Sunteți pe pagina 1din 24

ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

V I E W
E
R

SC E
I N

A
D V A

The Sociology of Markets


Neil Fligstein and Luke Dauter
Department of Sociology, University of California, Berkeley, California 94720;
email: fligst@uclink4.berkeley.edu, luked@berkeley.edu

Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2007. 33:6.1–6.24 Key Words


The Annual Review of Sociology is online at fields, networks, institutions, performativity, culture, politics
http://soc.annualreviews.org

This article’s doi: Abstract


10.1146/annurev.soc.33.040406.131736
The sociology of markets has been one of the most vibrant fields in
Copyright  c 2007 by Annual Reviews. sociology in the past 25 years. There is a great deal of agreement
All rights reserved
that markets are social structures characterized by extensive social
0360-0572/07/0811-0001$20.00 relationships between firms, workers, suppliers, customers, and gov-
ernments. But, like in many sociological literatures, the theory camps
that have formed often seem to speak by each other. We show that
some of the disagreement between theory camps is due to differ-
ences in conceptual language, and other disagreements stem from
the fact that theory camps ignore the concepts in other theory camps,
thereby making their theories less complete. We end by considering
deeper controversies in the literature that seem open both to new
conceptualization and further empirical research.

6.1
ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

O how they cling and wrangle, some who claim their attempts to understand the origins, op-
For preacher and monk the honored name! erations, and dynamics of markets as social
For, quarreling, each to his view they cling. structures, the primary perspectives that have
Such folk see only one side of a thing. emerged tend to remain separate and distinct
at the theoretical level. Much like the blind
(from the text of Jain and Buddhist origin,
monks and preachers who fail to see the whole
Udana 68–69, “Parable of the Blind Men and
of the elephant in Buddha’s famous parable,
the Elephant”)
scholars have often focused on a particular so-
cial aspect of markets and acted as if it was a
INTRODUCTION more general understanding.
The sociology of markets has been one of the This theoretical separateness produces
most vibrant fields in sociology in the past two problems. First, because many scholars
25 years.1 Starting with a trickle of empiri- use similar concepts but identify them by
cal and theoretical papers, it has grown to a different terms, confusion results about the
river. One of the seminal pieces in the field, degree to which people are saying different
Granovetter’s (1985) “Economic Action and things. For example, most scholars, regardless
Social Structure: The Problem of Embedded- of their approach, believe that culture (shared
ness” has been cited over 2500 times since its meanings, normative understandings, identi-
publication, making it the most cited paper in ties, local practices) plays an important role
sociology in the postwar era.2 Although so- in market projects. Much of this conceptual
ciologists have made significant progress in overlap is hidden by the use of jargon (for ex-
ample, the use of terms like frames, logics, per-
1
We want to distinguish the sociology of markets from formativity, scripts, conceptions of control, or
the broader project of economic sociology (Fligstein 2001). local knowledge). Thus, scholars who purport
Following Polanyi (1957), economic sociology is the gen-
eral study of the conditions of the production and repro- to approach their subject matter from a partic-
duction of social life. Such a study would include studies ular perspective actually share concepts with
of consumption, the family, and the links between states a wide variety of other scholars.
and households, schooling, and economic life more broadly
(Smelser & Swedberg 2005, p. 3). The sociology of markets Second, to the degree that scholars are
refers more narrowly to the study of one kind of social ex- really saying different things, assessing how
change, that of markets, and to the structuring of that kind much their theoretical views are complemen-
of social exchange, under the conditions we call capitalist.
This focus includes the study of firms, product markets, and tary or contradictory is difficult. When one
labor markets as well as their broader linkages to suppliers, viewpoint complements another, theory is ad-
workers, and states and the role of local cultures (i.e., local vanced. Taking into account other possible el-
in the sense of belonging to a particular market), systems of
meanings insofar as they influence what products are, and ements in the social structuring of markets
the role of morality in the generation of particular kinds of yields a more complete view of market pro-
markets. cesses. But when theories contradict, scholars
2
Recently Jerry Jacobs (2005) calculated the most cited need to understand why their perspectives dif-
papers in the American Sociological Review in the postwar
era. The paper with the most citations was DiMaggio & fer and how those differences can be usefully
Powell’s (1983) “Institutional Isomorphism” paper, with explored to further both theory and research.
1700 citations. Granovetter’s paper appeared in the Amer- The primary purpose of this review is to be-
ican Journal of Sociology and, as far as we know, no one
has created a similar list for that journal. But, with almost gin to untangle the theoretical and empirical
2500 citations, it is hard to believe that many papers outdid work on the sociology of markets, clarifying
Granovetter’s. It should also be noted that the DiMaggio & what we know and where scholars really dis-
Powell paper has greatly influenced the sociology of mar-
kets as well. We argue that this paper has greatly influenced agree.
at least one strain of thought in the sociology of markets The literature (and the way that peo-
(i.e., institutional theory). If one takes both of these pa- ple teach their graduate courses) has of-
pers as part of the foundation of the field, arguably the two
most cited papers in the postwar era are at the core of the ten been divided into three theory groups
sociology of markets. (Fourcade-Gourinchas 2007) according to

6.2 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

whether scholars use (a) networks (Burt 1992; come to be created and sold, and in how the
Granovetter 1974, 2005; White 1981, 2002), local cultures of particular markets form what
(b) institutions (Dobbin 1994; Fligstein 1990, institutionalists call the institutionalization of
2001; Powell & DiMaggio 1991), or (c) perfor- particular markets.
mativity (Beunza & Stark 2004, Callon 1998, Although these three approaches encom-
Callon & Muniesa 2005, MacKenzie & Milo pass a large portion of the work done in the
2003, MacKenzie 2005) as explanatory mech- sociology of markets, they are by no means
anisms in the emergence and ongoing dynam- exhaustive. Along with considering these par-
ics of markets. Scholars in the network tradi- ticular perspectives with the goal of extracting
tion have focused on relational ties between what sociologist have learned about markets
actors as the material of social structure. Insti- and what remains to be resolved, we consider
tutionalists focus on how cognition and action in this review the degree to which the differ-
are contextualized by market rules, power, and ent theory groups offer incomplete represen-
norms. The performative school of thought tations of the social structuring of markets.
views economic action as a result of calculative The division of the field into networks, in-
processes involving the specific technologies stitutions, and performativity excludes other
and artifacts that actors employ. theoretical perspectives that should also be at
This division of the field overemphasizes the core of thinking about markets as social
the extent to which these perspectives are structures. We focus on two important ap-
in fact separate theory groups. All three ap- proaches that have been underplayed in the
proaches rely on viewing markets as social are- literature: political economy and population
nas where firms, their suppliers, customers, ecology.
workers, and government interact, and all Political economy has pioneered thinking
three approaches emphasize how the connect- about the linkages between states, law, and
edness of social actors affects their behavior. markets and the historical emergence of sys-
Network analysis is a technique for finding tems of governance. The literature on the
social structures in relational data. It is not a comparative study of capitalist arrangements
theory of the underlying relationships in the and their effects on various outcomes, includ-
data and the mechanisms that they represent. ing economic development, is part and par-
Scholars who use network techniques invoke cel of the sociology of markets. Institutional
theoretical constructs like power, resource de- theory is the approach that most frequently
pendence, cooptation, information, and trust adds political economy into its analyses. It
to explain the social structures that emerge focuses on the role of governments and law
from their analyses. These mechanisms are in the creation of particular features of mar-
common to institutional theory and to other kets, for example the types of alliances and
theories relevant to the sociology of markets. forms of cooperation that are legal or forms of
Institutional theorists are interested in how property rights (Campbell & Lindberg 1990,
field-level phenomena diffuse to make fields Carrutherst & Ariovich 2004). But network
isomorphic, often through social networks theorists and scholars interested in perfor-
(Davis 1991). Performativists have explicitly mativity have generally ignored the possible
connected their approach to network theory effects of government and law and the role
in what Callon (1998) calls the actor-network of preexisting relationships between the own-
approach. The actor-network approach views ers of firms, managers, workers, and govern-
not only humans, but also objects and artifacts, ments on market processes. This makes their
techniques, and ideas as agents embedded in accounts of particular markets incomplete.
networks of calculative relations. In addition, Population ecology is the branch of or-
performative approaches overlap with institu- ganizational theory that deals most directly
tional theory in their interest in how products with the effects of competition on the

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.3


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

production of markets. Scholars who use this pendence or mediate competition. But other
approach have drawn on network or institu- scholars who view the links between produc-
tional analyses (Baron et al. 1999, Haveman ers and consumers as pivotal to the produc-
& Rao 1997). But population ecology has tion of markets emphasize the role of trust and
not figured into the core of the sociology of culture (i.e., commonly held meanings about
markets, primarily because it has developed the product, its morality, and its usefulness)
a vocabulary and set of methods that do not in those relationships as key to understand-
easily translate into many of the current ap- ing market processes. Granovetter (1985) ar-
proaches to social structure. This is unfortu- gued early on that the main purpose of em-
nate because several developments in popula- beddedness in markets was that it increased
tion ecology have paralleled those in the other the trust between buyers and sellers. Zelizer
approaches. We show how many ideas in pop- has taken the relationship between produc-
ulation ecology have been expressed in a dif- ers and consumers in a different direction.
ferent language in the other points of view Her argument is that consumers must be con-
and argue that the insights of population ecol- vinced not just of the utility of the products
ogy should be added more explicitly to schol- they buy and the trustworthiness of those who
arly thinking about the social structuring of sell them, but also of the morality of the prod-
markets. uct (Zelizer 1983, 1994, 1997). Her more cul-
After one notes the similar ideas that run tural approach alerts scholars to the problem
through the literature, including the less rec- of framing products so that consumers find
ognized areas of contribution, there remain them not just useful, but in concert with their
a number of interesting problems that stem values.
from theoretical differences. Scholars in the A third source of disagreement is that
performative tradition have presented their some scholars view market structures as either
perspective as a critique of the predominant emergent or in equilibrium, whereas others
sociological modes of understanding markets. argue that markets are always changing. The
Their basic idea is that economic action is possibility for a sociological definition of mar-
about calculation, and that how the qualities ket equilibrium is intriguing. White (1981),
of goods are calculated (i.e., the amenability of for example, has defined a market as a “repro-
goods to calculation, the calculative capacities ducible role structure.” This idea implies that
of actors, and the interaction between them the social processes that occur when a market
in the act of exchange) is crucial to under- is formed are different from the social pro-
standing market structure. These scholars ar- cesses that occur once a more stable set of so-
gue that the tools actors have at their disposal cial relationships appear. Population ecology
to interpret and define their economic worlds has an implied theory of what could be called
and how they organize interaction over ex- punctuated equilibrium. At the beginning of
change are created by and enact ideas about markets, there is often a period of turmoil
how economic activity should and does oper- and change followed by some stasis and per-
ate. We interpret the performative argument haps a second period of turmoil. The alterna-
as an attempt to insert cultural understandings tive view is that markets are always fluid, with
of actors into the core of the social construc- products, processes, and advantage constantly
tion of markets. shifting. Here, equilibrium solutions to the
A second disagreement focuses on link- problem of what other market actors will do
ages between producers and consumers. Many never form (Nelson & Winter 1982). These
analyses of markets focus exclusively on pro- different views of market dynamics are impor-
ducers and their competitive relationships. tant because they imply very different ways of
Here, attention is given to how social struc- looking at the social structuring of a market.
tures resolve the myriad forms of resource de- On the one hand, if actors trying to find a place

6.4 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

in a market can collectively produce equilib- whether a particular set of social structures
rium, then the goal of actors in this market protects incumbents or, rather, fosters eco-
becomes the preservation of that order. This nomic growth and competition.
implies relationships of power and domina- In this review, we discuss the intellectual
tion in markets. On the other hand, if firms are roots of the sociology of markets and how the
resigned to live in a world where reproducing field evolved from problems posed in nearby
one’s position is not possible, then social re- fields. We then examine the crystallization of
lationships become temporary arrangements the major ideas in the sociology of markets and
that allow one to get information or secure in doing so discuss what we know. Finally, we
cutting edge technology. Because change is consider what the real differences of opinion
ubiquitous, one chooses one’s friends for their are and suggest avenues for future research.
usefulness, and when that usefulness ends, one
moves on.
Finally, sociologists generally have a com- CONTEMPORARY ROOTS OF
plicated relationship to the problem of THE SOCIOLOGY OF MARKETS
whether a given set of social arrangements is Many good reviews have been written about
efficient. The fact that so many kinds of so- the intellectual history of the sociology of
cial relationships exist in markets has led to markets as a field (Biggart & Beamish 2003,
the argument that social relationships exist be- Fourcade-Gourinchas 2007, Krippner 2001,
tween market actors to solve market problems Lie 1997, Smelser & Swedberg 1994, Trigilia
such as agency costs (Fama & Jensen 1983) 2002). Our goal in this section is to put this
and transaction costs (Williamson 1985) and literature together in a different way. Rather
to promote trust between buyers and sell- than focusing on the roots of the sociology of
ers. Some sociologists seem prepared to ac- markets in classical theory, we focus on the
cept that social structures could be efficient contemporary fields of study that contributed
(Baker 1984, Uzzi 1996). From this point of to the intellectual ferment around the soci-
view, social structures in markets operate to ology of markets. In particular, we trace the
reduce information costs, give firms access to influence of nearby fields on the different per-
knowledge about what the competition is do- spectives in the sociology of markets.
ing, allow market actors to trust one another, New fields of social inquiry are built in re-
and reduce resource dependencies. These so- lation to other fields of social inquiry. When
cial structures provide firms with information scholars working within one field find them-
that allows them to learn and adapt and, in do- selves in a dialogue with scholars working
ing so, compete effectively. But other scholars on similar problems in other fields, some-
are agnostic on this question (Fligstein 1990, times a new field of inquiry is created. At
Podolny 1993). For them, social structures the outset, new fields involve scholars bor-
can operate to mitigate the effects of competi- rowing one another’s perspectives and look-
tion. In this view, firms try to control markets ing for mechanisms and models that might
by using their size, technology, and access to help explain new objects of inquiry. In this
governments to promote a status hierarchy of case, political economy, the sociology of la-
incumbents and challengers. Incumbent firms bor markets, and organizational theory pio-
use their advantages to signal to their princi- neered thinking about the sociology of mar-
pal competitors what they will do to defend kets, and the cross-pollination of ideas in these
the existing market order. For these scholars, fields formed the basic insights leading to
the social structure of markets exists to pro- the establishment of the sociology of mar-
duce this order. One way to make progress on kets as a field in its own right. Scholars in
this issue is to problematize efficiency. The all these fields doubted that economics could
sociology of markets gives us tools to decide sufficiently make sense of what happens in

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.5


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

markets. In essence, they discovered that the ological convergence of institutions toward
atomized, price-taking actors, with perfect Western models implied by the economic un-
and symmetrical information assumed by neo- derpinnings in much of modernization theory
classical theory, did not seem to exist empiri- led scholars to look into how the evolving in-
cally. Social relations seemed to be crucial to stitutions of capitalism (laws, regulations, and
the functioning of markets and market actors institutionalized practices) came to regulate
in a myriad of ways. Although all these sub- the relationships between firms, owners, gov-
fields began to criticize economics, they did ernments, and workers in ways that produced
so from different perspectives and for differ- fundamental differences in the market struc-
ent reasons, and the critiques internal to the tures of these societies.
logics of these fields were the first moves to- As development projects took off, first in
ward the creation of a contemporary sociology Japan and then later in Taiwan and Korea,
of markets. It is useful to understand these de- scholars delved into how local arrangements
bates in order to make sense of the different between governments, economic elites, and
theoretical voices in the sociology of markets. workers provided the conditions of economic
Political economy in the 1960s was domi- growth in both developed and less developed
nated by modernization theory. This perspec- societies (Amsden 1991; Aoki 1990; Dore
tive sought to explain how economically un- 1973, 1987, 1997; Evans 1995; Johnson 1982;
derdeveloped countries might develop along Wade 1990). Meanwhile, the study of com-
the lines of industrialized nations. Generally, parative capitalisms revealed that the rela-
studies in this vein focused on how similar tionships between these groups showed re-
cultural and structural features in develop- markable diversity and reflected very much
ing nations, characterized as traditional, could a historical, cultural, and national trajectory
be overcome with the emulation of institu- (Campbell et al. 1991, Campbell & Lindberg
tional models extant in developed countries to 1990, Fligstein & Choo 2005). This perspec-
promote economic growth (Eisenstadt 1973, tive suggested that governments, workers, and
Kerr 1960, Lerner & Riesman 1963, Rostow capitalists produced market structures that
1961). Critiques of modernization theory in were different across countries (Albert 1993,
political economy led researchers to new per- Berger & Dore 1996, Boyer & Drache 1996,
spectives on development and comparative Hall & Soskice 2001, Hollingsworth et al.
capitalisms. 1994). Markets were not given by outsiders,
Scholars in this field looked back to but instead reflected the social and politi-
Polanyi’s (1957) The Great Transformation for cal construction of each society, where the
inspiration (see Block & Evans 2005 for a re- history and culture surrounding class rela-
view of the literature on the links between tions and the various kinds of interventions by
states and markets). Polanyi argued not only governments produced unique institutional
that the creation of markets required states, orders.
but also that the formation of capitalist mar- Organizational theory, much of which was
kets would produce social chaos. In response, centered in business schools, was concerned
he suggested that governments would have with understanding how the managers of
to intervene in markets to stabilize them firms read the demands of their environ-
and to provide social protection for work- ments and adjust their organizational struc-
ers and rules to guide the interactions be- tures in line with those contingencies (Miles
tween groups of capitalists. The ways they 1980). Although managerial theory rejected
did this would necessarily be contingent and some of the tenets of economics (March et al.
implied that historical institutional variation 1958, Simon 1957), such as perfect informa-
could help explain cross-national variation in tion and perfect rationality, the purpose of
market structures. The rejection of the tele- the firm was still to adjust to the world of

6.6 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

competition, as economics implied. The cri- that sectors that join all interested parties look
tique of management theory’s focus on in- quite similar to the set of actors that po-
ternal organizational processes led organiza- litical economy focuses on, i.e., firms, gov-
tional theorists in two directions. ernments, and workers. DiMaggio & Powell
Hannan & Freeman (1977) argued that (1983) extended these arguments and called
scholars had paid too much attention to such environments “organizational fields,” a
adaptive processes in organizations. Instead, term that has caught on. The field metaphor
they studied the emergence of organizational implies that firms watch one another, engage
forms at the level of populations. They im- in strategic behavior vis-à-vis one another,
plied that market opportunity brought for- and look to one another for clues as to what
ward the birth of firms. But the character of constitutes successful behavior. DiMaggio &
the market, i.e., the resources that could be Powell’s main focus was how firms in organi-
exploited by firms, would determine which zational fields came to resemble one another
forms of organization would survive. The through processes of mimetic, coercive, and
main problem that competition created for normative isomorphism.
firms, from Hannan & Freeman’s perspective, In 1981, White produced a sociological
was resource dependence (Pfeffer & Salancik view of what he thought firms do in markets.
1978). Many firms could not get the resources His central argument was that firms in pro-
they needed to survive, and this led to high duction markets position their organizations
rates of failure at the beginning of market vis-à-vis one another. Using the price and rel-
opening projects. Despite population ecol- ative quality of their product, they signal to
ogy’s focus on competition, scholars in this each other what kind of producer they want to
field realized that the formation of market be. This signaling produces what White called
boundaries was a social process and that the a market that he defined as a reproducible
formation of niches often reflected the ability role structure. White’s view combines some
of firms to segregate their markets (Carroll insights from economics about how price can
1985, Hannan & Freeman 1988). Firms de- be used as a signal (Spence 1974) with the or-
pend on legitimacy, and external shocks to a ganizational sociology focus on the construc-
niche, such as the introduction of a law, can tion of fields or niches.
have a profound effect on the dynamics of a While organizational scholars examined
niche (Ranger-Moore et al. 1991, Ingram & social processes structuring the relationships
Rao 2004, Haveman & Rao 1997). Recently, between organizations, scholars in stratifica-
ecologists have begun to focus on how firms tion and labor markets looked anew at the role
form identities and how these identities form of firms in resource distribution. During the
markets (Carroll & Swaminathan 2000). 1960s and 1970s, the main approach sociol-
While population ecology viewed the en- ogists used to examine labor markets was the
vironment of the firm as “hard,” and thus the status attainment model. This view focused on
main mechanism of selection was the avail- how individuals were sorted into a relatively
ability of the scarcest resource, institutional fixed set of positions according to their per-
theory posited that the environment was at sonal characteristics, such as family origins,
least partially a social construction. Scott & education, gender, and race (Blau & Duncan
Meyer (1982) called such environments “sec- 1967, Hauser & Featherman 1977). Because
tors” and described the socially constructed the status attainment model views the linkages
environment of firms as a function of all the between individuals and their socioeconomic
other organizations that might impinge on a outcomes as mainly a function of their per-
particular organization. They included gov- sonal characteristics, the problem of the de-
ernments, suppliers, workers, and customers mand for labor, and thus the role of the firm,
as part of such a social construction. We note was outside its purview.

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.7


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

During the 1970s, scholars became in- What began next was an exploration of
terested in two other questions: How does product and labor markets. Scholars studied
the structure of jobs affect individual mo- concrete cases and attempted to apply these
bility patterns and what is the actual pro- tools to account for what had emerged. The
cess through which people are matched to sociology of markets has been used to ex-
jobs? Sociologists answered these questions plain many aspects of markets. Some schol-
by considering the role of firms in the hir- ars have demonstrated how the social re-
ing process and social relationships in the lationships in markets produce more stable
matching process. The new structuralism prices (Baker 1984; Uzzi 1997, 2004). Oth-
modeled how firms affect the distribution of ers have focused on how the social structur-
rewards (Baron & Bielby 1980, Hodson 1983, ing of markets has affected the birth and death
Kalleberg & Griffin 1980). White’s (1970) of small firms (Stuart et al. 1999, Stuart &
Chains of Opportunity elaborated how vacancy Sorenson 2003). Still others have observed the
chains of jobs helped produce the distribu- innovation and spread of new market strate-
tion of workers and rewards. Granovetter’s gies such as new products, financial inno-
(1974) Getting a Job took on the question of vations, or changes in organizations such as
how people got matched to jobs. He intro- the diversification of products, geographic ex-
duced the idea that social networks mediate pansion, and vertical integration, as well as
the links between employers and employees. changes in which subunit controls the firm
Both White and Granovetter championed (Ahmadjian & Robinson 2001; Beckman et al.
network analysis as a way to understand 2002; Davis 1991; Davis et al. 1994; Fiss
the social structure linking employers and & Zajac 2004; Fligstein 1985, 1991; Gulati
employees. & Westphal 1999; Haunschild 1993; Hirsch
1986; Ocasio & Kim 1999; Westphal & Zajac
1998; Zorn 2004; Zuckerman 1999, 2000).
AGREEMENTS IN THE The exploration of all possible link-
SOCIOLOGY OF MARKETS ages between firms, suppliers, customers,
At the core of the sociology of markets is the governments, and workers pushed scholars
attempt to insert sociologists into the study to postulate a plethora of mechanisms for
of the economic realm by bringing social the- embeddedness. The literature groped with
ory and the way social life works in general trying to generalize these cases and began to
into firms, markets, and industries. As our re- elaborate different ways of thinking about the
view suggests, the theoretical pieces for the problem of the social embeddedness of mar-
construction of the sociology of markets were kets. Krippner (2001) has argued that the term
in place by 1983. Firms, the social structures embeddedness has become vaguely defined.
that defined their relationships to competi- We argue that this was the case from the very
tors, and the social structures that linked them beginning. Scholars who were coming at the
to suppliers, customers, workers, and govern- problem from very different points of view
ments were already theorized to exist and to examined different ways in which economic
vary across markets, historical time periods, transactions were socially structured.
and countries. Granovetter’s declaration that The variety of approaches has made pro-
economic life was always embedded in social viding a sociological definition for markets
life has proven to be the intellectual frame that difficult. For neoclassical theory, markets
justified opening a floodgate of research and simply imply exchange between actors for
brought a massive set of scholars armed with goods or services. These exchanges are usu-
sociological ideas into studying market activ- ally thought to be fleeting, with price (i.e.,
ity and, even more importantly, engaging one the amount of a commodity that is exchanged
another in discourse. for another using a generalized medium of

6.8 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

exchange, i.e., money) determined by the sup- repeated exchanges occur between buyers and
ply and demand for the commodity. From the sellers under a set of formal and informal
point of view of the sociology of markets, the rules governing relations between competi-
problem is that this type of exchange already tors, suppliers, and customers.4 These fields
shows a great deal of social structure. Mar- operate according to local understandings and
ket actors have to find one another. Money formal and informal rules and conventions
has to exist to allow market actors to get be- that guide interaction, facilitate trade, define
yond bartering nonequivalent goods. Actors what products are produced, indeed are con-
have to know what the price is. Underlying stitutive of products, and provide stability for
all exchange is that both buyers and sellers buyers, sellers, and producers. These market-
have faith that they will not be cheated. Such places are dependent on governments, laws,
faith often implies informal (i.e., personal and larger cultural understandings support-
knowledge of the buyer or seller) and formal ing market activity. The first thing a sociol-
mechanisms (i.e., law) that govern exchange. ogy of markets suggests is that market actors
Furthermore, market actors are often organi- will develop social structures to mediate the
zations, implying that organizational dynam- problems they encounter in exchange, com-
ics influence market structures. For sociolo- petition, and production. We discuss each of
gists, market exchange implies a whole back- these in turn and delineate the primary contri-
drop of social arrangements that economics butions of each perspective with regard to how
does not even begin to hint at. market actors solve these problems and, in do-
But the sociology of markets goes further ing so, construct and navigate their worlds.
than just questioning the institutional embed- Many aspects of exchange relationships
dedness of an anonymous market. It is pre- in markets have been examined by sociolo-
pared to unpack the black boxes of exchange, gists. Institutional theory suggests not only
competition, and production. Sociologists be- that contractual market exchange depends
gin by realizing that market actors are in- on the rule setting and sanction enforce-
volved in day-to-day social relationships with ment of states, but also that states may de-
one another, relationships based on trust, fine what types of products are appropriate
friendship, power, and dependence. For the for exchange. Furthermore, the internal struc-
modern sociology of markets (Durkheim ture of the state as rule setter and regulator
1964)3 , unstructured, haphazard, one-shot, can influence the types of products states al-
anonymous social exchange is not a market. low to be exchanged and the rules support-
Instead, markets imply social spaces where ing and surrounding exchange (Caruthers &
Halliday 1998, Delaney 1992, Schneiberg &
Soule 2005). Buyers and sellers also are gener-
3
Ironically, scholars of the sociology of markets almost ally known to one another and in many cases
never cite Durkheim. But a good case can be made that are involved in repeated exchange. Network
almost all of the important ideas in the sociology of mar-
kets have Durkheimian roots. Durkheim recognized the theorists have emphasized the role that so-
pivotal role of the state and law in capitalist exchange, pre- cial networks play in generating trust between
figuring the political economy concern with these issues. buyers and sellers that makes exchange possi-
He also recognized that there was a noncontractual basis
to contract that implied that personal relationships were ble (Granovetter 1985). Cultural sociologists
necessary for people to honor contracts. Finally, in the di- have looked at how specific exchange relations
vision of labor the major mechanism that drove modern
society was competition. Durkheim’s argument was that
people divided up tasks to lessen their competition with
4
other people. This mechanism is arguably at the core of Of course, some of the identities of the buyers and sellers
the population ecology view that market niches become change over time. In addition, more peripheral buyers and
partitioned by competition and White’s arguments about sellers come into the market, leave, and do not return. But
how firms avoid competition by signaling which part of the the core players in the market, the largest producers and
market they will produce for. consumers, create a social structure.

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.9


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

are deeply constructed by the cultural mean- also be a way to coopt such dependence. Burt
ings behind the products being bought and (1980a) demonstrates how American corpo-
sold (Zelizer 1983). Finally, sociologists gen- rations use board membership strategically to
erally believe that power influences social re- bring on representatives of firms upon whom
lations and, thus, market relations (Pfeffer & a particular firm is dependent for resources.
Salancik 1978). Relationships of exchange can Stuart et al. (1999) demonstrate that getting
be deeply influenced by the relative power of money from the right venture capitalists af-
the actors over the supply and demand of what fects the probability that a particular firm sur-
is being exchanged and by their relative de- vives. They interpret such connections as not
pendence on what is being exchanged. This just about securing funding but also about
conception of power in markets is generally conferring legitimacy upon a particular start-
referred to as resource dependence and has up firm and thereby allowing it to be more able
been described and employed in a variety of to secure workers and customers. In essence,
ways by many sociologists. one purpose of the ties between suppliers and
Resource dependence is a general con- customers is to control resource dependence
struct used in the sociology of markets. The and enhance the probability of a firm sur-
idea begins with the premise that in any social viving. Here, network theorists are rooted in
exchange, one side of the exchange may be the more general camp of both population
more dependent on what is being exchanged ecology and institutional theory by worrying
than the other (Emerson 1962). If one party about how resource dependence affects the le-
to the exchange was much more dependent gitimacy and survival of firms.
than the other, that party was either more Network theorists and experimental social
likely to have to obey the dictates of the sup- psychologists posit one additional mechanism
plier/customer or else face extinction.5 This that links buyers and sellers: trust (Cheshire &
idea has great generality when it comes to Cook 2004; Granovetter 1985, 2005; Kollock
examining exchange. So, for example, firms 1994, 1999; Uzzi 1996; Yamigushi & Cook
must obtain finance, secure inputs for their 1993). Granovetter’s main argument about
products and labor, and establish relationships embeddedness is that if one has close ties to
to their competitors, governments, and cus- others over long periods of time, one can trust
tomers. The empirical literature has shown that in any particular transaction, people are
that who might have the power in these rela- less likely to try to cheat one another. The
tionships varies on the basis of the nature of experimental literature has shown that trust
the resource dependency and the particular matters most in situations in which there is a
market being studied. great deal of uncertainty about the qualities
Although many scholars who have stud- of the product being exchanged (Cheshire &
ied exchange interactions have focused on us- Cook 2004, Kollock 1994). Kollock (1999) has
ing network methods, they frequently posit examined how reputation works as a way to in-
mechanisms that involve resource depen- crease trust between actors. Although trust is
dence. For example, Lincoln et al. (1996) show not a major mechanism in either population
how the ownership linkages between Japanese ecology or institutional theory, it does connect
firms affect the ability of the owner firms to back to those theories. Judging the trustwor-
dictate actions to their subsidiaries. Forming thiness of another actor is not just a matter
relationships to one’s principal suppliers can of having a long-term network tie to them.
Trust is also about power and resource de-
pendence. Firms work to reduce uncertainty
5
Note that in neoclassical economics, exchange is assumed and resource dependence by choosing part-
to be equal. If buyers and sellers have perfect information
about prices, then buyers will not pay more than they need ners who they either know to be reliable or
to and sellers cannot ask more. others think are reliable.

6.10 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

Scholars interested in culture and con- ferentiation of products is one of the main
sumption have also focused on exchange mechanisms firms have to control competi-
in markets. The sociology of consump- tion. This works in two ways. If firms can
tion (Bourdieu 1984; Csikszentmihalyi & choose in which part of the market they want
Rochberg-Halton 1981; Slater 1997; Zelizer to compete, then they can go where their
1983, 1994, 1997; for review papers see competitors are not. Carroll (1985), calling
Zelizer 2005, Zukin & Smith Maguire 2004) this process niche partitioning, showed that
focuses on what products mean for people and microbreweries were able to create a fast
how people use money and markets to estab- growing niche for themselves even as the
lish meaning, status, and morality. For these largest brewing companies were steadily in-
scholars, culture is deeply implicated in mar- creasing their hold over the brewing industry
ket exchange. Products are cultural objects (Carroll & Swaminathan 2000). White (1981)
imbued with meaning based on shared under- has made a similar argument. Markets for him
standings and are themselves symbols or rep- are reproducible role structures where firms
resentations of these meanings. Consumption decide between the prices they want to charge
reproduces the material lives of consumers for a good and the quality of that good they
and provides them means to express their produce. In making this decision, they decide
identities and affiliations with status groups. which part of the market to be in.
But most importantly for these scholars, the Leifer & White (1987) demonstrated how
meanings attached to products that are nego- this works for the frozen pizza market. White
tiated by consumers and producers shape the (2002) later identified this mechanism as a way
interpersonal relations of embedded market to produce entirely new markets. If products
exchange and, in turn, are shaped by them. become differentiated enough, then they are
Although exchange characterizes the re- no longer competing. White’s perspective can
lation between buyer and seller in mar- easily be translated into the language of pop-
kets, competition characterizes the relation ulation ecology. White is arguing that mar-
between producers.6 Sociologists posit that kets would be differentiated by firms occupy-
competitive markets confront producers as ing different positions in the niche, and, to
problems to be solved, and they do so using the degree that firms were in fact not com-
strategies of cooperation, combination, and peting, this could result in niche partitioning
product differentiation. The degrees to which or, in White’s language, the creation of new
a market is competitive, to which producers markets.
are allowed to cooperate, and to which pro- The differentiation of products can also
ducers are allowed to combine, as well as how help the stability of the firm through spread-
property rights are organized, are all regu- ing competitive pressures across multiple
lated by the government. Although producers product markets. If firms decide to produce
attempt to use a variety of strategies to con- multiple products, a downturn in a particular
trol competition, government defines accept- market will not threaten the firm’s existence
able modes of relation between producers and because it is not totally resource dependent
regulates competition through reacting to the on the exchange of one product. Population
strategies firms employ. ecology noted this process, describing the
Population ecology, network theory, and diversification tactic as a generalist strategy
institutional theory all recognize that the dif- (Hannan & Freeman 1977). Fligstein (1990)
comes at this process from the point of view
of institutional theory. He shows that prod-
6
Relationships to competitors can be characterized in terms uct differentiation in U.S. corporations be-
of resource dependence as well. In White’s model, when
firms signal their intentions to enter a different part of the gan as a marketing strategy in the 1920s that
market, they are trying to control their interdependency. was pioneered by large firms to stabilize their

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.11


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

overall structure. During the Great Depres- how the insurance industry in the nineteenth
sion of the 1930s, the largest corporations century expanded and contracted as regula-
produced as many different kinds of products tors shifted their roles over time. Haveman
as they could to continue to exist in such dis- & Rao (1997) demonstrate similar processes
mal business conditions. operating in the savings and loan industries.
In addition to product differentiation, pro- Fligstein (1990) presents evidence that the
ducers often seek to cooperate and to combine U.S. government played a major role in pre-
with one another to reduce competitive pres- venting the cartelization and monopoliza-
sure. In the old industrial organization litera- tion of American business at the end of the
ture in economics, a small number of firms nineteenth century by using antitrust laws.
dominating a market act to reduce compe- He also demonstrates that the federal gov-
tition in that market. Challenger firms can- ernment played a role in closing down the
not undercut the prices of their larger core 1960s merger movement by aggressively pur-
brethren because the large firms can outlast suing conglomerate mergers. Dobbin (1994)
any competitor in a price war. Podolny (1993), shows how government policies toward rail-
a network theorist, terms this kind of struc- roads early on affected their organization in
ture a status hierarchy. He studies how in- different countries. Dobbin & Dowd (2000)
vestment banks form such a hierarchy that is have documented how government played
primarily held in place by the large size and an important role in railroads in the United
prestige of the biggest banks. These banks States. Campbell & Lindberg (1990) argue
get the largest deals, and they reproduce their that property rights are at the heart of the
place in that structure by being able to under- relationships between governments and firms
cut their competitors if necessary. Fligstein (for a review of the sociological literature on
(1996), in a more institutionalist vein, calls property rights, see Carruthers & Ariovich
this an incumbent-challenger structure. He 2004).
argues that such structures get reproduced as The sociological view of relations among
incumbents use their market power to sus- producers begs the question of who these pro-
tain their advantage in a given market over ducers are and how they make production de-
time. cisions. From the point of view of neoclassical
Although producers may attempt to exert economics, whether producers are individuals
market power through the creation of hier- or organizations matters little; what is impor-
archies, this strategy has its limits. Govern- tant is the production function and the com-
ments regulate competition (Ranger-Moore bination of capital and labor used in the pro-
et al. 1991, Dobbin & Dowd 2000, Fligstein ductive process (Shepard 1970). Conversely,
1990, Haveman & Rao 1997, Ingram & Rao sociologists have long examined organizations
2004, Ingram et al. 2005), in turn affecting as social structures. Some take the unitary or-
the opportunities for firms to expand and ganization of the firm as a starting point, but
survive. The role of government and law most agree that organizations have complex
in the production of markets has been ac- internal dynamics that are important for or-
knowledged by the population ecology, insti- ganizational form and for the strategies they
tutionalist, and, of course, political economy use to solve the problems of competition and
camps. These theory groups understand that exchange. They have pointed to competition
governments can both open up opportuni- within the firm, culture, and power struggles,
ties and set up constraints for markets. For in addition to environmental influence, as im-
example, Hannan & Freeman (1987) show portant to understanding a firm’s strategy and
how the legalization of union activities af- thus the structure of markets (Fligstein 1990,
fected the founding and survival of those or- Ocasio & Kim 1999, Pfeffer 1981, Pfeffer &
ganizations. Ranger-Moore et al. (1991) show Salancik 1978).

6.12 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

The study of the internal dynamics of firms ics and interorganizational competition and
and how firms relate to their environments exchange.
is rooted in organization theory. Although Probably the most studied mechanism
much of the empirical work in the sociol- theorized to pass strategies and structures
ogy of markets treats firms as unitary, soci- from one firm to another is the board inter-
ologists are generally committed, at least the- lock (Mizruchi 1996). Board interlocks influ-
oretically, to viewing the internal dynamics of ence the spread of different kinds of struc-
the firm as important (Bourdieu 2005). The tural and strategic innovations (Burt 1980b,
two key aspects of firms with which organiza- Davis 1991, Gulati & Westphal 1999, Rao
tional scholars have been most concerned are & Sivakumar 1999). Sociologists tend to see
strategy and structure (Miles & Snow 1978). board interlocks as mechanisms for coopting
The design of the organization is its structure. various kinds of resource dependencies, for
This includes lines of authority and the for- generating trust, sharing information, medi-
mal and informal relationships between posi- ating competition, and forming political al-
tions in the firm. Meanwhile, strategy refers liances (here, one can make the link back to
to the means the organization employs to political economy).
achieve its goals. The central questions sur- The social structuring of markets is gener-
rounding these aspects of organizations have ally in response to the problems of competi-
been where they come from and how they are tion and exchange. The sociology of markets
related to market structures. does not posit that these problems will always
Although economistic explanations for be solved. But it does imply that where stable
various strategies and structures generally markets emerge, such structures will appear as
center on transaction costs, agency costs, or firms figure out how to resolve their problems.
aspects of the technology the firm uses in By establishing social relationships not just
production (Chandler 1962, Fama & Jensen with competitors, but also with customers,
1983, Williamson 1985), sociologists have suppliers, and employees, firms can establish
emphasized the contingent nature of the goals trust and guarantee access to scarce resources.
of the firm and how culture and managers’ By responding to directives from the govern-
backgrounds influence the firm’s strategy and ment and trying to coopt government agen-
structure. This emphasis makes the existing cies, firms can also secure their futures. All
divisions within the firm and the career paths these social mechanisms make it possible for
of managers important. The way the firm di- firms to juggle their resource dependencies
vides up functions, how the firm promotes and survive. One can conclude that despite
from within, and political struggle determine the varying theoretical perspectives and dif-
who manages the firm and thus the perspec- fering language and data analysis techniques,
tive that will dominate firm strategy. For ex- the empirical literature on the sociology of
ample, Fligstein (1990) has emphasized how markets converges on a few main mechanisms
the rise to prominence of managers with sales by which the social structuring of markets may
and marketing or finance backgrounds pre- be understood. The right way to think about
ceded the adoption of multidivisional struc- these mechanisms is that they form a tool
tures and strategies of product diversifi- box that might plausibly be used to analyze
cation. Processes of managerial succession, a particular market. One of the great dangers
the distribution of resources, and promo- in the literature is that scholars frequently fo-
tion are subject to internal competition. Per- cus on their favorite mechanism at the expense
haps the most promising aspect of the soci- of other possible ways to understand what is
ology of markets is the potential to theorize going on in the market of interest. We discuss
as well as empirically examine the con- how to solve this problem at the end of this
nections between intraorganizational dynam- review.

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.13


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

DIVERGENT ARGUMENTS and trust, something in which Callon seems


uninterested. But, given that scholars have
The real controversies in the sociology of
been interested in the coevolution of indus-
markets are those that do not turn on the dif-
try technologies and organizational forms,
fering use of terms to describe similar con-
Callon’s focus on how actors creating tech-
cepts or the fact that scholars in some theory
nology produce new markets seems less to
group ignore the ideas of the others. One of
contradict production-oriented models than
the most important critiques of the general
to complement them. Linking the process of
perspectives outlined above has come from
discovery and implementation of technology
the performativist school of thought. Per-
in new markets to the problems of resource
formativists have criticized the extant socio-
dependence, competition, exchange, and le-
logical work on markets for neglecting how
gitimacy will likely be a fruitful avenue of
markets are structured by the interaction of
research.
economic activity with scientific discovery and
One aspect that undermines Callon’s argu-
the creation of new technology. From this per-
ment is that new markets are often founded for
spective, Callon (2002) has argued that the
one purpose yet ultimately serve an entirely
sociology of markets has been worried too
different purpose. For example, the telephone
much about critiquing the neoclassical view
was thought to be useful only for business, and
that markets are anonymous, one-shot ex-
early on telephone companies discouraged ca-
changes and not worried enough about the
sual use of the phone (Fischer 1992). But once
role of economists (and others) in the creation
consumers discovered the phone as a way to
of cultural tools that actually enact the mar-
keep in touch with each other, phone com-
ket in fields like finance (Guala 2001; Knorr
panies were driven to expand their services
Cetina & Bruegger 2002; MacKenzie & Milo
dramatically. These more accidental discov-
2003; MacKenzie 2004, 2005). To demon-
eries of uses for technology imply less agency
strate this point, scholars have studied the di-
and intention and more processes of discovery
alectic between financial theories and the im-
about what things are good for.
plementation of new financial products and
A second arena of disagreement concerns
how the growth of these markets reflects the
the fact that studies focus either on competi-
ways those theories are used and applied.
tors or on suppliers and customers. Many
This perspective introduces a kind of cul-
studies in the sociology of markets focus on
tural dynamism into market processes and
communities of producers. These producer-
heightens the role of technological innova-
focused studies often only present consumers
tion. Actors in current markets invent new
to the degree that the machinations of firms
products in a self-aware fashion, and this
eventually produce a stable social structure
works to transform existing markets. Here,
that effectively mitigates competition or re-
we think that fruitful dialogue could occur.
duces the resource dependence of competi-
Despite Callon’s assertion to the contrary,
tor firms (see Zelizer 2005 for an extended
scholars using population ecology, institu-
version of this critique). When scholars fo-
tional theory, and network theory have been
cus on suppliers and customers, their discus-
interested in the linkage between the new cul-
sions focus on different relationships. Most
tural forms of products and the deployment
frequently, these relationships are thought to
of firm resources (for example, Carroll &
be about trust indexed through direct network
Swandinathan 2000, Granovetter & McGuire
ties that reflect ongoing social relationships
1998, Haveman & Rao 1997, Lounsbury &
between buyers and sellers (Baker et al. 1998;
Rao 2004, Powell et al. 2005). Of course,
Uzzi 1996, 1997).
much of the research has focused more on
None of these perspectives captures what
questions of legitimacy, resource dependence,
goes on in big consumer markets in which the

6.14 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

buyers are individuals and their preferences sumers. These interventions appear to have
are expressed in more roundabout ways. been as important in generating trust (be-
Scholars most interested in the cultural con- tween firms and customers) as the problem
struction of products have criticized the fo- of the morality of the market (Heimer 1985).
cus in the sociology of markets on production. A fruitful dialogue is needed between those
To some degree, the use of products to make who favor a more cultural approach to con-
moral judgments or claim social status can sumers that focuses on the moral and social
be analytically separated from the problem of uses of products and those who favor an ap-
producing a stable product market. After all, proach that stresses solving the problems of
how people use automobiles and what they competition for producers. Such a dialogue
mean to them and others may not affect which would allow us to understand if these views
firms survive at the high or low end of the mar- are contradictory or complementary. Consid-
ket or how many firms there are and how they ering all sides of the problem would help us
are organized. Still, this disjuncture between get a clearer picture as to how the produc-
producers and consumers is one of the inter- tion and legitimation of new products and the
esting frontiers in the sociology of markets. structuring of stable markets are related.
Zelizer argues that the focus on production The question of the dynamics of mar-
misses the fact that consumers have to become kets leads to a more general disagreement
convinced about the value and legitimacy of in the literature surrounding stability and
products (Zelizer 1983, 1994, 1997). She ar- change. Population ecology, institutional the-
gues that moral issues abound in the creation ory, and some versions of network theory (i.e.,
of new markets. The life insurance industry, White) have an explicit argument that market-
for example, had to overcome the obvious opening projects are going to be very differ-
moral ambiguity of people buying insurance ent than market-stabilizing projects. For pop-
that put a price on their deaths. Moreover, ulation ecology, the liability of newness and
firms were put in the position of gambling on smallness are particularly acute at the forma-
other people’s deaths. Many people resisted tion of new markets. In these moments, firms
buying life insurance because of these ghoul- either do not know what their key resource
ish qualities. Only when consumers became dependencies are or are not reliably able to
convinced through marketing efforts that life deliver products that people want. Thus, they
insurance was a way to provide for one’s loved are more vulnerable to competition. Once
ones after death did the market take off. A markets have settled, existing firms can re-
production-focused sociology of markets fails main stable incumbent players for long peri-
to consider consumers and consumer market- ods. Such firms continuously face challengers,
ing and, in so doing, misses an important as- but these moments are qualitatively differ-
pect of where markets come from. ent from market formation moments. Institu-
The life insurance industry presents an tional theory (Fligstein 1996) also posits that
empirical puzzle that allows scholars to ex- producing a market as a field is a social and
plore the relative role of consumers, govern- political project that begins without stable re-
ments, and firms in the production of a new lationships. White’s basic argument is that if
product. The industry’s problems were not firms cannot find a reproducible role struc-
just to convince people to buy insurance. At ture, stable markets will not emerge and firms
the beginning of the market, firms frequently will go out of business.
sold policies at too low a price to make money. There are several alternative views of these
When people came to collect, many of the processes. Inspired by Nelson & Winter’s
smaller firms went bankrupt and their owners (1982) view of population ecology, many
disappeared. Eventually, government regula- scholars have argued that some industries
tion became more extensive to protect con- are in a constant state of flux. Firms must

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.15


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

be nimble, change technologies, and inno- for example, in the population ecology view,
vate or risk dying (Powell et al. 2005, Stark organizations’ resource dependencies dictate
& Vedrez 2006). Some scholars have argued that organizations that do not fit their en-
that network organizations produce continu- vironments will perish. Hannan & Freeman
ous transformation and that modern markets (1977), of course, construct a general argu-
are so dynamic that they rarely settle into any- ment about all forms of organization. They
thing like equilibrium for very long (Stark & assume that whatever resource dependence
Vedrez 2006). The performativity perspective characterizes the niche (and here they include
also seems to be compatible with this view. nonprofit organizations and states) will oper-
To resolve such arguments, scholars need ate to select winners and losers. If the niche
to be clearer about how they might measure is a market, then one can infer that the popu-
and interpret stability or equilibrium. Put an- lation ecology argument seems hard to sepa-
other way, when is a change in a market a rate from the economic view propounded by
change? The general view of a market as a Milton Friedman (1957), which suggests that
niche, role, status, or hierarchical structure market forces determine efficiency and hence
of incumbents and challengers implies that a winners and losers. What separates popula-
market change would involve a change in the tion ecology from economics is that the price
identities and positions of the main actors. It mechanism is only one potential source of re-
would also involve a change in the underly- source dependence.
ing definition of the market (i.e., its princi- Many of our studies of the social structur-
pal activities, ways of organizing, etc.). But ing of markets end up arguing that the so-
this definition of change has several problems. cial relationships underlying markets have ef-
First, shifts in the identities of either chal- ficiency effects. If firms have the right social
lenger or incumbent firms occur all the time. connections, they can solve their resource de-
One would not want to be left arguing that pendence problems and reproduce themselves
any such changes deinstitutionalize the mar- (Baker et al. 1998, Stuart et al. 1999, Stuart
ket. Second, changes in products and produc- & Sorenson 2003, Uzzi 1997). But some au-
tion also evolve over time (often in piecemeal thors also recognize that while social relation-
forms). Here, again, one is left wondering ships might produce stable outcomes for par-
at which point such changes represent un- ticipants, they might also actually undermine
derlying transformations of existing markets. market efficiency (Podolny 2001). Long-term
Many of the disagreements about stability and social relationships not only produce trust,
change in the literature rest on how one thinks but also allow for cartels and price stabil-
about exactly what a change is. ity and in some cases make firms more vul-
Finally, one of the problems that haunts nerable because their suppliers can take ad-
all the discussions in the sociology of markets vantage of them by charging higher prices.
is the problem of efficiency. The economic Granovetter (1985) is ambivalent about this,
idea of efficiency is that scarce resources be- appearing sometimes to view social networks
come allocated so as to maximize their returns. as ways for people to solve their problems
Neoclassical economic theory assumes that of trust and therefore produce efficient out-
there is only one way for such an allocation comes and other times to view these networks
to occur when a market is in equilibrium, and as possible mechanisms for rent seeking (and
that constant updating of information means even illegal behavior). In his more recent re-
that firms are always shifting their activities view of the literature on business groups, for
to maintain efficiency. The sociology of mar- example, he appears to portray these groups
kets has an ambiguous relationship to this as- as efficiency generating (Granovetter 1994).
sertion that extends from basically accepting The political economy literature has also
economic logic to basically denying it. So, displayed this ambivalence. Scholars who have

6.16 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

documented that different national systems of ory is to worry less about efficiency and more
capitalism exist swing between viewing those about organizational effectiveness. Organiza-
systems as protectionist and viewing them tional theory realized long ago that organiza-
as efficient. So, for example, a whole series tions’ survival could come from many sources
of books have begun with the premise that (Thompson 1967): exploiting resource-rich
the differences between national capitalist sys- environments, defending themselves from
tems are about to disappear because the spread competitors, or coopting their resource de-
of global capitalism is forcing firms to se- pendencies. Thus, solving the problem of class
lect the most efficient forms of organizations struggle, obtaining finance, and getting state
(Berger & Dore 1996). The assumption is that intervention to enforce solutions to cutthroat
the various national models must be hiding competition are all tactics we should expect
inefficiencies that protect workers and that firms to use to survive. The efficient alloca-
the world market will simply force them to tion of internal resources from this point of
change. Then, these books document that in view is only one tactic.
fact Japanese, Korean, German, and French The problem with this perspective (even
capitalisms appear to be resilient. They fre- though it helps fill out our view of relevant
quently conclude that these national models firm behavior!) is that we know that mar-
must each be efficient in some way and that kets rise and fall, come and go, and that the
in the face of international competition, firms firms that exist today may disappear tomor-
adapt to new circumstances without chang- row. Sociologists do not want to say that firms
ing their ways completely. Hall & Soskice in markets do not worry about prices, costs,
(2001) argue that the national systems must and pleasing customers but care only about
have some efficiency properties as well as the controlling their resource dependencies or
ability to adapt to internationally changed cir- getting the government to intervene to pro-
cumstances most forcefully. The debate over tect their market shares. One way out of this
the role of states, law, and class struggle in de- dilemma is to realize that sometimes social
velopment projects suggests how difficult it is structures can promote efficiencies, and other
to understand market efficiency. times they can be used to protect incumbents.
Some scholars are even more skeptical One of the goals of economic sociology should
about the efficiency of social relationships. be to use our tools to understand how this
Fligstein (1990) views the emergence of the works in particular markets. This is akin to
large corporation in the United States at the the task of the old industrial economics that
turn of the twentieth century as principally a sought a way to identify when market struc-
function of the attempt to control competition tures were the result of efficient processes or
within particular industries, thereby deny- attempts to control markets.
ing the efficiency interpretations of Chandler Competition in new markets is likely to be
(1977) and Williamson (1985). Dobbin (1994) different from competition in stable markets.
views the different ways in which state-firm Firms in both cases will try to do what they can
relationships shaped the railroad industries to survive. In new markets, firms have many
as a reflection more of differences in culture resource dependencies that make survival dif-
and politics than of differences in efficiency. ficult. But even here, they can use their so-
The literature on comparative capitalisms fre- cial relationships with larger corporate enti-
quently demonstrates that the main factors ties, suppliers, customers, and governments
that effect firms’ organization in a nation-state to build coalitions that can produce stabil-
concern history, culture, class struggle, and ity. Relations with competitors can evolve as
the role of the state (Roe 2003). firms realize which part of the market they
One interpretation that comes from both want to be in and as the market segments be-
organizational theory and institutional the- come defined. In stable markets, incumbents

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.17


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

have more tools to fight off competitors by has been detrimental to the focused growth
either undercutting their prices, using vari- of the field. There are many points of agree-
ous tools to resist competitors’ entry into the ment in the sociology of markets, and we have
market, or coopting competitors by copying attempted to draw them out.
them or buying them out. Markets are always If people are convinced by our argument,
rising and falling, which means that attempts this implies two proscriptions for subsequent
to control are always potentially under assault. research. Scholars should seek out and explore
So, for example, the U.S. automobile industry the differences in terminology between their
was stable from roughly the mid-1930s until perspectives and other perspectives to decide
the 1970s (and even into the 1990s). The main the relevance of those differences to making
U.S. participants in that market are firms that sense of empirical cases. Scholars should also
now are approaching 100 years old. But, chal- be open to the possibility that the mechanisms
lenges to that industry exist today, and noth- that other scholars propose are relevant to
ing guarantees that the main U.S. producers their particular case. An exemplar of this kind
will either survive or maintain their separate of research is MacKenzie’s (2005) recent book
corporate existence. in which he carefully parses out the role of pol-
itics, markets, institutions, and economics in
understanding the emergence of modern fi-
CONCLUSION nancial markets. This does not mean that all
The sociology of markets is now a mature field mechanisms are operative in all cases. Instead,
of study. Scholars have developed a set of con- this kind of careful consideration is likely to
cepts to describe and understand how social lead to a better understanding of the scope of
relationships structure all forms of markets. various authors’ perspectives. If scholars en-
Along with the many fascinating questions re- gage in this kind of honest discussion, the field
maining to be explored, a cacophony of voices is also more likely to understand better what
espousing different strategies and perspec- its real disagreements are and make progress
tives still exist with which to explore them. on those issues. We hope our review helps
We have argued that in many respects schol- contribute to the intellectual ferment and en-
ars have talked past one another and that this courages continued research and debate.

LITERATURE CITED
Ahmadjian CL, Robinson P. 2001. Safety in numbers: downsizing and the deinstitutionalization
of permanent employment in Japan. Admin. Sci. Q. 46:622–54
Albert M. 1993. Capitalism Against Capitalism. London: Whurr
Amsden AH. 1991. Diffusion of development: the late-industrializing model and greater East
Asia. Am. Econ. Rev. 81:282–86
Aoki M. 1990. Information, Incentives and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge Univ. Press
Baker WE. 1984. The social structure of a national securities market. Am. J. Sociol. 89:775–811
Baker WE, Robert R, Faulkner, Gene A. Fisher. 1998. Hazards of the market: the continuity
and dissolution of interorganizational market relationships. Am. Sociol. Rev. 63:147–77
Baron JN, Bielby WT. 1980. Bringing the firms back in: stratification, segmentation, and the
organization of work. Am. Sociol. Rev. 45:737–65
Baron JN, Hannan MT, Burton MD. 1999. Building the iron cage: determinants of managerial
intensity in the early years of organizations. Am. Sociol. Rev. 64:527–47
Beckman C, Pamela R, Haunschild. 2002. Network learning: the effects of partners’ hetero-
geneity of experience on corporate acquisitions. Admin. Sci. Q. 47:92–124

6.18 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

Berger S, Dore R. 1996. National Diversity and Global Capitalism. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Univ.
Press
Beunza D, Stark D. 2004. Tools of the trade: the socio-technology of arbitrage in a Wall Street
trading room. Ind. Corp. Chang. 13:369–400
Biggart NW, Beamish TD. 2003. The economic sociology of conventions: habit, custom,
practice, and routine in market order. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 29:443–64
Blau PM, Duncan OD. 1967. The American Occupational Structure. New York: Wiley
Block F, Evans P. 2005. The state and the economy. See Smelser & Swedberg 2005, pp. 505–26
Bourdieu P. 1984. Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgment of Taste. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Univ. Press
Bourdieu P. 2005. Principles of an economic anthropology. See Smelser & Swedberg 2005,
pp. 75–89
Boyer R, Drache D. 1996. States Against Markets: The Limits of Globalization. London/
New York: Routledge
Burt RS. 1980a. Cooptive corporate actor networks: a reconsideration of interlocking direc-
torates involving American manufacturing? Admin. Sci. Q. 25:557–82
Burt RS. 1980b. The stability of American markets. Am. J. Sociol. 94:356–95
Burt RS. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Univ. Press
Callon M. 1998. The embeddedness of economic markets in economics. In The Laws of the
Markets, ed. M Callon, pp. 1–57. Oxford: Blackwell
Callon M. 2002. Technology, politics and the market: an interview with Michel Callon. Econ.
Soc. 31:285–306
Callon M, Muniesa F. 2005. Economic markets as calculative collective devices. Organ. Stud.
26:1229–50
Campbell JL, Lindberg LN. 1990. Property rights and the organizational activity of the state.
Am. Sociol. Rev. 55:3–14
Campbell JL, Rogers Hollingsworth J, Lindberg LN. 1991. Governance of the American Economy.
Cambridge, UK/New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Carroll GR. 1985. Concentration and specialization: dynamics of niche width in populations
of organizations. Am. J. Sociol. 90:1262–83
Carroll GR, Swaminathan A. 2000. Why the microbrewery movement? Organizational dy-
namics of resource partitioning in the U.S. brewing industry. Am. J. Sociol. 106:715–62
Carruthers B, Ariovich L. 2004. The sociology of property rights. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 30:23–46
Carruthers B, Halliday T. 1998. Rescuing Business and the Making of Corporate Bankruptcy Law
in England and the United State. Oxford: Oxford Univ. Press
Chandler AD. 1962. Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the Industrial Enterprise.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
Chandler AD. 1977. The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business.
Cambridge, MA: Belknap
Cheshire C, Cook K. 2004. The emergence of trust networks under uncertainty: implications
for Internet interaction. Anal. Krit. 28:1–20
Csikszentmihalyi M, Rochberg-Halton E. 1981. The Meaning of Things: Domestic Symbols and
the Self. Cambridge, UK/New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Davis GF. 1991. Agents without principles? The spread of the poison pill through the inter-
corporate network. Admin. Sci. Q. 36:583–613
Davis GF, Diekmann KA, Tinsley CH. 1994. The decline and fall of the conglomerate firm in
the 1980s: the deinstitutionalization of an organizational form. Am. Sociol. Rev. 59:547–70

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.19


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

Delaney K. 1992. Strategic Bankruptcy: How Corporations and Creditors Use Chapter 11 to their
Advantage. Berkeley: Univ. Calif. Press
DiMaggio PJ, Powell WW. 1983. The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and
collective rationality in organizational fields. Am. Sociol. Rev. 48:147–60
Dobbin F. 1994. Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain, and France in the Railway
Age. Cambridge, UK/New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Dobbin F, Dowd TJ. 2000. The market that antitrust built: public policy, private coercion, and
railroad acquisitions, 1825 to 1922. Am. Sociol. Rev. 65:631–57
Dore RP. 1973. British Factory–Japanese Factory: The Origins of National Diversity in Industrial
Relations. London: Allen & Unwin
Dore RP. 1987. Taking Japan Seriously: A Confucian Perspective on Leading Economic Issues.
Stanford, CA: Stanford Univ. Press
Dore RP. 1997. The distinctiveness of Japan. In The Political Economy of Modern Capitalism:
Mapping Convergence and Diversity, ed. C Crouch, pp. 19–32. London: Sage
Durkheim E. 1964. The Division of Labor in Society. New York: Free Press
Eisenstadt SN. 1973. Tradition, Change, and Modernity. New York: Wiley
Emerson RM. 1962. Power-dependence relations. Am. Sociol. Rev. 27:31–41
Evans PB. 1995. Embedded Autonomy States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton Univ. Press
Fama EF, Jensen MC. 1983. Separation of ownership and control. J. Law Econ. 26:301–25
Fischer CS. 1992. America Calling: A Social History of the Telephone to 1940. Berkeley: Univ.
Calif. Press
Fiss PC, Zajac EJ. 2004. The diffusion of ideas over contested terrain: the (non)adoption of a
shareholder value orientation among German firms. Admin. Sci. Q. 49:501–34
Fligstein N. 1985. The spread of the multidivisional form among large firms, 1919–1979. Am.
Sociol. Rev. 50:377–91
Fligstein N. 1990. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ.
Press
Fligstein N. 1991. The structural transformation of American industry: an institutional ac-
count of the causes of diversification in the largest firms. In The New Institutionalism in
Organizational Analysis, ed. P DiMaggio, pp. 311–36. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press
Fligstein N. 1996. Markets as politics: a political cultural approach to market institutions. Am.
Sociol. Rev. 61:656–73
Fligstein N. 2001. The Architecture of Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First-Century
Capitalist Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Fligstein N, Choo J. 2005. Law and corporate governance. Annu. Rev. Law Soc. Sci. 1:64–84
Fourcade-Gourinchas M. 2007. Theories of markets and theories of society. Am. Behav. Sci.
In press
Friedman M. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Granovetter M. 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
Univ. Press
Granovetter M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness.
Am. J. Sociol. 91:481–510
Granovetter M. 1994. Business groups. In The Handbook of Economic Sociology, ed. R Swedberg,
pp. 453–75. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Granovetter M. 2005. The impact of social structure on economic outcomes. J. Econ. Perspect.
19:33–50
Granovetter M, McGuire P. 1998. The making of an industry: electricity in the U.S. In The
Laws of the Market, ed. M Callon, pp. 147–73. Oxford: Blackwell

6.20 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

Guala F. 2001. Building economic machines: the FCC auctions. Stud. Hist. Philos. Sci. 32:453–
77
Gulati R, Westphal JD. 1999. Cooperative or controlling? The effects of CEO-board relations
and the content of interlocks on the formation of joint ventures. Admin. Sci. Q. 44:473–506
Hall PA, Soskice DW. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative
Advantage. Oxford, UK/New York: Oxford Univ. Press
Hannan MT, Freeman J. 1977. The population ecology of organizations. Am. J. Sociol. 82:929–
64
Hannan MT, Freeman J. 1987. The ecology of organizational founding: American labor unions,
1836–1985. Am. J. Sociol. 92:910–43
Hannan MT, Freeman J. 1988. Density dependence in the growth of organizational popu-
lations. In Ecological Models of Organization, ed. G Carroll, pp. 7–32. Cambridge, MA:
Ballinger
Haunschild PR. 1993. Interorganizational imitation: the impact of interlocks on corporate
acquisition activity. Admin. Sci. Q. 38:564–92
Hauser RM, Featherman DL. 1977. The Process of Stratification: Trends and Analysis. New York:
Academic
Haveman HA, Rao H. 1997. Structuring a theory of moral sentiments: institutional and orga-
nizational coevolution in the early thrift industry. Am. J. Sociol. 102:1606–51
Heimer CA. 1985. Reactive Risk and Rational Action: Managing Moral Hazard in Insurance Con-
tracts. Berkeley: Univ. Calif. Press
Hirsch PM. 1986. From ambushes to golden parachutes: corporate takeovers as an instance of
cultural framing and institutional integration. Am. J. Sociol. 91:800–37
Hodson R. 1983. Workers Earnings and Corporate Economic Structure. New York: Academic
Hollingsworth JR, Schmitter PC, Streeck W. 1994. Governing Capitalist Economies: Performance
and Control of Economic Sectors. New York: Oxford Univ. Press
Ingram P, Rao H. 2004. Store wars: the enactment and repeal of anti-chain-store legislation
in America. Am. J. Sociol. 110:446–86
Ingram P, Robinson J, Busch ML. 2005. The intergovernmental network of world trade: IGO
connectedness, governance, and embeddedness. Am. J. Sociol. 111:824–58
Jacobs J. 2005. ASR’s greatest hits. Am. Sociol. Rev. 70:1–3
Johnson C. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925–1975.
Palo Alto, CA: Stanford Univ. Press
Kalleberg A, Griffin LJ. 1980. Class, occupation, and inequality in job rewards. Am. J. Sociol.
85:731–68
Kerr C. 1960. Industrialism and Industrial Man: The Problems of Labor and Management in Economic
Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press
Kollock P. 1994. The emergence of exchange structures. Am. J. Sociol. 100:313–45
Kollock P. 1999. The production of trust in online markets. In Advances in Group Processes, ed.
E Lawlor, pp. 99–123. New York: Elsevier
Knorr Cetina K, Bruegger U. 2002. Global microstructures: the virtual societies of financial
markets. Am. J. Sociol. 107:905–50
Krippner G. 2001. The elusive market: embeddedness and the paradigm of economic sociology.
Theory Soc. 30:775–810
Leifer E, White H. 1987. A structural approach to markets. In Structural Analysis of Business,
ed. M Schwartz, pp. 85–108. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press
Lerner D, Riesman D. 1963. The Passing of Traditional Society: Modernizing the Middle East.
Glencoe, IL: Free Press

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.21


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

Lie J. 1997. Sociology of markets. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 23:341–60


Lincoln JR, Gerlach ML, Ahmadjian CL. 1996. Keiretsu networks and corporate performance
in Japan. Am. Sociol. Rev. 61:67–88
Lounsbury M, Rao H. 2004. Sources of durability and change in market classifications: a study
of reconstitution of product categories in the American mutual fund industry, 1994–1985.
Soc. Forces 82:969–99
MacKenzie D. 2004. The big bad wolf and the rational market: portfolio insurance, the 1987
crash and the performativity of economics. Econ. Soc. 33:303–34
MacKenzie D. 2005. A Camera, Not a Machine. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
MacKenzie D, Milo Y. 2003. Constructing a market, performing theory: the historical sociol-
ogy of a financial derivatives exchange. Am. J. Sociol. 109:107–45
March JG, Simon HA, Guetzkow HS. 1958. Organizations. New York: Wiley
Miles RE. 1980. Macro Organizational Behavior. Santa Monica, CA: Goodyear
Miles RE, Snow CC. 1978. Organizational Strategy, Structure, and Process. New York: McGraw-
Hill
Mizruchi MS. 1996. What do interlocks do? An analysis critique and assessment of research
on interlocking directorates. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 22:271–98
Nelson RR, Winter SG. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard Univ. Press
Ocasio W, Kim H. 1999. The circulation of corporate control: selection of functional back-
grounds of new CEOs in large U.S. manufacturing firms, 1981–1992. Admin. Sci. Q.
44:532–62
Pfeffer J. 1981. Power in Organizations. Marshfield, MA: Pitman
Pfeffer J, Salancik GR. 1978. The External Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence Per-
spective. New York: Harper & Row
Podolny JM. 1993. A status-based model of market competition. Am. J. Sociol. 98:829–72
Podolny JM. 2001. Networks as the pipes and prisms of the market. Am. J. Sociol. 107:33–60
Polanyi K. 1957. The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon
Powell WW, DiMaggio P. 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago:
Univ. Chicago Press
Powell WW, Douglas R, White, Koput KW, Owen-Smith J. 2005. Network dynamics and
field evolution: the growth of interorganizational collaboration in the life sciences. Am. J.
Sociol. 110:1132–205
Ranger-Moore J, Banaszak-Holl J, Hannan MT. 1991. Density-dependent dynamics in reg-
ulated industries: founding rates of banks and life insurance companies. Admin. Sci. Q.
36:36–65
Rao H, Sivakumar K. 1999. Institutional sources of boundary spanning structures: the es-
tablishment of investor relations departments in the Fortune 500 industrials. Org. Sci.
10:27–42
Roe MJ. 2003. Political Determinants of Corporate Governance: Political Context, Corporate Impact.
Oxford/New York: Oxford Univ. Press
Rostow WW. 1961. The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge,
UK: Cambridge Univ. Press
Schneiberg M, Soule SA. 2005. Institutionalization as a contested multilevel process: the case
of rate regulation in American fire insurance. In Social Movements and Organization Theory,
ed. GF Davis, D McAdam, WR Scott, MN Zald, pp. 122–61. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
Univ. Press
Scott WR, Meyer JW. 1982. The Organization of Institutional Sectors. Stanford, CA: Inst. Res.
Educ. Financ. Gov. Sch. Educ., Stanford Univ.

6.22 Fligstein · Dauter


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

Shepard R. 1970. Theory of Cost and Production Functions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Simon HA. 1957. Models of Man: Social and Rational; Mathematical Essays on Rational Human
Behavior in a Social Setting. New York: Wiley
Slater D. 1997. Consumer Culture and Modernity. Cambridge, UK/Cambridge, MA: Polity/
Blackwell
Smelser NJ, Swedberg R. 1994. The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton, NJ/New York:
Princeton Univ. Press/Russell Sage Found. 1st. ed.
Smelser NJ, Swedberg R. 2005. The Handbook of Economic Sociology. New York: Russell Sage
Found./Princeton Univ. Press. 2nd ed.
Spence AM. 1974. Market Signaling: Informational Transfer in Hiring and Related Screening
Processes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press
Stark D, Vedrez B. 2006. Social times of network spaces: network sequences and foreign
investment in Hungary. Am. J. Sociol. 111:1367–411
Stuart T, Hoang H, Hybels R. 1999. Interorganizational endorsements and the performance
of entrepreneurial ventures. Admin. Sci. Q. 43:668–98
Stuart T, Sorenson O. 2003. Liquidity events and the geographic distribution of entrepreneurial
activity. Admin. Sci. Q. 48:175–201
Thompson JD. 1967. Organizations in Action: Social Science Bases of Administrative Theory. New
York: McGraw-Hill
Trigilia C. 2002. Economic Sociology: State, Market, and Society in Modern Capitalism. Oxford/
Malden, MA: Blackwell
Uzzi B. 1996. The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance
of organizations: the network effect. Am. Sociol. Rev. 61:674–98
Uzzi B. 1997. Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: the paradox of embed-
dedness. Admin. Sci. Q. 42:35–67
Uzzi BRL. 2004. Embeddedness and price formation in the corporate law market. Am. Sociol.
Rev. 69:319–44
Wade R. 1990. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian
Industrialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Westphal JD, Zajac EJ. 1998. The symbolic management of stockholders: corporate governance
reforms and shareholder reactions. Admin. Sci. Q. 43:127–53
White HC. 1970. Chains of Opportunity: System Models of Mobility in Organizations. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard Univ. Press
White HC. 1981. Where do markets come from? Am. J. Sociol. 87:517–47
White HC. 2002. Markets from Networks: Socioeconomic Models of Production. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton Univ. Press
Williamson OE. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Con-
tracting. New York/London: Free Press/Collier Macmillan
Yamigushi T, Cook K. 1993. Generalized exchanges and social dilemmas. Soc. Psychol. Q.
56:235–48
Zelizer V. 1983. Morals and Markets: The Development of Life Insurance in the United States. New
Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books
Zelizer V. 1994. Pricing the Priceless Child: The Changing Social Value of Children. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton Univ. Press
Zelizer V. 1997. The Social Meaning of Money. New York: Basic Books
Zelizer V. 2005. Culture and consumption. See Smelser & Swedberg 2005, pp. 331–55
Zorn DM. 2004. Here a chief, there a chief: the rise of the CFO in the American firm. Am.
Sociol. Rev. 69:345–64

www.annualreviews.org • The Sociology of Markets 6.23


ANRV316-SO33-06 ARI 22 March 2007 21:26

Zuckerman EW. 1999. The categorical imperative: securities analysts and the illegitimacy
discount. Am. J. Sociol. 104:1398–438
Zuckerman EW. 2000. Focusing the corporate product: securities analysts and de-
diversification. Admin. Sci. Q. 45:591–619
Zukin S, Smith Maguire J. 2004. Consumers and consumption. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 30:173–98

6.24 Fligstein · Dauter

S-ar putea să vă placă și