 4597. Otsuki, Tsunehiro, 2003. "Trade facilitation
Shiu, A. and P-L. Lam (2008): “Causal and economic development : measuring the
Relationship between Telecommunications impact," Policy Research Working Paper
and Economic Growth in China and its Series 2988, The World Bank.
Region,” Regional Studies, Vol. 42.5, pp. World Bank (1994): World Development
705-718. Report, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
Sridhar, K. S. and V. Sridhar (2007): Zhan-Wei Qiang, C. and A. Pitt (2004):
“Telecommunications infrastructure and “Contribution of Information and
economic growth: evidence from Communication Technologies to Growth,”
developing countries,” Applied World Bank Publications No. 24.
Econometrics and International
Development, Vol. 7, No. 2.

10
Appendix

Estimated output
Elasticity to sector
Authors Sectors investment
Calderon & Serven (2009) Mixed 0,08
Canning (1999) Telecoms 0,14
Estache et al. (2005) Telecoms 0,19
Estache et al. (2005) Transports 0,34
Estache et al. (2005) Energy 0,5
Estache et al. (2005) Water 0,45
Hurlin (2006) Transports 0,07
Hurlin (2006) Energy 0,052
Hurlin (2006) Telecoms 0,104
Sridhar & Sridhar (2009) Telecoms 0,15

Average 0,2076

11

S-ar putea să vă placă și