Sunteți pe pagina 1din 4

y.

"^ d:o

OPUS General Editors


Christopher Butler
An Introduction to
Robert Evans
John Skorupski
OPUS books provide concise, original, and authoritative
Political
introductions to a wide range of subjects in the humanities
and sciences. They are written by experts for the general
reader as well as for students. Philosophy

Jonathan Wolff

Oxford New York


OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS

\u
^s
x Preface

book with me, or have commented on all or part of drafts (in


some cases, on many versions) include Paul Ashwin, Richard Introduction
Bellamy, AlanCarter,ElaineCollins, IssiCotton, VirginiaCox,
Tim Crane, Brad Hooker, Alya Khan, Dudley Knowles,
Annabelle Lever,VeroniqueMuiiozDarde,Mike Martin, Lucy We do not say that a man who showsno interest in politics
O'Brien. Sarah Richmond, Mike Rosen, Mike Saward, Mario is a man whominds his own business;we say that he has no
business here at all.
Scannella, Raj Sehgal, John Skorupski, Philip Smelt, Bob Stern,
and Nigel Warburton. I am very grateful to them all. (Pericles' funeral oration, in Thucydides,
The PeloponnesianWar, 147)

It has been said that there are only two questions in political
philosophy: 'who gets what?', and 'says who?' Not quite true,
but close enough to be a useful starting-point. The first of these
questions is about the distribution of material goods, and of
rights and liberties. On what basis should people possess prop-
erty? What rights and liberties should they enjoy? The second
question concerns the distribution of another good: political
power. Locke defined political power as 'the right of making
laws with penalties of death, and consequently all less penalties'.
This probably goes further than we need, but we can see the
point. Political power includes the right to command others, and
to subject them to punishment if they disobey. Who should hold
this power?
As soon as we reflect on these questions puzzles emerge. Is
there any good reason why one person should have more prop-
erty than another? Are there any justified limits to my liberty?
And what should the relation be between political power and
economic success? In some countries few obtain political power
unless they are already wealthy. In others, those who gain politi-
cal power soon find themselves rich. But should there be any
connection at all between possession of wealth and enjoyment of
political power?
Indeed, political power is puzzling enough on its own. If some-
one has legitimate political power over me then they have the
right to force me to do certain things. But how could another
person justify the claim to have such rights over me? It often
seems outrageous that someone else should tell me what to do,
|^ -Mf:. -!WP.. JC^irrL.

2 Introduction Introduction 3
worse still that they think they are entitled to punish me if I the question 'who holds wealth?' Why are we interested in this
disobey. Yet there is, of course, another side to this. Perhaps I descriptive question? Primarily because the distribution of
should also consider howothers might behave-how unpleasant wealth is relevant to normative questions about justice. (Com-
they could make my life-if they were left unrestrained by the pare the question: 'who holds string?'-inequalities in the pos-
law and the threat of punishment. Reflecting on this, perhaps sessionof string are of no political interest.)
there is something to be said, after all, for the existence of Furthermore, questions about human behaviour often seem
political power. Sowecanidentify withboth the anarchist's plea to straddle the descriptive/normative divide. A sociologist seek-
for the autonomy of the individual, and the authoritarian's mg to explain why people generally obey the law, for example, is
claims for the power of the state. likely to appeal at some point to the fact that many people
One task for the political philosopher, then, is to determine believe that they ought to obey. And, of course, factual
the correct balance between autonomy and authority, or, in questions about human behaviour arejust as relevant to norma-
other words, to determine the proper distribution of political tive issues. For example, there is no point in putting forward a
power. This example also illustrates what is distinctive about theory of the just society without having some knowledge of
political philosophy. Political philosophy is a normative disci- human behaviour and motivation. Some theories ofjustice, for
pline, meaning that it tries to establish norms (rules or ideal example might make unrealistic assumptions about people's
standards). We can contrast the normative with the descriptive. capacity (or lack ofcapacity) for altruism. Inshort, studying how
Descriptivestudies attempt to find out howthings are. Norma- things arehelps to explain howthings canbe, andstudying how
tive studies try to discover how things should be: what is right, they canbe is indispensable for assessinghowthey ought to be.
just, or morally correct. Politics can be studied from both a But how can we answer the question of how things ought to
descriptive and a normative standpoint. be? We know, broadly, how to go about answering purely de-
Characteristically, descriptive political studies are undertaken scnptive questions: we go and look. This is not to say that
by the political scientist, the sociologist, and the historian. So, political science or history is easy, for very subtle and detailed
for example, some political scientists ask questions about the work is often involved. But in principle we do think we know
actualdistribution of goods within a given society. Who in the how to do it, even if often we cannot find the information we
United States ofAmerica holds wealth? Whoin Germany holds seek. But what can we do to find out how things ought to be?
power?Thepoliticalphilosopher,like all ofus,hasgoodreason Where can we look?
to beinterestedin the answersto thesequestions,buthisor her The uncomfortable fact is that there is no easy answer. But,
primary concern is elsewhere: what rule or principle should despite this, very many philosophers have attempted to solve
govern the distribution ofgoods? ('Goods' hereincludes not only these normative political problems, and they have not been
property, but power, rights, and liberty too. ) The political phi- short ofthingsto say.Wewill examine some ofthemost impor-
losopher will ask, not 'how is property distributed?', but 'what tant contributions throughout this book, and we will see that.
wouldbea just orfairdistributionofproperty?' Not 'whatrights by andlarge, philosophers reason about politics in just the way
and liberties do people have?', but 'what rights and liberties they do about other philosophical issues. They draw distinctions,
should people have?' What ideal standards, or norms, should they examine whether propositions are self-contradictory, or
govern the distribution of goods within society? whethertwo or more propositions arelogically consistent. They
The partition between normative and descriptive studies, try to show that surprising theses can be deduced from more
though, is not quite asclear-cut as it might seem. Consider again obvious ones. In short, they present arguments.
4 Introduction
Introduction 5
And philosophers argue about politics for good reason. In If we have a state, how should it be organized? Should it be
political philosophy, unlike many other areas of philosophy, democratic? What does it even mean to say that the state is
there is no hiding-place. In philosophy, agnosticism ('the democratic? Is there any rationale for preferring rule by the
English translate their ignorance into Greek and call it agnosti- people to rule by an expert: a benevolent dictator? These are the
cism', said Engels) is often a respectable position. Perhaps I questions pursued in Chapter 3.
cannotfinda satisfactorypositionon the questionofwhetheror How much power should the state have? Or, viewed from the
not wehavefree will, so I professno view. In a widercontextthis other side, how much liberty should the citizen enjoy? Chapter
hardly matters. But in political philosophy agnosticism is self- 4 considers the theory that, to avoid the 'tyranny of the major-
defeating. It may not matter if a society hasno officialpolicy on ity', we should be given the liberty to act just as we wish, pro-
the solution to the problem of free will, but in every society vided that we do no harm to others.
someone (or no one) holds political power, and property is If we give citizens such liberty, should this include the liberty
distributed in some wayor other. Ofcourse, any one individual's to acquire and dispose of property however they see fit? Or are
influence on society's decisions is likely to be minute. But poten- there justified restrictions on economic activity in the name of
tially we all have some say, if not by voting then by making our liberty or justice? This is the topic of Chapter 5: distributive
views known through debate and discussion, whether on the justice.
public stage, or by 'underground' means. Those who prefer not The five main chapters of this book take us through topics of
to participate will find their political decisions made for them, enduring concern: the state of nature, the state, democracy,
whether they like it or not. To say or do nothing is, in practice, liberty, and property. The final chapter looks briefly at some of
to endorse the present situation, howeverrepellent. the assumptions underlying my choice of topics, and examines
In the course of this book we shall raise and discuss the main those assumptions in the context of recent work in feminist
questions of political philosophy, examining some of the most political theory. By this point, with two and a half thousand
mfluential answers, from the ancient Greeks to the present day. years of hindsight, we may have some sort of answerto a ques-
Each chapter takes on a particular question or controversy. The tion raised, yet not satisfactorily answered, in this Introduc-
natural starting-point is political power, the right to command. tion-howdowedo politicalphilosophy? Onthis topic, ason all
Why should some have the right to pass laws to regulate the those discussedhere, my aim is not to force an opinion on you;
behaviour of others? Well, suppose no one had such a right. I hope insteadto present somematerials that will help you form
What would life be like? This is the question pursued in the your own view. Of course it will be possible to read this book
first chapter: what would happen in a 'state of nature' without and end up as uncertain as before. But we must not underesti-
government? Wouldlifebeunbearable?Or animprovementon mate the progress made by advancingfrom muddled ignorance
how things are now? to informed bemusement.
Suppose we come to accept that life under government is
preferable to life in the state of nature. Does it follow from this
that we have the moral duty to do as the state decrees? Or is
there another argument that will deliver this conclusion? This is
the problem of political obligation, which we shall discuss in
Chapter 2.

S-ar putea să vă placă și