Sunteți pe pagina 1din 13

World Development Vol. 66, pp.

400–412, 2015
0305-750X/Ó 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2014.09.006

Food Standards, Certification, and Poverty among Coffee


Farmers in Uganda
BRIAN CHIPUTWA a, DAVID J. SPIELMAN b and MATIN QAIM a,*
a
Georg-August-University of Goettingen, Germany
b
International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington, USA
Summary. — Voluntary standards are gaining in importance in global markets for high-value foods. We analyze and compare impacts of
three sustainability-oriented standards – Fairtrade, Organic, and UTZ – on the livelihoods of smallholder coffee farmers in Uganda.
Using survey data and propensity score matching with multiple treatments, we find that Fairtrade certification increases household living
standards by 30% and reduces the prevalence and depth of poverty. For the other two certification schemes, no significant impacts are
found. Several factors that can explain differential impacts are discussed. Overly general statements about the effects of sustainability
standards on smallholder livelihoods may be misleading.
Ó 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — smallholder farmers, impact assessment, Organic, Fairtrade, Uganda, Africa

1. INTRODUCTION Jaffee, 2008; Raynolds, Murray, & Leigh Taylor, 2004;


Utting-Chamorro, 2005; Valkila, 2009; Valkila & Nygren,
Food systems around the world are undergoing a rapid 2010), while there are only a few papers focusing on Africa
transformation, with modern retailers, private standards, and (Bolwig, Gibbon, & Jones, 2009; Jena, Chichaibelu,
vertically integrated supply chains gaining in importance Stellmacher, & Grote, 2012). Concerning the methods used,
(Melo, Engler, Nahuehual, Cofre, & Barrena, 2014; Reardon, many impact studies do not control for possible selection bias
Barrett, Berdegué, & Swinnen, 2009). This transformation is (Bacon et al., 2008; Beuchelt & Zeller, 2011; Mendez et al.,
partly driven by changing consumer preferences, induced by 2010; Utting-Chamorro, 2005; Valkila, 2009; Valkila &
rising living standards and growing concerns about food safety Nygren, 2010), so it is unclear whether observed differences
and the environmental and social consequences of agricultural between certified and non-certified farmers are really attribut-
production (Mergenthaler, Weinberger, & Qaim, 2009). To sat- able to certification. In terms of outcome variables considered,
isfy consumer demands, retailers and manufacturers – in coop- there is a heavy focus on coffee prices. In many cases, certified
eration with certification bodies and NGOs – increasingly use farmers receive higher prices, but sales prices alone are not a
sustainability-oriented standards and labels (Kleemann, comprehensive indicator of livelihood impacts.
Abdulai, & Buss, 2014; Tran, Bailey, Wilson, & Phillips, A few impact studies controlled for selection bias and also
2013). This trend is especially pronounced for luxury foods, considered broader indicators of household welfare. Jena
such as coffee, tea, cocoa, or tropical fruits. For coffee, the glo- et al. (2012) used propensity score matching (PSM) to evaluate
bal market share of products with sustainability certification – impacts in Ethiopia. They showed that certification contrib-
such as Organic, Fairtrade, UTZ, or Rainforest Alliance – has utes to higher incomes among coffee farmers, but the impact
doubled from 4% in 2006 to 8% in 2009; this share is expected on poverty was insignificant. Ruben and Fort (2012) also used
to grow to over 20% in the next couple of years (ITC, 2011). In PSM in their study of Fairtrade impacts in Peru. They did not
rich and emerging countries in particular, many consumers are find significant income gains, although certified households
willing to pay more for foods that are labeled to be sustainably were able to accumulate more wealth, possibly due to lower
produced. For coffee and other tropical products, this also price risk. Arnould, Plastina, and Ball (2009) looked at Fair-
involves consumer perceptions to contribute to improved live- trade impacts in Peru, Guatemala, and Nicaragua. While they
lihoods of smallholder farmers (Basu & Hicks, 2008; Elfenbein revealed positive price effects, impacts on household welfare
& McManus, 2010). However, actual evidence about producer were small and uneven across the three countries. Bolwig
benefits is mixed (Hansen & Trifkovic, 2014; ITC, 2011; et al. (2009) used Heckman selection models to analyze
Subervie & Vagneron, 2013). Here, we analyze the impacts of impacts of Organic certification in Uganda, showing that cer-
sustainability standards on smallholder coffee producers in tified production contributes to higher farm revenues.
Uganda. Uganda is one of Africa’s major coffee exporters. These findings suggest that the livelihood effects may differ
Around 500,000 small-scale farmers produce coffee in Uganda; depending on various factors, including regional context and
around 10% of them are already certified under different type of standard. Hence, general conclusions about the
sustainability standards (UCDA, 2012). impacts of sustainability standards on smallholder farmers
There is a growing body of literature about the impacts of are not justified. To gain further insights, comparing effects
standards on coffee farmers, yet with shortcomings in terms of different types of standards in the same regional context
of regional coverage, methods used, and outcome variables would be useful. Such comparisons are rare in the existing
considered. Most existing studies concentrate on Latin
America (e.g., Bacon, 2005; Bacon, Mendez, Gomez, Stuart,
& Flores, 2008; Barham, Callenes, Gitter, Lewis, & Weber, * This research was financially supported by the German Research
2011; Barham & Weber, 2012; Beuchelt & Zeller, 2011; Foundation (DFG). Final revision accepted: September 13, 2014.
400
FOOD STANDARDS, CERTIFICATION, AND POVERTY AMONG COFFEE FARMERS IN UGANDA 401

literature. Two exceptions are Bacon (2005) and Ruben and Fairtrade certification can only be attained by producer orga-
Zuniga (2011). Bacon (2005) compared farmers supplying nizations that are farmer managed, transparent, and founded
Fairtrade, Organic, and specialty coffees in Nicaragua, sug- on democratic principles. Democratic principles require that
gesting that higher and more stable prices in Fairtrade and leaders are elected by all members of the organization. In order
Organic markets may reduce the livelihood vulnerability of to be certified, a producer organization has to make an appli-
smallholders. Ruben and Zuniga (2011) also looked at farmers cation and is physically inspected against Fairtrade standards.
in Nicaragua, using PSM to compare the impact of Fairtrade, If successful, a certificate – usually valid for up to one year – is
Rainforest Alliance, and Starbucks CAFE. They showed that issued. The Fairtrade label guarantees producers a minimum
Fairtrade farmers receive better prices but that Rainforest floor price, whenever the international free market price falls
Alliance and Starbucks CAFE lead to higher yields and qual- below a certain threshold. In addition, a Fairtrade premium
ity performance. is paid to the producer organization to be used for capacity
We contribute to this literature by comparing the impact of building, community development, and related projects. Pro-
three different standards – Fairtrade, UTZ, and Organic – on ducers have to ensure good labor conditions for workers,
smallholder farmers in Uganda. Uganda is an interesting including payment of minimum wages, no child labor, and
study country for such comparison in Africa, because farmers measures to reduce occupational health hazards. There are also
certified under different schemes and their non-certified coun- specific rules for environmental protection, including practices
terparts operate in the same locations. Our approach is similar for sustainable soil and water management and safe use of
to Ruben and Zuniga (2011). We also use survey data and pesticides and fertilizers. The most important markets for
PSM, but employ a refined approach to estimate propensity Fairtrade coffee are the United States, United Kingdom,
scores, which explicitly accounts for the fact that there are Germany, France, and the Netherlands (ITC, 2011).
multiple treatments (Lechner, 2002). Furthermore, we extend The UTZ labeling system (formerly known as UTZ Kapeh)
the analysis of welfare effects and also examine impacts of cer- is a more recently founded standard. It was established in 1999
tification on the prevalence and depth of poverty. by the Ahold Coffee Company, a Dutch roaster, but is now
used by other European coffee companies and restaurant
chains as well. The primary focus of UTZ is on traceability
2. FAIRTRADE, UTZ, AND ORGANIC STANDARDS and sustainable production processes, based on Good Agricul-
tural Practice (GAP) as specified by GlobalGAP. The Global-
Fairtrade, UTZ, and Organic are among the most important GAP standard requires producers to comply with the labor
sustainability-oriented standards in the global coffee market in laws concerning wages and working hours, and to handle
terms of volumes traded and number of farmers certified (ITC, agrochemicals responsibly, as stipulated by the International
2011). Recent trends in the global trade of coffee under these Labor Organization. The UTZ label does not guarantee a
standards are shown in Figure 1. All three standards are rele- minimum price to producers, nor does it provide any premium
vant for smallholder farmers in developing countries, and all or protection against price volatility. It is mandatory for UTZ-
three have social and environmental objectives. Fairtrade cer- certified farmers to be trained in GAP. The idea is that this
tification is only possible for farmer groups or cooperatives. training will contribute to higher coffee yields, better quality,
This is different for Organic and UTZ where certification of and thus higher prices. The official website says: “Through
individual farmers is also possible. However, due to the rela- the UTZ-program farmers grow better crops, generate more
tively high fixed costs involved, individual certification is not income and create better opportunities while safeguarding
practicable for smallholder farmers. Therefore, in a small-farm the environment and securing the earth’s natural resources”
context UTZ and Organic certification are also implemented (UTZ Certified, 2014). The certification process is less bureau-
as group approaches. The three standards are explained in cratic for UTZ than for other sustainability standards, which
more detail in the following. may be one reason for its rapid expansion. The Netherlands is
Fairtrade certification and labeling systems for coffee were the biggest consumer of UTZ-certified coffee; around 30% of
launched in 1988 by the Fairtrade Labeling Organization all coffee consumed in the Netherlands has the UTZ label
(FLO) with the aim of improving the livelihoods of smallholder (ITC, 2011).
producers and cushioning them from volatile market prices. The Organic standard follows the principles of health, ecol-
ogy, fairness, and care. Certified farmers have to use produc-
tion methods based on traditional and scientific knowledge
120 that maximize farm soil fertility and enhance biodiversity.
The use of inorganic inputs such as synthetic fertilizers and
100 chemical pesticides is prohibited. Organic certification requires
farmers to strictly follow organic production guidelines for a
Thousand metric tons

80
minimum period of three years (referred to as the conversion
period) before getting full certification, thus making it one of
the most stringent among the voluntary standards (Coulibaly
60 & Liu, 2006). Prices paid for Organic coffee are often higher
than for non-certified coffee, although no minimum price is
40 guaranteed. The international guidelines for organic farming
are set by the International Federation of Organic Agriculture
20 Movements (IFOAM), an organization based in Germany with
Organic Fairtrade UTZ affiliated organizations in over 100 countries. In addition, some
countries and companies use their own organic standards,
0
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 which are similar to the IFOAM guidelines but may differ in
certain details.
Figure 1. Global import quantities of Organic, Fairtrade, and UTZ-certified A fundamental difference between the three standards is that
coffee. Source: Own graphical presentation based on data from ITC (2011). Fairtrade provides a minimum quality-invariant floor price,
402 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

while UTZ and Organic do not provide such a minimum price. (b) Modeling the impact of certification
The prices paid for UTZ and Organic coffee may be higher
than for non-certified coffee, depending on quality and current In theory, impacts of a program should be evaluated by esti-
demand and supply in the relative market segments, but a mating the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) as
price premium is not guaranteed. Furthermore, as for non-cer- follows:
tified coffee, prices paid for UTZ and Organic coffee may at
times fall below the cost of production, so that farmers face EðW i jI ¼ 1Þ ¼ EðY i1 jI ¼ 1Þ  EðY i0 jI ¼ 1Þ; ð5Þ
a downside risk. This is different for Fairtrade coffee, where
the minimum floor price is calculated such that it stays above where Wi denotes the unbiased welfare effect for households i
the average cost of production. Hence, the Fairtrade minimum that participate in the program, I = 1. In our case, I = 1 means
price may not only increase the expected average price for that households participate in a particular certification scheme.
farmers participating in this certification scheme, but it also Yi1 is the outcome variable of interest (e.g., income, poverty)
reduces the economic risk. with certification, while Yi0 is the outcome variable if the same
households were not certified. Unfortunately, the same house-
holds are not observed with and without certification, so in
3. METHODS reality one has to compare certified and non-certified house-
holds that are not identical as follows:
(a) Modeling farmers’ choice of certification scheme EðW i jI ¼ 1Þ ¼ EðY i1 jI ¼ 1Þ  EðY i0 jI ¼ 0Þ; ð6Þ
We model farmers’ participation in a particular certification where E(Yi0|I = 0) is the outcome for households not
scheme in a random utility framework. Utility, U, is deter- participating in certification. Eqns. (5) and (6) lead to identical
mined by a set of farm and household variables, X, which also results when there is no systematic difference between partici-
influence the farmers’ ability and willingness to participate in pating and non-participating households, except for the
certification. The farmer is assumed to maximize utility: certification scheme itself. Yet, whenever participating and
non-participating households differ in terms of observed or
MAX U ¼ f ðX Þ: ð1Þ unobserved characteristics, Eqn. (6) will lead to biased impact
We postulate that coffee farmer i will participate in a certified estimates, where the bias B can be represented as:
coffee market j if the utility Uij derived is greater than the util- B ¼ EðY i0 jI ¼ 1Þ  EðY i0 jI ¼ 0Þ: ð7Þ
ity Uim that results from accessing an alternative market m.
This relationship can be represented by latent variable I * as: A good method to avoid estimation bias is an experiment
I  ¼ U ij > U im 8m–j ð2Þ where households are randomly assigned to treatment and
control groups, thus ensuring that there are no systematic dif-
where I * is representing the benefits of participating in certi- ferences. In our case, such random assignment was not possi-
fied coffee market j as opposed to market m. While I * itself ble. Our study builds on observational data, where households
is unobserved, we can observe the type of marketing channel self-selected into certification. We use a propensity score
the farmer participates in. The probability that a farmer par- matching approach to reduce selection bias B when evaluating
ticipates in certified market j can be denoted by Pr(I = 1). If the impact of different certification schemes.
the farmer does not participate in market j, I * takes a value
of zero. The utility-maximizing behavior of farmers can be (c) Propensity score matching with multiple treatments
represented as:
  We use generalized propensity scores to control for pre-
I if I ij P 0
Ui ¼ 8m–j ð3Þ treatment differences between certified and non-certified
0 if I im < 0 households in estimating the ATT. Propensity score match-
If we assume a linear relationship, I* can be written as: ing (PSM) is often used to evaluate impacts of a binary treat-
ment variable (e.g., Fischer & Qaim, 2012; Ruben & Fort,
I ij ¼ bj X i þ uij ð4Þ 2012). However, in our case there are three different certifica-
tion schemes j that farmers can participate in, so that the
where b is a vector of coefficients to be estimated, and u is a
treatment variable can take more than two values. In partic-
vector of random disturbances of the unobserved factors
ular, with three certification schemes and one control group,
affecting the participation decision.
the treatment variable can have four possible values. We
In a smallholder environment with widespread market
define j = 0 for farm households that are not certified under
imperfections, utility maximization may differ from profit max-
any scheme, j = 1 for households with Fairtrade certification,
imization. Hence, the variables included in X should cover a
j = 2 for households with UTZ certification, and j = 3 for
broad set of socioeconomic variables that also capture individ-
households with Organic certification. We follow theoretical
ual market access conditions and risk preferences. We analyze
foundations by Imbens (2000) and empirical applications
farmers’ decision to participate in three different certification
by Gerfin and Lechner (2002) and Lechner (2002) for esti-
schemes j (Fairtrade, UTZ, and Organic), each with different
mating propensity scores with multiple treatments. For each
certification requirements and different expected benefits.
marketing channel, we predict the individual probability of
Hence, the factors that influence participation in each scheme
participation using an unconditional multinomial probit
may differ as well. As discussed, unlike the other schemes, Fair-
model. Predicted propensity scores of participation can be
trade guarantees a minimum floor price that reduces market
written as:
risk. Thus, Fairtrade might disproportionately appeal to risk-
averse farmers with limited access to formal and informal Pb j ðxÞ; j 2 J ¼ f0; 1; . . . 3g: ð8Þ
insurance markets. Larson and Plessmann (2009) showed that
farmers’ ability and willingness to take on risks are important Following Lechner (2002), the resulting pairwise propensity
factors to explain their investment decisions and efficiency. scores are,
FOOD STANDARDS, CERTIFICATION, AND POVERTY AMONG COFFEE FARMERS IN UGANDA 403

Pb j ðxÞ index, when a = 1. For the calculations, we use the interna-


Pb jjmj ðxÞ ¼ 8m–j; j; m 2 J ¼ f0; 1; . . . 3g; tional poverty line of $1.25 a day in terms of purchasing power
Pb j ðxÞ þ Pb m ðxÞ
parity (PPP). Expenditures by households in Ugandan shil-
ð9Þ lings (UGX) are converted to international dollars by using
the PPP exchange rate (World Bank, 2013). 1
where Pb jjmj ðxÞ is the predicted conditional propensity score of a
household participating in channel j as opposed to an alterna-
tive channel m. We want to evaluate the impact of certification
4. DATA AND DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS
in comparison to no certification. In addition, we are interested
in how each certification scheme compares to no certification,
(a) Coffee production in Uganda
and how the different schemes compare against each other.
Thus, there are seven pairwise comparisons, namely certified
Uganda is one of the top coffee producers in Africa,
vs. non-certified, Fairtrade, UTZ, and Organic vs. non-certified,
accounting for approximately 2.5% of global coffee produc-
as well as Fairtrade vs. UTZ, Fairtrade vs. Organic, and UTZ
tion. Coffee is also the most important export crop in Uganda.
vs. Organic.
Eighty-five percent of the coffee grown in the country is
Following Lechner (2002), estimation of ATT with multiple
Robusta, which is indigenous to Uganda, while the rest is
treatments can be extended to,
Arabica (World Bank, 2011). It is estimated that in Uganda
ATTjjm ¼ EfY j  Y m jJ ¼ jg; 8m–j; j 2 J ¼ f0; 1; . . . 3g the coffee sector employs more than 3.5 million people directly
and indirectly. The crop is mostly grown by smallholders; an
ð10Þ estimated 90% of the coffee in Uganda is produced by farm
j|m
In our case ATT estimates the expected average effects of households with less than 7 acres of total land (GAIN,
participating in certification scheme j compared to the alterna- 2012). In smallholder production systems, coffee is often inter-
tive channel m. cropped with staples like banana, maize, and cassava; coffee is
As in any PSM analysis, an algorithm to match treated and the main source of cash income, while the other crops are pre-
control households has to be chosen. We use nearest neighbor dominantly grown for subsistence consumption.
matching (NNM) and kernel matching (KM), two commonly Prior to 1991, the Ugandan coffee market was centrally con-
used algorithms for empirical analysis (Caliendo & Kopeinig, trolled by a marketing board. Coffee producers were organized
2008). NNM involves choosing a partner from the control in cooperatives, and through these cooperatives the marketing
group for matching with each treated household or individual board paid farmers a fixed price upon delivery, and a premium
based on propensity scores. We match each treated household based on quality at a later stage. The fixed prices were often
with the three nearest neighbors (with replacement) in terms of below world market levels, and the quality premium was often
propensity score distances. To avoid the possibility of bad paid with significant delays. The system was liberalized in
matches, we impose a maximum caliper restriction of 0.1. 1991. The Uganda Coffee Development Authority (UCDA)
KM uses non-parametric techniques to compare treated and was established to monitor and regulate the market, and to
control households based on kernel-weighted averages promote value addition and competitiveness among local
(Caliendo & Kopeinig, 2008). For the KM, we specified a farmers. But the UCDA is not directly involved in purchasing
default bandwidth of 0.06. or marketing coffee; this is left to independent private traders
It should be stressed that PSM builds on the conditional and companies. As a result of liberalization, market efficiency
independence assumption (CIA), which is also called selection and prices that farmers received for their coffee increased,
on observables (Rosenbaum & Rubin, 1983). This means that while poverty rates in coffee-growing regions decreased
the method only controls for observed heterogeneity between (Baffes, 2006).
treated and control households. Estimates of the ATT may Farmers in Uganda sell their coffee in different forms,
still be biased when there is unobserved heterogeneity. We test depending on technical ability, availability of labor, financial
for the influence of such hidden bias by calculating Rosen- needs, and other factors. When farmers urgently need cash
baum bounds (Becker & Caliendo, 2007; DiPrete & Gangl, already before the harvest, they sometimes decide to sell their
2004). coffee to middlemen when it is still at the flowering stage in the
field. Prices received by farmers for such coffee sales are very
(d) Estimating poverty outcomes low. Alternatively, when the coffee turns red, it can be har-
vested and sold as fresh red cherries. If the cherries are dried
We are interested in analyzing how sustainability certifica- in the sun to a moisture content of about 12%, they can be sold
tion affects the living standard and poverty of coffee-producing as ‘kiboko’. The sun-dried cherries can also be milled, by sep-
households in Uganda. We use household per capita expendi- arating the husk from the bean, using a hulling machine.
ture on food and non-food consumption items as our measure While drying is usually done by individual farmers, milling
of living standard. This also includes the market value of is carried out centrally at the cooperative level. After milling,
home-produced goods. In evaluating poverty outcomes, we the coffee is sold as green beans. Green beans are then further
make use of the FGT (Foster, Greer, & Thorbecke, 1984) class graded by size, shape, and quality and exported to various
of poverty measures, which are calculated as: international destinations for roasting (Fafchamps & Hill,
2005).
1 Xz  qi a
q
FGT a ¼ with a P 0; ð11Þ (b) Household survey
N i¼1 z
where N is the total number of households in the sample, z is We carried out a structured survey of coffee-producing
the poverty line, qi is per capita expenditure of household i; q is households in Uganda between July and September 2012.
the number of households below the poverty line, and a is the For the selection of households to be interviewed, we used a
poverty aversion parameter. We calculate two measures, (i) multi-stage sampling procedure. At first, we contacted the
the head count index, when a = 0, and (ii) the poverty gap main coffee associations in Uganda to obtain lists of existing
404 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

farmer cooperatives, including information on their location, Organic use chemical fertilizers or pesticides. Organic certifica-
the number of cooperative members, and certification details. tion in particular requires additional agronomic measures to
Based on these lists and visits to many of the locations, we enhance soil fertility and biodiversity. And all three schemes
purposively selected three cooperatives. These three coopera- have certain requirements in terms of gender equity and
tives had similar agro-ecological and market access conditions. post-harvest treatment of the coffee fruits. Therefore, certain
All three are located in the Central Region of Uganda; two changes in traditional practices are required, although drastic
of them in Luwero District, and the third in Masaka District. differences between certified and non-certified production are
In all three cooperatives, farmers produce Robusta coffee. not yet observed in Uganda.
Luwero and Masaka are among the top four districts that
account for over 50% of Uganda’s Robusta coffee produc- (c) Descriptive statistics
tion. 2
All three cooperatives selected had acquired UTZ certifica- Table 1 shows descriptive statistics of sample farmers with a
tion around the year 2007; two of them had added a second disaggregation by certification scheme. There are a few signif-
certification scheme shortly thereafter. At the time of the sur- icant differences between certified and non-certified farmers.
vey, one cooperative had only UTZ, the second had UTZ plus Certified farms have larger households, older household
Fairtrade, and the third had UTZ plus Organic certification. heads, longer experience with coffee cultivation, and better
We could not identify farmers that are only certified under access to credit and the public agricultural extension service.
Fairtrade or Organic without also having UTZ certification. They also have larger farms and shorter distances to all-
This may be considered a drawback for the evaluation of indi- weather roads and input shops. Furthermore, we observe a
vidual standards. However, we evaluate the impact of each few significant differences between farmers in different certifi-
standard not only in comparison to non-certified farmers cation schemes. On average, Fairtrade farmers are better edu-
but also in comparison to farmers with other standards, so cated, own larger houses, and have better access to credit than
the combination in two of the cooperatives is not a problem. UTZ and Organic farmers. On the other hand, UTZ farmers
As Fairtrade and Organic standards both have stronger have shorter distances to all-weather roads and output mar-
requirements than UTZ, we refer to the UTZ-Fairtrade com- kets, and Organic farmers have somewhat larger landholdings.
bination as “Fairtrade” and to the UTZ–Organic combination Considering household consumption expenditures and pov-
as “Organic” below. erty levels, which are shown in the lower part of Table 1, Fair-
Farmers have to be member of a group or cooperative to trade farmers seem to be better off than all other groups. This
participate in the certification schemes, but not all members is also visualized in Figure 2, which depicts cumulative distri-
of the three cooperatives actually participated in certifica- bution functions (CDFs) of per capita expenditure for certified
tion. 3 Hence, participation is an individual decision. Cooper- and non-certified farmers in our sample. A Kolmogorov–
ative management provided us with lists of all members, Smirnov test confirms that the Fairtrade distribution stochas-
including details on the location of each farm household and tically dominates the CDF of non-certified farmers (p < 0.01)
their participation in certification schemes. In each coopera- and that of UTZ farmers (p < 0.05). The pooled CDF of cer-
tive we randomly selected two parishes, and in each parish tified farmers dominates that of non-certified farmers at 10%
we randomly selected three villages. In these villages, we ran- significance level. Figure 3 shows the poverty headcount index
domly selected households for the interviews from the lists of and the poverty gap. Fairtrade farmers are less likely to be
certified farmers. For the control group, we randomly selected poor, and those below the poverty line are less likely to be very
non-certified farmers in the same villages. Some of these non- poor.
certified farmers were cooperative members while others were These descriptive statistics suggest that there are systematic
not. But even farmers who were not members had access to differences between participants and non-participants in certi-
some of the services offered by the cooperatives, such as cer- fied markets and also between participants in different certifi-
tain training programs, buying inputs from the cooperative, cation schemes. However, without estimating treatment effects
or selling non-certified coffee to the cooperative. In total, we we do not know whether the observed differences in household
interviewed 108 Fairtrade farmers, 101 Organic farmers, 62 living standards are impacts of certification or the result of
UTZ farmers, and 148 non-certified control farmers. other factors. This will be analyzed in the next section.
The farmers were interviewed with a structured question-
naire by a small team of local enumerators that were carefully
selected, trained, and supervised by the researchers. The ques- 5. ESTIMATION RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
tionnaire covered all economic activities of households with a
detailed breakdown for coffee production and marketing. We (a) Factors influencing the certification decision
also captured the household demographic composition, food
and non-food consumption, and a variety of household con- We start this analysis by analyzing the factors that influence
textual characteristics. As the timing of the survey was shortly household decisions to participate in a particular certification
after the main harvest, consumption levels may be somewhat scheme. We estimate a multinomial probit model for the three
higher than during other times of the year. Yet, as all farmers certification schemes and take non-certified farmers as the base
were surveyed during a relatively short period, this should not category. As described above, this multinomial probit is also
lead to any bias in the impact assessment. employed to calculate propensity scores. Hence, we include a
The coffee farmers in our sample are typical smallholders broad range of explanatory variables. 4 The certification deci-
with average farm sizes of around 5 acres. Use of external sion may be influenced by individual characteristics of the farm
inputs and hired labor is relatively low, so one may ask in household head, such as gender, age, education (measured in
how far the sustainability standards with their regulations in terms of the number of schooling years), and farming experi-
terms of input use and worker welfare actually change tradi- ence (measured in terms of the number of years growing cof-
tional ways of coffee cultivation. However, most coffee farmers fee). Depending on the certification scheme, certain changes
hire laborers for certain operations such as weeding and har- in cultivation practices are required, so that farm size and fam-
vesting. Around 15–20% of the farmers that are not certified ily labor capacity are also expected to play a role. Furthermore,
FOOD STANDARDS, CERTIFICATION, AND POVERTY AMONG COFFEE FARMERS IN UGANDA 405

Table 1. Summary statistics by certification scheme


Pooled sample By certification scheme
Non-certified (N = 148) Certified (N = 271) Fairtrade (N = 108) UTZ (N = 62) Organic (N = 101)
Household characteristics
Male household head (dummy) 0.791 0.738 0.806 0.694 0.693
(0.41) (0.44) (0.40) (0.46) (0.46)
Age of household head (years) 47.378 55.432*** 55.824*** 56.258*** 54.505***
(15.44) (12.82) (11.96) (13.05) (13.60)
Education of household head (years) 6.534 6.590 7.787** 6.710d 5.238**,i
(3.33) (3.78) (3.66) (3.57) (3.63)
Cellphone ownership (dummy) 0.750 0.775 0.907**,b 0.758 0.644i
(0.43) (0.42) (0.29) (0.43) (0.48)
Household size (members) 5.919 6.919** 6.731* 6.452 7.406***
(3.07) (3.23) (2.55) (2.95) (3.94)
Labor capacity (worker equivalents)# 3.370 4.200*** 4.246*** 3.821 4.384***
(1.78) (2.19) (1.80) (1.82) (2.70)
Number of rooms 4.128 4.613** 5.296***,c 4.435d 3.990i
(1.48) (1.51) (1.53) (1.25) (1.33)
Years resident in village 34.074 40.321* 44.194**,a 37.855 37.693h
(32.79) (17.33) (16.15) (17.88) (17.59)
Years growing coffee 16.662 26.786*** 26.787*** 25.597*** 27.515***
(12.75) (15.59) (15.33) (16.50) (15.40)
Leadership position (dummy) 0.372 0.513** 0.685***,b 0.484 0.347i
(0.48) (0.50) (0.47) (0.50) (0.48)
Access to public extension (dummy) 0.486 0.598* 0.667** 0.677*,d 0.475h
(0.50) (0.49) (0.47) (0.47) (0.50)
Access to savings account (dummy) 0.182 0.347*** 0.444*** 0.323* 0.257h
(0.39) (0.48) (0.50) (0.47) (0.44)
Access to credit (dummy) 0.291 0.487*** 0.657***,b 0.403 0.356i
(0.46) (0.50) (0.48) (0.49) (0.48)
Farm characteristics
Total land owned (acres) 4.533 6.220*** 5.857** 5.378d 7.126***
(3.30) (4.70) (3.37) (3.53) (6.20)
Farm altitude (m) 1210.02 1168.85*** 1249.65***,c 1140.13***,f 1100.07***,i
(47.70) (71.65) (24.75) (22.64) (23.52)
Distance to input market (km) 5.712 4.009** 4.484 3.677 3.705*
(8.32) (3.87) (4.74) (3.21) (3.10)
Distance to output market (km) 4.135 3.523 3.521 2.863d 3.930g
(6.19) (3.02) (3.10) (2.46) (3.19)
Distance to all-weather road (km) 18.793 14.998** 15.450*,c 4.959***,f 20.675i
(15.40) (8.31) (6.71) (3.31) (6.01)
Living standard and poverty
Per capita expenditure (UGX/day) 3,176 3,579* 4,010***,b 3,154 3,380g
(1,582) (1,821) (1,902) (1,666) (1,743)
Poverty headcount index 0.26 0.21 0.14*,a 0.26 0.25g
(0.44) (0.41) (0.35) (0.44) (0.43)
Notes: Mean values are shown with standard deviations in parentheses. Mean values across schemes are tested for statistically significant differences;
*
p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01 when compared to non-certified farmers; ap < 0.1, bp < 0.05, cp < 0.01 for differences between Fairtrade and UTZ;
d
p < 0.1, ep < 0.05, fp < 0.01 for differences between UTZ and Organic; gp < 0.1, hp < 0.05, ip < 0.01 for differences between Organic and Fairtrade.
#
Worker equivalents were calculated by weighting household members; less than 9 years = 0; 9–15 years or above 49 years = 0.7; 16–49 = 1.

access to information may influence farmers’ certification deci- house and landholding, we use values lagged by five years, as
sion. One channel of information flow is the public agricultural this was the time when the certification schemes started. Thus,
extension service. Yet, social networks – including neighbors, we avoid possible reverse causality. Risk preferences were not
fellow farmers, and friends – can also be important mediums captured directly in the survey, but we use access to credit and
of information exchange. We proxy the household’s embedd- to a savings account as proxies for households to cope with
edness into social networks, and thus the expected intensity risk. Finally, we include farm location variables, such as alti-
of information flows, with ownership of a cellphone, the num- tude, which can influence coffee quality, and distance to roads
ber of years that the household has resided in the village, and and markets as measures of infrastructure conditions and mar-
whether or not a household member has ever held a leadership ket access.
position in the community. Estimation results from the multinomial probit model are
Asset ownership and risk preferences may also influence a shown in Table 2. Lagged size of the landholding does not
household’s ability and willingness to participate in a particu- influence participation in any of the three schemes, suggesting
lar certification scheme. For durable assets, such as size of the that certification is scale-neutral in this local context.
406 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 2. Multinomial probit estimates for participation in certification


1

schemes
Variables Fairtrade UTZ Organic
Cumulative fraction of households
.8

Household characteristics
Male household head (dummy) 0.142 0.158 0.893
.6

(0.384) (0.501) (0.634)


Age of household head (years) 0.104 0.127 0.270**
.4

(0.077) (0.093) (0.115)


Age of household head squared 0.001 0.001 0.002**
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
.2

Education of household head (years) 0.067 0.073 0.036


(0.050) (0.071) (0.083)
0

0 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000 10,000


Cellphone ownership (dummy) 0.106 0.334 0.284
Per capita household expenditure (UGX/day)
(0.467) (0.475) (0.586)
Labor capacity (worker equivalents) 0.061 0.172 0.243*
All non-certified All certified UTZ
Organic Fairtrade
(0.087) (0.119) (0.135)
Number of rooms (5 years ago) 0.276*** 0.289** 0.096
Figure 2. Cumulative distribution of per capita expenditure by certification (0.100) (0.132) (0.211)
scheme. Years resident in village 0.006 0.008 0.004
(0.005) (0.011) (0.009)
Years growing coffee 0.038*** 0.017 0.029
35
(0.013) (0.020) (0.024)
Leadership position (dummy) 0.853*** 0.554 0.695
Headcount index Poverty gap (0.326) (0.466) (0.653)
30
Access to public extension (dummy) 0.389 1.477*** 1.357**
25
(0.312) (0.484) (0.584)
Access to savings account (dummy) 0.200 0.312 0.536
20
(0.364) (0.558) (0.666)
Percent

Access to credit (dummy) 0.985*** 0.631 0.854


15
(0.303) (0.443) (0.523)
Farm characteristics
10 Total land owned 5 years ago (acres) 0.017 0.089 0.059
(0.042) (0.069) (0.071)
5 Farm altitude (m) 0.018*** 0.044*** 0.076***
(0.004) (0.009) (0.010)
0 Distance to input market (km) 0.030 0.038 0.069
Non-certified Certified Fairtrade UTZ Organic
(0.027) (0.071) (0.071)
Figure 3. Poverty indicators by certification scheme. Distance to output market (km) 0.039 0.076 0.092*
(0.037) (0.088) (0.053)
Distance to all-weather road (km) 0.058*** 0.161*** 0.061**
However, the size of the house increases the likelihood of Fair- (0.015) (0.037) (0.025)
trade and UTZ certification. Households with members who Constant 28.25*** 42.27*** 75.17***
have held a local leadership position are more likely to be (5.239) (9.834) (10.94)
Fairtrade certified, while access to public extension services Log likelihood 178.7
seems to be more important for UTZ and Organic certifica- Chi-square 200.0***
tion. Organic production involves knowledge-intensive agro- Observations 419
nomic practices, so farmers with access to public extension Notes: Coefficient estimates are shown with standard errors in parenthe-
may find it easier to participate. Organic practices are often ses. The base category consists of farmers without any certification.
*
more labor-intensive, too. Hence, households with a larger p < 0.1.
**
family labor capacity have an advantage. And, in organic pro- p < 0.05.
***
duction external inputs such as chemical fertilizers and pesti- p < 0.01.
cides are replaced with household resources, which may
explain why farms further away from roads and markets are (b) Impact of certification
more likely to be certified in the Organic scheme. For them,
it is more difficult to access such external inputs anyway. In Table 3 shows the average treatment effects of certification
contrast, better road access increases the likelihood of partic- on household expenditure and poverty levels for the different
ipation in Fairtrade and UTZ certification. matching comparisons. On average, the ATTs are somewhat
Based on this multinomial probit model, we predicted pro- larger with nearest neighbor matching than with kernel
pensity scores. Figures A1 and A2 in the appendix show the matching, although the significance levels are almost identical.
propensity score distributions for each of the seven pairwise Looking at the first comparison between certified and non-
comparisons. Regions of common support are identified by certified farmers, we find that certification increases consump-
eliminating observations in the treatment and control groups tion expenditure by UGX 369–479 per capita and day (PPP $
that do not find matches due to too low or too high propensity 0.50–0.64). This effect is significant and implies an increase in
scores (“untreated off-support” and “treated off-support”). living standard by 12–15% when compared to mean expendi-
These eliminated observations are not included in the calcula- ture levels of non-certified households. However, the effects
tion of the treatment effects below. on household poverty are not statistically significant.
FOOD STANDARDS, CERTIFICATION, AND POVERTY AMONG COFFEE FARMERS IN UGANDA 407

Table 3. Average treatment effects for household expenditure and poverty


Nearest neighbor matching Kernel matching U
ATT S.E. ATT S.E.
All certified vs. non-certified
Per capita expenditure (UGX) 478.99** 191.88 369.44** 180.24 1.9
Poverty headcount index 0.08 0.05 0.05 0.05 1.5
Poverty gap index 0.01 0.04 0.01 0.04 1.3
Fairtrade vs. non-certified
Per capita expenditure (UGX) 1028.58*** 239.84 871.27*** 229.69 1.6
Poverty headcount index 0.15** 0.06 0.13** 0.05 2.0
Poverty gap index 0.09* 0.04 0.11** 0.04 1.5
UTZ vs. non-certified
Per capita expenditure (UGX) 51.70 269.70 36.72 254.52 1.2
Poverty headcount index 0.02 0.08 0.03 0.07 1.3
Poverty gap index 0.05 0.07 0.05 0.07 1.1
Organic vs. non-certified
Per capita expenditure (UGX) 242.42 286.99 0.55 252.84 1.3
Poverty headcount index 0.04 0.08 0.02 0.07 1.4
Poverty gap index 0.06 0.05 0.07 0.06 1.1
Fairtrade vs. UTZ
Per capita expenditure (UGX) 984.83*** 318.74 850.20*** 286.93 1.8
Poverty headcount index 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 1.4
Poverty gap index 0.21** 0.06 0.22*** 0.06 2.3
Fairtrade vs. Organic
Per capita expenditure (UGX) 619.75* 334.15 484.8 331.01 1.4
Poverty headcount index 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.08 1.1
Poverty gap index 0.19** 0.08 0.24** 0.1 2.3
UTZ vs. Organic
Per capita expenditure (UGX) 97.53 405.28 106.55 343.34 1.2
Poverty headcount index 0.15 0.11 0.13 0.09 1.1
Poverty gap index 0.17 0.18 0.03 0.13 1.1
Notes: ATT: average treatment effect on the treated; S.E.: bootstrapped standard errors; U: Rosenbaum bounds (critical levels for hidden bias).
*
p < 0.1.
**
p < 0.05.
***
p < 0.01.

Disaggregating by certification scheme, we find that the farmers actually have UTZ plus Fairtrade certification,
positive impact on household expenditure is entirely driven whereas Organic farmers have UTZ plus Organic certification.
by Fairtrade certification. Participation in Fairtrade increases Our estimates show that participation in UTZ alone has no
per capita expenditure by 27–33%, while the effects for UTZ significant effect on living standard. Hence, it seems justified
and Organic are both insignificant. Likewise, we find signifi- to attribute the combined UTZ-Fairtrade effects primarily to
cant poverty-reducing effects for Fairtrade, but not for UTZ the Fairtrade standard. This does not rule out that UTZ cer-
and Organic. Participation in Fairtrade reduces the poverty tification may facilitate participation in more stringent stan-
headcount index by 0.13–0.15, implying a 50% reduction of dards, such as Fairtrade or Organic.
the poverty rate observed among non-certified households.
Fairtrade also reduces the poverty gap by 9–11 percentage (c) Robustness tests
points. These results confirm that differentiating impacts by
certification scheme is important. In this subsection, we carry out additional analyses to test
How do the three certification schemes compare with each the robustness of the results with respect to possible hidden
other in terms of living standard effects? Fairtrade farmers bias and issues of sample size. As discussed in Section 3,
have significantly higher household expenditures than both PSM controls for selection bias in impact assessment that is
UTZ and Organic farmers. The differences in the poverty caused by observed heterogeneity between treatment and con-
headcount index between certification schemes are not statisti- trol groups. While we have used a broad set of farm, house-
cally significant. Interestingly, however, Fairtrade farmers hold, and contextual variables to calculate the propensity
below the poverty line have a much lower poverty gap than scores, it is still possible that there are unobserved factors that
their colleagues in the UTZ and Organic schemes. Comparing could be jointly correlated with the decision to participate in
UTZ with Organic, none of the effects is statistically signifi- certification and household living standard. Such unobserved
cant. These patterns underline that Fairtrade is more benefi- heterogeneity could bias the estimated treatment effects. To
cial for smallholder coffee farmers in Uganda than the other test the robustness of the results we calculated Rosenbaum
two certification schemes. The results also suggest that the bounds for hidden bias (Becker & Caliendo, 2007; DiPrete &
combination of treatments in two of the cooperatives is unli- Gangl, 2004). Assume two matched individuals with the same
kely to confuse the impact assessment. As discussed, Fairtrade observed covariates that differ in their odds of participating in
408 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

a certification scheme solely by the difference in unobserved Table 4. Median prices received for coffee in different certification schemes
factors. The Rosenbaum bound (U) measures how big the dif- Certification scheme Median coffee price Interquartile range
ference in unobserved factors that drive the participation deci- (UGX/kg)
sion would have to be, in order to render the estimated ATT
All non-certified 1550 1150
insignificant.
All certified 2000a 1350
The Rosenbaum bounds are shown in the last column of
Fairtrade 3233a,c,d 1783
Table 3. 5 For the significant ATTs, the values for U range
UTZ 1750b 762
between 1.5 and 2.3. The lower bound of 1.5 (for the Fairtrade
Organic 1500b 900
poverty gap effect) implies that matched farmers with the same
observed covariates would have to differ in terms of unob- Notes: Median coffee prices received by farmers were calculated over the
served covariates by a factor of 1.5 (50%), in order to invali- last two seasons. Prices are expressed per unit of coffee as sold or delivered
to the cooperative (‘kiboko’). If further processing occurred at the coop-
date the inference of a significant treatment effect. The upper
erative level, processing costs and value addition are reflected in the price
bound of 2.3 implies that unobserved covariates could even per unit of ‘kiboko’ that farmers receive from the cooperative. The
differ by a factor of 2.3 (130%). Based on these results we con- interquartile range is analogous to the standard deviation for the median.
clude that the impact estimates are quite robust to possible Median prices between schemes are tested for statistically significant dif-
hidden bias. ferences using the Kruskal–Wallis test;
a
Concerning issues of sample size, it should be acknowledged p < 0.01 when compared to non-certified.
b
that PSM was initially developed and used for the estimation p < 0.01 when compared to Fairtrade.
c
of treatment effects with large sample sizes (Rosenbaum & p < 0.01 when compared to UTZ.
d
p < 0.01 when compared to Organic.
Rubin, 1983). When the sample size is small, the matching
procedure may possibly lead to biased results. In particular,
in small samples it may be difficult to find enough matches
to produce reliable estimates due to loss in the statistical for UTZ and Organic coffee are not significantly different from
power of the comparison between treated and untreated indi- prices received for non-certified coffee. This also confirms
viduals. In a recent study, Pirracchio, Resche-Rigon, and farmers’ subjective perceptions. Especially Organic farmers
Chevret (2012) used simulations to demonstrate that PSM in our sample pointed out that there is usually no difference
can produce reliable estimates also with small samples when in prices between certified Organic and non-certified channels.
the propensity model is properly specified. They showed that An advantage of selling to traders in non-certified channels is
the relative bias remains below 10% even when reducing the that farmers get cash on the spot, while sales in the Organic
sample size to 40 observations. channels are through the cooperative and associated with pay-
In the same study, Pirracchio et al. (2012) also tested the ment delays.
performance of an alternative propensity score method, On average, Fairtrade farmers received about double the
namely inverse probability of treatment weighting (IPTW). price than their colleagues who sold in UTZ, Organic, or
They concluded that IPTW can also produce unbiased esti- non-certified channels. This is primarily due to two reasons. 6
mates with small samples. While PSM has become more pop- First, the Fairtrade minimum price plays a role whenever the
ular in recent years, IPTW has been used frequently to reduce free market price falls below a certain threshold, which hap-
selection bias in studies with observational data (Hirano & pened repeatedly during the two seasons. We reckon that the
Imbens, 2001; Imbens, 2000). As a robustness test, we re-esti- minimum price guarantee has raised the average price for
mated the impact of certification on household living standard Fairtrade farmers by 30%. Second, the Fairtrade cooperative
using IPTW and compared these estimates with the PSM mills most of the coffee delivered by certified farmers and sells
results. The comparisons are shown in Table 5 in the appen- it in the form of green beans, whereas the UTZ and Organic
dix. The estimated treatment effects with both methods are cooperatives sell coffee primarily in the ‘kiboko’ stage. Non-
very similar, which increases the confidence in the PSM results certified farmers sell their coffee as red cherries or as ‘kiboko’.
in spite of the relatively small sample size. Against this background one could argue that parts of the eco-
nomic benefits observed for Fairtrade farmers are due to the
(d) Possible impact pathways value addition through processing rather than Fairtrade certi-
fication as such. However, in this particular context both
We have shown that Fairtrade certification leads to signifi- aspects are directly linked. Successful value addition requires
cant gains in living standard, which is not the case for UTZ the ability to mill the coffee properly and having access to buy-
and Organic. What are the reasons for these differences in ers of green beans – conditions which are met for Fairtrade,
impact? Differences in prices seem to play an important role. but not for UTZ, Organic, and non-certified farmers. 7
In Table 4, we present average coffee prices received by farm- In addition to the minimum floor price, the Fairtrade coop-
ers in different marketing channels. As coffee prices can fluctu- erative receives a social premium, which is used for improving
ate considerably, average prices over a period of two seasons – processing facilities and other infrastructure investments. 8
as reported by farmers – are shown. These price data are not Furthermore, there are important differences in terms of access
normally distributed; we show median prices that better reflect to buyers. The Fairtrade cooperative is entirely managed by its
the average than arithmetic means. These prices are expressed member farmers, and it owns the certification documents
per unit of coffee as sold or delivered to the cooperative. Farm- itself. The cooperative independently sells the coffee directly
ers deliver their coffee to the cooperative in the ‘kiboko’ stage. to exporters in Kampala. There are different Fairtrade export-
If further processing occurs at the cooperative level, processing ers in Kampala buying coffee in the green bean stage, so there
costs and value addition are both reflected in the price per unit is competition and some scope to negotiate prices. In contrast,
of ‘kiboko’ that farmers receive from the cooperative. the UTZ and Organic cooperatives do not own the certifica-
Prices received by farmers for certified coffee are signifi- tion documents. Instead, these documents are owned by
cantly higher than for non-certified coffee. Further disaggrega- export companies. This setup is the result of development pro-
tion reveals that this pattern is primarily driven by the high grams involving public–private partnerships. The UTZ and
prices in the Fairtrade scheme. In fact, average prices received Organic certification processes were supported by NGOs that
FOOD STANDARDS, CERTIFICATION, AND POVERTY AMONG COFFEE FARMERS IN UGANDA 409

also linked farmers to specific export companies in order to tion to negotiate conditions. In contrast, the UTZ and Organic
ensure access to certified international markets. These compa- certification documents are owned by specific exporters, to
nies cover part of the certification and monitoring costs; in which participating farmers have to sell their coffee. Fourth,
exchange, they own the certification documents. A contract and related to the previous point, the Fairtrade cooperative
specifies that the UTZ and Organic cooperatives can sell their sells most of the certified coffee after milling, which further
certified coffee only to these exporters, who determine prices increases the sales price. UTZ and Organic farmers, on the
and processing stages. Most of the UTZ and Organic coffee other hand, sell most of their coffee in unprocessed form, as
is sold to these exporters in the ‘kiboko’ stage. specified by the exporters that own the certification documents.
Another possible impact pathway that may lead to dynamic Some of these factors are specific to the particular coopera-
benefits for Fairtrade farmers is through higher capital invest- tives analyzed here. Therefore, one should not extrapolate
ments (Ruben & Fort, 2012). The guaranteed minimum price, these findings to other settings without further analysis. We
which truncates the downside of the price distribution, encour- should also stress that our study is not an attempt to holisti-
ages risk-averse farmers to invest more in capital items and cally assess all possible impacts of certification. We focused
improved production technology. This may contribute to on socioeconomic implications for smallholder producers in
wealth accumulation over time. In the survey, we did not cover terms of living standard and poverty. Especially the Organic
farmer investments, but we have data on the value of house- standard places higher priority on aspects of environmental
hold productive assets in 2012. Furthermore, we asked farmers sustainability, which we did not analyze. While the Fairtrade
how many of these assets were purchased during the last five minimum price and premium help to reduce poverty among
years. The value of productive assets is significantly higher coffee farmers in Uganda, these pricing elements are not
for Fairtrade farmers as compared to all other sample farmers intrinsically tied to sustainable production methods. Nor do
combined. Fairtrade farmers also purchased slightly more our results imply that Fairtrade pricing schemes are superior
assets than other farmers during the last five years. This is to other policy measures in terms of reducing poverty.
not a proof of any causal relationship but it indicates that How do our findings from Uganda compare with case studies
dynamic aspects may play a role. on Fairtrade coffee in Latin America? Most of these other stud-
ies did not analyze poverty effects, but many compared prices.
Generally, mean Fairtrade prices are reported to be higher than
6. CONCLUSION free market prices (Arnould et al., 2009; Bacon, 2005;
Raynolds et al., 2004; Ruben & Zuniga, 2011), although de
The role of sustainability standards in global coffee markets Janvry, McIntosh, and Sadoulet (2010) found that effective
is growing. Consumers typically assume that such standards price advantages are minimal for some farmers due to over-cer-
benefit smallholder farmers in developing countries, but robust tification. Over-certification entails that certified farmers may
evidence is relatively thin. We have analyzed and compared the sell only a small quantity of their coffee through the Fairtrade
impact of three such standards and certification schemes – channel. Such over-certification is not yet an issue in Uganda.
Fairtrade, UTZ, and Organic – on the livelihoods of coffee Other important points to consider are yield and coffee quality.
farmers in Uganda. Results show that farm households in all Based on data from coffee farmers in Mexico and Peru,
three schemes combined have significantly higher living Barham and Weber (2012) showed that yields may be more
standards than their matched counterparts in non-certified important than price premiums for increasing net returns. This
channels. Poverty effects are not statistically significant for is not the case in Uganda, probably because the use of yield-
the combined sample of certified households. These findings increasing external inputs is not yet very widespread. Concern-
are in line with Jena et al. (2012) who analyzed the impact of ing quality, de Janvry et al. (2010) and Ruben and Zuniga
Fairtrade and Organic certification on coffee farmers in (2011) reported that Fairtrade farmers in Central America do
Ethiopia. In Nicaragua, Valkila (2009) and Valkila and not have sufficient incentives to improve their performance,
Nygren (2010) also looked at Fairtrade and Organic, without because the guaranteed minimum price is quality-invariant.
finding significant benefits. Valkila (2009) argued that these As a result, coffee farmers in other certification schemes with
standards may even contribute to poverty traps through per- different incentive structures outperform Fairtrade farmers in
petuating low-input production systems. These authors did terms of quality performance. This is also not yet observed in
not disaggregate their analyses by certification scheme. Uganda. These regional differences make sense: average yield
However, our results suggest that disaggregation is impor- and quality levels are still lower in Africa than in Latin America
tant, because impacts may differ considerably between certifi- and the markets for certified coffees are not yet as developed.
cation schemes. In Uganda, Fairtrade certification contributes In conclusion, we highlight two broader lessons to be learned.
to significant improvements in household living standard, First, African smallholders are capable of participating in cer-
whereas UTZ and Organic certification do not. Fairtrade tified markets. The cooperatives investigated in this study, in
increases per capita consumption expenditures by 30% and one of the poorest countries in the world, were certified around
reduces the likelihood of being poor by 50%. Fairtrade also the year 2007 and have since managed to fully comply with the
reduces the poverty gap among certified farmers. different international standards. This is encouraging and dis-
The observed differences in impact can be explained by var- proves pessimistic views that poor smallholders will not be able
ious factors. First, Fairtrade guarantees a minimum support to participate in high-value markets on a sustained basis. Sec-
price, which increases the average price received by farmers ond, the impact of standards and certification on farmer liveli-
and reduces downside risk. Second, Fairtrade cooperatives hoods may differ significantly by certification scheme and
receive a premium, which they use for investments in infra- market conditions. Hence, it is worthwhile to take a closer look.
structure and training programs. Such price guarantees and Better understanding of impact differences and factors that con-
premiums are not provided in UTZ and Organic certification tribute to these differences may be relevant for all actors along
schemes. Third, farmers in the Fairtrade cooperative in the supply chain, including consumers who wish to make more
Uganda have more freedom in terms of marketing their certi- informed purchase decisions. Better understanding may also
fied coffee. The cooperative owns the Fairtrade certification help to improve the design of standards and certification sys-
documents and can sell to any buyer; thus it is in a better posi- tems from a social perspective.
410 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

NOTES

1. The PPP exchange rate is 744.62 UGX per dollar. In 2012, the official 5. The Rosenbaum bounds shown in Table 3 refer to the nearest
market exchange rate was around 2,600 UGX per US dollar. neighbor matching algorithm. We did the same calculations also for the
kernel matching algorithm with almost identical results.
2. The coffee-growing regions in Luwero and Masaka Districts have
altitudes of up to 1,300 m above sea level where only Robusta coffee is 6. As a third possible reason one might expect quality differences.
grown. Arabica coffee is grown in the highland areas in the Eastern and However, while certified coffee may be of higher quality than non-certified
South-Western Region of Uganda with altitudes of over 1,500 m. The fact coffee, Fairtrade is not of higher quality than UTZ or Organic.
that all farmers in our sample grow Robusta coffee facilitates the impact
evaluation and comparison between certification schemes. 7. There are commercial coffee milling centers in larger towns that non-
Fairtrade farmers could use in principle to sell green beans independently.
3. As discussed, also for UTZ and Organic, where individual certification However, this would require transporting the coffee to these milling
is possible in theory, smallholder farmers are only certified in groups, in centers and having access to buyers of green beans. As the main market
order to reduce certification costs. Coffee cooperatives in Uganda can be for green coffee is in Kampala, selling there independently would be
quite large, sometimes involving several thousand members. These associated with significant transaction costs.
cooperatives comprise smaller groups of farmers, and these groups are
the relevant units for certification. Hence, the same cooperatives include 8. In 2013, the Fairtrade cooperative with around 800 certified farmers
certified and non-certified farmers and groups. Group sizes are flexible. received a premium of 150,000 US dollars. Other types of investment with
Farmers may change their affiliation to a particular group depending on this money include the establishment of a credit and savings unit for
individual certification preferences. farmers, a fund for advance payment of certified coffee, and training
programs related to issues of production and gender equity.
4. For the calculation of propensity scores, it does not matter if the
explanatory variables are endogenous. However, to the extent possible we
tried to use exogenous variables.

REFERENCES

Arnould, E. J., Plastina, A., & Ball, D. (2009). Does fair trade deliver on Goldman School of Public Policy Working Paper. Berkeley, CA:
its core value proposition? Effects on income, educational attainment, University of California.
and health in three countries. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, DiPrete, T., & Gangl, M. (2004). Assessing bias in the estimation of causal
28(2), 186–201. effects: Rosenbaum bounds on matching estimators and instrumental
Bacon, C. M. (2005). Confronting the coffee crisis: Can fair trade, organic, variables estimation with imperfect instruments. Sociological Method-
and specialty coffees reduce small-scale farmer vulnerability in north- ology, 34, 271–310.
ern Nicaragua?. World Development, 33(3), 497–511. Elfenbein, D. W., & McManus, B. (2010). A greater price for a greater
Bacon, C. M., Mendez, V. E., Gomez, M. E., Stuart, D., & Flores, S. R. good? Evidence that consumers pay more for charity-linked products.
(2008). Are sustainable coffee certifications enough to secure farmer American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(2), 28–60.
livelihoods? The Millenium development goals and Nicaragua’s fair Fafchamps, M., & Hill, R. (2005). Selling at the farmgate or traveling to
trade cooperatives. Globalizations, 5(2), 259–274. market. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 87(3), 717–734.
Baffes, J. (2006). Restructuring Uganda’s coffee industry: Why going back Fischer, E., & Qaim, M. (2012). Linking smallholders to markets:
to basics matters. Development Policy Review, 24(4), 413–436. Determinants and impacts of farmer collective action in Kenya. World
Barham, B., Callenes, M., Gitter, S., Lewis, J., & Weber, J. (2011). Fair Development, 40(6), 1255–1268.
trade/organic coffee, rural livelihoods, and the “agrarian question”: Foster, J., Greer, J., & Thorbecke, E. (1984). A class of decomposable
Southern Mexican coffee families in transition. World Development, poverty measures. Econometrica, 52(3), 761–766.
39(1), 134–145. GAIN. (2012). Uganda coffee annual report 2012. Kampala: Global Agricul-
Barham, B. L., & Weber, J. G. (2012). The economic sustainability of tural Information Network, USDA Foreign Agricultural Services.
certified coffee: Recent evidence from Mexico and Peru. World Gerfin, M., & Lechner, M. (2002). A microeconometric evaluation of the
Development, 40(6), 1269–1279. active labour market policy in Switzerland. Economic Journal,
Basu, A., & Hicks, R. (2008). Label performance and the willingness to 482(112), 854–893.
pay for Fair trade coffee: A cross-national perspective. International Hansen, H., & Trifkovic, N. (2014). Food standards are good – For
Journal of Consumer Studies, 5(32), 823–842. middle-class farmers. World Development, 56, 226–242.
Becker, S., & Caliendo, M. (2007). Mhbounds – Sensitivity analysis for Hirano, K., & Imbens, G. W. (2001). Estimation of causal effects using
average treatment effects. The Stata Journal, 7(1), 71–83. propensity score weighting: An application to data on right heart
Beuchelt, T. D., & Zeller, M. (2011). Profits and poverty: Certification’s catheterization. Health Services and Outcomes Research Methodology,
troubled link for Nicaragua’s organic and fairtrade coffee producers. 2(3–4), 259–278.
Ecological Economics, 70(7), 1316–1324. Imbens, G. (2000). The role of the propensity score in estimating dose–
Bolwig, S., Gibbon, P., & Jones, S. (2009). The economics of smallholder response functions. Biometrika, 87(3), 706–710.
organic contract farming in tropical Africa. World Development, 37(6), ITC. (2011). Trends in the trade of certified coffees. Technical Paper.
1094–1104. Geneva: International Trade Center, World Trade Organization and
Caliendo, M., & Kopeinig, S. (2008). Some practical guidance for the United Nations.
implementation of propensity score matching. Journal of Economic Jaffee, D. (2008). “Better, but not great”: The social and environmental
Surveys, 22(1), 31–72. benefits and limitations of fair trade for indigenous coffee producers in
Coulibaly, A. L., & Liu, P. (2006). Regulations, standards and certification Oaxaca, Mexico. In R. Ruben (Ed.), The impact of fair trade
for agricultural exports. A practical manual for producers and exporters (pp. 195–222). Wageningen: Wageningen Academic Publishers.
in East Africa. Rome: Food and Agricultural Organization of the Jena, P. R., Chichaibelu, B. B., Stellmacher, T., & Grote, U. (2012). The
United Nations. impact of coffee certification on small-scale producers’ livelihoods: A
de Janvry, A., McIntosh, C., & Sadoulet, E. (2010). Fair trade and free case study from the Jimma Zone, Ethiopia. Agricultural Economics,
entry: The dissipation of producer benefits in a disequilibrium market. 43(4), 429–440.
FOOD STANDARDS, CERTIFICATION, AND POVERTY AMONG COFFEE FARMERS IN UGANDA 411

Kleemann, L., Abdulai, A., & Buss, M. (2014). Certification and access to Ruben, R., & Fort, R. (2012). The impact of fair trade certification for
export markets: Adoption and return on investment of organic- coffee farmers in Peru. World Development, 40(3), 570–582.
certified pineapple farming in Ghana. World Development, 64, 79–92. Ruben, R., & Zuniga, G. (2011). How standards compete: Comparative
Larson, D. F., & Plessmann, F. (2009). Do farmers choose to be impact of coffee certification schemes in Northern Nicaragua. Supply
inefficient? Evidence from Bicol. Journal of Development Economics, Chain Management: An International Journal, 16(2), 98–109.
90, 24–32. Subervie, J., & Vagneron, I. (2013). A drop of water in the Indian Ocean?
Lechner, M. (2002). Program heterogeneity and propensity score match- The impact of GlobalGap certification on lychee farmers in Mada-
ing: An application to the evaluation of active labor market policies. gascar. World Development, 50, 57–73.
Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(May), 205–220. Tran, N., Bailey, C., Wilson, N., & Phillips, M. (2013). Governance of global
Melo, O., Engler, A., Nahuehual, L., Cofre, G., & Barrena, J. (2014). Do value chains in response to food safety and certification standards: The
sanitary, phytosanitary, and quality-related standards affect interna- case of shrimp from Vietnam. World Development, 45, 325–336.
tional trade? Evidence from Chilean fruit exports. World Development, UCDA. (2012). Coffee’s contribution to Uganda’s economic development
54, 350–359. since independence. Retrieved on 5 June 2014 from <www.uganda-
Mendez, V. E., Bacon, C. M., Olson, M., Petchers, S., Herrador, D., coffeetrade.com/documents/UgandaCoffeeYearbook2011_12.pdf>.
Carranza, C., et al. (2010). Effects of fair trade and organic Utting-Chamorro, K. (2005). Does fair trade make a difference? The case
certifications on small-scale coffee farmer households in Central of small coffee producers in Nicaragua. Development in Practice, 15(3),
America and Mexico. Renewable Agriculture and Food Systems, 584–599.
25(03), 236–251. UTZ Certified. (2014). Retrieved on 17 June 2014 from <https://
Mergenthaler, M., Weinberger, K., & Qaim, M. (2009). The food system www.utzcertified.org>.
transformation in developing countries: A disaggregate demand Valkila, J. (2009). Fair trade organic coffee production in Nicaragua –
analysis for fruits and vegetables in Vietnam. Food Policy, 34(5), Sustainable development or a poverty trap?. Ecological Economics,
426–436. 68(12), 3018–3025.
Pirracchio, R., Resche-Rigon, M., & Chevret, S. (2012). Evaluation of the Valkila, J., & Nygren, A. (2010). Impacts of fair trade certification on
propensity score methods for estimating marginal odds ratios in case of coffee farmers, cooperatives, and laborers in Nicaragua. Agriculture
small sample size. BMC Medical Research Methodology, 12, 70. and Human Values, 27(3), 321–333.
Raynolds, L. T., Murray, D., & Leigh Taylor, P. (2004). Fair trade coffee: World Bank. (2011). Ugandan coffee supply chain risk assessment.
Building producer capacity via global networks. Journal of Interna- Washington, DC: World Bank.
tional Development, 16(8), 1109–1121. World Bank. (2013). World development indicators. Washington, DC:
Reardon, T., Barrett, C. B., Berdegué, J. A., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2009). World Bank.
Agrifood industry transformation and small farmers in developing
countries. World Development, 37(11), 1717–1727.
Rosenbaum, P. R., & Rubin, D. B. (1983). The central role of the
propensity score in observational studies for causal effects. Biometrika,
70(1), 41.
APPENDIX A

Certified vs. non-certified Fairtrade vs. non-certified

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Propensity score Propensity score

Untreated Treated: on support Treated: off support Untreated: off support Untreated: on support Treated

Organic vs. non-certified UTZ vs. non-certified

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Propensity score Propensity score

Untreated Treated: on support Treated: off support Untreated: off support Untreated: on support Treated

Figure A1. Propensity score distribution and common support for certified and non-certified farmers.
412 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Fairtrade vs. UTZ Fairtrade vs. Organic

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Propensity score Propensity score

Untreated Treated: on support Treated: off support Untreated: off support Untreated: on support Treated

Organic vs. UTZ

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Propensity score
Untreated Treated: on support Treated: off support

Figure A2. Propensity score distribution and common support for farmers in different certification schemes.

Table 5. Comparison of PSM and IPTW treatment effects for per capita expenditure (UGX)
PSM (nearest neighbor matching) PSM (Kernel matching) IPTW
** **
All certified vs. non-certified 478.99 (191.88) 369.44 (180.24) 428.605** (174.10)
Fairtrade vs. non-certified 1028.58*** (239.84) 871.27*** (229.69) 973.789*** (239.97)
UTZ vs. non-certified 51.70 (269.70) 36.72 (254.52) 80.544 (257.34)
Organic vs. non-certified 242.42 (286.99) 0.55 (252.84) 129.988 (212.05)
Fairtrade vs. UTZ 984.83*** (318.74) 850.20*** (286.93) 893.245*** (300.35)
Fairtrade vs. Organic 619.75* (334.15) 484.8 (331.01) 843.800*** (262.33)
UTZ vs. Organic 97.53 (405.28) 106.55 (343.34) 49.444 (278.51)
Notes: Estimated treatment effects are shown with standard errors in parentheses. PSM: propensity score matching; IPTW: inverse probability of
treatment weighting.
*
p < 0.1.
**
p < 0.05.
***
p < 0.01.

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

S-ar putea să vă placă și