Sunteți pe pagina 1din 14

This article was downloaded by: [Carnegie Mellon University]

On: 20 January 2015, At: 19:46


Publisher: Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer
House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Regional Studies
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cres20

Regional accessibility and economic potential in the


European community
a b a
David Keeble , Peter L. Owens & Chris Thompson
a
Department of Geography , University of Cambridge , Downing Place, Cambridge, CB2
3EN, UK
b
Department of Geography , University of Sheffield , S10 2TN, UK
Published online: 04 Feb 2007.

To cite this article: David Keeble , Peter L. Owens & Chris Thompson (1982) Regional accessibility and economic potential
in the European community, Regional Studies, 16:6, 419-432, DOI: 10.1080/09595238200185421

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09595238200185421

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained
in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no
representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of
the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors,
and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied
upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall
not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other
liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or
arising out of the use of the Content.
This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic
reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any
form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://
www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions
Regional Studies, Vol. 16.6 pp. 41%432.

Regional Accessibility and Economic Potential


in the European Community
DAVID KEEBLE*, PETER L. OWENSJ- AND CHRIS T H O M P S O N *
*Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, Downing Place, Cambridge, CB2 3EN,
~fDepartment of Geography, University of Sheffield, SI0 2TN, UK.

(Received August 1981)

KEEBLE D., OWENS P. L. and THOMPSON C. (1982) Regional accessibility and economic potential in the European
community, Reg. Studies16, 41%432. This paper investigates changes in regional accessibility to economic activity within the
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

European Community between 1965 and 1977 as measured by the 'economic potential' index. Potential measures proximity by
road to regional economic activity as that is geographically distributed throughout the Community, allowing for tariff barriers
and sea-ferry crossings, as well as successive enlargements to Nine in 1973 and, prospectively, to Twelve. While 1973
enlargement benefited accessibility levels in the 'new' periphery quite considerably, already severe centre-periphery disparities
in regional accessibility in general widened still further during the period, largely because of continuing concentration of
economic activity in core EC regions.

European Community Regional disparities Accessibility Economic potential

KEEBLE D., OWENS P. L. and THOMVSON C. (1982) KEEBLE D., OWENS P. L. and THOMPSON C. (1982)
L'accessibilit6 r6gionale et les potentialit6s 4conomiques au Zug~inglichkeit von Regionen und wirtschaftliches Poten-
sein de la Communaut6 Europ6enne, Reg. Studies 16, tial in der europ~iischen Gemeinschaft, Reg. Studies 16,
41%432. Cet article examine ~ partir de l'indice des 419-432. Diese Abhandlung untersucht Wandlungen in der
potentialit6s &onomiques les changements dans l'accessibi- unterschiedlichen regionalen Zug~inglichkeit innerhalb der
lit4 r4gionale ~ l'activit4 4conomique au sein de la Com- EG in der Periode 1965-1977, wie sie in der Bewertung des
munaut6 Europ6enne de 1965 h 1977. L'indice des poten- Index ffir 'Wirtschaftspotential' erscheinen. Potential heisst
tialit6s &onomiques a pour but de mesurer la proximit6 Entfernung aufdem Strassenweg von regionaler wirtschaft-
routi~re ~ l'activit4 6conomique en fonction de la r6partition licher Aktivit~it, da diese geographisch fiber das Gesamt-
de celle-l?~ sur l'espace g6ographique, en tenant compte et gebiet der Gemeinschaft hinweg verteilt ist, wobei sowohl
des barri~res douani~res et des travers6es en ferry, aussi bien Tarifbarrieren und Kosten der Schiffsfiihren als auch
que des 61argissements successifs; h savoir les 'Neuf' en 1973 sukzessive Erweiterungen auferst Neun imJahre 1973, dann
et, ce qui est pr4vu, les 'Douze'. Tandis que l'41argissement Zw61f Mitgliedstaaten in Anschlag gebracht werden. Die
qui s'est effectu6 en 1973 4tait dans l'int4r& non-n6gligeable Erweiterung des Jahres 1973 begfinstigte den Zug~inglich-
des niveaux d'accessibilit4 de la nouvelle p6riph4rie, il 4tait keitsgrad der neuen Peripherie ganz betr/ichlich, doch
d6j~ ~ noter que de lourdes in6galit4s du centre et de la ohnehin schwerwiegende Ungleichheiten vom Zentrum
p4riph6rie ~ propos de leur accessibilit6 r4gionale s'agrandis- zur Peripherie in der regionalen Zug~inglichkeit im
saient en g6n4ral au cours de cette p6riode-l~. C'&ait dfi allgemeinen versch~irften sich w/ihrend dieser Periode
notamment a la concentration soutenue de l'activit4 4cono- zunehmend weiter, haupts/ichlich wegen fortgesetzter Kon-
mique dans les r4gions centrales de la Communaut6 zentration wirtschaftlicher Aktivit~it in den Kerngebeiten
Europ4enne. der EG.
Communaut6 Europ6enne Accessibilit4 Europ~ische Gemeinschaft Regionale Ungleichheiten
In6galit6s r6gionales Potentialit6s &onomiques Zug~inglichkeit Wirtschaftspotential

INTRODUCTION poorer regions remains as intractable as ever' ( C o M -


MISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES (CEC),
Article 2 o f the 1956 Treaty o f R o m e sets the 1975, p. 5).
European C o m m u n i t y (EC) the task o f p r o m o t i n g While regional inequalities within the C o m m u n i t y
' . . . a continuous and balanced e x p a n s i o n . . . ' o f have received attention f r o m academics, national
economic activity, ' t h r o u g h o u t ' the C o m m u n i t y . governments, E C agencies, and the media t h r o u g h -
Almost two decades later however, the Regional out this period, significant concern has only de-
D e v e l o p m e n t Fund's inaugural Report admitted that veloped in recent years, for several reasons. First,
' . . . the underlying gap between the richer and there has been an increasing introspection o f the

419
420 David Keeble, Peter L. Owens and Chris Thompson
Community's progress towards its 'goals', prompted actual changes in the distribution of economic activity
by recession and a faltering in the early enthusiasm for and the removal of constraints on interaction, like
European integration. Second, progressive enlarge- tariff barriers.
ment of the Community has entailed membership for
relatively poorer nations, often with marked regional
ECONOMIC POTENTIAL ANALYSIS
problems, and in some cases already possessing a
background of regional policy experience and exper- The concept of regional potential is analogous to that
tise with which to evaluate the EC's own fledgling of electrical potential in physics, and was first
policy instruments and approaches, such as the proposed by STEWART, 1947, in his study of
post-1975 European Regional Development Fund. population distribution. It has been subsequently
Third, the 1979 transformation of the European developed and used in industrial location analysis, in
Assembly into a directly-elected Parliament, with the form of market or economic potential, by such
members representing regional constituencies, is workers as HARRIS, 1954; CLARK, 1966; and RICH,
allowing greater expressions of regional concern, 1975; 1980. The first attempt to apply economic
with Members of the European Parliament from potential to locational issues in a European context
different countries and political groupings sharing a was by CLARK, WILSON and BRADLEY, 1969, who
common interest. used it to measure the attractiveness--in terms of
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

Some writers have addressed regional issues while accessibility--of different regions to manufacturers,
investigating the theory of integration, development, and the likely effect on this accessibility of an enlarged
and centre-periphery relations (GOTTMAN, 1980; Customs Union. Their study has now been updated,
SEERS and VAITSOS, 1980). Others have treated enlarged and improved upon, by the present research.
regional topics more generally in their own right As defined by previous workers, economic poten-
(CLouT, 1981; ROMUS, 1978, 1979)or examined tial is a measure of accessibility to economic activity
systematic topics in a regional manner (MORGAN, which can be calculated by the following formula
1973; MARQUAND, 1980). Some have addressed (RICH, 1980):
specific aspects of the regional problem, for example,
n
the impacts of enlargement (SCHLAIMand YANNA-
POULOS, 1976; BIEHL, 1978; DENTON, 1981), or the P= D--~j
problems of the poorest areas (SEERS, SCHAFrER, and
KILJUNEN, 1979). Increasingly, EC regional policy
mechanisms and their effects have become a research where: Pi = the potential of region 'i',
fOCUS (SANT, 1974; MACLENNAN, 1979; YUILL, Mj = a measure of the volume of economic
ALLEN, and HULL, 1980). Much material for activity in region )",
academic evaluation has been generated by the D o = a measure of the distance, or cost of
EC itself (CEC, 1971, 1975, 1981; STRASSER, 1981; transport, between i and j.
STATISTICAL OFFICE OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUN-
ITY (SOEC), 1978, 1979), whose general openness to When summed for all 'n' regions in a trading
outside enquiry and policy of disseminating informa- community, this yields a potential value for each in
tion is a model some member-country governments units of economic activity per unit of distance, or
could perhaps follow. transport cost. Economic potential values can thus be
This article reports research into one important interpreted as representing the volume of economic
theme in this growing debate over regional problems, activity a region has access to after the cost of covering
namely the role of relative regional accessibility in the distance to that activity has been accounted for.
influencing investment decisions, and hence the rate Regions with higher potential values thus have access
and nature of economic development in different to more economic activity within a given distance
regions. This was the main focus of the 'EC than those with lower ones, and could in this respect
Centrality-Peripherality Project' in the Department of be considered to have a comparative advantage for
Geography at the University of Cambridge (KEEBLE, economic development over them. Certainly much
OWENS and THOMPSON, 1981). The extent of, and previous research and theoretical literature has argued
trends in, regional differences in relative accessibility that high relative accessibility within a trading
within the Community in recent years, were mea- community confers a comparative advantage on firms
sured using the technique of 'economic potential in the region concerned, by reducing various distance
analysis'. This generated summary indices of each costs incurred by them (on for example, products,
region's relative potential for interaction with econo- inputs and information). Conversely, firms in more
mic activity, as that is actually geographically distri- inaccessibleregions suffer a comparative disadvantagein
buted across the whole EC trading-unit. Comparison the form of higher distance costs. If such differences in
of results for different years reveals how regional accessibility and distance costs are large, and if they
accessibility has been changing, allowing for both the are significant in the creation, competitive perfor-
Regional Accessibility and Economic Potential in the European Community 421

mance, and hence growth of firms, then over a


medium or longer time scale there may emerge
differences between the nature and rate of economic
growth taking place in more accessible, as opposed to
less accessible, regions.
The pioneering study of CLARK, WILSON and
BRADLEY, 1969, used potential analysis to seek the
answers to certain specific questions. Working some
years before the UK's entry to the Community, they
were naturally enough primarily concerned with
whether ' . . . any part of Britain would be included
within the region of greatest p o t e n t i a l . . . ' in an
enlarged EC. They thus compared patterns of
potential values for three main situations (pre-Treaty,
Community of the Six, and a hypothetical Commun-
ity of the Ten) and two subsidiary conditions (cheaper
shipping costs and a Channel Tunnel). While stimu-
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

lating and valuable, their work was perforce based on


disparate and inadequate regional income data for the
early 1960s only, and involved arbitrary assumptions
about levels of tariff barriers and sea-ferry costs. The
present study has been able to use improved data for
the years 1965-77, within a more logical methodolo-
Fig. 1. Primary road network nodes and links
gy, as outlined in the following sections.
tage of being an official base, for which various
socio-economic data series, including GDP estimates,
METHODOLOGY
are published (SOEC, 1979). Moreover, the above-
The chief methodological issues raised by Commun- average regional size in the U K almost certainly
ity-wide economic potential analysis concern the results only in a less detailed potential surface for this
regional framework and system to be used, the country, rather than in any overall distortion of
definition and measurement of economic activity, average potential values relative to the rest of the
distance considerations including the extra barrier Community.
effect of sea-ferry crossings, the problem of tariff The total number of regions used in the present
barriers, and the estimation of regional self-potential. study (108) is similar to that in CLARK, WILSON and
Each of these will be considered in turn. BRADLEY'S, 1969, research (102), except that this
study has finer detail for West Germany (30 regions
now as compared to 22 before) and Denmark (3
Regions and Nodes compared to 1 earlier), and of course, Norway's
The framework of 108 regions adopted for the study regions are excluded. However the earlier work
was based on the official level-II system~ of the adopted a different approach to the selection of nodes,
nine-member Community. 2 In each region a 'node' choosing towns according to a variety of criteria,
(the major town or city) was designated, and the including geometric centrality to the region. By
volume of economic activity in the region was contrast, the present study consistently defined nodes
allocated to that location. Neighbouring nodes (in- as the economically most important city. Thus for
cluding, where appropriate, those from regions which example, London was selected as the node for the
were not contiguous) were connected by 'links', of 'South East', rather than Reading for 'Southern
which there are 357 in the final E U R 9 model (Fig. 1). England' as in the CLARK, WILSON and BRADLEY,
The official level-II E C regional classification is I969, formulation.
relatively coarse and uneven, because SOEC had to In addition to this basic EC regional framework,
accept regions defined by the different national the model included values for neighbouring countries
statistical systems. Continental regions are therefore possessing significant trading links with the Com-
generally smaller, and perhaps more representative of munity. These were: Norway, Sweden, East Ger-
functional economic areas, than the UK's 'Standard many, Czechoslovakia, Austria, Switzerland, Yugos-
Regions'. Thus Scotland and Ireland are single lavia, Spain, Greece and Portugal. National mass
regions, but so too are West Berlin and Hamburg, values were assigned to the country's largest city in
while the Netherlands, covering a smaller physical each case. However, for the E U R 12 analysis, a
area than either of the first two, is divided into eleven special regional classification was devised for Greece,
regions. However, this system does have the advan- Spain, and Portugal, given that at the time of
422 David Keeble, Peter L. Owens and Chris Thompson
working, Eurostat had not published its official regional and national economies within the Com-
breakdown for these countries. This classification munity over time much more accurately than would
defined 9 regions in Greece, 13 in Spain, and 4 in an arbitrary choice of any one year's prices and
Portugal, each with its own regionally most impor- exchange rates as a base. Moreover, it is also true that
tant city as a node. The potential model thus different national rates of price inflation are to some
recognised 108 EC regions and 10 neighbouring degree compensated for by exchange rate move-
countries for the E U R 6 and E U R 9 analyses, and 134 ments.
EC regions with 7 neighbours, for the EUR 12
analysis.
Distance measurement
The chief empirical work in calculating potential
Economic activity values centres on the estimation of the distance, or
Specifying the mass or Mj term, poses the problem of transport cost, component, D o. This involves choos-
selecting and measuring the most appropriate ing appropriate cost or distance measures, and, if
variable. Most economic potential analyses have necessary, modes o f transport and distance exponents.
measured the volume of economic activity in different Given the explicit concern of CLARK, WILSON and
regions by values of regional gross domestic product BRADLEY'S, 1969, study with the location of manufac-
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

(GDP), as the best available summary index of turing activity, they argued that the most appropriate
economic activity in all its forms. measure was an estimate of the average transport cost
The present research used official Eurostat esti- of manufactured goods shipped from the node of
mates of 1965, 1970, 1973, and 1977 regional GDP, region i to that ofregionj. They assumed a 200 mile
expressed in European Units of Account (EUAs), at limit to road movement, with journeys over this
current prices and exchange rates, on the basis of the distance being handled by rail, and also adopted an
European System of Accounts. Eurostat claim that arbitrary Value for ferry shipments as an allowance for
with the exception of the regierungsbezirke of Nord- sea crossings. However, the present research used
rhein-Westfalen and certain UK regions, these series shortest road distances between the regional and
are comparable over time. The nature of potential national nodes defined earlier. This choice reflected
calculation means that the small boundary changes the study's wider concern with regional economic
which affected these during the 1970s are unlikely to development generally, and the judgement that the
have any measurable effect on actual potential values. considerable extra time and difficulty involved in
For the E U R 12 analysis, regional GDP data obtained obtaining meaningful transport cost data was unlikely
from national sources for Spain, Portugal and Greece, to be justified in terms of appreciable differences in the
were used to allocate Eurostat's national GDP totals final potential surface.
to the regions defined in the previous section. The choice of road rather than rail distance was
The decision to express GDPs in EUAs--based on made after examination of the evolving pattern of
weighted exchange rates for a basket of European goods movement in the Community. This showed
currencies--rather than in Purchasing Power Stan- that by 1972, road transport was responsible for
dards (PPS), conversion factors for which are also handling a larger share of intra-national goods
available (SOEC, 1978), reflects the judgement that movement (measured in tonne-kilometres) than any
EUAs provide the more appropriate measure of other form of transport, in all Community countries
economic activity with regard to the possibilities for except The Netherlands and Luxembourg. In each of
trading goods (VAN DER KNAAP, 1980). PPS values the four most peripheral countries (Denmark, Ireland,
reflect national variations in the cost of living, Italy and the UK) the road transport share was over
including the indirect costs of non-traded goods and two-thirds (ROBINSON and BAMrO~D, 1978, p. 137).
services such as housing, and are therefore more a While rail movements are still important for bulky
measure of welfare and income relative to living commodities, goods movement between and within
standards in different areas. This judgement is EC countries is increasingly being handled by lorry
supported by a similar choice in the Commission's container units, given both the difficulties of transfer-
'First Periodic Report' on the regions of Europe ring consignments between different national rail
(CEC, 1981, pp. 40-2) and by the argument that from organisations, and the progressive harmonisation of
the point of view of inter-regional trade and invest- lorry transport regulations.
ment decisions, ' . . . exporters would be more Measurements of shortest road distances between
interested in the money incomes of their markets, and neighbouring nodes were based on information from
not in their purchasing power over local goods' national and European road atlases and national
(CLARKE, WILSON and BRADLEY, 1969, p. 199). motoring organisations. Computer programs then
Regional GDP was expressed in current, rather calculated the shortest paths between all possible pairs
than constant, prices and exchange rates, on the of nodes, placing over 7,000 resulting distances in a
grounds that the former reflect the real evolution of matrix for later use in the potential formula.
Regional Accessibility and Economic Potential in the European Community 423

One important limitation to the above approach to The close correspondence between these parameters
distance measurement is that no allowance was made and the ones estimated by Ric~ for the Scottish case
for changes in the quality of particular road links (160 and 2"0) is general confirmation of his argument
during the study period, for example through the that this kind of formula, ' . . . represents reasonably
construction of motorways. Incorporating such well the high break of bulk and terminal costs
changes was not feasible, given the time and resources involved in sea crossings, and their relatively low
available. However, it could be argued that road movement cost per unit of distance, as well as the
improvements during the 1960s and early 1970s in psychological barrier and inconvenience inherent in
most Community countries tended to focus on major such crossings.' (Rich, 1975, p. 67).
cities and metropolitan regions, such as Paris and
Dusseldorf. Such improvements are thus likely to
have increased the relative accessibility of central
Distance exponents
regions to Community-wide economic activity to a Various empirical research has argued that when
greater extent than the peripheral regions, whose simple distance is used in potential calculations,
motorway links are often less well-devel0ped exponents greater than unity yield better statistical fits
(KEEBtE, 1976, pp. 54--9). This qualification should with other variables, such as GDP per head. Thus
be borne in mind when evaluating subsequent results. CHISHOLM and O'SULLIVAN, 1973, p.8, argued from
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

1962 road transport data that for gravity and potential


modelling 'the appropriate empirical" distance expo-
Ferry crossings
nent for road freight in Britain is -2.5'. They
Sea-ferry crossings play a strategic role at several nonetheless chose to use an exponent of -1.0 for
points in the European transport network. For each technical reasons associated with their self-potential
potential analysis, the model included as a link, ferry calculation. RICH, 1978, found that testing for best-fit
routes which in that year provided at least one relationships in the Scottish case, with 1960s data,
roll-on/roll-off car-ferry service per day. In 1973 for yielded a typically sharp-peaked calibration curve,
example, twenty such routes were identified (includ- centred on exponent values between -1"5 and -2.5.
ing eight between the U K and the Continent, three to Since the 1960s, however, increasing speed and ease
Ireland, and two each to Corsica and Sardinia). For the ofmotorway movement, coupled with increased scale
EUR 12 analysis, ferry routes linking Greece, Spain, economies through the use of larger lorries, has
and Portugal to various parts of the Nine as well as resulted in a considerable fall in the real cost of
ferry services established in the rest of the Commun- transport, and hence friction of distance, within
ity between 1977 and 1980, were included. the EC. Simply in terms of best-fit relationships
Ferry crossings represent an additional barrier in therefore, distance exponents as great as -2"5 would
cost and time to the free flow of goods, services and be too large. In addition, sensitivity testing using
people within the Community. However the CLARK, distance exponents o f - 1"5 and 2"0, revealed that these
WILSON and BUADLEV, 1969, study found it 'ex- generate more sharply-peaked potential surfaces,
tremely difficult to reach an estimate of a representa- which in turn give much poorer statistical relation-
tive cost for shipping.' Their eventual, arbitrary, ships with other variables. Thus, for example, r2values
solution used the costs of sending 10 tons of cheap for regressions of potential against 1977 GI)P per
glassware by container between various European capita in 108 regions, were 0-453 for an exponent of
ports. By contrast, the form of the modification used 1"0, 0.322 for 1-5, and 0"280 for 2.0. Interestingly,
in the present model was originally devised by RICH, potential values based on an exponent of 0.5 also
1975, after much empirical testing in Scotland. This yielded a poor r2 relationship with GDP per capita
was in turn recalibrated for this study, using indepen- (0.381). Sensitivity testing thus supports the main
dent data given by BELL, 1979, on the actual 1978 reason for choosing an exponent of unity, namely the
land, terminal and ro-ro sea-costs, of shipping goods absence of clear theoretical justification for other
by 32-ton articulated container lorries on ferries values.
between various origins and destinations in Britain, The use of more complex expressions in the
Germany and France. Conversion of these costs into denominator of the potential equation was also
distance equivalents, on the basis of a typical 500km considered. Recent German work (HusSMAN, 1976;
journey, yielded these parameters for the formula: ADLUNg et al., 1979) has investigated two alternatives
to the standard distance term, D~=. These are:
F
R = 150 + 1"5

where F = the ferry crossing in kilometres


R = the road distance to which it is to be
converted. (1 + v)-a', (2)
424 David Keeble, Peter L. Owens and Chris Thompson
In these formulae, the parameters (5 and y represent over U K £12,000 million in that year. This average
empirically-derived constants selected to give as good value was U K £17,335, indicating that most container
a fit as possible between potential values and a loads were of high-value manufactured or semi-
'control' variable such as G D P per capita. In both the manufactured goods.
standard form and (1), the larger the constant ~ or Second, an average ad vatorem tariffrate o f 7% was
the smaller the influence o f distant G D P values on a used to calculate the actual tariff U K £1,213---which
region's potential; the converse is true for y in (2). The would have been levied on an average load from these
three terms yield different distance-decay curves for ports to a continental E C country, had the preq973
the influence of a given mass-value, and different tariffs still been in force. In reality, tariffs vary widely
levels of correlation with the control variable. HUss- in rate between different classes of commodities, but
MAN'S research (HusSMAN, 1976) found that the third other workers have calculated that ' . . . the average ad
expression gave the best fit between market potential valorem, tariffagainst the U K vis-a-vis the old EC was
and G D P per capita across 178 labour market areas in of the order of 7%' (BALL, 1974, p. 55). Both the
West Germany. In a similar analysis, Adlung's team current and pre-1973 list of C o m m u n i t y external
used a y parameter of 0'056, and obtained a correlation tariffs suggests this figure is fairly typical for a variety
coefficient of 0"81, with data for the 37 official of manufactured products, such as steel, engineering
planning regions of the Federal Republic. However, and electrical goods, and footwear.
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

since again there is no particular theoreticaljustification Third, the estimated E C tariffwas translated into a
for using either of these more complex distance road-distance equivalent, using the actual 1978 road
expressions, the present research adopted the standard transport cost value for a 500 kin journey by container
and simplest one, D o. lorry within the EC, as used in the sea-ferry
adjustment (i.e. U K £0.54 per km). This converts to a
distance-equivalent barrier of 2250 km (rounded from
Tariff barriers
2247).
That tariffbarriers do significantly inhibit trade across Fourth, this logically-derived constant was added
international boundaries is both a classic theoretical to any shortest path in the distance matrix which
expectation and an observed fact. As DALY, 1978, p. joined two regional or national nodes, across
45 points out for the U K case, ' . . . the effect of tariff whichever C o m m u n i t y boundary was in force for the
reductions on U K imports has in the past been year under consideration. This boundary application
significant, accounting for more than 33% of the total was selective, since after 1973, all adjacent European
increase in imports of semi-manufactures and over countries were granted 'special' preferential tarifrates
25% of the increase in finished goods for the period vis-a-vis the enlarged E C (with the exceptions of
1959 to 1972.' In a similar fashion, the phased removal Czechoslovakia, East Germany and Yugoslavia).
over the period 1973-7 of the previous E C - U K t a r i f Inspection o f the official list for such rates reveals that
barrier was accompanied and followed by a shift in the for virtually all commodities, the 'special' post-1973
balance and volume of U K trade towards its com- rate was zero for Greece, Portugal, Austria, Switzer-
munity partners, especially in manufactured goods. land, N o r w a y and Sweden, while for Spain it was
As a proportion of total external trade by value, U K generally two-fifths of the external rate. In the
exports to the other eight countries rose from 30"2 to post-enlargement analyses (1973 and 1977, E U R 9
37'9% over the six year period 1972-8, while imports and E U R 12) therefore, no tariffdistance barrier was
rose from 3•.6 to 40.5% (FETHERSTON,MOORE and added for journeys involving the six zero-rated
RHODES, 1980). countries, while the Spain-EUR 9 barrier was set at
As with the CLARK, WILSON and BUADLEY, 1969, 900 km, and that for the three East European countries
study, the present research thus incorporated a mentioned above at the full 2250 km.
measure of the barrier effect of the EC's common ex- Several comments may be made concerning the
ternal tariff. However, unlike the earlier study which tariff barrier calculation. First, although derived from
adopted a totally arbitrary tariff value of an additional 1978 transport figures, it can be argued that there is no
US $210 on transport costs, the current research fol- obvious basis for adjusting the precise distance
lowed a logical methodology similar to that of the identified with respect to earlier years, given the lack
ferry crossing adjustment. This involved four steps. of change in the average tariff level before and after
First, statistics were obtained from the U K Cus- 1973. Second, a sensitivity analysis with 1970 data,
toms and Excise, and from U K National Ports using a lower tariff barrier distance of 1250 km and
Council publications, on the average value (for 1970 G D P data, showed the relative ranking and
customs purposes) of a unit container-load of goods distribution of regional potential values to be very
passing through the ports of Dover and Felixstowe in similar to that obtained with the derived figure.
1978. These are the two leading ro-ro container ports Third, the tariff barrier adjustment is concerned only
for trade between the U K and the rest of the with quantifiable economic barriers to trade, whose
community, handling imports and exports valued at extent may be estimated in a logical non-arbitrary
Regional Accessibility and Economic Potential in the European Community 425

way. Clearly, actual trading patterns between coun- the smaller radius value as the better approximation to
tries may also be influenced by certain secondary reality. Thus the research adopted a constant of 0-333
non-economic considerations, such as cultural dif- with RIclt's formula, in the self-potential calcula-
ferences in taste and consumer preference, language tions.
and historic ties (e.g. within the Scandinavian coun-
tries, or between the U K and Portugal). However,
RESULTING PATTERNS OF
any attempt to incorporate such factors would
ECONOMIC POTENTIAL
necessarily be arbitrary, and in any case, increasing
economic integration within Western Europe is Regional economic potential values were .computed
diminishing their relative importance over time. with the above methodology, for 1965, 1970, and
Fourth, it is worth noting that the tariff barrier 1973 with the Community of the Six, for 1973 and
identified by the logical procedure here is in fact 1977 with the Community of the Nine, and for a
smaller than that chosen in the CLARK, WILSON and hypothetical year with the Community of the
BRADLEY, 1969, study (their US $210 translates into a Twelve. The resulting potentials, expressed in mil-
2900 km distance-equivalent, using their long- lions of EUAs per kilometre, are mapped as potential
distance rail transport cost rate of 7.2 cents per km). contours in Figs. 2-7. Each region's value is expressed
The present estimate is thus not only based on a logical as a percentage of the highest value found in the
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

procedure incorporating empirical data on the actual Community that year. Contours are interpolated at
movement of goods in the Community, but exerts a successive 10% intervals up to the maximum, which
less extreme effect upon computed potential values in each case was for Rheinhessen-Pfalz. Comparison
than that adopted arbitrarily in the earlier study. of these potential results throws light on changes in
regional accessibility over this period, and the effect
on this of enlargement and tariff barrier removal.
Self-potential
A final consideration in operationalising the potential
model is that of'self-potential', or the contribution to
The 1977pattern
the potential of region i of its own mass value. This Fig. 6 is based on the most recently available regional
reduces to the problem of adopting a non-zero GDP data, and relates to the Community of the
internal distance for region i (that is, for the special Nine's first year of full economic integration, in the
case of Dii in the array D~). sense of complete dismantling of formal tariff bar-
Various approaches have been tried in the past. riers.
RAY, 1965, adopted an arbitrary five mile distance for The most striking feature of the pattern is the wide
each areal unit, while CLARK, WILSONand BRADLEY, disparity in regional accessibility. The most inacces-
1969, defined a fixed minimum transport cost of US sible region of the Community, as defined by
$28 per 10 ton load, for each region. More recently, potential, is Calabria, which records a value (1,134.3
RICH, 1975, used the following formula: mio EUAs per km) equal to only 11.7% of that for
Rheinhessen-Pfalz (9,664'1). A further ten regions--
seven of them in Italy, (Campania, Abruzzi, Molise,
1 / area of region
Dii = 2 /~/ zr Puglia, Basilicata, Sicilia and Sardegna), plus I.reland,
Northern Ireland and Corsica--have values below
20% of the maximum. At the other extreme, twelve
which gives a distance value one-half the radius of a regions in addition to Rheinhessen-Pfalz (Hamburg,
circle the same area as region i. Dusseldorf, Koln, Arnsberg, Karlsruhe, West Berlin,
The present study tested the sensitivity of results Zuid-Holland, Noord-Brabant, Antwerpen, Bra-
obtained using RICH'S, 1975, formula to variations in bant, Hainaut, and Ile de France) achieve potential
the constant, using 0.333 instead of 0"5. This revealed values more than 60% of the maximum. These
that two small, highly-urbanised regions (West Berlin high-potential regions may thus be thought of as
and Bremen) record significant falls in rank if the being more than three times as accessible to Com-
larger internal distance is used. Fourteen other regions munity-wide economic activity in 1977 as the listed
also recorded lower potential values, but few of these low-potential regions. This disparity in accessibility,
exhibited changes in their rank order with respect to as measured by the potential index, indicates that if
other regions (e.g. Hamburg, down from 5th to 6th; accessibility is important for the location and growth
Ile de France, 4th to 5th; Dusseldorf, no change). of economic activity, these low-potential regions are
Theoretically too, as RICH, 1980, p. 26, has more at a considerable relative disadvantage within the
recently argued, the clustering of economic activity in Community.
and around the chief metropolitan centre of most A second aspect deserving comment is the geo-
officially-defined regions (e.g. London and the South graphical pattern. The map's dominant feature, as
East, Paris and Ile de France) strongly supports use of measured by the 50% potential contour, is a roughly
426 David Keeble, Peter L. Owens and Chris Thompson
triangular 'plateau' of high accessibility located in the
north-east of the Community, with corners on
Stuttgart, Hamburg and Lille. Peaks of exceptional
accessibility (over 70% of the maximum) rise from
this plateau at three points (Hamburg, Dusseldorf and
Rheinhessen-Pfalz/Karlsruhe). Three other neigh-
bouring but separate regions (South East, lie de
France, and West Berlin) form outlying peaks of
lesser, but still relatively high, accessibility. This map
therefore seems to support the popular notion of an
EC 'Golden Triangle' covering parts of West Ger-
many, Belgium and The Netherlands, at least in terms
of exceptional accessibility.
Together, the high-accessibility regions defined by
the 50% contour occupy only 10% of the total land
area but contain 30% of the population of the Nine
and no less than 40% of all Community economic
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

activity measured by GDP.


Conversely, regions of low potential, as defined
broadly by the 30% contour, are located in the
southern, western, and northern (though not eastern)
margins of the Community. On this measure, the (2184 9rnio EUAs per kin)
Community's most relatively inaccessible regions are
all geographically peripheral, and comprise most of Fig. 2. E E C regional economic potentials 1965
southern, central and north-eastern Italy, southern
and western France, northern and western Britain and
Northern Ireland, the Republic of Ireland, and
Denmark outside Storkobenhavn. While accounting
for 47% of the Community's land area and 32% of its
population, these peripheral, inaccessible, regions
contain only 22% of Community economic activity.

Regional accessibility trends, 1965-73


Comparison of results from the E U R 6 potential
analyses for the years 1965 (Fig. 2), 1970 (Fig. 3), and
1973 (Fig. 4), reveals a clear trend towards widening
regional disparities in relative accessibility. This trend
was most evident for regions of the UK, all of which
recorded quite dramatic declines in potential values
relative to the Rheinhessen-Pfalz maximum. Interes-
tingly, the relative declines in potential for Ireland and
Denmark, which were also at the time outside the
encircling tariff wall, were not as great as in the U K
case, though they were still considerable. Within the
Community of the Six itself, declines in relative
accessibility also characterised the peripheral regions 3641 7 m,oEOAsper~m,
of southern Italy and southern and western France.
Examples of the latter changes are given in Table 1. Fig. 3. E E C regional economic potentials 1970
These trends clearly reflect the relative concentra-
tion of economic growth during this period in the
Table 1. Selected peripheral region potentials, 1965-73 more central regions of the Community, which led to
1965 1970 1973 a rapid rise in central region GDP and hence relative
Calabria 12"7 12"3 10'9 economic potential This, together with the relative
Pugli a 17'4 16-7 14-8 isolation of the above peripheral regions from the EC
Midi-Pyrenees 21'8 20"6 19.1 core and the slower rates of G D P growth in them,
Bretagne 28"3 26'9 25"4 explains the trend of widening disparities in accessibil-
Note: Potentials expressed as a percent o f maximum E U R 6 value. ity levels. Table 1 also indicates that this trend
Regional Accessibility and Economic Potential in the European Community 427
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

Fig. 4. EEC regional economic potentials 1973: EU'R 6 Fig. 5. EEC regional economic potentials 1973: E U R 9
quickened appreciably between 1970 and 1973, com- Interestingly, enlargement and tariffremoval would
pared with the earlier 1965-70 period: the annual also have benefited the periphery of the original
decline in relative potential values for these regions Six proportionally more than its centre, with gains of
was between two and five times faster in the early t4-17% for the regions shown. However, this
1970s than during the second half of the 1960s. apparent differential in favour of the periphery of the
Six chiefly reflects the mathematics of percentage
The impact of the 1973 enlargement calculations in the context of very low base potentials.
In absolute terms, Table 2 shows that the gain to the
The 1973 E U R 9 map (Fig. 5) illustrates the effect of
central regions was much greater than that to the
the removal of the tariff barrier on trade following
periphery, as exemplified by the two extreme cases,
enlargement to the Nine, holding everything else--
Calabria (+93 mio E U A s per km) and Rheinhessen-
notably the regional distribution of economic activity
Pfalz (+365). This further widening of absolute
as measured by GDP--constant. In fact, the removal
disparity in accessibility to economic activity between
of the EC tariff barrier between the Six and the Three
the Six's centre and periphery, is probably due to the
was phased over a five-year transition period, with a
greater proximity of the central regions to the three
20% reduction each year. So were other measures of
new member countries. By contrast, the peripheral
Community integration. The 1973 E U R 9 map thus
records a purely hypothetical regional accessibility
Table 2. Selected regions' potentials at the 1973
surface, but nevertheless isolates the particular effect enlargement (mio EUAs per km)
of tariff barrier removal upon accessibility values.
EUR 6 EUR 9 Change
Comparison of the E U R 6 and E U R 9 situations
Abs. %
for that year (Figs. 4 and 5) reveals, as might be
Scotland 813 1233 +420 +40
expected, that complete tariff removal, ifeffected in a
Northern Ireland 1059 1583 +524 +49
single year, would have increased the relative accessi- Ireland 660 1050 +390 +59
bility to Community-wide economic activity of all Vest for Storebaelt 776 1378 +602 +76
regions--including peripheral ones--in the three new
members. However, what is perhaps surprising is the Calabria 618 711 +93 +15
scale of the increase, both absolutely and relative to Puglia 839 962 +123 +15
Midi-Pyrenees 1085 1236 + 151 +14
increases recorded by more central regions of the Six. Bretagne 1442 1685 +243 +17
As Table 2 indicates, potential values for the most
peripheral regions of the UK, Denmark and Ireland, Rheinhessen-Pfalz 5667 6032 +365 +6
would have risen by between 40-76%, compared Dusseldorf 4730 5045 +315 +7
with rates of growth in the central regions listed of lie de France 4270 4570 +300 +7
Brabant 3323 3693 +370 +11
only 6-11%.
428 David Keeble, Peter L. Owens and Chris Thompson
regions of the Three did benefit both absolutely and Table 3. Changes in selectedregions'potentials
relatively, compared with the centre: the absolute gap (mio EUAs per kin) 1973-7
in potentials narrowed following enlargement, even Potential values Potentialchange
in the extreme comparison of Rheinhessen-Pfalz as a per cent of
(+365 mio E U A s per km) and Ireland (+390). 1973-77 EUR 9 maximum
Abs. % 1973 1977
Regional accessibility trends 1973-7 Scotland +722 +59 20"4 20.2
Ireland +636 +61 17.4 17.4
Comparison of the hypothetical 1973 and actual 1977 Calabria +423 +59 11-8 11.7
E U R 9 surfaces (Figs. 5 and 6) highlights the changes Puglia +566 +59 16"0 15-8
in regional accessibility which arose from trends in the Midi-Pyrenees +783 +63 20.5 20.9
regional distribution of economic activity during this Bretagne + 1050 +62 27.9 28.3
period, since both analyses incorporated the same Rheinhessen-Pfalz +3632 +60 100.0 100.0
external tariff barrier around the Nine. Dusseldorf +3037 +60 83-6 83.6
The maps indicate that the years 1973-7 again Ile de France +2777 +61 75"8 76.0
witnessed a tendency towards widening of C o m m u n - Brabant +2656 +72 61.2 65.7
ity centre-periphery accessibility disparities. H o w -
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

ever this occurred at a much slower rate than during their percentage values. In absolute terms however, as
either the late 1960s or the early 1970s. The Table 3 indicates (see column 1), central region
widening was most evident in the case of the Italian accessibility gains were invariably still far greater than
and British peripheries. Visual comparison of the those for any peripheral region, with, at the extremes,
positions of contours shows a shift inwards towards Rheinhessen-Pfalz recording a gain nearly nine times
the central EC core in both cases (see for example the greater than that for Calabria. In absolute terms
decline of Lombardia to a value below its earlier 40% therefore, the centre-periphery accessibility differen-
level). The same is indicated by data in Table 3 for tial widened substantially during this period, as a
selected regions. Three of the more peripheral regions result of the faster growth of economic activity in
chosen record a decline in potential (expressed as a more accessible central regions.
percentage of the maximum) between 1973-7 (see
columns 3 and 4), whereas all four central regions
listed maintain or increase their relative values; the The impact of enlargement in the 1980s
increase in Brabant's percentage potential is particu- Fig. 7 maps potential values on the assumption of the
larly striking. Only in the case o f the two French further enlargement of the European C o m m u n i t y
peripheral regions was there a narrowing of the during the 1980s to include not only Greece, a
relative accessibility differential, and an increase in member since January 1981, but also Spain and
Portugal. The potential analysis uses the most recent
(1977) EC regional G D P data available for the Nine,
together with estimates for regions of Greece and the
two prospective entrants, as explained earlier. The
tariffbarrier which had been incorporated for the 1977
E U R 9 analysis between the Nine and Spain was, of
course, removed.
The chief, and inevitable, result of prospective
enlargement to Twelve is a further widening of
C o m m u n i t y regional accessibility disparities. In the
C o m m u n i t y of the Twelve (and also of the present
Ten), the lowest potential is recorded by the Aigaiou
(Aegean) region of Greece, whose value is only 7.0%
o f the E U R 12 maximum. Six other Greek regions
record potentials below 10"0%, while the highest
Greek value, for Athinai, is only 13"4% of the
maximum. Regional potentials in Spain are appre-
ciably higher than in Greece, with one region,
Cataluna, achieving a value of 22-0% o f the max-
imum, thereby placing it higher than sixteen other
regions (eleven Italian, two French, two U K , and
Ireland) in the Nine. The next highest potential within
Spain is also for a northern region bordering France
Fig. 6. E E C regional economic potentials 1977 (Vascongadas Y Navarra, 19'1%), while the lowest
Regional Accessibility and Economic Potential in the European Community 429

@
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

Fig. 7. Regional economicpotentials: EUR 12

values are for regions in the far south-west (Extrama- countries after 1973, with in effect a zero tariffbarrier
dura, 11"1%)and north-west (Galicia, 11'5%)of the in the case of goods from Greece and Portugal, and a
country. Regional potentials in Portugal are lower substantially reduced barrier against Spanish manu-
than that for Athinai, ranging from 10.7 to 12.7% of factured goods. Final removal of this barrier conse-
the maximum; the highest value is recorded by the quent upon an enlargement to Twelve would thus
Norte Litoral region centred on Porto, and the lowest benefit, in the sense of accessibility, neighbouring
value by the Sud Interior region inland from Lisbon. French regions only slightly, and central Community
The impact of enlargement to Twelve on regions regions hardly at all.
already in the Nine is small, and largely confined to
French peripheral regions bordering Spain, as illus-
CONCLUSIONS
trated by Table 4. This lack of impact reflects the
preferential treatment accorded to manufactured This study has used the methodology of economic
goods entering the EC from the prospective member potential analysis to calculate a quantitative index of
regional accessibility to economic activity within the
Table 4. Future changes in selected regions' potentials European Community which, it is suggested, can be
Potential values E U R 9 to E U R 12 used in two main ways: first, as a summary measure
(mio E U A s per km) changes implying reduced distance costs for economic activ-
E U R 9 E U R 12 Abs. % ity, and hence a degree of regional comparative
advantage for economic growth, and second, as a
Midi-Pyrenees 2019 2076 +57 +2.8
Aquitaine 2207 2213 +6 +0.3 measure of how regional accessibility to economic
Languedoc-Roussillon 2263 2324 +61 +2.7 activity has changed over time, and with the removal
of tariff barriers to economic interaction.
Rheinhessen-Pfalz 9664 9672 +8 +0.1 When calculated for the official level-II regions of
Dusseldorf 8082 8085 +3 +0.0
the Community, the index highlighted wide---and
430 David Keeble, Peter L. Owens and Chris Thompson

widening--disparities in accessibility, between high- bility within a trading C o m m u n i t y such as the E C is


potential central regions and low-potential peripheral important in reducing distance costs for economic
regions. This was found to be not only a statistical activity, and hence in influencing investment deci-
artefact resulting from entry of successively poorer sions and the rate and nature of economic growth,
nations, but also a trend affecting peripheral regions of then the peripheral regions of the Nine are becoming
long-standing membership. increasingly disadvantaged relative to central loca-
Currently, the pattern of regional potentials within tions. To that extent, this study's analyses lend further
the C o m m u n i t y is characterised by a triangular weight to the concern over widening regional econo-
plateau of high accessibility in its north-east m mic disparities n o w being expressed in official and
reminiscent of the popular 'Golden Triangle' notion--- academic circles, disparities which constitute one of
with outlying secondary peaks o f relatively high the most fundamental problems facing the European
accessibility around Paris, London and West Berlin. C o m m u n i t y in the eighties.
Extensive areas of low potential are located in the
south, west, and northern periphery. Acknowledgements--The research on which this article is
This basic pattern reflects historic processes of based was jointly sponsored by the Directorate-General for
industrialisation, urbanisation and investment in fixed Regional Policy in the Commission of the European
capital, which have been operating for at least two Communities, and the UK Department of Industry. The
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

authors would like especially to thank: Bert van der Knaap,


centuries. It is not therefore surprising that the
Andrea Cendali-Pignatelli and David Rich, research consul-
contour maps presented here, covering only a short tants to the project, together with Hugh Quigley, Judith
period, exhibit no striking changes in the broad Marquand, and other members of the Commission of the
pattern of regional accessibility. Nonetheless, what is EC and the UK Department of Industry, for helpful
clear from them is the trend towards widening comments throughout the study; John Evelyn of the
regional disparity during the 1965-70 period, which Ipswich Port Authority, Mine Franchi of Eurostat, Roy
became more pronounced from 1970-3. Tariff Bradshaw and Simoes Lopes, for access to unpublished data;
removal as the Six became the Nine then widened Graham Chapman for help with computer programming;
further the disparity between the centre and periphery and Arthur Shelley and Pamela Morgan-Lucas for carto-
of the Six, but to a lesser degree from 1973-7 than graphic assistance.
earlier. In terms of accessibility, C o m m u n i t y enlarge-
ment in 1973 actually benefited the periphery of the NOTES
Three more than it did the centre. Future enlargement 1. See SOEC, 1980, for the full list. Data problems for
to Twelve will inevitably widen disparities still certain German regions necessitated reduction of the 112
further because of the nature of the prospective EC level-lI regions to 108: Aurich, Stade, Osnabruck,
entrants' economies, but the impact for the regions of and Oldenburg were amalgamated to form Weser-Ems,
the Nine will be small. and Hildesheim was incorporated into Braunschweig.
These findings thus suggest that if relative accessi- 2. Abbreviated in official publications to 'EUR 9'.

REFERENCES
ADLUNC R., GOTZINGERH., LAMMERSK., SCHATZK-W., SEITZJ. and THOROE C. (1979) Konzeption Und Instrumente
Einer Potentialorientierten Regionalpolitik, Institut fur Kommunalwissenschaften der Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung E. V., St.
Augustin.
BALLR. J. (1974) The prospects for the UK economy, in BEESLEYM. and HAGUED. C. (Eds.) Britain in the Common Market:
a New Business Opportunity pp. 51-68. Longman, London.
BELLJ. (1979) Market factors relevant in considering capital development of port RORO facilities, Unpublished Research
Report, London Business School.
BIEHL D. (1978) The impact of enlargement on regional development and regional policy in the European Community,in
WALLACE W. and HEVREMANN 1. (Eds.) A Community of Twelve? The Impact of Further Enlargement on the European
Communities. De Tempel, Bruges.
CHISHOLMM. and O'S tJLLIVANP. (1973) FreightFlows and Spatial Aspectsof the British Economy. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
CLARK C. (1966) Industrial location and economic potential, Lloyds Bank Review 82, 1-17.
CLARK C., WILSONF. and BRADLEYJ. (1969) Industrial location and economic potential in Western Europe, Reg. Studies 3,
197-212.
CLOUT H. (1981) Regional Development in Western Europe. Wiley, Chichester.
COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES(1971) Regional Development in the European Community: Analytical Survey.
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg GD.
COMMISSIONOF THE EOROVEANCOMMUNITIES(1975) European regional development fund, first Annual Report, Bulletin of
the European Communities, Supplement 7/76, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg
GD, (and annually thereafter).
Regional Accessibility and Economic Potential in the European community 431
COMMISSIONOF THE EUROPEANCOMMUNITIES(1981) The Regions of Europe, First Periodic Report, Directorate-General for
Regional Policy, Commission of the European Communities, Brussels.
DALY A. E. (1978) UK visible trade and the Common Market Nat. Inst. Econ. Rev. 86, 42-54.
DENTON G. (1981) Regional divergence and policy in the Community, with special reference to enlargement, in HODGES M.
and WALLACEW. (Eds.) EconomicDivergence in the European Community, pp. 135-50. Royal Institute of International Affairs,
Allen and Unwin, London.
FETHERSTON M., MOORE B. and RHODES J. (1980) Britain, in SEERS D. and VAITSOS C. (Eds.) Integration and Unequal
Development: the Experience of the EEC, pp. 136-54. Macmillan, London.
GOTTMANNJ. (1980) Centre and Periphery: Spatial Variation in Politics. Sage/Focus, Beverley Hills.
HALL P. and HAY D. (1980) Growth Centres in the European Urban System. Heinemann Educational, London.
HARRIS C. (1954) The Market as a factor in the localization of industry in the United States, Ann. Ass. Am. Geogr. 44, 31548.
HUSSMAN E. (1976) Das Lagepotential dee Arbeitsmarktregionen der Bundesrepublik, Die Weltwirtschaft H1, 66-80.
KEEBLE D. (1976) Industrial Location and Planning in the United Kingdom. Methuen, London.
KEEBLE D., OWENS P. L. and THOMPSON C. (1981) The influence of peripheral and central locations on the relative
development of Regions: final Report, Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, on behalf of the
Directorate-General for Regional Policy, Commission of the European Communities, and the U K Department of Industry.
VANDER KNAAP G. (1980) The Centre-Periphery Model and EconomicPotentialAnalysis. Economic Geography Institute, Erasmus
University, Rotterdam.
Downloaded by [Carnegie Mellon University] at 19:46 20 January 2015

MACLENNANM. (1979) Regional policy in a European framework, in MACLENNAND. and PARRJ. (Eds.) Regional Policy: Past
Experience and New Directions pp. 245-71, Martin Robertson, Oxford.
MARQUAND J. (1980) The role of the tertiary sector in regional policy, Regional Policy Series no. 19, Commission of the
European Communities Studies Collection, Brussels.
MORGAN E. (1973) Regional problems and common currencies, Lloyds Bank Review 110, 19-30.
RAY D. (1965) Market potential and economic shadow, Research Paper No. 101, Department of Geography, University of
Chicago.
RICH D. (1975) Accessibility and economic activity: a study oflocational disadvantage in Scotland, unpublished PhD Thesis,
University of Cambridge.
RICH D. (1978) Population potential, potential transportation cost and industrial location, Area 10, 222-6.
RICH D. (1980) Potential models in Human Geography, Geoabstracts 26, Norwich.
ROBINSON H. and BAMFORD C. G. (1978) The Geography of Transport. MacDonald and Evans, Plymouth.
ROMUS P. (t978) Economie Regionale Europ~enne, 3rd edition. Presses Universitaires de Bruxelles.
ROMUS P. (1979) L'Europe et les Regions. Editions Labor, Bruxelles.
SANT M. (1974) Regional Policy and Planningfor Europe. Saxon House, D. C. Heath, Farnborough Hants.
SCHLAIM A. and YANNOPOULOS G. (1976) The EEC and the Mediterranean Countries. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
SEERS D., SCHAEFER B. and KILJUNEN M. (1979) Underdeveloped Europe: Studies in Core-Periphery Relations. Institute of
Development Studies, Harvester Press, Sussex.
SEERS D. and VAITSOS C. (1980) Integration and Unequal Development: the Experience of the EEC. Macmillan Press, London.
SOEC (1978) National Accounts USA, Aggregates 1960-77 Office des Publications Officielles des Communaut~s Europ6enes,
Luxembourg GD.
SOEC (1979) Regional Statistics: Population, Employment, Living Standards, 1977 Office des Publications Officielles des
Communaut6s Europ~enes, Luxembourg GD.
SOEC (1980) Codification des Unites Territorials Statistiques: Etat au 1/6/80, Mimeo, Luxembourg GD.
STEWARTJ. Q. (1947) Empirical mathematical rules concerning the distribution and equilibrium of population. Geogr. Rev.
37, 461-85.
STRASSER D. (1981) The Finances of Europe, European Perspectives Series, Office for Official Publications of the European
Communities, Luxembourg GD, Commission of the European Communities.
YUILL D. and ALLEN K. (1980) European Regional Incentives: 1980. European Regional Policy Monitoring Unit, Centre for the
Study of Public Policy, University of Strathclyde, Glasgow.
YUILL D., ALLEN K. and HULL C. (1980) Regional Policy in the European Community. Croom Helm, London.

S-ar putea să vă placă și