Sunteți pe pagina 1din 10

More or Less Ambition in the Doha Round?

Modeling the Development Impact of Recent


Proposals Quelle ambition pour la négociation de Doha ? Un modèle de
l’impact des dernières propositions sur le développement.

Mehr oder weniger Ehrgeiz in der Doha-Runde? Eine


Modellierung der Auswirkungen auf die Entwicklung der neuesten
Vorschläge

Antoine Bouet, Simon Mevel and David Orden1

What is at stake in the stand- for developing countries is open computable general equilibrium model
off between the United States, to question. Using the MIRAGE of the global economy (see Box 1) we
Europe and developing countries
over agriculture in the World
Box 1. The MIRAGE Model
Trade Organization’s (WTO) Doha
Development Round of trade talks? The MIRAGE model was developed at the Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et
What impact would an agreement d’Informations Internationales (CEPII) in Paris. It is a multi-sector, multi-
based on greater or lesser levels region model devoted to trade policy analysis. The model has a sequential
of ambition have on developing dynamic annual setup with labour and capital accumulation over time. Fixed
technology or technological change can be adopted (our model is based on
countries, whose economies
fixed technology). We report results for 2019. This is a 14-year horizon after
depend heavily on agriculture? Trade
we anticipate initiation of reforms assumed to take place over 5 years in
liberalization is a potential stimulus
developed countries and 10 years among developing countries. In the model
for growth in poor countries and the
reported herein, unskilled labour is imperfectly mobile between agricultural
Doha Round was launched with the and non-agricultural activities, reflecting the costs and time-delays in rural–
objective of drawing these countries urban labour migration. Reforms in the services sectors are not modeled.
more fully into the global trade Further research will be needed to illuminate the effects of these reforms in a
system. Yet, two years after the WTO general equilibrium framework.
talks broke down in Cancún, reform
Our analysis within MIRAGE utilizes the latest Global Trade Analysis Project
of the heavily and diversely protected (GTAP) country-disaggregated database (GTAP 6). Tariffs come from the
and subsidized developed-country detailed MacMaps HS-6 dataset. Tariff reductions are applied on ‘bound’
agricultural sectors remains a major duties (maximum levels countries can apply under WTO rules) at a high
impediment to progress, despite disaggregation (about 5,200 products), then the results are aggregated to the
reforms undertaken during the last 15 level of the sectors included in the model. This approach allows tariff ‘binding
years. The December 2005 Hong Kong overhangs’ (difference between the maximum tariffs that countries can apply
ministerial showed little finality in the under WTO rules (bound duties) and the actually applied tariffs of the WTO
negotiations, even though members members) to be taken into account, and are often quite large in developing
agreed to eliminate agricultural countries. The MacMap-HS6 dataset also includes all the regional agreements
export subsidies in 2013 and that less and preferential schemes prevailing in 2001, which allows the modeling
exercise to reflect losses of preferential access.
developed countries (LDCs) will gain
free access to OECD markets for at The MIRAGE model is currently in use at CEPII, the European Union’s Trade
least 97 per cent of agricultural and Unit (Brussels, Belgium), the UN Economic Commission for Africa (Addis-
manufacturing tariff lines. Ababa, Ethiopia), and the International Food Policy Research Institute
(Washington DC, USA). MIRAGE has been the basis for many peer-reviewed
Whether a final Doha Round trade publications and presentations at international conferences. Full descriptions
agreement will eventually produce of MIRAGE and the GTAP and MacMap data are available at the CEPII and GTAP
something substantially more positive web sites (www.cepii.fr and www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu).

40 ★ EuroChoices 5(2) © The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006

5-2_06bouet.indd 40 06/07/2006 11:54:22


compare possible scenarios for the exports to the rest of the world, each
Doha outcome, taking real numbers measured relative to the world average. Die Ergebnisse
from the proposals put on the table
Among the developing countries, some
für diese beiden
by the European Union (EU) and
the United States (US). The results
face high tariffs on their exports (for Doha-Szenarien
from these scenarios demonstrate
example, Argentina, Brazil, Malawi, zeigen auf, wie viel bei
Uruguay, and Zimbabwe). Differences
the high stakes of this negotiation
among countries arise from differences
dieser Verhandlung
given the positions articulated by
in the products they export and auf dem Spiel steht
key WTO members. A global reform
outcome based on the most ambitious
differences in the destinations of their ... eine erfolgrei-
exports. Many developing countries
components of the US and EU
impose relatively high tariffs on their
che Runde könnte
negotiating proposals could deliver
imports, so their tariff average often sowohl auf globaler
noticeably more benefits than an
unambitious outcome, although clearly
exceeds the world average. Ebene als auch für die
less than full trade liberalization. The third point is illustrated in Figure Entwicklungsländer
2. In terms of agricultural trade, tatsächlich von Vorteil
Heterogeneity among both large net food importers and
developing countries substantial food exporters exist among
sein.
middle-income countries (MICs) and
Both developed and developing
LDCs. The net trade positions are
countries are heterogeneous in like Brazil, Argentina, or Thailand,
crucial since global trade liberalization
terms of their own trade policies, the but it will cause a deterioration of
is expected to increase world
trade barriers they face, and their net terms of trade (the ratio of a country’s
agricultural prices, as production
agricultural trade positions. The first export prices to its import prices) for
contracts and consumption expands
two points are illustrated in Figure 1 food-importing developing countries
in response to lower tariffs and
through a comparison of the duties like Venezuela, Bangladesh or the
subsidies in most countries. This will
applied by each country on their Philippines.
be beneficial for developing countries
imports versus the duties faced on their

Figure 1. Applied protection on their imports and faced on exports of countries in 2001
16.0%

Malawi

12.0%
Applied duty on exports relative to world average

Uruguay

Zimbabwe
Argentina
8.0%

Brazil

Australia/NZ

4.0%
Colombia Thailand Tanzania

India

USA EU Mozambique China Tunisia


0.0%
-10.0% 0.0% 10.0% Morocco 20.0% 30.0%
Chile Zambia
Singapore Peru Bangladesh

Canada
Malaysia
Madagascar Philippines
Venezuela
Mexico
-4.0%
Applied duty on imports relative to world average

© The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006 EuroChoices 5(2) ★ 41

5-2_06bouet.indd 41 06/07/2006 11:55:02


Figure 2. Agricultural trade balance of selected developing countries in 2005 (billion US dollars)

Developing Asia
Singapore
Venezuela
Bangladesh
Philippines
China

Tunisia
Mozambique
Zambia
Morocco
Madagascar
Uganda
Tanzania
Malawi
Uruguay
Peru
Zimbabwe
Colombia
Viet Nam
India
Malaysia
South African Customs Union
Indonesia
Chile
Thailand
Argentina
Brazil

-4.0 -2.0 0.0 2.0 4.0 6.0 8.0 10.0 12.0 14.0

US and EU agricultural subsidizing agriculture, which stifles increased in the most recent (2002)
protection and subsidies trade opportunities. The US and EU farm bill which expires in 2007. The
follow somewhat different regimes. US provides relatively less preferential
Criticism has been directed at
The US has relatively low tariffs, but access than does the EU for selected
developed countries for protecting and
its domestic agricultural support was developing-country trade partners. The

42 ★ EuroChoices 5(2) © The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006

5-2_06bouet.indd 42 06/07/2006 11:55:04


EU, in contrast, has higher agricultural rates and a lower cap on maximum with strong trade liberalization
(but similarly low industrial) tariffs and allowable tariffs; few sensitive or components from the US and EU
has recently realigned its agricultural special products; and moderately proposals and contrast this with a less
support, which remains quite high, tough bindings on domestic support ambitious outcome drawn from the
toward policy instruments that are less that encourage decoupling of lower-end elements (see Box 2).
trade distorting than in the past. In subsidies from production. Strong
On market access, our ambitious
these US–EU policy differences lie the points of the EU proposal in terms of
proposal includes most elements of
seeds of different approaches to the trade liberalization lie in the call for
the US formula. The US proposal prior
trade negotiations. free access of LDCs to OECD markets,
to the Hong Kong meeting called for
a specific initiative for cotton to help
cuts of 85–90 per cent in agricultural
Similarities and differences in West Africa, and a push for lower
tariffs above 60 per cent for developed
the US and EU proposals industrial tariffs worldwide.
countries and lesser cuts in three
The Doha Round negotiations may bands of lower initial tariffs, while the
What difference will the Doha EU called for less ambitious cuts (60
reach a final agreement on agriculture
outcome make?
and other provisions of a trade deal in per cent in agricultural tariffs above 90
2006, but the outcome is still far from What difference will the Doha per cent for developed countries and
certain in the spring. No proposal was Round’s outcome make to global similarly less ambitious cuts for lower
complete even after the Hong Kong trade and welfare and to developing initial tariff bands). Both proposals
ministerial. The US and EU proposals countries in particular? To examine allow lesser cuts by developing
have some broad commonalities, such this question using numbers from countries. The ambitious scenario
as progressive tariff and domestic- the negotiating table, we define a adds to the US tariff formula the EU
support cuts and the elimination of relatively ambitious reform scenario proposal for free access by LDCs to
export subsidies. But the specifics of
the proposals deviate on matters such
as rates of reduction of tariffs and Box 2. Overview of two scenarios
domestic support and the number of
sensitive or special products (the latter AMBITIOUS SCENARIO
for developing countries only) that Tariffs:
will be subject to lesser disciplines.
• US tariff formula for agriculture.
In terms of an ambitious agenda for
• Tariff caps in agriculture (developed countries, 100 per cent; developing
agricultural trade liberalization, strong countries, 150 per cent).
points of the US proposal include • US sensitive/special products clause (1 per cent).
sharper reductions in bound tariff • Swiss formula cuts for manufacturing tariffs (developed-country coefficient,
8 per cent; MIC coefficient, 20 per cent; LDC coefficient, 30 per cent).
• EU proposal of free OECD access for LDCs.
Les résultats
Domestic support levels cut by 20 per cent.
obtenus avec chacun Export subsidies eliminated.
des deux scénarios
UNAMBITIOUS SCENARIO
montrent l’ampleur de Tariffs:
l’enjeu … un accord • EU tariff formula for agriculture.
à la fin des négocia- • No agricultural tariff caps.
• EU sensitive/special products clause (8 per cent).
tions pourrait permettre • Swiss formula cuts for manufacturing tariffs (developed-country
de vrais gains, aussi coefficient, 10 per cent; MIC coefficient, 30 per cent).
• LDCs do not reduce their import duties.
bien pour les pays en
• Additional free OECD access for LDCs, but exceptions for Japan and South
développement que Korea (rice) and the US (sugar, textile and apparel).
pour le monde en Domestic support levels unchanged.
général. Export subsidies eliminated.

© The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006 EuroChoices 5(2) ★ 43

5-2_06bouet.indd 43 06/07/2006 11:55:07


Results for the ambitious versus
unambitious Doha outcomes
Summary results for our ambitious
and unambitious scenarios are shown
in Tables 1, 2 and 3 and Figure 3.
As a benchmark, we also report the
outcomes of a MIRAGE simulation of
full global trade liberalization.

With full liberalization (which includes


elimination of border protection,
domestic support and export subsidies
in agriculture and industry) world
protection (averaging 5.4 per cent as
measured by a weighted aggregate
statistic) is eliminated. World trade
expands by 12.0 per cent, and the
total annual real income (welfare)
OECD markets, imposes tariff caps in sensitive/special products (exceptions
gain worldwide is US$158 billion (in
agriculture, and defines an exception for 8 per cent of tariff lines), the tariff-
constant 2001 dollar value, 0.5 per cent
regime for sensitive/special products reduction Swiss formula for industry
of expected world income without a
of only 1 per cent of agricultural (higher tariff targets for developed
Doha agreement). This is less income
tariff lines per country. Applied trade- countries and MICs and no cuts by
gain than reported in October 2005 by
distorting domestic agricultural LDCs), and free OECD access for LDCs
the World Bank (US$287 billion) mainly
support is cut by 20 per cent. Strong only with some exceptions retained. No
because we use more conservative
manufacturing tariff reductions cuts are assumed in applied domestic
‘trade elasticities’ (production and
are imposed on developed and agricultural support of developed
consumption responses to shifting
developing countries (including LDCs) countries.
prices). Although not shown in the
using a ‘Swiss formula’ that reduces
Our application of the MIRAGE model table, full liberalization is slightly
higher tariffs fastest until the rates
to assess the effects of an ambitious progressive in the sense that the
among products converge to a given
versus unambitious Doha outcome share of welfare gains for developing
level (lower for developed countries
focuses on the heterogeneity among countries as a group (21.3 per cent)
than for MICs or LDCs).
developing countries and the is greater than their initial share of
In contrast to the ambitious scenario, relatively high levels of protection world income (19.4 per cent). But
our unambitious scenario adopts the within agriculture and textiles and results differ widely among individual
EU formula for less deep tiered tariff apparel. Of 41 regions identified countries, and even the aggregate gain
cuts for agriculture by developed in the model, 33 are developing is small for the LDCs.
countries (with corresponding smaller countries or groups of countries.
The unambitious scenario leads to
cuts for MICs and no cut for LDCs). Among the 18 sectors considered, 10
global real-income gains of US$38.3
The unambitious scenario does not are agricultural and the textiles and
billion, just 24 per cent of the
impose any cap on agricultural tariffs, apparel sectors are separated from
gain from full liberalization. World
and adds fewer liberalizing elements on other manufacturing.
protection measured by the weighted

Table 1: Global results of alternative liberalization scenarios

World protection World trade Real income


Scenario (per cent decrease) (per cent increase) gain in billion US dollars
Full liberalization –5.4 12.0 158
Ambitious Doha outcome –1.9 2.8 76.7
Compared with full liberalization (35 per cent) (23 per cent) (49 per cent)
Unambitious Doha outcome –1.2 1.6 38.3
Compared with full liberalization (22 per cent) (13 per cent) (24 per cent)

44 ★ EuroChoices 5(2) © The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006

5-2_06bouet.indd 44 06/07/2006 11:55:09


The results
for the two Doha
scenarios demonstrate
the high stakes of
this negotiation…a
successful round
could deliver real gains
both globally and for
developing
countries.

aggregate statistic declines by 1.2


per cent. This is 22 per cent of the
of these income and trade gains come tariffs and the limited number of
decline (to zero protection) with full
from lower agricultural protection sensitive products.
liberalization. World trade expands by
in wealthy countries, whereas little
just 1.6 per cent. The impact of the two scenarios on
reduction in applied agricultural
market access of selected countries is
In comparison to unambitious protection occurs among developing
illustrated in Figure 3. The ambitious
liberalization, a substantially greater countries in the ambitious scenario.
scenario implies a much larger
movement is observed under the The gain in world real income is
liberalization in those rich countries
ambitious scenario. Global welfare proportionally much larger than
where protection is initially highest
increases by US$76.7 billion, 49 the reduction in average protection
and unevenly distributed (the rest of
per cent of the gain from full because the ambitious scenario
OECD, developed Asia, and the EU).
liberalization. World protection falls reduces the dispersion of tariffs
The binding overhang phenomenon
by 1.9 per cent, which is 35 per cent among products in rich countries, due
(see Box 1) is so large in developing
of the effect of full liberalization, and to the caps imposed on agricultural
countries that even the ambitious
trade expands by 2.8 per cent. Most
scenario has a mitigated impact in
agricultural protection except in India
Figure 3. Agricultural protection before and after a potential Doha agreement
and Morocco.
(Applied duties)
The heterogeneity among developing
0.6
countries is illustrated by divergence
in the real-income effects of the
0.5
alternative liberalization scenarios.
0.4
In terms of individual developing
MICs that might benefit from trade
0.3 liberalization, the unambitious scenario
delivers very little real-income gain
0.2 for two reasons. First, these countries
gain little from improved terms of
0.1
trade in world markets despite the
somewhat reduced protection among
0
Australia/New Zealand

Developed Asia

wealthy countries. Second, they


European Union

Rest of OECD

Zambia
Malawi
Bangladesh
USA

China

India

Morocco
Argentina

Brazil

gain little from ‘allocation efficiency’


(realignment of resource use within
their economies) largely because
they make so few changes to their
Initial protection (2005) After ambitious scenario After unambitious scenario

© The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006 EuroChoices 5(2) ★ 45

5-2_06bouet.indd 45 06/07/2006 11:55:10


Table 2: Effects of liberalization on real income of selected developing countries Both terms-of-trade gains (or losses)
and allocation efficiency gains are
Gain or loss as per cent of base level
Full Ambitious Unambitious larger under the ambitious scenario
Country liberalization scenario scenario than under the unambitious scenario,
Middle-income countries (MICs) but they remain less than in the case
Argentina 1.2 0.3 0.2 of full liberalization.
Brazil 0.8 0.3 0.1
Caribbean economies 0.7 0.4 0.2 While overall global gains are largest
Chile 0.7 0.2 0.1 for full liberalization, distributional
China –0.1 0.4 0.4 trade-offs among countries are
India 0.3 0.4 0.3 evident from the results for the three
Thailand 4.9 1.4 0.7
scenarios. In the case of Bangladesh
Venezuela –0.5 –0.3 –0.3
for example, full liberalization has a
Viet Nam 3.3 0.7 0.5
negative effect as it entails complete
Zimbabwe 3.1 0.7 0.3
Least-developed countries (LDCs) elimination of its preferential access
Bangladesh –0.5 2.3 0.3 to Europe in the textile and apparel
Madagascar –0.3 2.6 –0.1 sectors, while world prices rise for its
Malawi 11.9 5.1 5.0 agricultural imports. Bangladesh does
Mozambique –0.2 1.4 0.0 better under the ambitious scenario
Rest of Sub-Saharan Africa 0.0 1.2 0.0 where it gains preferential duty-free
Tanzania 0.7 0.2 0.2
access for its textile and apparel
Uganda 0.5 0.2 0.2
products to all OECD markets, but it
Zambia –0.6 –0.2 –0.1
does not achieve these gains under
the unambitious scenario. Zambia
own policies. Were they to make such Under the ambitious scenario, is also a net importer of agricultural
changes, it would reduce consumer developing countries gain more from commodities while it mostly exports
prices, which would increase domestic trade reform. Among the MICs, gains copper which faces low tariffs
consumption and economic activity. in real income tend to be about one- throughout the world. For Zambia,
Furthermore, own-liberalization would half of those under full liberalization. losses due to higher world agricultural
expand domestic competitiveness
due to reduced prices of intermediate
consumption and capital goods and
to increased competitive pressure.
The same results occur for the
LDCs that might gain from trade
liberalization—terms-of-trade gains
and allocation efficiency gains are very
small under the unambitious scenario.
Other developing countries (both
MICs and LDCs) face smaller potential
gains, or net losses, from full global
liberalization because they are net food
importers or export products (such
as coffee, cocoa or oil) which already
benefit from excellent market access,
or have been conceded preferential
access to EU (e.g., EBA, Cotonou)
or US (e.g., AGOA) which would be
eroded by multilateral reductions in
protection. Effects on these countries
are also dampened in the unambitious
scenario (see Table 2).

46 ★ EuroChoices 5(2) © The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006

5-2_06bouet.indd 46 06/07/2006 11:55:12


Table 3. Effects of liberalization on production in selected countries and regions

Full trade liberalization Ambitious Unambitious

Non Agro-food production

Non Agro-food production

Non Agro-food production


Agro-food production

Agro-food production

Agro-food production
(vol) – %

(vol) – %

(vol) – %

(vol) – %

(vol) – %

(vol) – %
Region

Australia/New Zealand 27.7 –1.9 –14.2 1.0 4.4 –0.3


High Developed Asia –11.1 0.7 –6.0 0.3 –1.2 0.1
income European Union –4.3 0.3 –3.0 0.3 –1.8 0.1
countries Rest of OECD –17.4 0.5 –10.3 0.6 0.7 0.1
US 1.6 –0.2 1.4 –0.1 0.8 –0.1
Argentina 9.0 –1.4 2.9 –0.3 1.3 –0.1
Brazil 17.2 –1.8 6.5 –0.7 2.2 –0.2
Chile 7.6 –0.9 1.8 –0.3 1.1 –0.2
China 0.6 0.3 1.1 –0.1 0.7 0.0
Developing Asia –8.0 1.9 –0.8 0.5 0.2 0.2
India –5.6 3.9 0.4 0.9 0.5 0.5
Middle Malaysia 60.8 0.8 3.0 1.9 –0.1 1.7
Morocco –1.7 1.4 0.4 0.2 1.0 0.0
income
Peru 1.0 0.2 0.5 –0.1 0.3 –0.1
countries Philippines –1.5 2.6 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.1
South African Customs Union 8.1 –0.4 3.6 –0.2 1.5 0.0
Thailand 14.2 2.7 4.0 1.1 0.1 1.1
Tunisia 3.3 1.5 2.5 0.0 –0.5 0.0
Venezuela –1.0 –0.4 1.0 –0.1 0.6 0.1
Viet Nam –5.6 6.7 0.8 0.6 0.5 0.5
Zimbabwe 13.6 –4.7 3.7 –1.2 1.2 –0.3
Bangladesh –1.6 3.5 12.5 –2.4 0.4 0.1
Madagascar 1.4 –2.9 14.3 –6.7 2.2 –2.0
Low Malawi 21.8 –7.6 14.3 –5.2 13.6 –4.8
Mozambique 1.3 0.0 11.0 –2.8 4.4 –0.8
income
Rest of Sub-Saharan Africa –4.5 –0.1 8.2 –1.8 1.0 –0.5
countries Tanzania 0.8 –0.3 0.9 –0.3 0.9 –0.3
Uganda 0.2 –0.2 0.3 0.0 0.3 0.0
Zambia –0.2 1.2 2.4 –0.7 2.2 –0.7

prices dominate the welfare effects region and of wheat to India), and not agreed upon in December 2005,
under all three scenarios. In contrast, Malawi. Conversely the contraction of and we compared those outcomes
Malawi’s gains are impressive under agro-food production in Developed with the estimated effects of full
all three scenarios and largest with Asia, Rest of OECD, Developing global trade liberalization.
full liberalization due to it being an Asia and to a lesser extent in the EU
The results for the two Doha
agricultural exporter and its economic explains why forces resisting trade
scenarios demonstrate the high
size (trade reform often has magnified liberalization are so strong. Impacts on
stakes of this negotiation given
impacts in small countries). production are smaller under the Doha
the positions articulated by the
scenarios and depend on the level of
Trade liberalization also has a countries involved. A successful
ambition.
substantial impact on the pattern round could deliver real gains both
of production among countries globally and for developing countries.
The stakes are high
(see Table 3). In the case of full However the magnitude of those
trade liberalization, the increases of We have presented an analysis of an gains depends on the shape of the
agricultural and food (agro-food) ambitious versus an unambitious agreement. A reform outcome based
production are large in Australia/New Doha Round outcome. Our on the most ambitious components
Zealand, Argentina, Brazil, Thailand, simulations are based on negotiating of the negotiating proposals of
Malaysia (particularly due to increased proposals from the run-up to the the US and EU delivers noticeably
exports of rice to the Developed Asia Hong Kong ministerial meeting but greater benefits than an unambitious

© The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006 EuroChoices 5(2) ★ 47

5-2_06bouet.indd 47 06/07/2006 11:55:14


outcome based on the lower-
end elements of their proposals.
The details matter in the differing
proposals, such as the tariff and
domestic support reduction formulae,
tariff caps, and number of sensitive
and special products. Negotiating
commitment and diligence are
needed in 2006 to avoid a hollow
Doha outcome given the technical
character of these details.

Developing countries are


heterogeneous in terms of their
own policies, the trade barriers they
face, and their net agricultural trade.
Overall, developing countries gain
most—and might achieve the best
deal in the negotiations—when
they join in the reform process for
a global trade agreement. Attention
is needed in the case of some of the
LDCs and other poor countries that
may face declining terms of trade due
to higher world agricultural prices
or eroding preferences. In addition,
many developing countries can
achieve the full benefits of trade only
with substantial attention to broad
development needs that will enhance
their competitiveness (transportation
infrastructure, insurance and credit
markets, as well as relevant political
and social concerns). This too needs
to be part of a successful Doha Round Further Reading
outcome. ■ Anderson, K. and Martin, W. (eds.) (2005). Trade Reform and the Doha Agenda,
Washington DC: The World Bank.
Note ■ Bouët, A., Bureau, J.-C., Decreux, Y. and Jean, S. (2005). Multilateral agricultural
trade liberalization: The contrasting fortunes of developing countries in the Doha
1 Round, The World Economy, 28(9): 1329–1354.
This article is a revised version
of a presentation made at ■ Bouët, A., Mevel, S. and Orden, D. (2005). More or Less Ambition? Modeling the
Development Impact of US–EU Agricultural Proposals in the Doha Round., IFPRI
a luncheon seminar of the brief, Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
German Marshall Fund of the ■ Fontagne, L., Guerin, J.-L. and Jean, S. (2005). Market access liberalization in the
United States, December 1, Doha Round: Scenarios and assessment, The World Economy, 28(8): 1073–1094.
2005, in Washington, D.C. and ■ Francois, J., Van Meijl, H. and Van Tongeren, F. (2005). Trade liberalization in the
Doha development round, Economic Policy, 20(42): 349–391.
in several sessions in Hong
Kong during the WTO meetings Antoine Bouet, David Orden, and Simon Mevel, International Food Policy Research
at which a somewhat more Institute, Washington, D.C., USA.
ambitious reform scenario was Email: a.bouet@cgiar.org; d.orden@cgiar.org; s.mevel@cgiar.org
analyzed.

48 ★ EuroChoices 5(2) © The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006

5-2_06bouet.indd 48 06/07/2006 11:55:14


summary
More or Less Quelle ambition pour Mehr oder weniger
Ambition in the Doha la négociation de Ehrgeiz in der
Round? Modeling the Doha ? Un modèle de Doha-Runde? Eine
Development Impact of l’impact des dernières Modellierung der
Recent Proposals propositions sur le Auswirkungen auf
développement. die Entwicklung der
neuesten Vorschläge
We analyse the impact on developing On se propose d’analyser Wir analysieren die Auswirkungen
countries, whose economies depend l’impact sur les pays en voie de eines mehr oder weniger
heavily on agriculture, of a WTO Doha développement, dont les économies ehrgeizigen Abschlusses der WTO-Doha-
Development Round agreement based on dépendent plus ou moins de l’agriculture, Entwicklungsrunde auf Entwicklungsländer,
greater or lesser levels of ambition. We de différentes variantes possibles, plus ou deren Wirtschaft stark von der Landwirtschaft
present the results of an ambitious versus an moins ambitieuses, de l’accord final sur abhängt. Wir zeigen den Vergleich eines
unambitious Doha Round outcome, using le cycle de Doha pour le développement ambitionierten Ergebnisses mit einem
the MIRAGE model of the global economy, discuté à l’OMC. A l’aide du modèle weniger ambitionierten Ergebnis der
with a special focus on developing countries. MIRAGE de l’économie mondiale, et en Doha-Runde unter Verwendung des
Our simulations are based on negotiating s’intéressant spécialement aux pays en MIRAGE-Modells der Weltwirtschaft auf und
proposals from the run-up to the Hong voie de développement, on oppose un konzentrieren uns dabei besonders auf die
Kong ministerial meeting but not agreed scenario « ambitieux » pour les résultats des Entwicklungsländer. Unsere Simulationen
upon in December 2005. We compare those négociations à un autre « conservateur ». beruhen auf Verhandlungsvorschlägen
outcomes with the estimated effects of full Nos simulations sont basées sur les von der Vorbereitungszeit bis zum
global trade liberalization. The results for propositions de négociation telles qu’elles Ministertreffen in Hongkong. Diese
the two Doha scenarios demonstrate the ont été présentées, mais non adoptées, à Vorschläge wurden jedoch im Dezember
high stakes of this negotiation given the la conférence ministérielle de Hong-Kong 2005 nicht angenommen. Wir vergleichen
positions of EU, US and the G-20 coalition. A en décembre 2005. Ces propositions sont diese Ergebnisse mit den geschätzten
successful round could deliver real gains both confrontées à ce qu’on aurait pu obtenir Auswirkungen einer vollständigen globalen
globally and for developing countries, but d’une libéralisation totale. Les résultats Handelsliberalisierung. Die Ergebnisse
the magnitude of those gains depends on the montrent l’importance de l’enjeu, étant dieser beiden Doha-Szenarien zeigen auf,
shape of the agreement. A reform outcome donné les positions de l’UE, des Etats- was im Hinblick auf die Positionen von
based on the most ambitious components of Unis, et du G20. Une issue heureuse de la EU, USA und G-20-Koalition auf dem Spiel
the negotiating proposals of the US and EU négociation pourrait conduire à de vrais gains steht. Eine erfolgreiche Runde könnte
delivers noticeably greater benefits than an tant pour le monde dans son ensemble que sowohl auf globaler Ebene als auch für die
unambitious outcome. Developing countries pour les pays en voie de développement, Entwicklungsländer tatsächlich von Vorteil
are exposed to very contrasting fortunes. mais l’ampleur de ces gains dépend de la sein; die Bedeutung dieser Vorteile hängt
The details matter in the differing proposals, façon dont se ferait l’accord. La version jedoch von der Art des Abkommens ab.
such as the tariff and domestic support « ambitieuse » de l’accord donnerait des Das Ergebnis einer Reform, welches auf
reduction formulae, tariff caps, and number gains sensiblement plus élevés que celle den ambitioniertesten Komponenten der
of sensitive and special products. Negotiating basée sur les principes plus conservateurs. Verhandlungsvorschläge von USA und EU
commitment and diligence are needed in Les pays en voie de développement, dans ce beruht, führt zu deutlich größeren Vorteilen
2006 to avoid a hollow Doha outcome given cadre, subissent des fortunes diverses. Les als ein weniger ambitioniertes Ergebnis.
the technical character of these details. détails des différentes propositions, tels que Die Wirkungen für die Entwicklungsländer
les formules adoptées pour la réduction des sind sehr gegensätzlich. Die Details der
tarifs et la mesure des soutiens internes, les unterschiedlichen Vorschläge spielen
tarifs plafonds, et le nombre de produits eine große Rolle, wie z.B. die Formeln

summary
sensibles et spéciaux, ne sont pas dépourvus zur Zollreduktion und zum Abbau der
d’importance. Etant donné le caractère très inländischen Stützung, die Zollobergrenzen,
technique de ces détails, il faudra mobiliser sowie die Anzahl der sensitiven und
efforts et diligence en 2006 pour éviter de besonderen Produkte. Auf Grund der
terminer la négociation par un accord par technischen Zusammenhänge bei diesen
trop creux. Einzelheiten sind bei den Verhandlungen im
Jahr 2006 Engagement und Einsatzbereitschaft
gefragt, um ein bedeutungsleeres Doha-
Ergebnis zu vermeiden.

© The Agricultural Ecomomics Society and the European Association of Agricultural Economists 2006 EuroChoices 5(2) ★ 49

5-2_06bouet.indd 49 06/07/2006 11:55:15

S-ar putea să vă placă și