Sunteți pe pagina 1din 17

Informal Institutions and Comparative Politics: A Research Agenda

Author(s): Gretchen Helmke and Steven Levitsky


Source: Perspectives on Politics, Vol. 2, No. 4 (Dec., 2004), pp. 725-740
Published by: American Political Science Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3688540 .
Accessed: 04/08/2011 15:11

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Perspectives on Politics.

http://www.jstor.org
Articles

Informal Institutions and Comparative


Politics: A Research Agenda
Gretchen Helmke and Steven Levitsky

Mainstreamcomparativeresearchon politicalinstitutionsfocusesprimarilyon formalrules.Yetin manycontexts,informalinsti-


tutions, rangingfrom bureaucraticand legislativenormsto clientelismand patrimonialism,shapeeven more stronglypolitical
behaviorand outcomes.Scholarswho fail to considertheseinformalrulesof the gameriskmissingmanyof the most important
incentivesandconstraintsthatunderliepoliticalbehavior.In thisarticlewe developa frameworkforstudyinginformalinstitutions
and integratingthem into comparativeinstitutionalanalysis.The frameworkis basedon a typologyof four patternsof formal-
informalinstitutionalinteraction:complementary, accommodating,competing,andsubstitutive.Wethenexploretwo issueslargely
ignored in the literature
on this the
subject: reasons
andmechanismsbehindthe emergenceof informalinstitutions,andthe nature
of theirstabilityandchange.Finally,we considerchallengesin researchon informalinstitutions,includingissuesof identification,
measurement,and comparison.

ver the last two decades,institutionalanalysishas that many "rulesof the game" that structurepolitical life
become a central focus in comparative politics. are informal-created, communicated, and enforced out-
Fueled by a wave of institutional change in the side of officially sanctioned channels.6Examples abound.
developingand postcommunistworlds,scholarsfrom diverse For decades, Mexican presidentswere selected not accord-
researchtraditionshave studied how constitutionaldesign, ing to rules in the Constitution, the electorallaw, or party
electoral systems, and other formal institutional arrange- statutes,but rathervia the dedazo("bigfinger")-an unwrit-
ments affectpoliticaland economic outcomes.1These stud- ten code that gave the sitting presidentthe right to choose
ies have produced important theoreticaladvances. his successor,specified the candidatepool, and prohibited
Nevertheless,a growingbody of researchon LatinAmer- potentialcandidatesfrom openly seekingthe job.7 In Japan,
ica,2 postcommunist Eurasia,3Africa,4and Asia5 suggests the "strictbut unwrittenrules"ofAmakudari("descentfrom
heaven"), through which retiring state bureaucrats are
awarded top positions in private corporations, have sur-
GretchenHelmkeis assistantprofessorofpolitical scienceat vived decades of administrativereform.8In Central Asia,
the Universityof Rochester(hlmk@mail. Her
rochester.edu). clan-based norms have "become the rules of the game,"
bookCourts Under Constraints:Judges, Generals,and while the constitutionalstructurescreatedafterthe collapse
Presidentsin Argentina,will bepublishedby CambridgeUni- of the Soviet Union are "increasingly... inconsequen-
versityPress.StevenLevitskyis associateprofessorofgovern- tial."9And in much of the developing and postcommunist
mentat Harvard University(levitsky@wcfia.harvard. edu). world, patternsof clientelism, corruption, and patrimoni-
He is the authorof TransformingLabor-BasedParties alismcoexistwith (and often subvert)new democratic,mar-
in Latin America:Argentine Peronismin Comparative ket, and state institutions.10
Perspectiveand is currentlywritinga bookon competitive Attention to informal institutions is by no means new
authoritarianregimesin thepost-Cold Warera. The to political science. Earlier studies of "prismatic soci-
authorsthank the Weatherhead Centerfor International eties,"11 "moraleconomies,"12"economiesof affection,"13
Affairsat HarvardUniversityand the KelloggInstitutefor legal pluralism,14clientelism,15corruption,16and consoci-
InternationalStudiesat the Universityof Notre Damefor ationalism,17as well as on government-businessrelations
generouslysponsoringconferenceson informalinstitutions.The in Japan,18blat in the Soviet Union,19 and the "folkways"
authorsalsogratefullyacknowledgecommentsrJomJorge of the U.S. Senate20highlightedthe importanceof unwrit-
Dominguez,Anna Grzymala-Busse, Dennis Galvan, Goran ten rules. Nevertheless, informal rules have remained at
Hyden,JackKnight,LisaMartin, Hillel Soifer,Benjamin the marginsof the institutionalistturn in comparativepol-
Smith, SusanStokes,Maria VictoriaMurillo,and Kurt itics. Indeed, much current literatureassumes that actors'
Weyland,as well as threeanonymousreviewersand the incentives and expectations are shaped primarily,if not
editorsof Perspectiveson Politics. exclusively,by formal rules. Such a narrow focus can be

December 2004 1Vol. 2/No. 4 725


Articles | InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

problematic,forit risksmissingmuchof whatdrivespolit- to vote by local brokers,such electionsare won not by


ical behaviorand can hindereffortsto explainimportant ideologicalcandidates
butby thosewiththelargestpolitical
political phenomena.21 machine.32
This articlebroadensthe scopeof comparative research Informalinstitutionsalsoshapeformalinstitutionalout-
on politicalinstitutionsby layingthe foundationfora sys- comesin a less visibleway:by creatingor strengthening
tematicanalysisof informalrules.Our motivationis sim- incentivesto complywith formalrules.In otherwords,
ple: good institutionalanalysisrequiresrigorousattention they maydo the enablingand constrainingthat is widely
to both formaland informalrules.Carefulattentionto attributedto formalinstitutions.33
SincetheFederalist
Papers,
informalinstitutions is criticalto understandingthe incen- scholarshaverecognizedthatthe normsunderlyingformal
tivesthat enableand constrainpoliticalbehavior.Political institutionsmatter.The stabilityof the UnitedStates'pres-
actorsrespondto a mix of formaland informalincen- identialdemocracyis not only a productof the ruleslaid
tives,22and in some instances,informalincentivestrump out in the Constitution,butis alsorootedin informalrules
the formalones. In postwarItaly,for example,normsof (such as gracious losing, the underuse of certain formal
corruptionwere"morepowerfulthanthe lawsof the state: andbipartisan
prerogatives, consensuson criticalissues)that
the lattercould be violatedwith impunity,while anyone preventformalchecksandbalancesfromdeteriorating into
who challengedthe conventionsof the illicitmarketwould severeconflictamongthe branchesof government.
meetwithcertainpunishment."23 To takea differentexam- Thesearehardlyisolatedexamples.Informalrulesshape
ple, althoughBrazilianstate law prohibitsextra-judicial formalinstitutionaloutcomesin areassuch as legislative
executions,informalrulesandprocedures withinthepublic politics,34 judicial politics,35 party organization,36cam-
securityapparatus enable and even encouragepoliceofficers paignfinance,37regimechange,38federalism,39 publicadmin-
to engagein suchkilling.24Thusofficerswho killsuspected istration,40and state building.41
violentcriminalsknow they will be protectedfrompros- Bringingtogethera largebut disparatebodyof scholar-
ecutionandpossiblyrewarded witha promotionorbonus.25 ship,we developa researchagendaaimedat incorporating
In suchcases,a strictanalysisof the formalruleswouldbe informalinstitutions
intothetheoretical toolkitsusedbystu-
woefullyinsufficientto understandthe incentivesdriving dentsof comparative In
politics.42 the sectionwe clarify
first
behavior. the conceptof informalinstitution,distinguishingit not only
Considerationof informalrulesis also often criticalto fromthatof formalinstitution,butalsofromotherinformal
explaininginstitutionaloutcomes.Informalstructures shape phenomena,includingweakinstitutions,informalbehav-
the performance of formalinstitutionsin importantand ioralregularities,
informalorganizations,andculture.Inthe
often unexpectedways.For example,executive-legislative secondsectionwe examinehow formaland informalrules
relationscannot alwaysbe explainedstrictlyin termsof interact.Expanding on theworkof Hans-Joachim Lauth,43
constitutionaldesign. Neopatrimonialnormspermitting wedistinguish among fourtypesof informalinstitution:
com-
unregulatedpresidentialcontroloverstateinstitutionsin plementary, accommodating, competing, and substitutive.
Africaand LatinAmericaoftenyielda degreeof executive The thirdandfourthsectionsaredevotedto issuesof infor-
dominancethat far exceedsa presidents'constitutional malinstitutionalemergenceandchange-questionslargely
authority.26Informalinstitutionsmayalso limitpresiden- ignoredin recentcomparative research.Finally,we discuss
tialpower.In constitutionalterms,Chilepossesses"oneof specificchallenges relatedto researchon informalinstitu-
the mostpowerfulpresidencies in theworld."27 Yet,dueto tions, such as issuesof identification,measurement,and
a setof informalinstitutionsthatencouraged executivecon- comparison.
sultationandpowersharing,Chileanpresidentssystemati- A few caveatsarein order.Althoughthe terminformal
callyunderusedtheirconstitutional duringthe
prerogatives institutionencompassesa wide rangeof social (e.g., the
1990s;28consequently,Chile was cited as an exception in a handshake, ortherulesof dating)andeconomic(e.g.,black
regioncharacterizedby presidentialdominance.29 markets)institutions,we areconcernedonly withpolitical
Informalinstitutionsalsomediatethe effectsof electoral rulesof the game.We restrictour analysisto the modern
rules.For example,Costa Rica'sproportionalrepresenta- period,whencodificationof lawis nearlyuniversal.Before
tion systemand ban on congressional reelectionofferno this period,our distinctionbetweenformaland informal
to performconstituencyser-
formalincentiveforlegislators rulesis less meaningful.Finally,althoughwe drawon a
vice. YetCostaRicanlegislatorsroutinelyengagein such broadrangeof cases,the exampleswe cite are illustrative
activities in response to informal, party-sponsored "dis- only, not comprehensive.
In the areaof candidateselection,
tricts"andblacklisting.30
studiesin theUnitedStatessuggestthatbecausecommitted
votersaremorelikelyto participatein primaries,primary What InformalInstitutions Are
systemsencouragethe electionof ideologicallypolarizing (and Are Not)
candidates.31 clientelism,where
Yetin a contextof pervasive The terminformalinstitutionhasbeenappliedto a dizzy-
primaryparticipationis limited largely to people induced ing array of phenomena, including personal networks,44

726 Perspectives on Politics


clientelism,45corruption,46clans and mafias,47civil soci- paperarewidely circumventedor ignored.Yetformalinsti-
ety,48traditionalculture,49and a varietyof legislative,judi- tutional weakness does not necessarilyimply the presence
cial, and bureaucraticnorms.We proposea more precise- of informalinstitutions.It may be that no stableor binding
and analyticallyuseful-definition of informal institution. rules-formal or informal-exist. For example,in his sem-
It should captureas much of the universeof informalrules inal articleon delegativedemocracy,GuillermoO'Donnell
as possible, but it must be narrow enough to distinguish arguedthat in much of Latin America, the formal rules of
informal rules from other, noninstitutional, informal representativedemocracyareweakly institutionalized.58In
phenomena. the absenceof institutionalizedchecks on executivepower,
We begin with a standard definition of institutions as the scope of permissiblepresidentialbehaviorwidened con-
rulesand procedures(both formaland informal)that struc- siderably,which resulted in substantialabuse of executive
ture social interactionby constrainingand enabling actors' authority.In subsequentwork, O'Donnell highlightedhow
behavior.50How to distinguish between formal and infor- particularisticinformal institutions, such as clientelism,
mal institutionsis, however,less clear.Some scholarsequate undermined the effectiveness of representative institu-
informal institutions with cultural traditions.51 Others tions.59O'Donnell'swork points to two distinct patternsof
employ a state-societaldistinction, treating state agencies formalinstitutionalweaknessthat should not be conflated.
and state-enforcedrules as formal, and the rules and orga- Clientelism and abuses of executive authorityboth depart
nizationswithin civil society as informal.52Still others dis- from formal rules, but whereas the former is an informal
tinguish between informalnorms,which areself-enforcing, institution, the latteris best understoodas noninstitutional
and formalrules,which areenforcedby a third party,often behavior.
the state.53 Second, informalinstitutionsmust be distinguishedfrom
Each conceptualizationfails to captureimportant infor- other informal behavioral regularities.Not all patterned
mal institutions.Forexample,althoughsome informalinsti- behavior is rule-bound or rooted in shared expectations
tutions are undoubtedly rooted in cultural traditions, about others' behavior.60Behavioralregularitiesmay be a
many-from legislative norms to illicit patterns of party productof a varietyof incentives.To cite an exampleoffered
finance-have little to do with culture. With respect to by Daniel Brinks,61removing one's hat in church is an
the state-societaldistinction, many institutions within the informal institution, whereasremovingone's coat in a res-
state (frombureaucraticnorms to corruption)arealso infor- taurantis simply a behavioralregularity.In the latter case,
mal,54while the rules governing many nonstate organiza- leaving one's coat on may bring physicaldiscomfort,but it
tions (such as corporations and political parties and is not expected to triggersocial disapprovalor sanction.To
corporations)are widely considered to be formal. Finally, be consideredan informalinstitution, a behavioralregular-
although the self-enforcingdefinition is analyticallyuseful, ity must respond to an established rule or guideline, the
it fails to account for the fact that informal rules may be violation of which generatessome kind of external sanc-
externallyenforced(for example,by clan and mafiabosses), tion. To take anotherexample, public graftis clearlyinfor-
even by the state itself (i.e., organizedstate corruption).55 mal behavior, but only some patterns of graft should be
We employ a fourth approach.We define informalinsti- considered institutional. Where graft is enforced from
tutions as sociallysharedrules, usuallyunwritten, that are above,62or where it is rooted in widely sharedexpectations
created,communicated,and enforcedoutsideof officiallysanc- among citizensand public officials(and a refusalto go along
tioned channels.56By contrast,formal institutions are rules risks incurringimportant costs),63corruption may indeed
and proceduresthatarecreated,communicated,and enforced be an institution. By contrast,where graft is neither exter-
through channelswidely accepted as official.This includes nally sanctioned nor rooted in sharedexpectations,but is
state institutions (courts, legislatures,bureaucracies)and rathera responseto low public sector salariesand ineffec-
state-enforcedrules (constitutions, laws, regulations),but tive enforcement,it may be best characterizedas a behavior
also what Robert C. Ellicksoncalls "organizationrules,"or pattern.
the officialrules that governorganizationssuch as corpora- Third, informalinstitutionsshould be distinguishedfrom
tions, political parties,and interestgroups.57 informal organizations.Although scholars often incorpo-
Distinguishing between formal and informal institu- rate organizationsinto their definition of institution,64it
tions, however,is only half the conceptual task. "Informal is useful, following Douglass North, to separatethe polit-
institution" is often treated as a residual category, in the ical actors (or "players")from the rules they follow.65
sense that it can be applied to virtually any behavior that Just as formal organizations (such as political parties or
departsfrom, or is not accounted for by, the written-down unions) may be distinguishedfrom formal rules, informal
rules.To avoid this pitfall,we must say more about what an organizations (clans, mafias) should be distinguished
informal institution is not. from informalinstitutions.Nevertheless,informalrulesmay
Four distinctions areworth noting. First,informalinsti- be embedded within these organizations,and just as for-
tutionsshouldbe distinguishedfromweakinstitutions.Many mal political organizations are studied under the rubric
formalinstitutions areineffective,in that rulesthat exist on of "institutionalism,"clans, mafias, and other informal

December 2004 | Vol. 2/No. 4 727


Articles I InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

structures may be usefully Figure 1


incorporated into informal A typology of informal institutions
institutional analysis.
Finally,we returnto the dis- Effective formal Ineffective formal
tinction betweeninformalinsti- Outcomes institutions institutions
tutionsand the broaderconcept
Convergent Complementary Substitutive
of culture.Culturemay help to
shapeinformalinstitutions,and Divergent Accommodating Competing
the frontierbetween the two is
a criticalareafor research.66In
our view, however,the best way
to pursue this agenda is to cast informal institutions in tion noncompliance. Where formal rules and procedures
relativelynarrowterms by defining informal institution in areineffective,actorsbelievethe probabilityof enforcement
termsof sharedexpectationsratherthansharedvalues.Shared (and hence the expected cost of violation) will be low.
expectationsmay or may not be rooted in broadersocietal These two dimensions produce the fourfold typology
values.67Distinguishing between sharedvalues and shared shown in figure 1. The types located in the upperleft (com-
expectationsallowsfuturescholarsto analyzepotentialcausal plementary)and lower right (competing) cells correspond
relationshipsbetween cultureand informalinstitutions,such to the "functional"and "dysfunctional"types that predom-
as whethersocietalvaluesreinforceor undermineparticular inate in much of the literature.The typology also yields two
informal institutions. novel types (accommodatingand substitutive)that allow us
to make sense of other, less familiarinstitutional patterns.

Four Types of InformalInstitution


Formal and informal institutions interact in a variety of Complementary informal institutions
ways. In this section, we develop a typology aimed at cap- The left side of the figure correspondsto informal institu-
turing these relationships.68Characterizationsof formal- tions that coexist with effective formal institutions, such
informal institutional relationshipstend to fall into one of that actors expect that the rules that exist on paperwill be
two sharplycontrastingcategories.One camp treatsinfor- enforced. The upper left corner combines effective formal
mal institutions as functional, or problem solving, in that rulesand convergentoutcomes, producingwhat Lauthcalls
they providesolutions to problemsof social interactionand complementary informalinstitutions.73Such institutions"fill
coordination,69which enhance the efficiency or perfor- in gaps"either by addressingcontingencies not dealt with
mance of formalinstitutions.70A second camp treatsinfor- in the formal rules or by facilitatingthe pursuit of individ-
mal institutions as dysfunctional, or problem creating. ual goals within the formal institutionalframework.These
Clientelism, corruption, and patrimonialism are said to informal institutions often enhance efficiency. Examples
undermine the performanceof formal democratic,market, include the myriad norms, routines, and operating proce-
and state institutions.71However, recent studies suggest a dures that ease decision making and coordination within
more complex picture than envisioned by either camp, in bureaucracies,74and judicial norms (such as the opinion
which informal institutions at times reinforceor substitute assignmentproceduresand the "Ruleof Four")that facili-
for the formal institutions they appearto undermine. tate the work of the U.S. SupremeCourt.75
To capture these differences,our typology is based on Complementaryinformalinstitutionsmay also serveas a
two dimensions.The firstis the degreeto which formaland foundation for formal institutions, creatingor strengthen-
informal institutional outcomes converge.The distinction ing incentivesto comply with formalrulesthat might other-
hereis whetherfollowing informalrulesproducesa substan- wise exist merelyon paper.76Thus scholarshave linked the
tively similar or differentresult from that expected from a effectivenessof the U.S. Constitution to a complementary
strict and exclusive adherenceto formal rules. Where fol- set of sharedbeliefsand expectationsamong citizens.77Like-
lowing the informal rule leads to a substantivelydifferent wise, the efficiencyof Singapore'spostcolonial bureaucracy
outcome, formal and informal institutions diverge.Where (the formalorganizationof which resembledthose of Indo-
the two outcomes are not substantivelydifferent, formal nesia and the Philippines) has been attributedto underly-
and informal institutions converge. ing norms of meritocracyand discipline.78Rural Chinese
The second dimension is the effectivenessof the relevant villagegovernmentsaremore likely to providepublic goods
formal institutions, that is, the extent to which rules and where there exist informal norms of social obligation gen-
proceduresthat exist on paper are enforced and complied erated by membership in local temple associations.79In
with in practice.72Effectiveformalinstitutions actuallycon- each case, informal institutions do not merely exist along-
strain or enablepolitical actors'choices. Actors believe that side effective formal ones, but rather play a key role in
there is a high probabilitythat officialauthoritieswill sanc- making effectivethe formal rules of the game.

728 Perspectives on Politics


Accommodating informal institutions enforced, which enables actors to ignore or violate them.
The lower left cornerof figure 1, which combines effective The cell in the lower right cornercombines ineffectivefor-
formalinstitutions and divergentoutcomes, correspondsto mal rules and divergent outcomes, producing competing
accommodatinginformal institutions.These informal insti- informalinstitutions.These informalinstitutions structure
tutions create incentives to behave in ways that alter the incentives in ways that are incompatible with the formal
substantiveeffectsof formalrules, but without directlyvio- rules:to follow one rule, actors must violate another. Par-
lating them; they contradictthe spirit, but not the letter,of ticularisticinformal institutions such as clientelism, patri-
the formal rules.Accommodatinginformal institutions are monialism,clan politics,and corruptionareamongthe most
often createdby actorswho dislike outcomes generatedby familiar examples.87Thus postwar Italian corruption was
the formal rules but are unable to change or openly violate embedded in "alternativenorms"underwhich actorscould
those rules.As such, they often help to reconciletheseactors' violate certainstate laws "with impunity,"88whereasthose
interests with the existing formal institutional arrange- who adheredto the law "metwith certainpunishment."89
ments. Hence, although accommodatinginformal institu- Competing informalinstitutionsareoften found in post-
tions may not be efficiency enhancing, they may enhance colonial contextsin which formalinstitutionswereimposed
the stabilityof formal institutions by dampening demands on indigenous rules and authoritystructures.In postcolo-
for change. nial Ghana,civil servantswere officiallyinstructedto follow
Chile'sexecutive-legislative power-sharingmechanismsare the rulesof the publicbureaucracy, but as RobertPricefound,
a clear example. Leadersof the Democratic Concertation most believedthey would pay a significantsocial cost (such
inheritedan "exaggeratedly strongpresidentialsystem"and a as a loss of standingin the community) if they ignoredkin-
majoritarian electoral systemthat rancounterto theirgoal of shipgroupnormsthatobligedthem to providejobsandother
maintaining a broad multipartycoalition.80Lackingthe leg- favorsto their families and villages.90Similarly,scholarsof
islativestrengthto amend the 1980 Constitution, Concer- legalpluralismhavearguedthat the imposition of European
taci6n elites createdinformalmechanismsof interpartyand legalsystemscreated"multiplesystemsof legalobligation."91
executive-legislativeconsultationaimed at counteractingits Becausethesesystems"embodiedverydifferentprinciplesand
effects.These power-sharingarrangements"enhancedcoali- procedures,"92adherenceto custom law at times requireda
tional trust"in a formalconstitutionalsettingthat otherwise violation of state law (and vice versa).
"providedvery few incentivesfor cooperation."81
Dutch consociationalpracticesmay also be characterized
as accommodating. The Netherlands' post-1917 democ- Substitutive informal institutions
racy was based on a set of "informal,unwritten rules"of Finally,the upper right corner,which combines ineffective
elite accommodation and power sharing, including exten- formal institutions and compatible outcomes, corresponds
sive consultationin policy making, mutualveto power,and to substitutiveinformalinstitutions.93Like complementary
the proportionalallocationof governmentjobs among polit- institutions,substitutiveinformalinstitutionsareemployed
ical parties.82Although these cartel-likearrangementsvio- by actorswho seek outcomes compatiblewith formalrules
lated the democratic spirit of the Dutch constitution (by and procedures.Like competing institutions,however,they
limiting the power of the vote), they reducedclassand reli- exist in environmentswhere formal rules are not routinely
gious conflict, therebyenhancing democraticstability.83 enforced. Hence, substitutiveinformal institutions achieve
Accommodatinginformalrulesalso emergedwithin state what formalinstitutionsweredesigned,but failed,to achieve.
socialistinstitutionsin the SovietUnion. Becausestrictadher- Substitutiveinstitutionstend to emergewherestatestruc-
ence to the formal rulesgoverningSoviet political and eco- tures are weak or lack authority. During Mexico's pro-
nomic life did not allow enterprisesto fulfill state targetsor tracteddemocratictransition,formalinstitutionsof electoral
permit individuals to meet basic needs, a set of informal dispute resolution(such as the electoralcourts)lackedcred-
norms-commonly known as blat-emerged in which indi- ibility and were frequentlybypassed.In this context, offi-
viduals met these goals through personal networks.84Not cialsof the nationalgovernmentand the oppositionNational
strictlyillegal, blat enabled factorymanagers,workers,and Action Partyresolvedpostelection disputes through infor-
bureaucratsto "find a way around formal procedures."85 mal concertacesiones, or "gentleman'sagreements."94Con-
By helping enterprisesto fulfill state targetsand individuals certacesiones thus served as a "waystation"for government
to obtain essentialgoods and services,this informalsystem and opposition elites until formal institutions of electoral
of exchangewas criticalto the survivalof the Sovietsystem.86 disputeresolutionbecamecredible.95In ruralnorthernPeru,
where state weaknessresultedin inadequatepolice protec-
tion and ineffective courts during the late 1970s, citizens
Competing informal institutions createdinformal rondascampesinas(self-defensepatrols)to
On the right side of figure 1 we find informal institutions defend their communities and rondaassemblies(informal
that coexist with ineffective formal institutions. In such courts) to resolve local disputes.96In rural China, some
cases, formal rules and proceduresare not systematically local officialscompensate for the state'sincapacityto raise

December 2004 1Vol. 2/No. 4 729


Articles I InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

revenueand provide public goods by mobilizing resources words, why, given the existenceof a set of formal rules and
throughtemple and lineageassociations,thereby"substitut- rule-makingmechanisms,do actorschoose to createinfor-
ing the use of these informal institutions for ... formal mal rules?Building on the previous section, we see three
politicalinstitutionalchannelsof publicgoods provisions."97 generalmotivations.
Taken together, these four types suggest that informal First,actorscreateinformalrules becauseformal institu-
institutionscannotbe classifiedin simpledichotomous(func- tions areincomplete.104Formalrulesset generalparameters
tional versus dysfunctional) terms. Although substitutive for behavior,but they cannot cover all contingencies. Con-
informal institutions such as concertacesiones and rondas sequently,actorsoperatingwithin a particularformal insti-
campesinas subvert formal rules and procedures,they may tutional context, such as bureaucraciesand legislatures,
help achieveresults(resolutionof postelectoralconflict,pub- develop norms and proceduresthat expedite their work or
lic security) that the formal rules failed to achieve. And addressproblemsnot anticipatedby formal rules.105
althoughaccommodatinginformalinstitutionssuch as con- Second,informalinstitutionsmaybe a "secondbest"strat-
sociationalism violate the spirit of the formal rules, they egy for actorswho prefer,but cannot achieve,a formalinsti-
may generateoutcomes (democraticstability)thatareviewed tutional solution.106 In some cases, actors simply lack the
as broadlybeneficial.It remainsan open question, however, power to changethe formalrules.Thus post-Pinochetelites
whether accommodating and substitutive institutions can in Chilecreatedinformalpower-sharing arrangementsbecause
contributeto the developmentof moreeffectiveformalstruc- they lacked the political strength to rewritethe 1980 Con-
tures, or whether they "crowdout" such development (by stitution.107Similarly,Soviet workersand managersopted
quelling demands for formal institutional change or creat- for the informalityof blatin partbecausetheywere unableto
ing new actors, skills, and interestslinked to the preserva- reformor do awaywith state socialistinstitutions.
tion of the informalrules).98The following two sections lay A broader statement of this motivation, elaboratedby
a foundation for addressingsuch questions. Carol Mershon, is that actors create informal institutions
when they deem it less costly than creatingformal institu-
tions to their liking.108In postwar Italy,Christian Demo-
Origins of InformalInstitutions cratic leaders who sought to keep the communist and
To date, much empiricalliteratureon informalinstitutions
neofascistpartiesout of power found it easierto develop an
has neglected questions of why and how such institutions
informal"formula"to excludethose partiesfrom governing
emerge.99Analysesof entrenchedcompeting informalinsti- coalitions than to push through parliamenta majoritarian
tutions such as custom law,clientelism,and patrimonialism
electoralsystemaimed at strengtheninglargemoderatepar-
frequentlytake them as historicalgivens, or part of a static ties.109Similarly,Costa Rican partyleaders'use of informal
cultural landscape, rarelyasking why they emerged in the
devices to induce legislatorsto engage in constituency ser-
first place. As a result, they often understatethe degree to
vice may have been easier than overturning the ban on
which informal institutions are modified, adapted,or even
reinventedover time.100Meanwhile, many existing expla- legislativereelection.1l0
nations (particularly studies of complementary institu- Inventing informal institutions may also be a second-
best strategywhere formal institutions exist on paper but
tions) confronta majorpitfallof earlyfunctionalistaccounts are ineffectivein practice.In the case of substitutiveinfor-
of formal institutions:they explain the emergenceof infor-
mal institutions, for example, actors create informal struc-
mal institutionsprimarilyin termsof theirpurportedeffects
tures not becausethey dislike the formal rules, but because
(e.g., the efficiency gains they yield), without identifying the existing rules-and rule-makingprocesses-lack credi-
the mechanismsby which they arecreated.101For example,
bility.Thus Mexican opposition leadersengagedin concert-
many earlyrational-choiceanalysestreatedinformalnorms acesionesduring the 1990s because they did not view the
as efficient solutions to problems of cycling, information,
formal electoral courts as credible, and Peruvianvillagers
or collectiveaction.102Although such explanationsmay par-
created rondascampesinasbecause the state judicial system
tially explain the persistenceof informal institutions once failed to enforce the rule of law.
established,they areinsufficient,if not misleading,for gen- A third motivation for creating informal institutions is
erating theories about institutional emergence. In this sec- the pursuit of goals not considered publicly acceptable.
tion we seek to move beyond static and functionalist
Becausethey are relativelyinconspicuous,"1informalinsti-
accounts, arguingthat compelling explanationsof informal tutions allow actors to pursueactivities-ranging from the
institutions must not only ask why actors create informal
rules, but also examinehow actorscreateand communicate unpopular to the illegal-that are unlikely to stand the
test of public scrutiny. Even where bribery,patrimonial-
those rules.
ism, and vote-buyingarewidely accepted,prevailingnorms
of universalismprevent their legalization. Norms of lax
Why Informal Institutions? enforcement-what the Dutch call gedogen-provide
We focus our discussion here on informal institutions that anotherexample.112Prostitution,soft drug use, and eutha-
areendogenousto formalinstitutionalstructures.103 In other nasia (or abortion in predominantly Catholic countries)

730 Perspectives on Politics


are legally proscribedbut widely tolerated. The informal out of elite-level strategicinteraction (Mexico'sconcertace-
proceduresenabling extrajudicialexecutions in Brazilmay siones). In other instances (corruption, clientelism, blat)
also be explained in these terms.113 informalrulesemergeout of a decentralizedprocessinvolv-
Informal institutions may also be created in pursuit of ing a much largernumber of actors. In either process,we
goals that are not internationallyacceptable.For example, may understandmechanismsof emergencein termsof focal
the geopolitical changes produced by the end of the Cold points, l8 repeatedinteraction,119or bargaining.120Alter-
War raised the external cost of maintaining openly (e.g., natively, informal institutional creation may be a histori-
military or Leninist one party) authoritarianregimes dur- callycontingent processin which informalstructuresarean
ing the 1990s, which led many autocraticelites to adopt unintended product of particularconflicts and compro-
formal democratic institutions. To maintain power in this mises. For example, Amakudarioriginated as a makeshift
new internationalcontext, autocratsin countrieslike Bela- strategyby Japaneseministry officialsseeking to reconcile
rus, Kazakhstan,Kenya, Peru, Russia, Ukraine, and Zim- prewarnorms of lifetime employment with postwar reali-
babwe resorted to informal mechanisms of coercion and ties of resource scarcity and strict seniority systems.121
control, rangingfrom use of paramilitarythugs to elaborate Although such informal institutions may ultimately take
systems of vote buying, fraud, co-optation, espionage, and on functions that are perceived as efficient or beneficial,
blackmail.14 these functions often have little to do with their origins.
Understandingwhy actorscreateinformalinstitutions is Analysesof the originsof informalinstitutionsmust also
not, however,sufficientto explainhow they areestablished. account for how they arecommunicatedand learnedin the
Incompletenessdoes not by itself explain how the need for absence of written down rules and public enforcement. In
additional rules translatesinto their creation (or, for that some cases, informal institutionalizationappears to be a
matter,why informal,ratherthan formal,rulesareadopted). processof sociallearningthroughwidely observedinstances
Where informalinstitutions area second-beststrategy,why of trialand error.The Mexican dedazowas institutionalized
are actorswho lack the capacityto change the formal rules through a "processof learningby example,"as PRI leaders
neverthelessable to establish and enforce informal ones? who broke the informal rules during the 1940s and 1950s
And where actors share certain illicit goals, how are they suffered political defeat and marginalization,while those
able to establish mechanisms that effectively circumvent who playedby the rules"wererewardedwith betterposts."122
the formalrules?In short, to avoid the functionalisttrap,it Similarly,postwar Italian prime ministers who broke the
is essentialto examine the mechanismsby which informal informal rule that gave parties the right to name govern-
institutions are established. ment ministers "sawtheir governmentsmeet rapid ends."
Their successorsquickly "learnedthe lesson," and by the
mid-1950s, "the rule of negotiated decisions by party and
How InformalInstitutions are Created faction leadershad been hammeredout."123
and Communicated Socialnetworksand politicalorganizationsmayalsotrans-
The construction of informal institutions differsmarkedly mit informal rules. Thus the norms of Amakudariwere
from formal rule-makingprocesses.Whereas formal rules diffused through social networks that linked universities,
are created through official channels (such as executives state bureaucracies,and privatecorporations,124 and infor-
and legislatures)and communicated and enforced by state mal networkswithin the Peruvianand Ukrainianstatescom-
agencies (such as the police and courts), informal rules are municated the rules of corruption and blackmail that
created, communicated, and enforced outside of public sustainedautocraticregimesduring the 1990s.125Political
channels, and usuallyoutside of the public eye. The actors parties also carry informal rules. Parties communicated
who create and enforce them may deny having done so. power-sharingarrangementsin Chile, the Netherlands,and
Hence, their origins are often unclear.1l5 postwarItaly;126 partyorganizationsenforcedthe systemof
Preciselybecauseof these differences,scholarsshould take kickbacksand briberyin Italy;127 and competinglocal party
the process of informal rule-makingseriously by identify- leadersspread rondascampesinasacrossnorthernPeru.128
ing the actors, coalitions, and interestsbehind the creation In sum, moving beyond functionalist accounts entails
of informal rules.To the extent that these rules are created identifying the relevantactors and interests behind infor-
in a context in which power and resourcesare unevenly mal institutions, specifying the process by which informal
distributed, they can be expected to produce winners and rulesare created,and showing how those rulesare commu-
losers.ll6 Thus, following Jack Knight,117scholarsshould nicated to other actors in such a manner that they evolve
be sensitive to underlying processes of conflict and coer- into sets of sharedexpectations.
cion, ratherthan assume pure coordination.
Processes of informal institutional emergence vary. In
some cases,the processis "topdown";informalinstitutions InformalInstitutional Change
may be a product of elite design and imposition (the Mex- Informalinstitutions areoften characterizedas highly resis-
ican dedazo,Dutch consociationalism),or they may emerge tant to change, possessinga "tenacioussurvivalability."129

December 2004 1Vol. 2/No. 4 731


Articles I InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

When change occurs, it is expected to be slow and incre- electoral courts over the course of the 1990s reduced the
mental.130Lauth, for example, argues that because infor- incentive of opposition leaders to work through informal
mal rules "do not possess a center which directs and concertacesiones, 138and the increasedeffectivenessof Peru's
co-ordinatestheir actions,"informalinstitutionalchange is public security and judicial systems led to the collapse of
likely to be an "extremelylengthy"process.131Yet informal many rondascampesinasand rondaassemblies.139
institutions do change-and often quite quickly. The Other sources of informal institutional change lie out-
centuries-oldChinese practiceof foot-binding disappeared side the formalinstitutionalcontext. For scholarswho view
within a generation,132and many of the informalrulesthat informalinstitutionsprimarilyas a productof culture,infor-
structuredMexican elite politics for much of the twentieth mal institutional change is rooted primarilyin the evolu-
century (includingthe dedazo)collapsedquicklyduringthe tion of societal values.l40 Because such shifts tend to be
late 1990s.133 glacialin pace, this patternof informalinstitutionalchange
Severalsources may generate the impetus for informal will be slow and incremental.We might understand the
institutional change. One important source is formal insti- erosionof traditionalor kinship-basedpatternsof authority
tutional change.The impact of formal rule changesshould in Europe in these terms.
not, of course, be overstated;many informal institutions Informal institutions may also change as the status quo
have proved resilienteven in the face of large-scalelegal or conditions that sustain them change. 1 Developments in
administrativereform.134Nevertheless, to the extent that the external environment may change the distribution of
formal institutional change alters the costs and benefits of power and resourceswithin a community,weakeningthose
adhering to particularinformal rules, it can serve as an actors who benefit from a particularinformal institution
important catalystfor informal institutional change. and strengtheningthosewho seekto changeit. Thus Mexico's
Two typesof formalinstitutionalchangearerelevanthere. increasinglycompetitive electoral environment during the
The first is change in formal institutional design. Particu- 1990s strengthenedlocal PRI leadersand activistsvis-a-vis
larly for informal institutions that are endogenous to for- the nationalleadership,which allowed them to contest and
mal structures,a change in the design of the formal rules eventuallydismantle the dedazosystem.'42In the Nether-
may affectthe costs and benefitsof adheringto relatedinfor- lands, a long-term decline in class and religious identities
mal rules, which can produce rapid informal institutional strengthened new parties that challenged the consocia-
change. In the case of complementary informal institu- tional rules of the game and induced establishedpartiesto
tions, for example,modifying the relevantformalrulesmay abandon them.143The growth of middle-classelectorates
change the natureof the gaps that the informal institution erodes the bases of clientelism by reducing voters' depen-
had been designed to address,which may createincentives dence on the distributionof selectivematerialgoods.144In
for actors to modify or abandon the informal rule. The these cases,informalinstitutionalchange tends to be incre-
1974 Bill of Rights of Subcommitteesin the House of Rep- mental, as actors graduallyreorient their expectations to
resentatives"produceda sharp change in formal rules that reflect underlying changes in their and others' bargaining
overrodepreviousinformal committee structures."135 power.
Informal institutional change may also be a product of Other analytictools may be needed to explainsome rapid
changes in formal institutionalstrengthor effectiveness.In informal institutional change or collapse. Tipping models
such cases, changes in the level of enforcement of formal offer one such tool.145These models suggest that if a suffi-
rulesalter the costs and benefitsadheringto informalinsti- ciently large enough number of actors become convinced
tutions that compete with or substitutefor those rules. For that a new and betteralternativeexists, and if a mechanism
example, compliancewith competing informalinstitutions exists through which to coordinate actors'expectations, a
becomes more costly with increased enforcement of the shift from one set of norms to another may occur quite
formal rules, and at some point, these costs will induce rapidly. Gerry Mackie argues that the move to end foot
actors to abandon the informal institution. Thus the binding in China hinged on creating an alternativemar-
increasedjudicialenforcementtriggeredby the Mani Pulite riagemarketthat allowedsons to marrydaughterswho had
investigations weakened corruption networks in Italy;136 naturalfeet, therebyescapingconventional inferiority.'46
the tight controls imposed by the postrevolutionarystate Figure 2 summarizesthese sources of informal institu-
weakenedtraditionalgift-givingnorms in Maoist China;137 tional change. As the figure suggests, informal institutions
and federalenforcementof civil rightslegislationweakened vary considerablywith respect to both the source and the
Jim Crow practicesin the South. pace of change.Whereassome (complementary,accommo-
Increased formal institutional effectiveness may also dating) are highly susceptibleto changes in formal institu-
weaken substitutiveinformalinstitutions. When the credi- tional design, others (substitutive, competing) are more
bility of previouslyineffectiveformalstructuresis enhanced, likely to be affected by changes in formal institutional
the benefits associatedwith the use of substitutiveinstitu- strength.With respectto the pace of change, culturalevo-
tions may diminish,potentiallyto the point of theirdispens- lution is likely to produce incrementalchange, but formal
ability. For example, the increasedcredibility of Mexico's institutional change or coordination around an alternative

732 Perspectives on Politics


CV)
equilibrium may trigger the rapid collapse of informal
co
CO E institutions.
c: 0
0 t-
c
0
a) 0L_
0)
co
0) Research Challenges: Identification,
L2 Q.
.--
C CZ
Measurement, and Comparison
0
0
a) co 0C Bringing informal institutions into mainstreamcompara-
a
.1
ai tive institutional analysisposes a new set of researchchal-
E E CO 0
E
E S
x 0 C: V)
0)
C
lenges.A majorissue is identifyingand measuringinformal
LU o R :5 c O
c :5 institutions. In formal institutional analysis, this task is
0O C
0 0.)
= .?:5
C.s
C
-5 co -0
relativelystraightforward.Because formal institutions are
usuallywrittendown and officiallycommunicatedand sanc-
CD 28Q X C 0
c: 0
a
<sl^)
_ m *
0
C
o_
.O.
0 tioned, their identificationand measurementoften requires
I'-.D i O i
uc
~0 little knowledgeof particularcases,which facilitateslarge-n
8\2 0
LLI IE C
W comparison.Identifyinginformalinstitutions is more chal-
lenging. A country'sconstitution can tell us whether it has
a presidentialor parliamentarysystem of government,but
it cannot tell us about the pervasivenessof clientelism or
~c .~ ~c CZ kinship networks.
E One way of identifying informal institutions is to look
(0
.? ?c0 for instances in which similar formal rules produce differ-
o
._ 0 C
)
>> ent outcomes and then attributethe differenceto informal
o 0
institutions.147Although the logic of this approachis clear,
E0 - c
it reduces informal institutions to a residualcategory and
E ? a > m risksconflatinginformalinstitutionsand weak institutions.
An alternativestrategyis to identifystablepatternsof behav-
ior that do not correspondto formal rules. However, this
co - o
approachruns the risk of treatingall behavioralregularities
0 as informalinstitutions.
At a minimum, efforts to identify informal institutions
should answerthree basic questions.148First,what are the
actors'sharedexpectationsabout the actualconstraintsthey
*5 1 y5, .c face?Only by examiningactors'mutualunderstandingof the
rules can one distinguish between informal behavior pat-
ternsand informalinstitutions.Second,what is the commu-
c C C nity to which the informalrulesapply?Whereasthe domain
of a formal institution is often delineatedby laws or other
statutes,the domain of informalrulesis often more difficult
to discern.The relevantcommunitymaybe avillage,a nation,
C. : (
O)
Eo CO 0
UO
an ethnicor religiousgroup,or an organizationsuchasa polit-
icalparty,legislature,or statebureaucracy.In some cases,the
C o C- C relevantcommunityis a politicalelite,the boundariesofwhich
s are often blurry.Third, how are informalrules enforced?If
OC C a, f g)
informalbehavioris rule-bound,then violations must trig-
0 0 E- E
4) ger externalsanction. Unlike formal enforcement mecha-
oC o Cm
C .C c-:
0-
nisms (police, courts),informalsanctioningmechanismsare
E C: .-
CE often subtle, hidden, and even illegal.They may rangefrom
o
c E
o.~
E
_
ac
o
( D.
zin hostileremarks,gossip,ostracism,andotherdisplaysof social
0? 0"
oL
0? 0r O? disapprovalto extrajudicialviolence.149
Identifying the shared expectations and enforcement
c mechanismsthat sustaininformalinstitutionsis a challeng-
0 ? .S a) ^ r S
.^ 0
4 ,
0 01:::7)
CD0-
0
'-
1:::7
E)
0
0C ing task, requiringin most cases substantialknowledge of
0 22, '
oU1, L~c 0 ~~ S
the community within which the informal institutions are
*-
embedded. Hence there is probablyno substitutefor inten-
o
sive fieldworkin informalinstitutionalanalysis.Indeedmost

December 2004 [ Vol. 2/No. 4 733


Articles I InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

studies of informal institutions take the form of either islative rules?156In comparativepolitics, the issue of how
abstracttheory (N=0) or inductive case studies (N= 1).150 informal institutions sustain or reinforce-as opposed to
Case studies provide essentialbuilding blocks for compari- undermine or distort-formal ones has not been well
son and theory building. However,a more generalbody of researched.When institutionsfunction effectively,we often
theorywill requirescholarsto incorporateother methods as assume that the formal rules are driving actors' behavior.
well. Yet in some cases, underlyinginformal norms do much of
One such method is rigoroussmall-n comparison.With- the enabling and constrainingthat we attributeto the for-
out losing the sensitivity to context that characterizescase mal rules.
studies, small-n analysescan begin to identify patterns of Second, we need to theorize more rigorouslyabout the
informal institutional effects, formal-informalinstitutional emergence of informal institutions and particularlyabout
interaction, and informal institutional change. For exam- the mechanismsthrough which informal rules are created,
ple, Kathleen Collins'scomparativestudy of three Central communicated,and learned.Some seeminglyage-old infor-
Asian statesenabledher to examinethe interactionbetween mal institutions are in realityrelativelyrecent reconfigura-
clan networks and different formal regime types.'51 Simi- tions (or reinventions);this fact makes the issues of origins
larly, Scott Desposato's analysis of legislative behavior in all the more compelling.157
five Brazilian states with varying degrees of clientelism Third, we need to betterunderstandthe sourcesof infor-
allowed him to consider how clientelism affects the func- mal institutional stability and change. One question not
tioning of legislatureswith similarformal structures.152 addressedin this article is that of codification of informal
Large-nsurveysmay alsoproveusefulin researchon infor- rules.In some instances,state actorsopt to legalizeinformal
mal institutions. Surveyresearchmay captureactors'expec- institutions that are perceived to compete with or under-
tations and beliefs about the "actual"rules of the game. mine formalrules.SeveralLatinAmericangovernments"con-
Here it is important to distinguish between conventional stitutionalized"aspects of indigenous law (granting them
surveys that capture values or attitudes toward particular constitutional status) during the 1990s in an effort to
institutions (e.g., the World Values Survey) and those enhance compliance with state law.158Similarly,in Argen-
designedto capturesociallysharedbeliefsabout constraints tina, in an effort to regulatePresidentCarlos Menem'suse
thatindividualsface.An exampleof the latteris SusanStokes's of extraconstitutionaldecree authority,legislatorsincluded
analysisof informalinstitutions of accountabilityin Argen- a provision for executive decrees in the 1994 Constitu-
tina, which uses surveydata to demonstratethe existencein tion.159We need to know more about what induces state
some parts of the country of shared citizen expectations actorsto formalizeratherthan oppose informalinstitutions.
that voters will punish politicians who behave dishonest- Comparativepolitics researchon informalinstitutions is
ly.153Although expectations-basedsurveysmay initially be still at an incipient stage. Advances are likely on several
limited to identifying of informal institutions, they might fronts, ranging from abstractformal modeling to ethno-
eventuallybe used to generateand test causalclaims. graphicstudies to survey research.New insights will come
from a varietyof disciplines, including anthropology,eco-
nomics, law, sociology, and political psychology.Hence, it
Conclusion is essentialto promotea broadand pluralisticresearchagenda
SinceJamesMarchand Johan P.Olsen declaredthat "anew that encouragesfertilizationacrossdisciplines,methods, and
institutionalismhas appearedin politicalscience,"154research regions. Given the range of areasin which informal rules
on political institutions has advanced considerably. Yet and organizationsmatterpolitically,it is essentialthat polit-
because the comparativepolitics literaturehas focused pri- ical scientists take the real rules of the game seriously-
marily on formal institutions, it risks missing many of the whether they arewritten into parchmentor not.
"real"incentivesand constraintsthatunderliepoliticalbehav-
ior.Indeed,rational-choiceanalysesof institutionshavebeen Notes
criticized for an "excessiveattention to formal rules"and 1 For an excellent surveyof this literature,see Carey
"insufficientattention to firmly establishedinformal prac- 2000.
tices and 'institutions.'"'55 2 Taylor 1992; Hartlyn 1994; O'Donnell 1996; Siave-
We have sought to provide a frameworkfor incorporat- lis 1997; Starn 1999; Van Cott 2000; Levitsky2001;
ing informal rules into mainstreaminstitutional analysis. Levitsky2003; Helmke 2002; Brinks2003a; Eisen-
Farfrom rejectingthe literatureon institutions, we seek to stadt 2003.
broaden and extend it, with the goal of refining, and ulti- 3 Clarke 1995; Ledeneva1998; Borocz2000; Easter
matelystrengthening,its theoreticalframework.We see sev- 2000; Sil 2001; Collins 2002a, 2003; Grzymala-
eral areasfor future research.First,we must posit and test Busseand Jones Luong 2002; Way 2002; Gel'man
hypotheses about how informal rules shape formal institu- 2003.
tional outcomes. For example, how do clientelism and 4 Dia 1996; Sandbrookand Oelbaum 1999; Hyden
patronagenetworksmediate the effectsof electoraland leg- 2002; Lindberg2003; Galvan2004.

734 Perspectives on Politics


5 Yang 1994; Hamilton-Hart 2000; Wang 2000; 50 See North 1990; Knight 1992; Carey2000.
Gobel 2001; Tsai 2001, 2004; Colignon and Usui 51 Dia 1996; Pejovich 1999. Pejovichdefines informal
2003. institutions as "traditions,customs, moralvalues, reli-
6 For generalanalysesof informal institutions, see gious beliefs, and all other norms of behaviorthat
North 1990; Knight 1992; O'Donnell 1996; Lauth have passedthe test of time .... Thus, informalinsti-
2000. tutions are the part of a community'sheritagethat
7 Langston2003. we call culture"(p. 166).
8 Colignon and Usui 2003. 52 Boussard2000; Manor 2001; Tsai 2002.
9 Collins 2002b, 23, 30. 53 Knight 1992; Calvert 1995.
10 O'Donnell 1996; Lauth 2000; Borocz 2000; Gibel 54 Hamilton-Hart 2000; Grzymala-Busseand Jones-
2001; Lindberg2003. Luong 2002; Colignon and Usui 2003.
11 Riggs 1964. 55 Waterbury1973; Darden 2002; Langston2003.
12 Scott 1976. 56 This definitionborrowsfrom Brinks2003a and is con-
13 Hyden 1980. sistent with North 1990; O'Donnell 1996; Carey
14 Hooker 1975; Griffiths1986. 2000; and Lauth 2000. We treat informal institu-
15 Scott 1972; Lemarchand1972; tions and norms synonymously.However,norms
16 Scott 1969; Waterbury1973; Rose-Ackerman1978. have been defined in a varietyof ways, and some con-
17 Lijphart1975. ceptualizationsdo not include externalenforce-
18 Johnson 1974, 1982. ment. See Elster 1989.
19 Bauer,Inkeles, and Kluckhohn 1956; Berliner 1957. 57 Ellickson 1991, 31.
20 Matthews 1959. 58 O'Donnell 1994.
21 O'Donnell 1996; Weyland 2002. 59 O'Donnell 1996.
22 North 1990. 60 See Hart 1961; Knight 1992.
23 Della Portaand Vannucci 1999, 15. 61 Brinks2003a.
24 Brinks2003a, 2003b. 62 Waterbury1973; Darden 2002.
25 Brinks2003b. 63 Manion 1996; Della Portaand Vannucci 1999.
26 O'Donnell 1994; Hartlyn 1994; Sandbrookand Oel- 64 See Huntington 1968.
baum 1999. 65 North 1990.
27 Siavelis2002a, 81. 66 North 1990; Galvan 2004.
28 Siavelis2002b. 67 For example, some indigenous institutions in Latin
29 O'Donnell 1994. Americadraw on culturaltraditionsbut others do
30 Taylor 1992. not. See YrigoyenFajardo2000; Van Cott 2003.
31 Wright and Berkman 1986. 68 Lauth2000 distinguishesamong threetypesof formal-
32 Levitsky2001; 2003. informal institutional relationships:complementary,
33 Stokes 2003. substitutive,and conflicting. He does not elabo-
34 Mershon 1994; Desposato 2003. rate on these types, however.
35 Helmke 2002; Van Cott 2003; Bill Chavez 2004. 69 Ullman-Margalit1978; Axelrod 1986.
36 Freidenbergand Levitsky2002; Langston2003; Lev- 70 Weingast 1979; Weingast and Marshall1988; March
itsky 2003. and Olsen 1989.
37 Della Portaand Vannucci 1999; Samuels2003. 71 O'Donnell 1996; Borocz 2000; Lauth 2000; Collins
38 Collins 2002a, 2002b; Ottaway 2003. 2002a.
39 Way 2002. 72 By effectiveness,we do not mean efficiency.History
40 Della Portaand Vannucci 1999; Hamilton-Hart is litteredwith examplesof inefficientinstitutions
2000; Colignon and Usui 2003. that neverthelesseffectivelyshaped actors' expecta-
41 Darden 2002; Grzymala-Busseand Jones Luong tions (North 1990).
2002; Tsai 2004. 73 Lauth 2000.
42 For other efforts in this direction, see Lauth 2000 74 March and Olsen 1989.
and Pasotti and Rothstein 2002. 75 Maltzmanand Wahlbeck 1996; Epstein and Knight
43 Lauth 2000. 1997.
44 Wang 2000. 76 Stokes 2003.
45 O'Donnell 1996; Lauth 2000. 77 North, Summerhill,and Weingast,2000.
46 B6r6cz 2000; Darden 2002. 78 Hamilton-Hart 2000.
47 Lauth 2000; Collins 2002a; Collins 2003. 79 Tsai 2004.
48 Boussard2000; Manor 2001. 80 Siavelis2002b, 10-11.
49 Dia 1996; Pejovich 1999. 81 Ibid., 21.

December 2004 | Vol. 2/No. 4 735


Articles I InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

82 Lijphart1975, 122-38. ones), or they may be createdwithout taking pre-


83 Ibid. existing informal structuresinto account (as occurred
84 Bauer,Inkeles, and Kluckhohn 1956; Berliner 1957; with many colonial institutions).
Ledeneva 1998. 104 Johnson 2002.
85 Ledeneva 1998, 43, 1. 105 March and Olsen 1989; Nelson and Winter 1982;
86 Berliner1957; Ledeneva1998. Guanxi,or personalrela- Weingast 1979; Weingastand Marshall 1988.
tionships maintained by gift giving and reciprocal 106 We thank Susan Stokes for suggesting this point.
favors,playeda similarrole in post-Maoist China. See 107 Siavelis2002b.
Yang 1994. 108 Mershon 1994.
87 O'Donnell 1996; Borocz 2000; Lauth 2000; Collins 109 Ibid.
2002a, 2003; Lindberg2003. Accordingto O'Donnell 110 Taylor 1992.
(1996, 40), particularisticnorms are "antagonistic 111 Mershon 1994, 50.
to one of the main aspectsof the full institutionalpack- 112 Van Oenen 2001.
age of polyarchy.... Individualsperformingroles 113 Brinks2003a.
in political and state institutions are supposed to be 114 Darden 2002; Levitskyand Way 2002; Schedler
guided not by particularisticmotives but by uni- 2002; Ottaway 2003.
versalisticorientationsto some version of the public 115 See, for example, Starn'saccount of the disputed ori-
good.... Where particularismis pervasive,this gins of the ronda campesinasin Peru (1999, 36-69)
notion is weaker,less widely held, and seldom and Ledeneva's(1998) analysisof the origins of
enforced." blat in the Soviet Union.
88 Della Portaand Vannucci 1999, 146, 15. 116 Knight 1992.
89 Ibid., 15, 122. 117 Ibid.
90 Price 1975. 118 Schelling 1960.
91 Hooker 1975, 2; also Griffiths 1986; Merry 1988. 119 Sugden 1986; Schotter 1981; and Calvert 1995.
92 Merry 1988, 869. 120 Knight 1992
93 Lauth 2000. 121 Johnson 1974; Colignon and Usui 2003. Similarly,
94 Eisenstadt2002; Eisenstadt2003. norms of restraintand flexibilitywithin Japan'ssecu-
95 Eisenstadt2002. rity forces have been tracedto the intense socio-
96 Starn 1999. political conflicts in the aftermathof World War II
97 Tsai 2001, 16. (Katzenstein1996).
98 Wang 2000; Tsai 2001. 122 Langston2003, 14-16.
99 The question of informal institutional emergence 123 Mershon 1994, 67-68.
has been the subject of a largeliteraturewithin for- 124 Colignon and Usui 2003.
mal political theory. See Schotter 1981; Knight 125 Darden 2002; Moreno Ocampo 2002.
1992; Calvert 1995. 126 Siavelis2002b; Lijphart1975; Mershon 1994.
100 For example, some indigenous institutions widely 127 Della Portaand Vannucci 1999, 93-124.
viewed as "traditional"are in fact recent creations 128 Starn 1999.
that merelydrawon earliertraditions.See Starn 1999; 129 North 1990, 45; See also Dia 1996; O'Donnell
Van Cott 2000, 2003; Galvan 2004. 1996; Pejovich 1999; Collins 2002b.
101 For a critique, see Knight 1992. 130 North 1990; Lauth 2000.
102 See, for example, earlywork on legislativenorms by 131 Lauth 2000, 24-25.
Weingast 1979; Shepsle and Weingast 1981; Wein- 132 Mackie 1996.
gast and Marshall1988. 133 Langston2003.
103 Many informal institutions emerge endogenously 134 Dia 1996; O'Donnell 1996; Pejovich1999. Forexam-
from formal institutional arrangements.Actors cre- ple, Amakudaripersistedfor decadesdespite multi-
ate them in an effort to subvert, mitigate the ple legislativereformsaimedat its eradication(Colignon
effectsof, substitutefor,or enhancethe efficiencyof for- and Usui 2003, 43-49); clan politics in Central
mal institutions. However,other informal institu- Asiasurvivedthe riseand fallof the SovietUnion (Col-
tions develop independently of formal institutional lins 2002a, 2002b); and many Soviet-eranorms sur-
structures, in response to conditions that are vived Russia'stransitionfrom state socialism to a
unrelatedto (and frequentlypre-date)the formalinsti- marketeconomy (Clarke 1995; Sil 2001).
tutional context. Formalinstitutions may then be 135 North 1990, 88.
built on the foundation of these informal institu- 136 Della Portaand Vannucci 1999.
tions (actorsmay formalizepre-existinginformal 137 Yang 1994.
rules or use them as the bases for designing formal 138 Eisenstadt2002.

736 Perspectives on Politics


139 Starn 1999. Boussard,Caroline. 2000. Democratic consolidation:The
140 North 1990; Dia 1996; Pejovich 1999. role of informal institutions. Illustrationsfrom Central
141 Knight 1992. America. Paperpresentedat the 22nd International
142 Langston2003. Congress of the Latin American Studies Association,
143 Lijphart1975. Miami, FL, March 16-18.
144 Kitschelt2000. Brinks,Daniel. 2003a. Informalinstitutions and the rule
145 Schelling 1960, 1978. of law:The judicial responseto state killings in Bue-
146 Mackie 1996. nos Aires and Sao Paulo in the 1990s. ComparativePol-
147 See, for example, North 1990. itics36 (1): 1-19.
148 For a more elaboratediscussion of how to identify . 2003b. Courts, norms, and laws: Competing rules
and measureinformal institutions, see Brinks2003b. and legal rights in Salvador,Sao Paulo, and Buenos
149 An additionalproblem, identified by Brinks(2003b), Aires. Paperpresentedat the conferenceInformalInsti-
is that some informalrulespermit, but do not require, tutions and Politics in LatinAmerica, Kellogg Insti-
certain behavior.Under rules of this type, actors tute for InternationalStudies,Universityof Notre Dame,
who refrainfrom the permittedbehavior(e.g., govern- April 24-25.
ment officialswho choose not to collect bribes) do Calvert,Randall. 1995. The rationalchoice theory of
not breakthe informalrule and thus will not be sanc- social institutions:Cooperation, coordination,and
tioned. In such cases, sanctions are likely to be communication." In Modernpolitical economy:Old
applied only to actorswho seek to formallysanction topics,new directions,ed. JeffreyS. Banks and Eric A.
behaviorpermittedby the informalrules-i.e., whis- Hanushek, 216-67. New York:CambridgeUniver-
tle blowers. sity Press.
150 Within the case study tradition, a more microlevel Carey,John M. 2000. Parchment,equilibria,and institu-
approachis to construct analyticnarrativesthat tions. ComparativePoliticalStudies33 (6): 735-61.
blend elements of deductive and inductive reason- Clarke,Simon, ed. 1995. Managementand industryin Rus-
ing. See Bates et al. 1998. sia: Formaland informalrelationsin theperiod of transi-
151 Collins 2002a. tion. Aldershot,UK: EdwardElgar.
152 Desposato 2003. Colignon, RichardA, and Chikako Usui. 2003. Amaku-
153 Stokes 2003. dari: The hiddenfabric ofJapanseconomy.Ithaca:Cor-
154 March and Olsen 1984, 734. nell UniversityPress.
155 Weyland 2002, 67. Collins, Kathleen.2002a. Clans, pacts and politics in Cen-
156 On these questions, see Kitschelt 2000; Desposato tralAsia."Journalof Democracy13 (3): 137-52.
2003 and Taylor-Robinson2003. .2002b. Clans, pacts, and regime transitionsin
157 Van Cott 2000, 2003; Galvan 2004. CentralAsia. Paperpresentedat the conferenceInfor-
158 YrigoyenFajardo2000; Van Cott 2000, 2003. mal Institutions and Politics in the Developing World,
159 FerreiraRubio and Goretti 1998, 56-57. WeatherheadCenter for InternationalAffairs,Har-
vard University,April 5-6.
.2003. The politicalroleof clansin CentralAsia. Com-
References parativePolitics35 (2): 171-90.
Axelrod, Robert. 1986. An evolutionaryapproachto Darden, Keith. 2002. Graft and governance:Corruption
norms."AmericanPoliticalScienceReview80 (4): as an informal mechanism of state control. Paper
1095-1111. presentedat the conference Informal Institutions and
Bates, Robert H., Avner Greif, MargaretLevi, Jean- Politicsin the DevelopingWorld,WeatherheadCen-
LaurentRosenthal,and BarryR. Weingast. 1998. Ana- ter for InternationalAffairs,HarvardUniversity,
lytic narratives.Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress. April 5-6.
Bauer,RaymondA, Alex Inkeles, and Clyde Kluckhohn. Della Porta, Donatella, and Alberto Vannucci. 1999. Cor-
1956. How the Sovietsystemworks:Cultural,psychologi- rupt exchanges: Actors,resources,and mechanismsofpolit-
cal, and socialthemes.Cambridge:HarvardUniver- ical corruption.New York:Aldine de Gruyter.
sity Press. Desposato, Scott W. 2003. How informalelectoralinstitu-
Berliner,Joseph S. 1957. Factoryand mangerin the USSR. tions shape the legislativearena.Paperpresentedat the
Cambridge:HarvardUniversityPress. conferenceInformalInstitutionsand Politicsin Latin
Bill Chavez, Rebecca.2004. The rule of law in nascent America,KelloggInstitutefor InternationalStudies,Uni-
democracies:Judicialpolitics in Argentina.Stanford, versityof Notre Dame, April 24-25.
CA: StanfordUniversityPress. Dia, Mamadou. 1996. Africa'smanagementin the 1990s
Borocz,J6szef.2000. InformalityRules. EastEuropeanPol- and beyond: Reconciling indigenous and transplanted
itics and Societies14 (2): 348-80. institutions.Washington:World Bank.

December 2004 | Vol. 2/No. 4 737


Articles I InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

Easter,GeraldM. 2000. Reconstructing thestate:Personalnet- Helmke, Gretchen. 2002. The logic of strategicdefection:
worksand elite identityin SovietRussia.New York:Cam- Court-executiverelationsin Argentinaunder dictator-
bridge UniversityPress. ship and democracy.AmericanPoliticalScienceReview
Eisenstadt,Todd. 2002. Trust but verify:How Mexico's 96 (2): 291-304.
oppositionforcedelectoraldisputeresolutionfrom bar- Hooker,M. B. 1975. Legalpluralism:An introductionto colo-
gaining tables to courtrooms and lived to tell about it. nial and neo-coloniallaws. Oxford: ClarendonPress.
Paperpresentedat the conference InformalInstitu- Huntington, SamuelP 1968. Politicalorderin changingsoci-
tions and Politics in the Developing World, Weather- eties.New Haven: YaleUniversityPress.
head Centerfor InternationalAffairs,HarvardUniversity, Hyden, Goran. 1980. BeyondUjamaain Tanzania:Under-
April 5-6. developmentand an uncapturedpeasantry. London:
.2003. Thinking outside the (ballot) box: Informal Heinemann.
electoralinstitutions and Mexico'spolitical opening, Hyden, Goran. 2002. Why Africa finds it so hard to
LatinAmericanPoliticsand Society45 (1): 25-54. develop? Reflections on political representation and
Ellickson, Robert C. 1991. Orderwithoutlaw: How neigh- accountability.Paperpresentedat the conferenceCul-
borssettledisputes.Cambridge:HarvardUniversity turaland PoliticalFoundationsof Socio-EconomicDevel-
Press. opment in Africaand Asia, Monte Verita,Switzerland,
Elster,Jon. 1989. The cementof society:A surveyof social October 6-11.
order.New York:CambridgeUniversityPress. Johnson,Chalmers.1974. The reemploymentof retiredgov-
Epstein, Lee, and JackKnight. 1997. Thechoicesjustices ernmentbureaucratsin Japanesebig business."AsianSur-
make.WashingtonDC: CongressionalQuarterlyPress. vey 14 (11): 953-65.
FerreiraRubio, Delia and Matteo Goretti. 1998. When 1982. MITI and theJapanesemiracle:Thegrowthof
the presidentgovernsalone:The Decretazo in Argen- industrialpolicy,1925-1975. Stanford:StanfordUniver-
tina, 1989-93. In Executivedecreeauthority,ed. John M. sity Press.
Careyand Mathew SobergShugart,33-61. New York: Johnson, James.2002. Opening questions. Paperpre-
CambridgeUniversityPress. sented at the conferenceInformalInstitutions and
Freidenberg,Flavia,and Steven Levitsky.2002. Organiza- Politics in the Developing World, WeatherheadCenter
ci6nes Partidistase Institucionalizaci6nInformalen Amer- for InternationalAffairs,HarvardUniversity,April
ica Latina. Paperpresentedat the LatinAmerican 5-6, 2002.
Congressof PoliticalScience, Universityof Salamanca, Katzenstein,PeterJ. 1996. Culturalnormsand nationalsecu-
July 9-11. rity:Policeand militaryin postwarJapan.Ithaca:Cor-
Galvan, Dennis C. 2004. Thestate must be our masterof nell UniversityPress.
fire: Howpeasantscraftculturallysustainabledevelop- Kitschelt,Herbert.2000. Linkagesbetweencitizensand pol-
ment in Senegal.Berkeley:Universityof CaliforniaPress. iticiansin democraticpolitics. Comparative PoliticalStud-
Gel'man,Vladimir.2003. Post-Soviettransitionsand democ- ies 33 (6-7): 845-79.
ratization:Towardtheory building. Democratization10 Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutionsand socialconflict.New
(2): 87-104. York:CambridgeUniversityPress.
Gobel, Christian.2001. Towardsa consolidateddemoc- Langston,Joy. 2003. The formal bases of informal power:
racy?Informaland formalinstitutionsin Taiwan'spolit- Mexico. Paperpresentedat the conferenceInformalInsti-
ical process. Paperpresentedat the annual meeting tutions and Politics in Latin America, Kellogg Insti-
of the AmericanPoliticalScience Association, San Fran- tute for InternationalStudies,Universityof Notre Dame,
cisco, August 30-September 2. April 24-25.
Griffiths,John. 1986. What is legal pluralism?Journalof Lauth, Hans-Joachim.2000. Informalinstitutions and
LegalPluralismand UnofficialLaw 24 (1): 1-56. democracy.Democratization7 (4): 21-50.
Grzymala-Busse,Anna, and PaulineJones Luong. 2002. Ledeneva,AlenaV. 1998. Russiaseconomyoffavours:Blat,net-
Reconceptualizingthe state: Lessons from post- workingand informalexchange.Cambridge:Cambridge
communism. Politicsand Society30 (4): 529-54. UniversityPress.
Hamilton-Hart, Natasha. 2000. The Singaporestate revis- Lemarchand,Rene. 1972. Politicalclientelism and ethnic-
ited. PacificReview13 (2): 195-216. ity in tropicalAfrica:Competing solidaritiesin nation-
Hart, H. L. A. 1961. Theconceptof law. New York:Oxford building. AmericanPoliticalScienceReview66 (1):
UniversityPress 68-90.
Hartlyn, Jonathan. 1994. Crisis-riddenelections (again) Levitsky,Steven. 2001. An "organizeddisorganization":
in the Dominican Republic:Neopatrimonialism, Informalorganizationand the persistenceof local
presidentialism,and weak electoral oversight. party structuresin Argentine Peronism.Journalof Latin
Journal of InteramericanStudiesand WorldAffairs AmericanStudies33 (1): 29-68.
36 (4): 91-144. .2003. Transforming labor-basedpartiesin Latin

738 Perspectives on Politics


America:ArgentinePeronismin comparative perspective. and elsewhere.Kellogg InstituteWorking Paper222.
New York:CambridgeUniversityPress. Notre Dame, IN: Kellogg Institute for International
Levitsky,Steven,and LucanA. Way.2002. The riseof com- Studies.
petitive authoritarianism.Journalof Democracy13 (2): Ottaway,Marina.2003. Democracychallenged:The riseof
51-65. semi-authoritarianism. Washington:CarnegieEndow-
Lijphart,Arend. 1975. Thepoliticsofaccommodation:Plu- ment for InternationalPeace.
ralismand democracyin the Netherlands.2nd ed. Berke- Pasotti, Eleanora,and Bo Rothstein. 2002. In the market
ley: Universityof CaliforniaPress. for ideas:A quest for a unified conceptual approachin
Lindberg,SteffanI. 2003. It'sour time to chop: Do elec- political science. Paperpresentedat the annual meet-
tions in Africafeed net-patrimonialismratherthan coun- ing of the AmericanPoliticalScienceAssociation,August
teract it? Democratization10 (2): 121-40. 29-September 1, Boston.
Mackie, Gerry. 1996. Ending footbinding and infibula- Pejovich,Svetozar.1999. The effectsof the interactionof for-
tion: A convention account. AmericanSociological mal and informalinstitutionson social stabilityand eco-
Review61 (6): 999-1017. nomic development.Journalof Marketsand Morality
Maltzman, Forrest,and PaulJ. Wahlbeck. 1996. May it 2 (2): 164-81.
please the chief? Opinion assignmentin the Rehn- Price, Robert M. 1975. Societyand bureaucracy in contem-
quist Court. AmericanJournalofPoliticalScience.40 (2): poraryGhana.Berkeley:Universityof CaliforniaPress.
421-43. Riggs, FredW. 1964. Administrationin developingcoun-
Manion, Melanie. 1996. Corruption by design: Briberyin tries:The theoryofprismaticsociety.Boston: Hough-
Chinese enterpriselicensing.Journalof Law, Economics, ton Mifflin.
and Organizations.12 (1): 167-95. Rose-Ackerman,Susan. 1978. Corruption:A studyin polit-
Manor,James. 2001. Center-staterelations.In Thesuccess ical economy.New York:Academic Press.
oflndias democracy, ed. Atul Kohli, 78-102. Cam- Samuels, David. 2003. Campaign finance as informal
bridge:CambridgeUniversityPress. contractinginstitutions:Brazilin comparative
March,James, and Johan Olsen. 1984. The new institu- perspective."Paperpresentedat the conference
tionalism:Organizationalfactorsin political life. Amer- InformalInstitutions and Politics in Latin America,
ican PoliticalScienceReview78 (3): 734-49. Kellogg Institute for InternationalStudies, University
March,JamesG., and Johan P. Olsen. 1989. Rediscovering of Notre Dame, April 24-25.
institutions:The organizationalbasisofpolitics.New Sandbrook,Richard,and Jay Oelbaum. 1999. Reforming
York:Free Press. the political kingdom: Governanceand development
Matthews, Donald R. 1959. The folkwaysof the United in Ghana'sFourth Republic. Center for Democracy and
States Senate:Conformity to group norms and legisla- Development, CriticalPerspectivesPaperNo. 2.
tive effectiveness.AmericanPoliticalScienceReview Schedler,Andreas.2002. The menu of manipulation.Jour-
53 (4): 1064-89. nal of Democracy13 (2): 36-50.
Merry,Sally Engle. 1988. Legalpluralism.Law and Soci- Schelling,Thomas C. 1960. Thestrategyof conflict.Cam-
ety Review22 (5): 869-96. bridge:HarvardUniversityPress.
Mershon, Carol A. 1994. Expectationsand informal rules 1978. Micromotivesand macrobehavior. New York:
in coalition formation. ComparativePoliticalStudies27 W. W. Norton.
(1): 40-79. Schotter,Andrew.1981. The economictheoryof socialinsti-
Moreno Ocampo, Luis. 2002. Corruptionand democracy: tutions. Cambridge:CambridgeUniversityPress.
The Peruviancase ofMontesinos. ReVista(Fall):26-29. Scott, JamesC. 1969. Corruption, machine politics, and
Nelson, RichardR., and Sidney G. Winter. 1982. An evo- political change. AmericanPoliticalScienceReview63
lutionarytheoryof economicchange.Cambridge:Har- (4): 1142-58.
vard UniversityPress. 1972. Patron-clientpolitics and political change
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions,institutionalchange, in SoutheastAsia. AmericanPoliticalScienceReview
and economicperformance.New York:CambridgeUni- 66 (1): 91-113.
versity Press. 1976. The moral economy of the peasant:Rebel-
North, DouglasC., WilliamSummerhill,and BarryR. Wein- lion and subsistencein SoutheastAsia. New Haven:
gast. 2000. Order,disorder,and economic change: YaleUniversityPress.
Latin AmericaversusNorth America. In Governingfor Shepsle, KennethA., and BarryR. Weingast. 1981. Struc-
prosperity,ed. Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and Hilton ture induced equilibriumand legislativechoice. Public
L. Root, 17-58. New Haven: YaleUniversityPress. Choice37: 503-19.
O'Donnell, Guillermo. 1994. Delegative democracy.Jour- Siavelis,Peter.1997. Executive-legislativerelationsin post-
nal of Democracy5 (1): 55-69. Pinochet Chile: A preliminaryassessment.In Presiden-
1996. Another institutionalization:LatinAmerica tialismand democracyin Latin America,ed. Scott

December 2004 | Vol. 2/No. 4 739


Articles I InformalInstitutions
and ComparativePolitics

Mainwaringand Mathew Sobert Shugart,321-62. ment in ruralChina. PhD diss., Departmentof Govern-
New York:CambridgeUniversityPress. ment, HarvardUniversity.
. 2002a. Exaggeratedpresidentialismand moderate Ullman-Margalit,Edna. 1978. The emergenceof norms.
presidents:Executive-legislativerelationsin Chile. In Leg- Oxford: ClarendonPress.
islativepolitics in Latin America,ed. Scott Morgen- Van Cott, Donna Lee. 2000. A politicalanalysisof legalplu-
stern and Benito Nacif, 79-113. New York:Cambridge ralismin Bolivia and Colombia. Journalof Latin Ameri-
UniversityPress. can Studies32 (1): 207-34.
. 2002b. Informalinstitutions and democratization: . 2003. Legalpluralismand informalcommunity jus-
TheoreticallessonsfromChile. Paperpresentedat the con- tice administrationin LatinAmerica. Paperpresented
ferenceInformalInstitutionsand Politicsin the Devel- at the conference Informal Institutions and Politics in
oping World, Weatherhead Center for International LatinAmerica,KelloggInstitutefor InternationalStud-
Affairs,HarvardUniversity,April 5-6, 2002. ies, Universityof Notre Dame, April 24-25.
Sil, Rudra.2001. Privatization,labor politics, and the Van Oenen, Gijs. 2001. Citizenship and "informalrule of
firm in post-Soviet Russia:Non-market norms, market law."How lax enforcementcan sustain the rule of law.
institutions, and the Soviet legacy.In Thepolitics of Paperpresentedat the annual meeting of the Latin
labor in a global age: Continuityand changein late- AmericanStudiesAssociation,Washington,DC, Septem-
industrializingand post-socialisteconomies,ed. Christo- ber 6-8.
pher Candland and RudraSil, 205-32. New York: Wang, Hongying. 2000. Informalinstitutions and foreign
Oxford UniversityPress. investment in China. PacificReview13 (4): 525-56.
Starn, Orin. 1999. Nightwatch:Thepolitics ofprotestin the Waterbury,John. 1973. Endemic and planned corruption
Andes.Durham: Duke UniversityPress. in a monarchicalregime. WorldPolitics25 (4): 533-55.
Stokes, Susan C. 2003. Do informal institutions make Way, Lucan A. 2002. The dilemmas of reform in weak
democracywork?Accounting for accountabilityin states:The caseof post-Sovietfiscaldecentralization."
Pol-
Argentina. Paperpresentedat the conferenceInformal itics and Society30 (December):579-98.
Institutions and Politics in Latin America, Kellogg Weingast,Barry.1979. A rationalchoice perspectiveon con-
Institute for InternationalStudies, Universityof Notre gressionalnorms. AmericanJournalof PoliticalScience
Dame, April 24-25. 23 (2): 245-62.
Sugden, Robert. 1986. The economicsof rights,cooperation, Weingast, BarryR., and William J. Marshall. 1988. The
and welfare.New York:Basil Blackwell. industrialorganizationof congress;or, Why legisla-
Taylor,Michelle. 1992. FormalversusInformalIncentive tures, like firms, are not organizedas markets.Journal
Structuresand InformalBehavior/Journalof Politics of PoliticalEconomy96 (1): 132-63.
54 (4): 1055-73. Weyland, Kurt. 2002. Limitationsof rational-choiceinsti-
Taylor-Robinson,Michelle. 2003. The difficult road from tutionalismfor the studyof LatinAmericanpolitics. Stud-
Caudillismoto democracy,or Can clientelism comple- ies in ComparativeInternationalDevelopment37 (1):
ment democraticelectoralinstitutions?Paperpre- 57-85.
sented at the conference Informal Institutions and Wright,GeraldC., Jr.,and MichaelB. Berkman.1986. Can-
Politics in Latin America, Kellogg Institute for Inter- didatesand policy in United StatesSenateelections.Amer-
nationalStudies,Universityof Notre Dame, April24-25. ican PoliticalScienceReview80 (2): 567-88.
Tsai, Lily Lee. 2001. Substitutingfor the state?The logic Yang,MayfairMei-hui. 1994. Gifts,favors, and banquets:
of privateefficiencyin Chinese local governance. Theart of socialrelationshipsin China. Ithaca:Cornell
Paperpresentedat the annual meeting of the American UniversityPress.
Political Science Association, San Francisco,August YrigoyenFajardo,Raquel.2000. The Constitutionalrecog-
30-September 2. nition of indigenouslaw in Andeancountries.In Thechal-
Tsai, Lily Lee. 2002. Cadres, temple and lineage institu- lengeof diversity:Indigenouspeoplesand reformof the
tions, and governancein ruralChina. The ChinaJour- statein LatinAmerica,ed. Willam Assies, Gemma van
nal48 (July): 1-27. der Haar,and Andre Hoekema, 197-222. Amster-
.2004. The informalstate:Governanceand develop- dam: Thela Thesis.

740 Perspectives on Politics

S-ar putea să vă placă și