Sunteți pe pagina 1din 18

Strategic Management Journal, Vol.

15, 131-148 (1994)

/ STRATEGIC RESOURCES:

c- TRAITS, CONFIGURATIONS AND PATHS TO


SUSTAINABLE COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE
JANICE A. BLACK and KIMBERLY 6. BOAL
College of Business Administration, Texas Tech University, Lubbock, Texas, U.S.A.

The resource-based view (RBV) of thefirm holds that certain assets with certain characteristics
will lead to sustainable competitive advantage. All the traits are required to be present to
result in sustainable competitive advantage. Such a trait approach overlooks the dynamics
of the creation of firm resources especially the strategically important factors as identified
by the resource based view theory. We propose that the resources are made up of factor
networks which have specific interfactor and inter-resource relationships that result in the
characteristic traits being evidenced. These strategic resource factor relationships include
network type, available substitutes and cogency relationships (compensatory, enhancing and
suppressing.) Spec$c configurations that lead to high or very high support of sustainable
competitive advantage are proposed. Twenty-two specific paths to sustainable competitive
advantage for a factor, contingent on resource factor traits and relationship configurations,
are proposed. The implications, upon confirmation of these configurations, are discussed.

Positioning the firm for a sustainable competi- First, it runs the risk of being tautological,
tive advantage by utilizing the firm’s strengths i.e., it posits that firms in attractive industries
to exploit opportunities and neutralize threats are successful. They are successful because they
while avoiding or fixing weaknesses has long are in attractive industries. A second, but more
served as the core framework for formulating important limitation of this framework is pointed
the firm’s strategy (Learned et a!., 1965). This out by Porter (1991) himself. The framework is
‘SWOT’ analysis benefited greatly from the concerned with the cross-sectional problem and
insights of industrial organizational economics, not the longitudinal problem. The cross-sectional
especially the work of Porter (1980; 1985). problem focuses on what makes some industries,
Porter’s famous 5 forces model emphasized and some positions within them more attractive.
analyzing industry structure to assess the rent It does not address why some firms are able to
earning potential of the industry based on entry get into advantageous positions in the first place,
and exit barriers. While Porter’s framework and why some firms are able to sustain these
has provided many useful insights to both positions and others are not. A third limitation
practitioners and researchers by concentrating stems from the implicit advice it gives to managers
on the external ‘OT’ side of the analysis, for formulating strategy. McWilliams and Smart
it nonetheless suffers from several significant (1993) point out that it misdirects managers to
problems. focus on industry level characteristics, encourag-
ing them to expend resources on influencing the
Key words: Resource-based view of the firm, net- industry’s structure even though their firm will
works, systems, strategic configurations, strategic not uniquely benefit from the *anges, thus
resources allowing competitors to free ride on the firm’s

CCC 0143-2095/94/09013 1-18


0 1994 by John Wiley & Sons. Ltd.
132 J. A . Black and K. B. Boa1

expenditures. One could possibly justify this if ance.’ There is acknowledged difficulty in
it could be shown that industry structure was the determining a priori what firm resources might
dominant determinant of firm performance. lead to a sustainable competitive advantage
Recent evidence however, (Rumelt, 1991; Roque- given the inherent uncertainty of the external
bert, Phillips, and Duran, 1993), suggests that, environment (Peteraf, 1993; Fiol, 1991). Nonethe-
at best, industry structure accounts for 8-15 less, Bromiley’s (1993) call for the operationali-
percent of variance in firm performance. Further- zation of RBV theory is well taken.
more, strategies based on market power can be Jay Barney begins to address this issue by
disastrous to the firm. For example, Carr (1993) identifying the needed characteristics of firm
in his analysis of the vehicle components industry resources and presents this in the VRIO frame-
found that firms utilizing a market power work (Barney and Griffin, 1992; Barney, 1992).
based strategy significantly underperformed, on This framework assesses the economic perform-
multiple performance measures, their competitors ance implications of resources by evaluating the
who followed a resource-based strategy. resources for the characteristics of value, rareness,
These limitations lead many (e.g., Barney, inimitability and organizational orientation
1986, 1991; Grant, 1991) to argue that strategy (VRIO).
formulation starts properly, not with an assess- The value of a resource will be dependent
ment of the organization’s external environment, upon the firm’s combination of resources and
but with an assessment of the organization’s the path that the firm is following. In other
resources, capabilities, and core competencies. words, value is the fit of the resource or factor
This resource based view (RBV) of the firm to strategy combined with the fit of the strategy
approach which emphasizes the internal side of to the external environment. The rareness of a
‘SWOT’ analysis to strategy formulation is gaining specific resource depends upon the combination
in popularity among strategy theorists (Reed and of physical rareness in the factor market and/or
DeFillipi, 1990; Summer et al., 1990; Meyer, the rareness of the perceived value of the
1991; Porter, 1991; Peteraf, 1993; Barney, 1991, resource due to a firm’s particular resource
1992). This emerging framework already contrib- combination. Inimitability is the continuation of
utes some promising insight into conditions imperfect factor markets via restricted infor-
leading to sustainable competitive advantages mation, the cost of recreating the specific
(Conner, 1991; Grant, 1991; Peteraf, 1993). RBV combination of resources that give a synergistic
theory notes that differences in firm resources result, or a combination of the two. Substitut-
will lead to differences in sustainable competitive ability rests on the continuation of imperfect
advantage (SCA). factor markets, the costs involved in the recreation
Porter argues that RBV theory also runs the of specific combination, or the cost of finding a
risk of being tautological, ‘Successful firms are new combination of resources that will enable
successful because they have unique resources. the firm to compete for the same product market
They should nurture these resources to be (i.e., a new path with new requirements).
successful (1991: l08).’ Barney (1993) points out Barney’s framework combines inimitability and
that the independent variables of RBV are nonsubstitutability into one category by treating
defined at one level of analysis (the level nonsubstitutability as a specialized case of inimita-
of resources or bundles of resources) while bility. Finally, the VRIO framework also
competitive advantage, not economic rent per explicitly considers if the organization is oriented
se, (the dependent variable) is at a different to utilize its strategic resources.
level of analysis (the level of strategies that the However, the VRIO framework, while
firm is pursuing). In essence, the independent implicitly acknowledging the importance of a
variable is at the functional level and the dynamic view, treats the evaluation of resources
dependent variable is either at the business or from a stand alone viewpoint ignoring how
corporate level. This eliminates the charge of resources are nested in and configured with one
RBV being tautological. another and the nature of relationshi& between
Bromiley (1993) notes that RBV theory them. Thus while Barney talks about bundles of
requires some concrete definitions of resources resources, the VRIO framework treats resources
that is less than ‘anything that leads to perform- as singular distinct items.
Strategic Resource Configurations 133

Another internal analysis that also reflects this In this paper we operationalize RBV theory
bundling problem is the Capital Asset Pricing by developing the network of relationships
Model (CAPM). When CAPM is used to assess among resources that is necessary for the
an investment decision, it considers a portfolio creation of the characteristic traits identified
of investments as a cross-sectional point-in-time by RBV theorists that are needed to attain a
issue similar to RBV theory and its bundle of sustainable competitive advantage. The paper
resources. CAPM assessments ignore whether is organized as follows. The first section gives
an investment in one project will affect the definitions of key RBV terms used in this
profitability of other ongoing or potential projects paper. The second section looks closer at the
(Oviatt, 1989). Rather than investigating these contribution network theory makes to our
internal relationships it assumes away these understanding of firm resources. The third
problematic interactions. Furthermore, as Robins section clarifies the identification of RBV
notes in his evaluation of the CAPM model, the strategic system resources. The fourth section
existence of firm specific capital raises ‘serious discusses the potential strategic relationship
problems in the use of the CAPM to estimate the configurations in detail. The last section pre-
risk associated with a capital project.’ (1992: 528) sents implications from this expansion of the
He points out that all firms have collateral assets RBV theory and our conclusions.
(X-assets) that are firm specific but do not have
defined opportunity cost and do not exist in
isolation from other tradeable assets. A firm’s DEFINITIONS OF FIRM RESOURCES
ability to generate quasi-rents is a function of the AND RELATIONSHIPS
interaction between these X-assets and other
marketable assets that the firm possesses. Yet, these Given the relative youth of RBV theory, we
X-assets (e.g., organizational routines, company explain our usage of the key terms and concepts.
policy, culture, etc.) will result in errors in the By accepting resources as the basic unit of
assessment of risk because of the unknown nature analysis (Grant, 1991) and constraining the
of that interaction. This example not only highlights resources of interest to strategic resources which
the bundling problem but also points out the are those that are theoretically characterized as
inadequacies of financial statements to accurately valuable, rare, neither imitable and/or substitut-
display asset value. This latter point is also able, and which an organization is oriented
supported by Hall as he too questions ‘the towards using (Barney, 1986, 1991; Dierickx and
significance of any quantification of shareholder’ Cool, 1989; Summer, et al., 1990), we bound
funds which does not recognize the value of our area of interest.
intangible assets’ (1992: 135).
Although the use of teams or bundles of
resources have been acknowledged in RBV RESOURCE FACTORS AND
theory (Grant, 1991; Dierickx and Cool, 1989; CATEGORIES
Fiol, 1991), most researchers do not address the
dynamic aspects of bundling resources and their Several researchers decompose firm resources
implications to RBV. Thus, while the RBV into combinations of resource ‘factors’ or ‘assets’
theory runs the risk of evaluating and categorizing (Barney, 1986; Dierickx and Cool, 1989; Porter,
resources without reference to the system in 1991; Grant, 1991; Mahoney and Pandian, 1992).
which those resources are embedded, it has not Since ‘assets’ implies something that is owned by
totally ignored interfactor relationships. For a firm and factors include either ownership and/
example, two such postulated relationships are or control, we choose to use factors as the
Teece’s (1986) discussion of cospecialized assets, elements making up a resource. While specific
and Amit and Schoemaker’s (1993) notion of relationships between the factors that make up
complementarity relationships affecting the value a particular resource have remained unexplored,
of a resource. However, these ideas of how general characteristics have been addres\ged.Bar-
resources within a firm interact with things both ney (1986) points out that resource factors differ
inside and/or outside the firm to create sustainable in their ‘tradeability.’ A tradeable factor is one
competitive advantage nee4Jurther development. that can be specifically identified and its monetary
134 J . A . Black and K . B. Boa1

value determined via a ‘strategic factor market.’ RESOURCE CATEGORIES


Tradeable factors’ availability and monetary
value in the factor markets will reflect the Several resource level categorizations recently
market’s awareness of those factors’ total have been presented in the literature. Barney
rareness (physical and/or particular use). By (1991) groups all firm resources into three
implication, a nontradeable factor will be firm categories: physical capital resources
specific and will not directly have its monetary (Williamson, 1975), human capital resources
value determined via that ‘strategic factor (Becker, 1964) and organizational capital
market.’ As an example, Arrow has earlier resources (Tomer, 1987). Grant (1991) lists six
brought attention to the factor of ‘trust’ which, categories of firm resources: financial, physical,
if purchased, immediately creates doubts in the human, technological, reputation, and organiza-
mind of the purchaser about what he/she tional. These categorical schemes appear to miss
purchased. This is a prime example of something the key issue in the search for sustainable
built up over time that is valuable but not competitive advantage (SCA). The key issue for
tradeable. He emphasizes this point in the firm resources, as regards to the creation and
following: maintenance of SCA, is based on the ability of
the resource to generate rent. While rent
Trust and similar value, loyalty, or truthtelling generation’s economic root is based on the
are examples of what an economist would differential between the expected rent and the
call “externalities.” They are goods, they are actual rent attained by a resource (Barney, 1993)
commodities; they have real practical value;
they increase the efficiency of the system, enable the bulk of the work rests also on implications
you to produce more goods or more of whatever of scarcity.
values you hold in high esteem. But they are Scarcity is related to the ease of identification
not commodities, for which trade on the open of the bundle of factors that creates or is the
market is technically possible or even meaningful. resource. If the bundle is a relatively simple one
(1974: 23).
which can be identified, then the ability to
imitate or find substitutes is increased and the
Dierickx and Cool (1989) suggest that resources opportunity for rent generation is decreased
should be differentiated as either asset flows or (Grant, 1991) and vice versa. Thus a more useful
asset stocks. An asset flow is a firm resource categorization would be one that focuses on this
that can be obtained or adjusted immediately. scarcity issue. Because of the link between
An asset stock is a firm resource which cannot scarcity and identification, we chose to categorize
be adjusted immediately and which is built up resources on the degree to which the factors that
over time from asset flows (Dierickx and Cool, make up the resource bundle can be identified.
1989). We name this aspect the Acquisition This categorization divides firm resources into
Process. Again since a company may utilize both two types: contained resources and system
something it directly owns and something that it resources.
controls, we choose to use ‘factor’ in referring
to the element that helps to create a resource.
Contained resources
The creation of a 2x2 matrix with the
two dimensions of ‘tradeability aspects’ and A contained resource is comprised of an identified
‘acquisition process aspects’ enables us to look simple network of resource factors that can be
at four factor types as described in Table 1. monetarily valued. By network, we mean the
Note that four general factors types are possible: configuration of factors, as well as, their relation-
tradeable asset flows, nontradeable asset flows, ships with each other that results in a particular
tradeable asset stocks, and nontradeable asset firm resource. We think that including both
stocks. It is the bundling of these four types of factors and their relationships is an important
factors that results in a particular resource. distinction, for the same reason that a list of
Thus resources can be viewed as a configuration ingredients from a recipe is not a cakb A cake
or network of factors. This in turn implies that requires the ingredients plus their relationships
there will be specific relationships between the among them for a successful result. A simple
factors. network is one with relatively few, mostly direct,
Strategic Resource Configurations 135
links among a small number of factors. ‘Simple,’ social creation, it is endowed with the implied
thus, implies that the network has definite creation and recreation of social constructs. By
boundaries. It is possible, then, to identify contrast, a contained resource is more similar
contained resources and, once identified, to to a discrete artifact. Indeed, it is the attributes
monetarily value them (Barney, 1986; 1989). of social creation that make the identification
This supports Barney’s contention that both assetof the complex network of system resources
difficult (Barney, 1992; Fiol, 1991). This implies
stocks and asset flows are tradeable either at the
resource level or, barring that, at the factor that the complete set or even a significant
number of factors will be neither readily nor
level. This implies that if a factor is nontradeable,
then, the nontradeable factor must have a easily identifiable. This poses problems in
substitute that is tradeable or alternatively be monetarily valuing such resources. This also
broken into component parts to allow market implies that fewer of the factors will be
value to be imputed to the resource. If the tradeable and that there are fewer substitutes
nontradeable factor has no tradeable substitute for factors or for the resource as a whole.
and can not be broken down into tradeable When Barney’s categories of resources (physical
components then, although the network it is resources, human resources and organizational
embedded in may appear simple, the nested resources) are again evaluated, it becomes
nontradeable factor implies that the network is evident that all three categories could be
complex. involved in the network of a system resource.
When we compare this categorization to In the case of a system resource, organizations
Barney’s (1991) three categories, it is evident are faced with a resource comprised of a
that since physical and some human resources complex network that makes an unknown
are ‘tradeable’ (Barney, 1991; Williamson, 1975),amount of contribution to a capability that may
contained resources will typically include them. itself be a member of a network of capabilities
Given the transparency of the simple network, which lead to a set of competitive advantages.
contained resources are unlikely to directly leadIt is clear, that often, while attempting to
to a SCA. replicate themselves through autopoietic pro-
Two conditions may occur where they might cesses (Morgan, 1983; Smith, 1983), the initial
support a SCA. First, the contained resource identification of a strategically important system
is disguised either by being overlooked by resource happens only when the resource
competitors or by being hidden or kept secret is unintentionally destroyed. For example,
consider Xerox’s initial decision not to develop
by the firm. In either case, since they are either
tradeable or have substitutes that are tradeable,further computer hardware and software tech-
they will be subject to quick erosion once nologies that later spawned Apple Computers
discovered. Second, they might be only one and Microsoft. These firms were participants
factor of a complex network which as a whole in the start of major technological changes in
creates the competency that supports SCA. Thus which Xerox had given up their ability to create
only indirect support is possible in the second a competitive advantage. Ultimately, it resulted
case. in a loss of competitive advantage in their chosen
industry as well. This inadvertent destruction of
the support of sustainable competitive advan-
System resources
tage can be likened to an internal Schumpeterian
A system resource is created by a complex shock. In this instance the external environment
network of firm resource factors. A complex didn’t change but the internal environment
network is one with many direct and indirect evolved and discarded the wrong genetic
links between a large number of factors which (resource) endowment. From our example, we
are made up of nested system resources, can infer that these internal choices may result
contained resources and other resource factors. in a later external Schumpeterian shock. To
‘Complex’ implies that the network doesn’t begin to address the question ob identifying
have definite boundaries which will make the networks of competencies, the general
monetary valuing implausible. Generally speak- characteristics of networks need to be integrated
ing, a system resourcs,is socially created. As a with RBV theory.
136 J. A . Black and K . B. Boa1

NETWORK THEORY AND THE chain will reveal the structural network. Notice
RESOURCE-BASED VIEW OF THE that a factor of that product’s network, the
FIRM manager of that department, will also individually
have links to other networks (the chain of
An organization’s unique set of assets is the command relationships). Sayles (1993) notes
result of the relationships both within and across that the widespread tactic of downsizing and
the levels of factors, resources, and competencies. eliminating middle managers may have a serious
This results in two types of networks: local impact on the firm’s ability to retain previous
networks (McCallister and Fischer, 1983) and competencies. Given that middle managers play
structural networks (Berkowitz, 1982). As applied a crucial role in integrating and aligning com-
to RBV theory, a local network is the configu- petencies, the competency is destroyed in the
ration of relationships within a level of analysis letting go of the managers (Sayles, 1993). This
as in among the factors, where it is the entire happened due to a lack of understanding of the
network that results in a resource. The resource inter-resource relationships that make up the
is not merely the listing of its factors but is the competency and results in further destruction
interaction configuration among the resource of other competencies due to the structural
factors. Thus if Resource D is composed of relationships that were involved.
factors A, B, and C; its local network consists Since a competency includes system resources
of all the existing relationships among A, B, and as factors, the competency’s local network will
C . For example, one can think simplistically of include all its component resources’ local net-
a unit’s performance as a result of the interactions works (since a resource is definitionally its
among the capacities of unit members (Factor local network). However, we do not expect a
A), the motivations present (Factor B), and the competency’s structural network to be just the
unit’s physical and capital resources (Factor C ) sum of its resource’s structural networks. Just as
(Blumberg and Pringle, 1982). the resource as a distinct entity has relationships
A structural network is the configuration of to other resources, we also expect a competency
relationships between local networks and between will have relationships with other competencies.
a factor of a local network and other networks For example, consider the case where G. M.,
or factors. Again applying social network theory under Roger Smith, spent 50 billion dollars
to RBV theory, this is the configuration of retooling and still wound up being the high cost
relationships between the focal resource and producer. We argue that this occurred because
other resources, as well as, the relationships plant and equipment are only one resource in
between other resources and the factors of the the competency (lean manufacturing) that they
focal resource. For example, if one looks at the were striving to attain and the weak link was
resource, a unit’s performance, as a single entity, the relationships needed with other resources,
it will have links to other resources and yet, such as management, HRM systems, the supply
individually, its factors (people’s skills, attitudes, chain, engineering, etc. (Womack, Jones, and
raw materials, etc.) will simultaneously also have ROOS,1990).
links between resources and/or factors. It is the A competency’s structural network will include
configuration of both of these sets of links that all of the factors’ structural networks, as well as,
create the resource’s structural network. This the overall competency’s external relationships.
structural network will be especially dense for This hierarchical nesting relationship is believed
nontradeable factors such as ‘trust’, given Itami to exist from the most nested single factor
and Roehl’s (1987) observation about the simul- through the overall organization as a unit
taneous use of intangible assets. (Berkowitz, 1982). Figure 1 shows a pictorial
In summary, a resource’s internal factor net- representation of the hierarchical nestings of
work is its local network (McCallister and Fischer, factors, resources, and competencies.
1983), and its relationship outside of its local Notice the dotted local network relationship
network is its structural network (Berkowitz, lines in the system resource linkink all the
1982). One might think of the product or resource factors together. Then, in the bottom network
that is a department’s end result as the artifact presentation, note that the system resource is
of the local network and *<
its place in a value imbedded in the competency’s local network. As
Strategic Resource Configurations 137

NETWORK HIERARCHICAL
NESTING
SYSTEM NETWORK

COMPETENCY NETWORK
with embedded system network

--LOCAL NETWORK
STRUCTURE NETWORK
ll.l....l.l.-l...
-
RELATIONSHIPSWITH ANY OTHER
FACTOR, RESOURCE OR COMPETENCY

Figure 1. Network hierarchical nesting


."...."....*."...

implied in Figure 1, the local networks and the being created when some objects or individuals
structural networks are not independent. While are internally related to each othe to form a
this creates problems in understanding causal structure' (Tsoukas, 1989).
i,
relationships, it helps us to understand the Given the potential complexity of the creation
creation of organizational synergy. It provides of firm resources, the RBV framework provides
further support of the idea of 'emergent powers a useful heuristic for discriminating between
138 J. A . Black and K . B. Boa1

situations of competitive parity, temporary com- Valuable was expanded to include the subdimen-
petitive advantage or sustainable competitive sions of an external link of ‘overlap with strategic
advantage (Barney, 1992). Although RBV litera- industry factors, and implied internal fit issue of
ture has evaluated a resource as a discrete unit ‘complementarity’.’ Rare was expanded to include
(Barney, 1992; Amit and Schoemaker, 1993; scarcity and low tradeability. Inimitable was
Grant, 1991), in the following section we show broken out into inimitability and limited substitut-
how it also can enable us to look for relationships ability. Finally Barney’s ‘0’ from ‘VRIO’,
that are believed to lead to high or very high organized to capitalize on the resource, would
support of sustainable competitive advantage. In align with Amit and Schoemaker’s appropriability
other words, to look for the relationships that and durability characteristics.
are resulting in the desired characteristics. The finer grained characteristics provided by
Amit and Schoemaker (1993) do provide a better
screening but the dynamic nature involved in the
RBV implied strategic relationships
bundling of the factors and resources into
In looking for stategic relationships, we note competencies remains a mentioned but not
from the literature that Schoemaker (1990) integrated feature. Our application of social
suggests that it is necessary to explore how network theory begins to unravel some of the
socially complex resource factors and resources issues of the dynamics. In our presentation, the
magnify or diminish each other, but he doesn’t choice of a resource to be evaluated is a reflection
specify what form those relationships may take. of the management’s belief in the overlap of the
In a similar vein, Grant (1991) points out the resource with the relevant key industry factors
need for examining intra and intercapability (Amit and Schoemaker, 1993). We do not address
resource relationships. Likwise, Conner (1991) this external link but turn our attention inwards
has noted a nested condition in regard to asset to the determination of just what it is that causes
stocks and flows. Amit and Schoemaker (1993) a resource to exhibit the rest of the needed
suggest that these complexities create nestedness characteristics. The issues of tradeability, dura-
problems across organizational level. Robins bility and possibly appropriability are reflections
(1992) argues that it is these firm specific of the 2x2 Tradeability and Acquisition Process
relationships which generate quasi-rents since the matrix of factor types. The issues of perceived
tradeable factors (barring market inefficiencies) scarcity and inimitability are reflections of the
would have their value bid away. complexity of the network. While substitutability
It has been argued that the needed character- ramifications may also be a reflection of the
istics of firm resources to generate rents also complexity of the network, they also may mitigate
make it unlikely if not impossible to be able to that complexity and so substitutability stands
determine a priori the set of resources needed as a separate relationship. The internal value
to gain or sustain a competitive advantage represented by complementarity, appropriability
(Barney, 1986, 1991; Peteraf, 1993; Robins, and possibly durability are the reflections of what
1992). Certainly, uncertainty in the external we term cogency relationships. These additional
environment contributes to this a priori determi- dynamic and key relationships are built on
nation problem but equally important is the Schoemaker (1990), Amit and Schoemaker
uncertainty in the internal environment due to (1993), and Robins (1992). We suggest that
the relationships between the factors that make cogency relationships have three forms: com-
up a resource, between resources that make up pensatory, enhancing, and suppressing/
competencies and between the competencies that destroying.
are needed to follow a firm’s strategy. The A compensatory relationship exists when a
nestedness problems may also point to important change in the level of one resource is offset by
relationships across the levels, as well as, within a change in the level of another resource. This
them. relationship may be symmetric or a ymrnetric.
We propose that these relationships are implied Note that here we focus on changes fin existing
. .
by the characteristics already identified as needed resources and not on replacing the existing
for SCA. Amit and Schoemaker (1993) expanded resource. Furthermore, compensatory relation-
upon Barney’s VRIO (19Q2) base characteristics. ships are not equivalent to substitutability
Strategic Resource Configurations 139
relationships. For example, increased effort can the concept of multiple paths leading to SCA
make up for differences in ability but it can’t for firms with heterogeneous resources. In other
substitute for lack of ability. words, value is the fit of the factor (and its
An enhancing relationship exists when the relationships to other factors in the resource
presence of one factor magnifies the impact of a network) to strategy combined with the fit of
different factor. Amit and Schoemaker (1993) the strategy to the external environment. Indeed,
refer to this as complementarity. We do not value may not be determined for each resource
think that enhancing relationships require a factor individually but for an entire bundle. For
bilateral dependence as is implied in Amit and example, if the ways of equally competing include
Schoemaker’s discussion of complementarity. Resources A , B, C, D, E, F, G, H and I but in
That is, an enhancing relationship may also be certain combinations; then Firm 1 may use
unidirectional or asymmetric. Changes in A A + B + C, while Firm 2 may use A + D + E.
magnify changes in B but not vice versa. At the same time, Firm 3 may use G + H + I
For example, Magic Johnson, a famous U.S. and Firm 4 may use B + E + F. Therefore,
basketball player, was noted for making other resource A has value for Firms 1 and 2, but not
players better; other players didn’t make him for Firms 3 and 4. The value depends on what
better (some might suppress his ability but other factors are present or controlled by the
not enhance it). Another example arises from specific firm in question. This implies that a
Parthasarthy and Sethi’s (1992) analysis of flexible resource factor as such may not be a substitute
automation use in manufacturing systems. They but that the entire bundle or configuration of
found that when both scope and speed flexibilities the resource factors may act as a substitute for
were in place, along with a flexible automation another and different bundle of resource factors.
system, then there was a positive significant It is this aspect of configurational use of resource
effect on performance. If there was only the factors that allows firms to pursue similar
presence of either speed or scope flexibilities competitive strategies with different resources.
with the flexible automation, then there was no We believe, this also helps to explain why firms
significant effect on performance. This illustrates following different generic competitive strategies
the enhancing relationship between the contained can be equally successful (Conant, Mokwa and
resource (speed and scope flexibilities) and the Varadarajan, 1990) and why there are no
contained resource (flexible automation system) consistent differences in performances between
but not compensatory relationship that result in strategic groups (Cool and Schendel, 1988).
the positive performance differential. We present theoretical combinations of factor
Likewise, suppressing relationships exist when characteristics (or attributes) and relationships,
the presence of one factor diminishes the impact as well as, potential benefits of these proposed
of another. The lack of ability on the part of heuristics. Later in this paper, we develop these
other players suppressing Magic Johnson’s playing relationships more fully (See Figures 3-6). Before
was previously acknowledged as a suppressing further exploring the relationships among
relationship. Again using Parthasarthy and Sethi resources, we need to identify the strategic
(1993), they found that a mechanistic structure system resource.
had a negative effect on the relationship between
flexible automation and performance levels. An
extreme case of suppression would be the IDENTIFICATION OF STRATEGIC
complete destruction of the resource. An example SYSTEM RESOURCES
would be in the clash of cultures in merging
companies with the ultimate destructon of the To summarize, a strategic system resource is a
suppressed culture. socially created complex network comprised of
The strategic value of cogency relationships is tradeable and nontradeable factor stocks and
proposed to be dependent upon specific intra flows and their relationships with each other.
and interresource inherited characteristic traits While complexity may be desirable to hnfound
and network and substitutability relationships. competitors, complexity makes it difficult for firms
This view is consistent with the concept of to create, manage, exploit and nurture their
equifinality in open systeq theory and supports resources. Amit and Schoemaker (1993) highlight
140 J. A . Black and K . B . Boa1
the difficulty of making decisions about resource ability (Barney, 1991, 1992; Grant, 1991), and
development and deployment in the face of Cogency (Schoemaker, 1990). The Cogency
uncertainty and complexity. Although the specifics relationship has three subdimensions: Compensa-
of a system resource will be dependent upon its tory, Enhancing and Suppressing relationships.
context, we develop a conceptual framework to We submit that the relevant relationships can
explain the key dimensions and the relationships only be considered when a proposed factor
between them in an effort to enlighten a firm as has been identified. The specification of these
it copes with this issue and to highlight specifically
characteristics will enable a firm to determine
the implication of a network orientation to the how much and what type of effort it will take to
bundling problem noted earlier. create and maintain that factor and ultimately
the resource and from. the resource to the
competencies that enable it to achieve its SCA.
System resource local network dimensions
Based on the preceding, we now present
In considering the composition of the system potential configurations of firm resource factors
resource network, we use the five strategic that we propose are necessary to lead a system
dimensions presented above. The dimensions are resource to high or very high support of
related to basic factor characteristics and their competitive advantage. We intend for these paths
interfactor relationships. Recall that the four to be useful heuristics enabling both managers
basic factor types are derived from the four cell and researchers to address the incredible com-
matrix utilizing Tradeability aspects (Barney, plexity and uncertainty that the socially created
1986) and Acquisition Process aspects (Dierickx resource inherently has.
and Cool, 1989). The applicable time dynamism
issues for this factor are included in the Acqui-
sition Process dimension (Dierickx and Cool, POTENTIAL CONFIGURATIONS OF
1989; Grant, 1991; Nelson and Winter, 1982; SYSTEM RESOURCE LOCAL
Porter, 1991). Recall also that the relevant NETWORKS
relationships derived from the characteristics
needed to support SCA include Network Type The support of a sustained competitive advantage
(Dierickx and Cool, 1989; Grant, 1991), Substitut- is proposed to be the result of the specific

INHERENT

I VERY HIGH
OR HIGH
SUPPORT OF
RELATIONSHIPS SUSTAINABLE
c
COMPETITIVE
ADVANTAGE

OMPENSATORY
ENHANCING

Figure 2. Strategic firm resource factor-inherent traits and relationships


Strategic Resource Configurations 141

combinations of the listed key dimensions. Thus Nontradeable asset flow


strategic resources will have networks with the
following configuration attributes. By using the A nontradeable asset flow factor can provide
RBV theory as previously presented by Barney high support if it is a member of a system
(1992), the potential 256 combinations of inferred resource with a complex network (Node 1, YES).
relationships are reduced to only 22 strategic This context diminishes the problem for SCA
configurations that theoretically support a SCA. from the time dependency aspect of the factor.
The specific configuration for a particular factor If it has substitutes (Node 2, YES), but there
can be identified by tracing a decision line throughare no compensatory relationships either with
the proposed strategically necessary relationships. tradeable or nontradeable network factors (Nodes
While acknowledging that many of these questions 3 and 4, NO) and there is an enhancing
have a range of answers, for the sake of parsimony, relationship (Node 5, YES; Path d), the factor
these combinations are shown in the form of may still lead to SCA due to the last relationship
decision trees (See Figures 3-6) and are discussed working to increase its specific importance to the
below. To minimize redundancy, the logic for the network. Note that this particular configuration
path choice is presented with the original path may be capable of only temporary high support
presentation. All subsequent presentations of that due to the substitutability relationship, if the
decision path are based on the original logic. substitute also is capable of providing an enhanc-
ing relationship.
Additional paths are postulated when this factor
Tradeable asset flow
has no substitutes (Node 2, NO). Depending upon
If a resource factor is a tradeable asset flow, it whether or not this factor has a compensatory
will only provide support for SCA in the presence relationship with other nontradeable factors, there
of X-assets (Robins, 1992) (recall that an X- are three possible paths to SCA. If it does have a
asset is the firm specific asset that allows the compensatory relationship with a nontradeable
attainment of a quasi-rent). We propose three factor (Node 4, YES), this is sufficient to lead to
configurations that can provide high support. high support of SCA (Path e). If, however, it does
They start with the requirements of the tradeable not have any compensatory relationships (Nodes
asset flow being a factor of a system resource 3 and 4, NO), it can lead to very high support of
that is in a complex network (Node 1, YES) SCA if it has an enhancing relationship (Node 5,
where substitutes for the element are not available YES; Path f). We believe that if the factor does
(Node 2, NO). These decisions address the issues not have an enhancing relationship it will still
of rareness and time dependency by creating support SCA if it also does not have any suppressing
ambiguity in the factor’s role in the firm resource relationships (Node 6, NO; Path g). A comparison
and impacting the amount of time it would take of Figures 3 and 4 suggests that nontradeable asset
a competitor to imitate it. The firm’s path to flows provide an additional path to SCA and
high support of SCA is attained when the factor where the paths are similar suggest that in some
has a compensatory cogency relationship only cases the magnitude of the effects may be greater.
with nontradeable factors (Node 3, NO; and
Node 4, YES), because decisions 3 and 4 again
Tradeable asset stock
diminish the tradeability and flow aspects by
allowing it to be offset with a firm specific asset When the factor under consideration is a tradeable
only (Path a). The last two paths (b and c) do asset stock, it will provide high support when it
not have any compensatory relationships (Nodes is a member of a complex network (Node 1,
3 and 4, NO) but have either an enhancing YES). This provides a starting point for assessing
(Node 5, YES) or neutral cogency relationship the six paths that lead to high support of SCA.
(Nodes 5 and 6, NO) with any other system factor. We will first discuss the two paths for which
We present the enhancing cogency relationship as substitutes exist (Node 2, YES). If the factor has
a path since this type of a relationship may no compensatory relationshipswith other tradeable
increase the particular factor’s importance since network factors (Node 3, NO) but has a compensa-
it may be the only possible factor that can tory relationships with other nontradeable factors
provide that particular enhancing capability. (Node 4, YES), that is sufficient to provide support
142 J . A . Black and K . B. Boa1

RESOURCE FACTOR --
TRADEABLE ASSET FLOW

POTENTIAL SUPPORT OF
SUSTAINABLE COMPETITIVE
ADVANTAGE

1. Is this factor a member of a complex network?


5. Is this factor in an enhancing relationship with another network
2. Do substitutes exist for this factor? factor?

3. Is this factor in a compensatory relationship with a 6. Is this factor in a suppressing relationship with another
tradeable network factor? network factor?

4. Is this factor in a compensatory relationship with a Leads to either competitive parity or competitive
nontradeable network factor? disadvantage.

# Decision Path to probable support of SCA This same pattern is followed for all decision nodes.

Figure 3. System resource local network configuration decision tree

of SCA (Path h). If, however, the factor has If no compensatory relationships exist (Node
no compensatory relationships with nontradeable 4, NO), two paths will still lead to SCA. In the
network factors (Node 4, NO), it can still lead to first instance, if this factor has an enhancing
SCA if it has an enhancing relationship with other relationship with another network factor (Node
network factors (Node 5, YES; Path i). While it 5, YES), then it will lead to very high support
is possible that due to the availability of a substitute of SCA (Path 1). The more of these enhancing
for these two configurations to be imitated or relationships, the stronger the support of SCA.
entirely substituted for, the overall effect of the It will still provide support without an enhancing
enhancing relationship, the time dependency of relationship if it does not have a suppressing
the stock and the complex network causing relationship (Node 6, NO; Path m). This is
ambiguity about the factor’s role make it unlikely. possible, because given the rest of the factors in
Returning to Node 2, if no substitutes exist that local network, it is not likely that competitors
(Node 2, NO) and even if this factor has will be able to timely duplicate this resource due
compensatory relationships with other network to the time constraints in creating this tradeable
factors without regard to tradeability (either Nodes asset stock and the complex network.
3 or 4, YES), it can still lead to at least high
support of SCA (Path j). The compensatory
Nontradeable asset stock
relationship with a nontradeable network factor
(Node 4, YES) magnifies the path effects to very The strongest supporter for sustained competitive
high support due to the complex network creating advantage is the nontradeable asset stock. Com-
ambiguity about the factor and the offsetting pared to tradeable asset stocks, nontradeable
abilities are tied to firm specific, or very rare, asset stocks provide the basis for three new paths
factors (Path k). and the magnification of some path effects.
Strategic Resource Configurations 143
RESOURCE FACTOR --
NON-TRADEABLE ASSET FLOW
POTENTIAL SUPPORT OF
SUSTAINABLE COMPETITIVE
ADVANTAGE
-
v
E
R
Y
H
I
G
H

1. Is this factor a member d a complex network?


5. Is this factor in an enhancingrelationshipwith another network
’ i. Do substitutesexist for this factor? factor?

3. Is this factor in a compensatory relationshipwith a 6. Is this factor in a suppressing relationship with another
tradeable network factor? network factor?

4. Is this factor in a compensatory relationshipwith a Leads to either competitive parity or competitive


nontradeable network factor? disadvantage.

# Decision Path to support of SCA This same pattern is followed for all decision nodes.

Figure 4. System resource local network configuration decision tree

Paths m, 0, p, q and r follow the same logic core ‘incompetency,’ i.e., a core competency
as Paths h, i, j , k, and 1 explained above with which hinders the organization’scompetitiveness.
respect to Figure 5 . Path t suggests that the Miller (1990) notes how a firm’s focus on
potential for support of SCA is very high when its core competencies may ultimately be self-
the asset stock is nontradeable compared to destructive-a process he refers to as the Icarus
when it is tradeable (Path m, Figure 5). This Paradox.
magnifying effect is due to the firm specific The last two paths do not require a complex
nature of nontradeable asset stock. Below we network (Node 1, NO). They do require that no
discuss paths s, u, and v. substitutes exist (Node 2, NO) but they do not
If a nontradeable asset stock is a complex require compensatory relationships (Nodes 3 and
network member (Node 1, YES) without substi- 4, NO). Providing that there is either an
tutes (Node 2, NO) despite the fact that enhancing relationship (Node 5, YES) or at least
there may be no compensatory nor enhancing no suppressing relationships (Node 6, NO), they
relationships existing (Nodes 3, 4, and 5 , NO), lead to high support of SCA (Paths u and v).
even if there is a suppressing relationship with Having no substitutes available will increase the
another network factor (Node 6, YES) providing importance of the firm specific aspects and time
the suppressing relationship is not resource or dependency aspects. The lack of compensatory
competency destroying, high support of SCA relationships among the factors does not hinder
(Path s) is still achievable. Note that not all the value and the enhancing relationships increase
suppressing relationships are harmful to firm the firm specific value. The neutral cogency
resources either because they do not suppress a relationship demonstrates that it at least does
key success factor or because they suppress a not detract from value creation.
144 J . A . Black and K . B. Boal

POTENTIAL SUPPORT OF
SUSTAINABLE COMPETITIVE
ADVANTAGE

RESOURCE FACTOR --
TRADEABLE ASSET STOCK

v
E
R
Y
H
[ I
G
H

I I
1. Is this factor a member of a complex network?
5. Is this factor in an enhancingrelationshipwith another network
2. Do substitutes exist for this factor? factor?

6. Is this factor in a suppressing relationship with another


3. Is this factor in a compensatory relationship with a
tradeable network factor? network factor?

Leads to either competitive parity or competitive .


4. Is this factor in a compensatory relationship with a
nontradeable network factor? disadvantage.

# Decision Path to support of SCA. This same pattern is followed for all decision nodes.

Figure 5. System resource local network configuration decision tree

Configuration implications
CONCLUSIONS AND IMPLICATIONS
Practitioner implications
The logic articulated above suggests that while
the debate between Barney (1986, 1989) and Recall that numerous practitioner problems were
Dierickx and Cool (1989) may be unimportant noted earlier in this paper. The problem of
in the sense that one can achieve SCA no inadvertently destroying a strategic resource by
matter what combination one starts from, it is divestiture or abandonment (Xerox’s example),
important in the sense that the number of the problem of choosing incorrectly based on a
potential paths available increases as one risk assessment that does not include firm specific
moves from flows to stocks and tradeable to resources (Robin’s 1992 argument), the problem
nontradeable. There are nine unique paths that of not understanding the relationships among
can at least potentially lead to high support of bundled things and their importance to the
SCA. When these decision paths are constrained utilization of those bundles are all problems that
by the resource factor types, the 22 paths just practitioners address with each strategic decision
presented occur. they make. This configurational network
Strategic Resource Configurations 145
POTENTIALSUPPORT OF
SUSTAINABLE COMPETITIVE
ADVANTAGE

RESOURCE FACTOR --
NON-TRADEABLE ASSET STOCK
f- f
n#
I v
I 0 .
E
H R
YES I Y
I .’ G
H H
-q I

1. Is this lador a member of a complex network?


:-+- -r

-t
G
H

2. Do substitutesexist for this factor?

3. Is thii fador in a mmpensatory reistionshipwith atradeable network


faW?

4. Is thisfactor in a compensatoryrelationshipwith a nontradeablenetwork


I
actor? 5. isthis factor in an enhancingrelatbnshipwith another network fador?
X Dedsbn Path to support of SCA. 6. Is this factor in a suppressingrelationshipwith amther network faclor?
* This same paltern is folbwed for ail decision nodes.
@Leads to either comptitiva parity or competKwe disadvantage.

Figure 6. System resource local network configuration decision tree

approach allows practitioners to determine the or analysis for many of the stratetic resources
effort it will take to create and maintain the of a firm (since these forms explicitly exclude
system asset of interest. By using the six strategic them) but ‘must actually IGNORE information
questions, a practitioner should be able, in from these sources to be successful in the long
addition to more fully identifying resources run’ (emphasis in the original, 1993:l). This
that make up their strategic competencies, to analysis will provide them -with somewhere to
understand the implications of changing one look and depending upon their ability to
factor of one resource on other apparently forecast the future, where to invest in system
unrelated resources. resources.
While the exact set of resource factors,
competencies and distinctive competencies will
Research implications and conclusions
vary from firm to firm and over time, this
framework gives practitioners a starting point The configurational aspects of a resource bundle
to more efficiently develop, change and use suggest that, while the external environment is
their resources. It also enables the confirmation important in determining and sustaining rent
of an educated guess about a firm resource and potential, other elements at either the strategic
to expand a subset of important factors. As group or firm level are also important (Rumelt,
Coff has noted, in many instances a practitioner 1991). Some may argue that rents are not
not only cannot look to a financial statement sustained but are earned all at once though they
146 J . A . Black and K . B . Boa1

may be extracted over time.’ We argue that competitive advantage. If the promise of these
beause resources implicitly have different eco- configurations holds upon confirmation by field
nomic life cycles, they are continually bundled, research, then these configurations and their
unbundled, and rebundled. This results in rents base definitions are an operationalization of
being sustained rather than earned all at once. resource based view of the firm theory. In such
This also implies that a firm may be using a a case, then the cross-sectional static view of
portfolio of rents instead of attaining a singular the firm’s ability to have a set of resources to
sustainable competitive advantage. The degree attain a sustainable competitive advantage will
to which a firm can keep its currently rent- be clarified as requested by Porter (1991). This
generating resources from being appropriated would also be a starting point to address the
by rivals is the degree to which a firm can longitudinal processes by which a firm creates
maintain its competitive position. and/or maintains such a competitive advantage.
By closely examining the resource based view With this operationalization, field work and
of the firm theoretically implied characteristics, testing of the firm resource based theory
necessary relationships (factor type, network of sustainable competitive advantage on the
membership, substitutability and cogency intrafirm level is attainable.
relationships) among factors can be identified.
Following this identification of relationships,
factor network configurations that lead to high ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
or very high support of sustainable competitive
advantage are proposed. We present a total of An earlier version of this paper was presented
16 projected configurations that should lead to at the 34th Annual Meeting of the Western
high support and six that lead to very high Academy of Management, San Jose, CA. The
support of sustainable competitive advantage. authors would like to thank Jay Barney,
These are the configurations of relationships Raphael Amit, anonymous reviewers, partici-
among the factors needed to create a sytstem pants at the Strategic Management Journal’s
resource that can support the attaining of a conference on New Strategy Paradigms, and
sustainable competitive advantage. In other the editors of this special edition, C.K. Prahalad
words, the configuration of factors and relation- and Gary Hamel for comments on an earlier
ships allows the creation of a resource that has version of this paper.
the needed strategic characteristics of valuable
rare, inimitable and organized to utilize.
The specific combination for any firm will be REFERENCES
a result of the firm’s history (and thus its
existing set of firm resource factors), a firm’s Amit, R. and P. J. H. Schoemaker (1993). ‘Strategic
strategy, and the degree to which the firm’s assets and organizational rent’, Strategic Manage-
strategy fits the external environment, especially ment Journal, 14(1), pp. 3345.
in regard to its competitors. The nesting Arrow, K. J. (1974). The Limits of Organization. W.
relationships of factors, resources, competenc- W. Norton, New York.
Barney, J. B. (1986). ‘Strategic factor markets:
ies and distinctive competencies calls for firm Expectations, luck and business strategy’, Manage-
resources comprised of contained resources and ment Science, 32, pp. 1231-1241.
system resources. Barney, J. B. (1989), ‘Asset stocks and sustained
We specifically see the use of substitution competitive advantage: A comment’, Management
relationships and cogency relationships as the Science, 35, pp. 1511-1513.
Barney, J. B. (1991). ‘Firm resources and sustained
screening for strategic resources. The appropri- competitive advantage’, Journal of Management,
ate combination of substitution, compensatory, 17(1), pp. 99-120.
enhancing, neutral and suppressing relation- Barney, J. B. (1992). ‘Integrating organizational
ships in a system resource makes it possible for behavior and strategy formulation research: A
all resource factor types to lead to sustainable resource based view’, Working Paper, Texas A&M,
College Station, TX.
Barney, J. B. (September 1993). Public communi-
cations in Business Policy and Strategy Email
Our thanks to Jay Barney for pointing this out. Network.
Strategic Resource Configurations 147
Barney, J. B. and R. W. Griffin (1992). The Meyer, A. D. (1991). ‘What is strategy’s distinctive
Management of Organizations: Strategy, Structure, competence?’, Journal of Management, 17,
Behavior. Houghton Mifflin Company: Boston, pp. 821-833.
MA. Miller, D. (1990). The Icarus Paradox: How Excep-
Becker, G. S . (1964). Human Capital: Columbia, New tional Companies Bring About Their Own Downfall.
York. Harper Collins, New York.
Berkowitz, S. D. (1982). An Introduction to Structural Morgan, G. (ed.) (1983). Beyond Method: Strategies
Analysis: The Network Approach to Social Research. for Social Research. Sage Publications, Beverly
Butterworth and Co., Ltd., Toronto, Canada. Hills, CA.
Blumberg, M. and C . D. Pringle (1982). ‘The missing Nelson, R. R and S . Winter (1982). An Evolutionary
opportunity in organizational research: Some impli- Theory of Economic Change. Harvard University
cations for a theory of work performance’, Academy Press, Cambridge, MA.
of Management Review, 7(4), pp. 560-569. Oviatt, R. (1989). ‘Caveats concerning application of
Bromiley, P. (September 1993). Public communications the capital asset pricing model in the strategic
in Business Policy and Strategy Email Network. management concept’. Proceedings of the Academy
Carr, C. (1993). ‘Global, national and resource-based of Management, 1989 pp. 37-41.
strategies: An examination of strategic choice and Parthasarthy, R. and S . P. Sethi, (1992). ’The impact
performance in the vehicle components industry’, of flexible automation on business strategy and
Strategic Management Journal, 14(7), pp. 551-568. organizational structure’, Academy of Management
Coff, R. (September 1993). Public communications in Review, 17, pp. 86-111.
Business Policy and Strategy Email Network. Peteraf, M. (1993). ‘The cornerstones of competitive
Cool, K. D. and D. E. Schendel(l988). ‘Performance advantage: A resource-based view’, Strategic Man-
differences among strategic group members’, Stra- agement Journal, 14(3), pp. 179-192.
tegic management Journal, 9(3), pp. 207-223. Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive Strategy. Free Press,
Conant, J . S., M. P. Mokwa and P. R. Varadarajan New York.
(1990). ‘Strategic types, distinctive marketing com- Porter, M. E. (1985). Competitive Advantage. Free
petencies and organizational performance: A mui- Press, New York.
tiple measures-based study’, Strategic Management Porter, M. E. (1991). ‘Towards a dynamic theory of
Journal, 11(5), pp. 365-383. strategy’, Strategic Management Journal, Summer
Conner, K. (1991). ‘Theory of the firm: Firm Special Issue, 12, pp. 95-117.
resources and other economic theories’, Journal of Reed, R. and R. J. DeFillippi (1990). ‘Causal
Management, 17(1), pp. 121-154. ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable
Dierickx, I. and K. Cool (1989). ‘Asset stock competitive advantage’, Academy of Management
accumulation and sustainability of competitive Review, 15(1), pp. 88-102.
advantage’, Management Science, 35, Robins, J. A. (1992). ‘Organizational considerations
pp. 1504-1511. in the evaluation of capital assets: Toward a
Fiol, C. M. (1991). ‘Managing culture as a competitive resource-based view of strategic investment by
resource: An identity based view of sustainable firms’, Organization Science, 3(4), pp. 522-536.
competitive advantage’, Journal of Management, Roquebert, J., R. Phillips, and C. Duran (August
17, pp. 191-211. 1993). ‘How much does strategic management
Hall, R. (1992). ‘The strategic analysis of intangible matter?’. Presentation at the National Academy of
resources’, Strategic Management Journal, 13(2), Management Meeting. Atlanta, GA.
pp. 135-144. Rumelt, R. P. (1991). ‘How much does industry
Itami, H. and T. W. Roehl(l987). Mobilizing Invisible matter?’ Strategic Management Journal, 12(3),
Assets. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. pp. 167-185.
Grant, R. M. (1991). ‘The resource-based theory of Sayles, L. R. (1993). ‘Doing things right: A new
competitive advantage’. California Management imperative for middle managers’, Organizational
Review, 33(3), pp. 114-135. Dynamics. 21(4), 5-14.
Learned, E. P., C. R. Christensen, K. E. Andrews Schoemaker, P. J. H. (1990). ‘Strategy, complexity
and W. D. Guth (1965). Business Policy: Text and and economic rent’, Management Science, 36( lo),
Cases. Irwin, Homewood, IL. pp. 1178-1192.
Mahoney, J. T. and J. R. Pandian (1992). ‘The Smircich, L. (1983). ‘Studying organizations as cul-
resource-based view within the conversation of tures’. In G . Morgan (ed.), Beyond Method:
strategic management’, Strategic Management Jour- Strategies for Social Research. Sage Publications,
nal, 13(5), pp. 363-380. Beverly Hills, CA, pp. 160-172.
McCallister, L. and C. S . Fischer (1983). ‘A procedure Smith, K. K. (1983). ‘Social comparison processes and
for surveying personal networks’. In R. S. Burt dynamic conservatism in intergroup relations’,
and M. J. Minor (eds.), Applied Network Analysis: Research in Organizational Behavior, 5 ,
A Methodological Introduction. Sage Publications, pp. 199-233.
Beverly Hills, CA, pp. 75-88. Summer, C. E., R. A. Bettis, I. H. Duhaime, J. H.
McWilliams, A. and D. L. Smart (1993). ‘Efficiency Grant, D. C. Hambrick, C. C. Snow, C. P.
v. Structure conduct performance: Implications for Zeithaml (1990). ‘1990 Doctoral education in the
strategy research & practice, Journal of Manage- field of business policy and strategy’, I990 Yearly
ment, 19, pp. 63-79. Review of Management of the Journal of Manage-
148 J. A . Black and K . B. Boa1
ment, 12, pp. 167-183. research explanations', Academy of Management
Teece, D. J. (1986). 'Profiting from technological Review, 14(4), pp. 551-561.
innovation.' Research Policy, 15, pp. 285-305. Williamson, 0. E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies.
Tomer, J. F. (1987). Organizational Capital: The Free Press, New York.
Path to Higher Productivity and Well Being. Womack, J. P., D. T. Jones and D. Roos (1990).
Praeger, New York. The Machine That Changed the World. Rawson
Tsoukas, M. (1989). 'The validity of idiographic Associates, New York.

S-ar putea să vă placă și