Sunteți pe pagina 1din 18

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/222561060

The “New” Kerala Model: Lessons for Sustainable Development

Article  in  World Development · April 2001


DOI: 10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00119-4

CITATIONS READS

109 1,692

1 author:

Véron René
University of Lausanne
33 PUBLICATIONS   861 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

In/formal urbanism: Cases drawn from Delhi View project

SSHRC Restructuring social space in India View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Véron René on 09 May 2019.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


World Development Vol. 29, No. 4, pp. 601±617, 2001
Ó 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/01/$ - see front matter
PII: S0305-750X(00)00119-4

The ``New'' Kerala Model: Lessons for Sustainable


Development
RENE  VERON
 *
University of Cambridge and Keele University, UK
Summary. Ð The ``Kerala model of development'' has won wide international attention for its
achievements in regard to social development and, to a certain extent, environmental sustainability.
The ``old'' Kerala model, preoccupied with redistributive policies, failed, however, to induce
economic development. As a result, attention is now being given to a ``new'' Kerala model. The new
policy explicitly seeks reconciliation of social, productive and environmental objectives at the local
level, and tries to develop synergies between civil society, local governmental bodies and the state
government. The new Kerala model thus holds important lessons for participatory, community-
based sustainable development in India and elsewhere. Ó 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights
reserved.

Key words Ð sustainable development, environment, decentralization, participatory development,


Asia, India

1. INTRODUCTION pollution. A careful appraisal of Kerala's


environmental conditions indicates a mixed
Since the late 1970s, a number of interna- record (Veron, 2000). In terms of sustainable
tional development scholars have held up the development, what is more important than the
south Indian state of Kerala as a ``model of allegedly achieved environmental sustainabil-
development'' (cf. Ratcli€e, 1978; Morris & ity, are the recent policies of Kerala's state
McAlpin, 1982; Amin, 1991; Franke & Chasin, government, nongovernmental organizations
1994). Indeed, Kerala's development has been (NGOs) and popular movements.
remarkable during the past four decades: In the 1990s, a ``new'' Kerala model began to
Public action, including both progressive state emergeÐone that promised to better integrate
interventions and popular movements, has sustainable-development goals into policy-
brought about high levels of social develop- making, and to go beyond mere state regulation
ment and improved living conditionsÐpartic- (setting and monitoring environmental stan-
ularly for lower classesÐin spite of low per dards) to include community-based strategies
capita income and nearly stagnant economic for environmental protection. The new policy
growth rates (Ramachandran, 1997). approach comprises decentralized administra-
Recent studies, however, have questioned the tion; participatory planning combining
sustainability of the ``Kerala model'' in light of productive and environmental objectives; and
an unfolding ®scal crisis due to economic collaboration between the state, NGOs and
stagnation and rising social expenditure civic movements. This far-reaching experiment
(George, 1993). Indeed, researchers as well as holds important lessons about opportunities
politicians have generally acknowledged that and limitations of community-based sustain-
these economic weaknesses threaten the able development.
sustainability of Kerala's welfare policies and, Section 2 of this paper clari®es the concept of
in fact, the ``old'' Kerala model. sustainable development, and introduces policy
Environmental sustainability has been held
up as another characteristic of the Kerala
model (Parayil, 1996). Most studies, however,
have tended to overemphasize positive aspects * I am grateful to Govindan Parayil, K.T. Rammohan,
of Kerala's environmental record such as the Antonito Paul and an anonymous referee for their
low level of resource consumption, low popu- invaluable comments on earlier drafts. Final revision
lation growth rates and moderate industrial accepted: 7 November 2000.
601
602 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

approaches towards this objective, including social capital (World Bank, 1997). Sustain-
the community-based strategy and the model of ability, or the capability of future generations
co-management of resources. Section 3 exam- to meet their needs, is ensured when the total
ines features and limitations of the old Kerala stock of these assets remains constant or is
model, and discusses the current policy trend increased in the production process. Natural
towards a new Kerala model. Section 4 ana- capital and social capital have generally been
lyzes old and new community-based initiatives undervalued because both are public goods or
to achieve sustainable development in Kerala, ``club goods'' (i.e., goods that are indivisible
including discussion of state action, the role of but exclude nonmembers), respectively (Pretty,
environmental NGOs, grassroots action and 1998).
environmental ethics. Section 5 analyzes how Development theory has commonly
the recent campaign for democratic decentral- acknowledged that economic and social devel-
ization has addressed common failures of opment are interrelated. Economic growth is
community-based strategies and ``community desirable because it makes poverty alleviation
failures'' (e.g., failure to include people's easier (Joshi, 1996). Growth is key in providing
participation in de®ning development priori- the means to meet basic needs, to ease poverty,
ties; community failure to address the needs of and to generate employment. It nearly always
future generations; failure to overcome con¯icts reduces absolute poverty, but it can have varied
between local interest groups; failure to reduce impact on inequality and not everybody bene-
spatial externalities and to consider broader ®ts from it (Fields, 1999). Economic sustain-
political, economic and ecological structures), ability in terms of sustained macroeconomic
and in how far the new Kerala model has been growth is thus a necessary, but not a sucient,
successful in overcoming these shortcomings. condition for sustainable development in
In conclusion, I argue that the new Kerala developing countries. An even distribution of
model holds some important lessons for growth and of access to resources is equally
community-based sustainable development and important. If, on the contrary, there are strong
co-management of environmental resources, in economic inequalities, ``growth without devel-
particular by utilizing synergies between opment'' as well as social and political unrest
government and civil society at the local level. are likely to occur, signifying unsustainable
But, failure to implement complementary development.
regulatory and price instruments for environ- Furthermore, social development, apart from
mental protection at the state level limits being an end in itself, is also a means to
Kerala's ability to achieve sustainable devel- promote economic growth. Dreze and Sen
opment. (1997) have argued that the expansion of social
opportunity is key to development. Extension
of basic education, better health care, more
2. SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT e€ective land reforms and greater access to
provisions of social security would enable the
(a) The role of natural, human and social capital marginalized sections of society to lead a less
restricted life and, also, to make better use of
A widely accepted de®nition of ``sustainable markets (Dreze & Sen, 1997). The expansion of
development'' put forward by the World social opportunity calls for public action, both
Commission on Environment and Develop- from the state and the civil society. But, lack of
ment (WCED) is as follows: ``Sustainable economic growth and ®scal crisis often a€ect
development is development that meets the the political will of governments to invest in
needs of the present without compromising the social services such education and health
ability of future generations to meet their own (Weiner, 1999). NGOs and community orga-
needs'' (WCED, 1987, p. 43). While the ®rst nizations have limited resources and reach for
part of this de®nition relates to conventional replacing crucial state services. What is needed
economic and social objectives of development, for sustainable development, therefore, are
the second part incorporates a long-term view, both an active state enhancing social opportu-
including consideration of environmental nity and a strong economic basis.
issues. It has become common to isolate four Recently, the importance of social capital,
factors that determine sustainable develop- including trust, norms of reciprocity and
ment: natural capital, physical or produced networks of civic engagement, has been stressed
capital, human capital, and more recently, for the success of development (Putnam, 1993;
THE NEW KERALA MODE 603

World Bank, 1997). As a result, ``social that is, to what degree growth implies the
sustainability'' has received new meaning, depletion of nonrenewable resources and
building on previous attention to socially the overuse of renewable resources, including
negative consequences of development and of the ``sink capacity'' (the regenerative capacity
environmental conservation. Now, social of the environment to absorb waste). To some
sustainability includes the strengthening of extent, growth can be made more environ-
community-based collective action for achiev- mentally sustainable and resource-ecient
ing the goal of sustainable development. For through the development of appropriate tech-
example, in an environmental context, there is nologies and substitutes for nonrenewable
already evidence of local user groups playing a resources (Pearce & Warford, 1993).
key role in regard to sustainable water and Yet sustainable development also suggests
forest management (World Bank, 1997). that many environmental problems might
The main contribution of the sustainable- actually originate from the lack of development
development debate has been to draw attention (i.e., that poverty might be a primary cause of
to environmental factors and consequences of environmental degradation) and that environ-
development. Some authors have also stressed mental degradation can, in turn, reinforce
the intrinsic value of nature (e.g., Sessions, poverty (i.e., the poor, whose livelihoods are
1995). This paper focuses, however, on the often directly dependent on natural resources,
instrumental value of environmental sustain- might be hit most severely by environmental
ability for long-term human development, and degradation). High local and global inequality
thus takes an anthropocentric view (cf. Arts, in wealth and access to resources can also lead
1994). to the unsustainable use of resources and to
Environmental sustainability includes the overconsumption by the a‚uent (WCED,
upkeep or improvement of essential ecological 1987).
processes, biological diversity, and the natural In sum, the concept of sustainable develop-
resource base. Environmental sustainability is ment suggests a potentially positive relation-
important for development because we humans ship between socioeconomic development and
are, through our bodies, part of nature. Thus, environmental sustainability. Indeed, the
the environment is important for our survival, discourse of the 1980s and 1990s has been
health and social life (Veron, 1999). Human life about how development and environment can
relies on natural capital for food production, be reconciled, and how sustainable develop-
drinking water, energy, etc. Air and water ment can be achieved (Lele, 1991). This stands
quality have a signi®cant impact on human in contrast to environmentalists of the 1960s
health. In developing countries the connections and 1970s who drew attention to contradictions
between health and environment are particu- between development and environmental
larly strong because growing agro-industrial protection, and to ``deep ecology'' that funda-
pollution and risks added to the environmental mentally rejects the compatibility of the
health problems rooted in underdevelopment modernistic project of development with envi-
(Smith, 1997). ronmental preservation (Sessions, 1995).
In order to become sustainable, economic
and social development should therefore retain (c) Strategies for sustainable development
or improve the ecological and resource poten-
tial to support future generations; and devel- The emphasis on natural and produced
opment of one group should have no capital has also been re¯ected in the widely
irrevocable, noncompensable adverse (envi- advocated market-based instruments to achieve
ronmental) e€ects on contemporaries. sustainable development, in addition to devel-
oping environmentally friendly technologies in
(b) Mainstream concept industry, agriculture, transportation, etc. 1
OECD countries in particular have considered
The mainstream concept of sustainable the introduction of price incentives and market-
development has focused on the relation based measures, such as environmental taxes,
between natural and produced capital. Propo- tradable emission permits and bonus-malus
nents of this concept have rejected the notion systems. These measures are generally guided
that economic growth inevitably leads to envi- by the ``polluter pays'' principle, and have
ronmental degradation. Rather, the outcome complemented the conventional method of
depends on the nature of economic growth; regulatory instruments (or ``command-and-
604 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

control'' instruments), such as emission stan- increased involvement of civil society, including
dards, permissions and prohibitions. For less- NGOs and popular movements.
developed countries, however, regulatory and Decentralization does not, however, always
market-based instruments tend to be ine€ective lead to the desired participation of marginal-
because of state failure to control environ- ized sections of society. Empirical research has
mental standards, and market failure to give shown that decentralization can reinforce
the right price signals. vested interests in existing patterns of patron-
As an alternative, the consensus emerging age if there is no synergy between local
from the United Nations Conference on Envi- government, civil society and an active central
ronment and Development in Rio in 1992 government that is committed to support the
recommended a community-based strategy mass of the local people in the struggle against
(Leach, Mearns, & Scoones, 1997). Sustainable local powerholders (Tendler, 1997; Crook &
environmental management can only occur Manor, 1998).
where active local-level support and participa- Potential synergies between the state and civil
tion exist. Particularly in less developed coun- society have been stressed by models of ``co-
tries, community participation is believed to be production'' (e.g., Ostrom, 1996; Lam, 1996).
the most e€ective strategy because people These synergies can emerge if ``complementa-
depend directly on their local physical envi- rity'' (of resources, access, skills, technologies)
ronment and thus have a genuine interest in and intimate connections and mutual trust
protecting it (Ghai & Vivian, 1992). Research between public ocials and citizens
on indigenous technical knowledge suggests (``embeddedness'') exist (Evans, 1996). While
that local communities are key to ®nding Putnam has looked at social capital as an
solutions for environmental problems. Often, institutional endowment that is established
local communities developed technologies that over a long period of time, models of co-pro-
are well adapted to local socioeconomic and duction have stressed the possibility of
environmental conditions (Gibbon, Lake, & constructing new institutions of cooperation.
Stocking, 1995). Such an approach tries to For example, synergetic interaction between
make better use of (renewable) human and government organizations and civic user
social capital than the regulatory and market- groups can lead to ecient production and
based instruments. 2 management of particular public goods, such as
Because of their locally adapted technical irrigation and drinking-water systems, graze-
knowledge and (assumed) positive social capi- lands, forests, education and health systems (cf.
tal in form of trust and norms of reciprocity, Ostrom, 1990).
local communities are regarded as appropriate Particularly in cases where indigenous
units to restore and manage their local envi- community management does not exist
ronment. But the pursuit of community-based (anymore), co-production or ``co-manage-
sustainable development requires ``a political ment'' becomes relevant for achieving
system that secures e€ective citizen participa- community-based sustainable development.
tion in decision making'' (WCED, 1987, p. 65). Co-management of resources (i.e., appropriate
Decentralization seems an adequate instrument sharing of planning, ®nancing and implemen-
for providing the appropriate political system tation responsibilities) between local commu-
for this purpose. It is commonly argued that nities and the state has therefore been
locally elected representatives know the local advocated as an e€ective strategy to promote
situation and are thus better positioned to sustainable development.
deliver certain public services than authorities The state of Kerala has recently carried out a
at the national level. Physical proximity makes comprehensive decentralization program that
it easier for citizens to put pressure on local encourages comprehensive citizen participation
ocials and to hold them accountable for their in decision making and in project implementa-
performance. There has also been a rising tion. Democratic decentralization has explicitly
interest in decentralization because liberaliza- included environmental goals in its policy
tion and globalization in the 1990s have approach. This makes Kerala a particularly
undercut the scope for governance at the interesting case for studying the community-
national level (Evans, 2000). Many organiza- based strategy for sustainable development.
tions, therefore, advocate democracy, decen- Even before Kerala embarked on its decen-
tralization of administration and planning, tralization program, it has been suggested that
more responsibility for local communities, and this state comes ``closest to the sustainable
THE NEW KERALA MODE 605

development ideal in practice'' (Parayil, 1996, education appears to have had a positive
p. 953). Some typical environmental problems in¯uence on children's health and reduced
of India are less apparent in Kerala because of fertility rates. Furthermore, formal education
high rainfall, distributed more evenly between has contributed to higher social mobility of
the seasons, and a topography that has low-caste people and to better opportunities for
hindered the wide expansion of environmen- migration. The advances in the ®eld of social
tally unsustainable Green Revolution technol- development have failed, however, to spur
ogies (Veron, 2000). economic development. Kerala's per capita
Kerala does not face a severe ecological state domestic product of about Rs. 8,200
crisis, but environmental problems have (about US$270) in 1994±95 and average annual
become more apparent and have started to growth rate of 0.3% during 1980±90 were very
a€ect environmental sustainability. The most low, even below the Indian average. 4
important environmental problems are caused Kerala's unique development pattern and its
by deforestation incurred in previous decades, outstanding accomplishments, achieved with
ongoing paddy conversions and disruption of little foreign aid, have gained respect in inter-
backwater ecosystems. Of growing concern are national circles. This kind of development
also the ``chemicization'' of agriculture, pollu- through public action has become known as the
tion of water and soils, urbanization and air ``Kerala model of development.''
pollution by growing vehicle trac. Further- Already in the 1950s and 1960s, the indica-
more, increasing consumerism in Kerala and tors of social development exceeded those of
rising imports from other states, boosted by the other Indian states. Since then, much more
in¯ux of Gulf remittances, suggest that Kerala progress has been achieved at low levels of
increasingly externalizes environmentally income through appropriate state interven-
unsound industrial production (Veron, 2000). tions, mainly by Communist-led state govern-
ments, and e€ective popular movements
(Ramachandran, 1997). State interventions
3. FROM THE ``OLD'' TO THE ``NEW'' have comprised important welfare policies and
KERALA MODEL social reforms such as the e€ective public
distribution of food, systematic extension of
(a) Standard arguments for the Kerala model public health and education facilities, and
e€ectual land reforms. Governments often
Kerala is located in the southwest of the acted in response to popular pressure. Popular
Indian subcontinent, on a narrow strip of land movements, including the caste-based reform
between the Arabian Sea and the Western organizations of the late 19th and early 20th
Ghats. The state covers an area of approxi- centuries and the class-based peasant and labor
mately 39,000 km2 (more than the size of associations in the second half of the 20th
Taiwan). According to the 1991 Census of century, struggled e€ectively for social justice
India, Kerala has about 29 million inhabitants. and radical reforms (Franke & Chasin, 1994).
The population density is among the highest in Kerala o€ers some general lessons on how
the world: 747 persons per km2 , as compared appropriate public action can improve social
with 267 in India as a whole. opportunities. Unlike an independent nation,
Kerala has become well known for its unique this subnational entity even had limited scope
development pattern. Despite its poverty in for taking action. Kerala cannot, however, o€er
terms of economic indicators, the state displays an easily reproducible model for other coun-
a set of very high social indicators of develop- tries because of particular historical and
ment that are outstanding in comparison with geographical contingencies and conditions that
the rest of India. Since Kerala's development facilitated the development of positive social
achievements have been widely discussed else- capital and the emergence of popular move-
where (e.g., Ramachandran, 1997), this article ments, creating strong accountability of the
mentions some remarkable characteristics only state (Sen, 1992). Stressing the importance of
very brie¯y. For example, Kerala's life expec- public action, the proponents of the Kerala
tancy of 72 years, infant-mortality rate of 13 model furthermore tended to neglect the
per 1,000 life births, and literacy rate of 91% substantial in¯uence of Gulf remittances since
follow only slightly behind those of industrial- 1973 in alleviating poverty. 5 Since the 1980s,
ized countries. 3 Apart from being important more attention has also been paid to Kerala's
for gender equality, the inclusion of women in development failures. Some now question
606 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

whether this state, or what I call the ``old'' opment so that Kerala can become a real
Kerala model, really represents an example of example of development.
development.
(c) The ``new'' Kerala model
(b) Limitations of the old Kerala model
Recent policy trends, including increased
Kerala's great social potential for economic attention to productive needs and democratic
development in form of human and social decentralization, may constitute the beginning
capital has not translated into actual achieve- of a ``new'' Kerala model. Local self-govern-
ments in the productive sphere. Economic and ment and decentralized planning were imposed
other failings include industrial backwardness; by amendments in India's constitution in 1992.
agricultural stagnation; massive ``educated'' Like other states, Kerala passed the corre-
unemployment; persistent poverty, especially sponding legislation (the Kerala Panchayat Raj
among tribal populations, the ®sherfolk, Tamil Act of 1994), held local elections in the three
labor migrants, elderly women and widows; tiers of panchayats at the village, block and
high and still rising suicide rate among young district levels (in 1995), and delegated 29
people (Prakash, 1994; Iyer, 1996). administrative functions to the local bodies.
The economic stagnation has been explained Kerala has, however, taken the national direc-
by the following: overemphasis on redistribu- tives for decentralization more seriously.
tion and welfare policies; quick responses to Remarkable compared with other decentral-
populist demands due to political stalemate; ization initiatives in India and abroad is that
inconsistent polices of successive state govern- Kerala's left-coalition government decided in
ments; discriminatory policies of the center August 1996 to allocate 35±40% of its annual
towards Kerala regarding the allocation of budget for new development plans to projects
public sector investment; power shortage; labor designed by the local bodies themselves.
militancy; 6 inappropriate curricula of higher Administrative decentralization was accompa-
education; use of Gulf remittances to catch up nied by ®nancial devolution and the provision
with consumption rather than to invest in to ensure participation of citizens, panchayats
production; and excessive party-politicization and municipalities in the formulation and
down to the local level (Oommen, 1993; Prak- implementation of development plans.
ash, 1994; George, 1997). In contrast to the World Bank formula for
Kerala's economic stagnation has resulted in successful decentralization (World Bank, 1999),
an increasing scarcity of ®nancial resources to Kerala's ®nancial devolution did not follow
pay for costly welfare schemes such as prior institutional design for the division of
pensions, unemployment relief and the public functional responsibilities between the local
distribution system of food (George, 1993). The governments and the state government. Rather,
®scal crisis together with the underdevelopment the actual practice of participatory planning
of productive sectors and the high reliance on and implementation in the context of a mass
Gulf money have threatened the sustainability campaign is expected to evolve into an e€ective
of the old Kerala model with its redistributive system of functional division that should
policies and radical reforms. The emerging eventually inform the institutional design and
consensus among scholars and politicians in administrative structure (Isaac, 2000).
Kerala suggests that the current development Although Kerala has now reached the stage of
priorities are to strengthen the production basis institutionalization, agency was put before
and to realize economic growth in order to structure during 1996±99.
overcome unemployment and to sustain the The new decentralized and democratic
outstanding social achievements made in the development planning gave people's participa-
past (Veron, 2000). tion and NGOs a bigger roleÐat the expense of
Yet Kerala's human capital, particularly its top-down planning by line departments
educated and skilled workforce, could be a (George, 1997). Government ocers were,
good basis for economic growth. In turn, however, included in the planning process.
achievements in the spheres of social justice, Indeed, planning was particularly successful
redistribution of assets, education and health where committed local government ocers
may ensure that increased attention to played an active role (see below). Furthermore,
productive aspects would not lead to ``growth the budgets of the line departments were not
without development'' but to equitable devel- cut signi®cantly. To a large extent, the steep
THE NEW KERALA MODE 607

expansion of the state budget from 15.6 billion preneurs and workers have been achieved
Rupees in 1995±96 to 22 billion Rupees in through successful mediation by the state
1996±97 and to 28.6 billion Rupees in 1997±98 (Heller, 2000). The new Kerala model seems to
provided the means for ®nancial devolution. have contributed to higher annual growth rates
This raises doubts about the ®scal sustainability of 6±7% in the 1990s (Franke & Chasin, 2000).
of the modelÐan issue rarely discussed by the The following sections will discuss whether
proponents of the new Kerala model. environmental goals could also be achieved
The new model seems to rely on the same through participatory strategies.
basics as the old Kerala model: development
through public action by a responsible state
and e€ective popular participation. But, unlike 4. THE JOURNEY TOWARD
the old Kerala model, the emphasis of state SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT
policies has, to a certain extent, been shifting
from welfare to participatory growth, and from (a) Previous community-based initiatives
top-down intervention to bottom-up planning.
Furthermore, the reformists, who currently Prior to the start of decentralized planning in
seem to have the upper hand in Kerala's 1996, Kerala's state government had initiated
present left-coalition government, are pursuing participatory-development programs with an
a di€erent kind of popular participation than environmental component. These initiatives
the previous class-based mobilizationÐwhich were carried together with Kerala's most
included the very successful land-reform in¯uential NGO, the Kerala People's Science
movement of the 1960s and 1970s as well as the Movement (Kerala Sastra Sahitya Parishad,
trade-union movement that has existed since KSSP), which has promoted environmental
the 1930s. Recognizing the economic protection for the past 25 years. 7 The most
contradictions of labor militancy, the left now signi®cant programs were ``group farming'' and
seeks class compromises and corporatist the ``people's resource mapping program.''
arrangements (Heller, 1995). New participatory The group-farming program was initiated by
development programs, initiated by the the left-coalition state government in 1989 with
reformist wing of the left, try to overcome class the primary aim of improving agricultural
con¯ict and party politics at the local level by growth and food self-suciency in Kerala.
emphasizing joint productive interests, and so Group farming was expected to reduce
attempt to build up broad alliances and medi- production costs and raise productivity of
ating bodies in which di€erent interest groups paddy cultivation, thus preventing paddy
are represented. Planning itself suggests a conversions. The Department of Agriculture,
system that is based on deliberation and nego- providing ®nancial and technical assistance
tiation rather than agitation. Moreover, through its newly decentralized local extension
decentralized planning seeks to include all oces, motivated paddy farmers of the same
adults of a village panchayat as citizens and not micro-watershed to take up collective farm
on the basis of class or political aliation. operations and to purchase jointly such farm
At the onset in 1996, decentralized partici- inputs as chemical fertilizers and mechanical
patory planning explicitly aimed at increasing tillers. Furthermore, the farmers were asked to
production and productivity in agriculture; form committees, and local corporatist bodies
alleviating ecological problems, including the comprising farmers, agricultural workers and
depletion and pollution of resources; improving bureaucrats were set up. But, group farming
the quality of social infrastructure; tackling failed in most cases. Not only did interests
gender injustice and deprivation of tribal between farmers and agricultural workers
populations and ®sherfolk. The challenge to diverge, but also common interests among
accelerate industrialization and to develop the fellow farmers usually did not go beyond
power sector remained in the realm of the state receiving subsidized farm inputs via the group.
and central government (Isaac & Harilal, 1997). Moreover, when these subsidies were with-
In sum, the new Kerala model has pursued drawn under the succeeding center-right-coali-
objectives of productive development, social tion government in 1992, most groups became
improvement and environmental sustainability, inoperative and fell apart (T ornquist, 1995).
thus representing a serious attempt to make In 1991, the KSSP launched the resource-
development sustainable. Recent studies mapping program in collaboration with the
suggest that class compromises between entre- Centre for Earth Science Studies (CESS) and
608 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

with support of the state government. The producing paddyÐa private goodÐnor for
program aimed at initiating more ecient and drafting a plan, the value of which was not
sustainable management of local resources. clear to the ordinary people. Furthermore,
With the help of a checklist designed by the Kerala's strong civil society in which half of the
CESS, local volunteers, including teachers, population is actively involved in civic organi-
retired and educated unemployed persons, zations (Isaac, 2000) appears to be structured
began to map local resources in cooperation along deep-rooted political and class bound-
with farmers. In doing so, it was intended that aries that are obstacles to all-inclusive partici-
ordinary people would learn about their local pation. For environmentally sustainable
resource potential and environmental prob- development, moreover, increased environ-
lems, thus developing ``land literacy'' and mental awareness among the population is
environmental awareness. In many panchayats, necessary.
the KSSP built up organizations of local lead-
ers and volunteers. These organizations were (b) Environmental ethics and grassroots action
expected to draft an ``action plan'' map that
would identify environmental problems and Environmental awareness may not be very
potential sustainable-development projects. At widespread in Kerala because the region does
completion of the program in 1992, when a not generally face a severe ecological crisis. As
center-right coalition came back to power in a consequence, most Keralites do not seem to
Kerala, mapping was done in 20 of the 25 pilot pass ethical judgement on inecient or unsus-
villages, but only two villages drafted an action tainable resource use. In other words, the
plan (Isaac, Franke, & Parameswaran, 1997). normative concept of sustainable development
Both group farming and resource mapping has not yet become a general cultural value in
were ``participatory'' programs initiated ``from Kerala. This may be contrasted with the ideas
above.'' Local people were not invited to de®ne of social development, justice and equity,
their own problems or determine the area of which, prompted by particularly extreme cast
action; instead the programs re¯ected the rigidities, became strong values in the ®rst half
perceptions of policy-makers, social activists of this century in Kerala and facilitated the
and scientists. As a consequence, these spread of education. Social and political
programs failed to gain the participation of awareness led to widespread popular partici-
farmers and agricultural workers; at best, they pation that has supported and even pressured
were able to mobilize volunteers from the the state government to implement welfare
middle class. This was because low eciency of policies and radical reforms. If the new Kerala
paddy cultivation, for example, was not an model is to become a model of sustainable
immediate or pressing problem for farmers as development, the strong sense for social justice
they can shift to other, more pro®table, crops. and the political consciousness among Kerala's
Furthermore, most people did not share the people must be complemented with more
concern of policy-makers and activists about environmental awareness and an enhanced
the environment, and so prioritized environ- ``development culture.'' In order to achieve this
mental problems di€erently. Their views of before a severe ecological crisis unfolds, initia-
``rational'' land use also di€ered from the ones tives by the KSSP and other environmental
of natural scientists. In addition, group farming NGOs to spread people's environmental edu-
overlooked di€erentiation by class, caste, cation and to provide ecological training of
gender, political aliation and micro-locality local planners will be crucial.
within villages and micro-watersheds. People in Although no general environmental aware-
these spatial units do not form a homogenous ness has yet evolved, people seem most
group, and may have only a few interests in concerned about speci®c environmental chan-
common. Moreover, many farmers perceived ges when these a€ect their livelihoods directly.
group farming and resource mapping as ``Grassroots environmental action'' (Ghai &
programs of leftist political parties, and there- Vivian, 1992) that links environmental protec-
fore refrained from participating (Veron, 2000). tion with livelihood issues is already common
In sum, the experience of previous partici- in Kerala. It often emerges as a consequence of
patory programs shows the diculty of identi- con¯icts over local resources. For example,
fying user groups with common productive neighborhood groups have acted against
interests and with complementary assets. excessive sandmining, which has enhanced
Collective action was not regarded suitable for river-bank erosion a€ecting human habitats
THE NEW KERALA MODE 609

and agriculture. Other groups have struggled Before the signi®cant ®nancial devolution in
against deep soil mining, which has caused 1997±98, the small untied funds to the panc-
serious accidents (i.e., people falling into the hayats were simply distributed evenly between
deep ditches at night on their way home). In a the territorial sub-units and used without prior
few places, paddy farmers took action against planning. In contrast, the signi®cant ®nancial
wetland conversions upstream, which has devolution of 35±40% to the panchayats
a€ected water availability on their ®elds occurred at the same time as decentralized
(Veron, 2000). Grassroots environmental participatory planning, project implementation
action tends to meet favorable conditions in and monitoring. Furthermore, the local bodies
Kerala because of its richness in social capital; and the communities were expected to match
people are politically aware and experienced 25% of the grant via additional fund raising,
with collective action. bene®ciary and voluntary contributions in the
As the concept of sustainable development, form of labor, material and/or money.
grassroots environmental action links develop- In August 1996, the newly constituted Kerala
ment issues with environmental sustainability. State Planning Board launched the ``people's
But, grassroots action usually re¯ects a con¯ict planning campaign'' for initiating decentralized
between di€erent local groups over resources planning, and it trained nearly 100,000 volun-
rather than a united community-based struggle tary resource persons to assist the local bodies.
against environmental degradation, or for joint The campaign was expected to last for one year
management of particular resources. Moreover, until the completion of the 1997±98 local plans
it does not consider the ``needs'' of future (Franke & Chasin, 2000). Four years and three
generations, which have no voice in current sets of local plans later, however, the State
con¯icts over local resources. In many cases, Planning Board, committed government o-
there is also a tradeo€ between ensuring a cers, elected people's representatives, and
livelihood and protecting the environment. thousands of volunteers and social activists
Like anywhere else, people in Kerala tend to were still in the campaigning mode.
prioritize their own immediate economic, social This ``planning from below'' started in
and political interests. Unless they see a close September 1996 with 14,147 meetings at the
link between environmental protection and ward level (the lowest panchayat constituency)
their own well being, they do not care about in Kerala's 991 village panchayats. In these
environmentally sound practices. For example, meetings, more than two million people
the local population in a granite-mining area of expressed their felt needs and discussed their
south Kerala has even accepted negative envi- local development problems. To complement
ronmental and health e€ects of neighboring these discussions, development volunteers
quarries because such quarries give employ- carried out participatory rapid appraisals and
ment to their families. organized village-development seminars. On
Because it ignores intergenerational justice the basis of this information, selected voluntary
and environmental sustainability as such, experts and ward representatives identi®ed the
grassroots environmental action has only main problems and drafted panchayat devel-
limited scope to form the basis of sustainable opment reports. These reports contained a
development. On the other hand, it brings to socioeconomic and environmental assessment
light the fact that mainstream sustainable-de- as well as 12 sectoral chapters, many of which
velopment concepts tend to underestimate were related to environmental issues (e.g., the
con¯icts between di€erent resource users and chapters on sanitation, energy, agriculture and
the possible tradeo€ that exists between liveli- irrigation). Based on these general reports,
hood security and environmental protection, as sectoral task forcesÐcomprising local ocials
well as between present and future needs. from relevant line departments, voluntary
experts and resource personsÐdrafted project
(c) The people's planning campaign proposals (Isaac, 2000).
While community volunteers were the driving
The new Kerala model goes beyond sponta- force behind the ®rst stages, the panchayat act
neous grassroots action to include citizens, requires that the elected representatives of the
popular movements, nongovernmental organi- local bodies prioritize the project proposals and
zations and state agents in a systematic process draft the local plan document. The elected
of decentralized planning that pursues broader representatives, often people with little educa-
productive, social and environmental goals. tion and heavy time constraints, were trained
610 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

and assisted by the resource persons. Although 2000), signifying the general nature of the plans
the funds to the panchayats were untied, the to re¯ect popular consumption needs. The
State Planning Board asked the panchayats to recommended grant-in-aid allocation of 40% to
follow broad guidelines for sectoral allotments productive sectors was achieved only in the
in the plan outlay in order to redirect devel- second plan (40%) but neither in the ®rst (34%),
opment investments in productive sectors. nor the third (28%) (Harilal & George, 2000).
Forty to ®fty percent of the grant-in-aid should Moreover, the majority of projects classi®ed
be spent for productive projects in agriculture, under the productive sector were consumption-
animal husbandry, ®sheries, small-scale indus- oriented, such as the subsidized provision of
try; 30±40% for social services (education, milch animals, seedlings and fertilizers. Indi-
health, sanitation, drinking water supply, vidual-bene®ciary schemes were more common
housing); and only 10±30% for infrastructure than group-based activities, and subsidy rates
(Isaac, 2000). were signi®cantly higher than those of line-de-
Then, the local plans of 991 village panc- partment schemes were. The bulk of the bene-
hayats were integrated in 152 block panchayat ®ciary contributions, which topped up the state
plans and 14 district panchayat plans. Block- grant-in-aid funds by more than 50%, were
and district-level government ocers went mandatory contributions of individuals for
through the panchayat reports and plans in receiving the subsidized goods. Furthermore,
order to identify areas that require coordina- the projects were partial interventions such as
tion and that are suitable for complementary single-crop schemes that neglected ecology and
projects. In addition, the development schemes the marketing side (Isaac, 2000). In sum, most
of the central government had to be integrated. projects showed little qualitative di€erence to
Block- and district-level panchayat representa- the earlier projects implemented by line
tives approved the plans in development semi- departments. The local plans re¯ected a lack of
nars. Finally, district- and block-level expert innovation and gave little indication of an
committees gave the required technical sanction emerging ``development culture.''
for the projects in the panchayat plans. In order There were important exceptions, however,
to accomplish this huge task in a reasonable that may lead the way and become models for
time, the committees relied on the newly other panchayats. For example, the agricul-
established voluntary technical corps of more tural ocer of a south Keralan village panc-
than 2,000 retired civil servants, professionals hayat suggested the establishment of a ``labor
and other technical experts that assisted the bank'' of trained agricultural workers that
government ocers-in-charge (Franke & ensures adequate, institutionalized supply of
Chasin, 2000). labor at short notice (which is crucial for
The local plans in 1997±98 produced nearly paddy cultivation). A new body, the ``Farm-
68,000 projects, from repairing irrigation ponds ers' Helping Group,'' including the elected
to developing cooperative vegetable gardens, to panchayat representatives, representatives of
introducing water-sealed latrines, establishing farmers and laborers, the voluntary resource
women's enterprises, building houses for persons of the planning campaign and
squatter families and reviving ritual traditions government ocers, was designed to bargain
(cf. Franke & Chasin, 1997). But, plan formu- ®xed wage rates. In view of more and guar-
lation and the subsequent allotment of the anteed days of employment that was made
panchayat funds were delayed by more than six possible through additional work from the
months. Project implementation and spending panchayat plan, the ®xed wage rate for the
were sluggish. Delays continued for the subse- 120 members of the labor bank could be
quent annual plan in 1998±99 (Isaac, 2000). below the market rate. The institutional
People are becoming accustomed to the new corporatist arrangement was supplemented
planning process, however; informal rules with labor training and subsidized provision of
between the various stakeholders have devel- farm inputs from panchayat funds (Moha-
oped; and additional provisions have been nakumar & Girishkumar, 2000).
included in an amended panchayat act in 1999. This project has been able to break the
In regard to the adoption of productive goals deadlock between decreasing land-use intensity,
and sustainable-development principles, the declining labor productivity and increasing
local plans show a mixed record. Most money wage rates. Two years after its implementation
was allocated to the construction of roads (18% in 1998, the project has led to agricultural
in 1999±2000) and to housing (23% in 1999± intensi®cation and employment creation, and
THE NEW KERALA MODE 611

to reversal of the environmentally unsound in achieving sustainable development rely to a


conversion of wetland. The economic e€ects of great extent on popular movements and envi-
this institutional innovation have been positive ronmental NGOs. For example, the KSSP,
for both the participating laborers and farmers which has played a leading role in the planning
(Mohanakumar & Girishkumar, 2000). More- campaign, has been able to combine produc-
over, this new institution has been able to tive, social and environmental objectives in
overcome entrenched mistrust between farmers most of its political campaigns and develop-
and laborers. The labor bank points to a ment programs. Although the plan preparation
general problem of institutional constructs, included participatory appraisal of environ-
such as user groups, to have a tendency to mental resources, environmental degradation
exclude people. Only 120 of 600 applicants has remained a ``problem'' of natural scientists
could be absorbed by the labor bank because of and social activists rather than the wider
the limited (though increasing) employment population.
opportunities in agriculture and from pancha- At the macrolevel, the state government,
yat work. The chance of excluded workers to prioritizing economic goals, tends to approve
receive panchayat work has been diminished. industrial or energy projects without proper
At the very least, the private contractors were environmental impact assessment. In addition,
replaced by an institution over which the Kerala's state institutions have not improved
laborers themselves have control. their performance in monitoring environmental
Decentralized planning produced only a standards (cf. Ramachandran, 1998). Environ-
very few ``pure'' environmental projects, mental NGOs, such as the KSSP, in¯uenced
although the campaigners propagated envi- environmental policies at the state level in the
ronmental protection. There was no separate past (e.g., through a successful campaign
``environmental component plan'' as for against a large hydroelectric project in the
women, scheduled castes and scheduled tribes. pristine rainforest in Silent Valley, Western
The state plan allocated more to environ- Ghats, in the 1980s), but they seem to be
mental protection than the panchayat plans preoccupied with local-level planning at
(cf. Harilal & George, 2000). But environ- present.
mental concerns were integrated in many Despite the new importance of decentralized
sectoral projects. For housing projects, for planning and signi®cant ®nancial devolution to
example, an NGO developed and produced the panchayats, the state government failed to
environment friendly building materials. restructure allocation to the various line
Agricultural projects promoted organic farm- departments. State government departments
ing and the use of bio-pesticides. The delivery were also not directed to concentrate on
of sealed latrines contributed to better envi- projects that are unsuitable for implementation
ronmental health (Isaac, 2000). But, only few by local bodies. The lack of coordination
projects combined the (subsidized) provision caused both duplications of projects and gaps
of environment friendly technologies with in investment in sectors such as power and
awareness-building. Moreover, few projects industry. This points to the drawback of the ad-
were able to utilize collective action for hoc planning campaign, and more generally to
improving environmental sustainability. Soil the lack of political might of the State Planning
and water conservation projects generally Board, the primary engine behind the
failed, as they were not part of an overall campaign, to push forward an appropriate
watershed-management plan. functional division, even at the expense of one
In those panchayats where committed or the other line department.
government ocers, nongovernmental organi-
zations and scientists/activists were closely
involved, sectoral projects seem to have inte- 5. LESSONS FOR COMMUNITY-BASED
grated the use of environment-friendly tech- SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT
nology very e€ectively. This indicates that
decentralized planning has expanded the scope (a) Problems of community participation
for environmentally concerned organizations to
implement sustainable-development projects. The new Kerala model has addressed some of
People's participation did not, however, auto- the general failures of community-based
matically lead to environmental projects. sustainable development, apparent in the
Therefore, the chances of the new Kerala model earlier participatory initiatives discussed above.
612 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

For example, many community-based political and class boundaries by stressing


programs elsewhere in developing countries do joint productive interests and by seeking the
not invite sucient local participation in active involvement of opposition parties. But,
de®ning problems, areas of action and project only 10±11% of the electorate could be mobi-
goals. Too often, ``participation'' refers only to lized to attend the village-level meetings in the
the implementation of schemes that were ®rst three years of the campaign, and the
designed at higher levels. ``Co-management'' attendance of supporters of opposition parties
may involve more responsibility for local was generally lower (Jagajeevan & Ramakan-
communities without o€ering more rights and than, 2000). This is probably because of ``self-
funds. Faced with ®scal constraints, many exclusion'' on part of political opponents who
states welcome decentralization and participa- regard the campaign as a vehicle of the leftist
tory programs, including local voluntary parties.
contributions of labor, material and money. By The village-level meetings for decentralized
contrast, the new Kerala model has already planning seem not appropriate institutions for
included increased allocation of funds for bridging political and class boundaries for
village development plans, and has imple- other reasons too. These meetings are not
mented a decentralized planning process that targeted to the solution of a particular prob-
aims to involve the civil society at every stage. lem but for expressing all sorts of felt needs.
Ordinary citizens get a fair chance to express Furthermore, the meetings are designed for
local development problems. the residents of the same political-administra-
Still, decentralized planning does not ensure tive unit, regardless of whether they could
empowerment. Village development plans may possibly share common productive or envi-
not fairly re¯ect the concerns of marginalized ronmental interests. The same is true for the
voices at local meetings. Key decisions are recently formed smaller neighborhood groups
taken by volunteering experts, social activists whose only joint interest may be to bring more
and elected representatives. Local development infrastructure into their vicinity. This is
reports and plans may make the prioritization re¯ected in the adoption of many road,
process more transparent, but are no guarantee housing, sanitation and drinking water
against favoritism and nepotism. It has been projects.
reported that in the majority of local bodies, Furthermore, community-based projects can
new project proposals were arbitrarily included support sustainable development only if
just before ®nalization of the plan (Isaac, 2000). people at the grassroots opt for environmental
On the other hand, when the people's expressed protection and consider the needs of future
``felt needs'' were acknowledged, they were generations, which have no say in the (decen-
translated into simple individual-bene®ciary tralized) planning process. Although commu-
asset distribution as opposed to productive nities may depend directly on natural
public investment. It seems, though, that ordi- resources, environmental awareness cannot be
nary citizens may be able to participate more assumed as there are often tradeo€s between
e€ectively in implementing and monitoring immediate livelihood needs and long-term
local projects rather than planning, and that environmental protection. In order to spread
this process has greater potential to spur environmental awareness, the new Kerala
empowerment and a new ``development model has sought the collaboration of NGOs
culture.'' Kerala's planning campaign has given that are engaged in environmental education.
a bigger role to ``bene®ciary committees'' in The main contribution of the participating
project implementation and monitoring, and NGOs has been, however, to o€er environ-
project expenses are made public in the village ment-friendly technology for moderately
meetings. Most bene®ciary committees, innovative projects.
however, are still dominated by private
contractors with vested interests. (b) Importance of synergies between local
Moreover, con¯icting interests within the government and civil society
village can impede compromises and solutions.
Local development plans are thus likely to The new Kerala model has shown the limi-
re¯ect the political power structure in the tations of community participation in planning
village rather than a ``common will.'' The for sustainable development. Collective action
initiators of decentralized planning have has been facilitated and initiated, however, at
explicitly attempted to overcome deep-rooted other levels in the decentralized planning
THE NEW KERALA MODE 613

process. In particular, decentralized planning ical concepts of space (e.g., ``watershed'') that
created a new space for committed government fail to consider the social reality of di€erenti-
ocials and social activists. One government ated access to natural resources and con¯icting
ocer spoke enthusiastically to me recently of individual and group interests. ``Environmen-
decentralized planning: ``Earlier, my work of tal'' problems are also largely social and polit-
implementing single schemes was very dull. ical constructs (cf. Bryant & Bailey, 1997).
Now, I ®nally can use my education and tech- Because no common ``environmental interests''
nical knowledge to help designing useful between people residing in the same ecological
projects for the good of the people.'' The unit can be assumed, projects that use purely
panchayats gives local government ocers and physical spatial concepts to identify potential
development volunteers the institutional frame participants, or user groups respectively, have
to mediate between di€erent interest groups limited scope in a community-based approach
and propose innovative new institutions. The to sustainable development. Similarly, the units
quoted example of the labor bank in south of decentralized planningÐpolitical-adminis-
Kerala shows that even deep-rooted political trative space de®ned by residencyÐrarely
and class boundaries can be overcome on the create appropriate user groups for environ-
basis of joint productive interests. This marks mental management.
an important departure from previous partici- Kerala's decentralization campaign has
patory initiatives in Kerala. recently paid more attention to environmental
Cases in which synergies between local planning, and has launched a complementary
government and civil society have resulted in program for participatory watershed planning.
innovative, community-based projects may still Local-level watershed committees that are
be exceptional. But the planning campaign has institutionally linked to the panchayats are
taken an active role in publicizing successful intended to prepare and implement action
projects and provided opportunities for panc- plans (Varma, George, Nair, Krishnakumar, &
hayats to exchange their experiences and learn Aniyan, 2000). The success of this program will
from each other. depend on identifying appropriate user groups
based on people's practice and intention in
(c) Units of collective action and character of relation to particular resources rather than
managed resources based on bio-physical space alone. Communi-
ty-based resource management can only occur
The scope for environmental co-management between groups that have interests, whether
is in many cases limited because of the nature of common or con¯icting, in the same resources.
particular goods to be produced or managed.
Most environmental resources are under
private control, and agro-ecological systems (d) Need for coordination
such as watersheds have both public-good and
private-good characteristics. In addition, the Village development plans made by local
``well being of future generations,'' an impor- bodies are likely to neglect spatial externalities
tant component of the sustainable-development as well as temporal externalities. Therefore,
concept, is not regarded as a ``good'' at all. It these plans require coordination at higher
is dicult to imagine reciprocity between levels, and some sort of top-down planning.
present and future generations. The mixed- This points to inevitable con¯ict between
good, club-good, or ``no-good,'' character of popular participation and planning. For
environmental sustainability complicates the example, Kerala's State Planning Board gives
establishment of appropriate institutions for guidelines on what village reports should
the co-management of particular resources. contain, and how much money village plans
In the ®rst year of Kerala's planning should allocate to the various sectors. Thus,
campaign, scientists/activists were involved in broad priorities are still set at the state level.
resource-mapping exercises and participatory For community-based development to
rapid appraisals that created village-level succeed, it is crucial to identify the potential
databases for planning. But, their in¯uence on areas of synergies between the state govern-
the planning process and on project proposals ment, the local governments and the civil soci-
seems insigni®cant. Obviously, ordinary people ety. The new Kerala model has tried to
did not share their idea of ``ecologically ecient integrate local civil servants into the process of
land use.'' Natural scientists tend to use phys- decentralized planning, hoping to make them
614 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

more responsible and accountable for the ®nancial devolution and decentralized planning
implementation of the village plans. In addi- are not easily reversible because they have
tion, the allocation of development funds has already raised the expectations at the grass-
been made transparent. But, the success of roots.
decentralized planning still depends too heavily In order to achieve sustainable development
on the commitment and dynamism of individ- with a participatory strategy, environmental
uals, both local government ocers and awareness among the population is essential.
development volunteers. Institutionalization of As in¯uential NGOs are engaged in environ-
rules to enhance the accountability of the state, mental education, there is scope for sustainable
the local ocials, the local bodies, NGOs and development to become a general value in
community organizations are necessary. A ®rst Kerala, as did social justice and equity in the
step in this direction is the recommended ®rst half of this century as a result of caste-
redeployment of line-department ocers to the based reform movements and class-based
panchayats. associations.
Though the state government is making a
genuine e€ort to initiate community-based
6. CONCLUSIONS sustainable development, and to make use of
synergies between civil society and the state at
The old Kerala model was certainly not an the local level, it fails to enforce environmental
example of sustainable development: The policies at the macrolevel. For example,
environmental record has been mixed, and monitoring of environmental standards and
economic stagnation threatened the sustain- use of environmental impact assessment have
ability of social progress. The new Kerala remained insucient, and the introduction of
model has, however, included policies toward environmental taxes has not been considered.
community-based sustainable development and The failure to create private-public synergies at
addressed common ``community failures.'' the macrolevel in regard to environmental
There are individual success stories where protection counteracts the e€orts of decen-
synergies between the local government and the tralized environmental planning, and may limit
civil society have been utilized to build new Kerala's prospects considerably in achieving
institutions that overcome con¯icting interests sustainable development. Participatory initia-
and more deep-rooted rifts based on class and tives at the local level have a limited reach
party politics. The success of the new Kerala because they take place in state and national
model will depend on whether these showcases political contexts, global markets and wider
can be replicated in other panchayats. Ecolog- ecological systems. This implies that commu-
ical concerns have been integrated in sectoral nity-based sustainable development and co-
projects on initiative of environmentally aware management of resources are no substitute for
development volunteers. But decentralized environmental planning and regulation at state
planning has not o€ered a platform for and international levels. It must be recognized
comprehensive environmental planning that there is also ``community failure'' to
because the units of planning based on resi- protect the environment (as there is market
dency are inappropriate for building resource- failure and state failure). Yet community-
user groups. based strategies may become an important
Community-based sustainable development addition to regulatory and price instruments if
meets very conducive social conditions in synergetic roles of the state, the market and
Kerala. The populationÐin cities, towns and civil society can be identi®ed, de®ned and
villages alikeÐis educated, informed, politi- utilized.
cally conscious and well organized to bring It would be premature to draw conclusions
about necessary far-reaching social change. about the success of the new Kerala model, but
Apart from the availability geographically well this participatory development experiment may
distributed human and social capital, the well provide more lessons for environmental
ideological commitment of the state govern- planners in developing countries. Kerala's
ment has been crucial. The current left-coali- attempt to foster environmental awareness
tion government has initiated and backed through decentralized planning and its perfor-
decentralized development planning. Although mance in developing accountability of local
some state-level politicians of both the ruling bodies, NGOs and state agencies deserves
and the opposition parties remain skeptical, further research.
THE NEW KERALA MODE 615

NOTES

1. The mainstream concept of sustainable development Statistical Organisation, Government of India, cited in
has been criticized for its preference for reformist Dreze and Sen (1995).
technical±economic solutions over more radical, struc-
tural and sociopolitical changes (Adams, 1990). 5. Gulf remittances may be as much as 13±28% of the
SDP (Nair & Pillai, 1994; Gulati and Mody, cited in
2. Pretty has argued that natural capital and social Mohandas, 1994). The remittances during 1975±90 were
capital are di€erent than produced and ®nancial capital about two to three times higher than the total plan
in the sense that they can increase with use. For example, outlay (government expenditures for new development
regenerative technologies in agricultural production schemes as formulated in Five-Year Plans) during 1950±
strengthen the resource base. Repeated interaction 90 (Oommen, 1993).
between co-producers build up mutual trust (Pretty,
1998). Similarly, human skills and knowledge are 6. Labor militancy was a major problem in the 1970s.
improved through their application. As a consequence, many industries shifted production to
neighboring states. According to ocial statistics, inci-
3. Figures of life expectancy (1992) and infant mortal- dences of labor disputes have declined considerably since
ity (1994) according to Sample Registration System then. In addition, the Communist Party called upon the
Data, Government of India, cited in Dreze and Sen workers to develop a new work culture, including labor
(1995); literacy rate according to 1991 Census, cited in discipline and higher productivity (Heller, 1995).
Kerala State Planning Board (1995).
7. The KSSP has more than 2,100 local units and as
4. Data on per capita SDP by Kerala State Planning many as 65,000 members (cf. Zachariah & Sooryamoor-
Board (1995); growth rate of per capita SDP by Central thy, 1994).

REFERENCES

Adams, W. M. (1990). Green development environment Franke, R. W., & Chasin, B. H. (1994). Kerala:
and sustainability in the Third World. London: Development through radical reform. New Delhi:
Routledge. Promilla.
Amin, S. (1991). Four comments on Kerala. Monthly Franke, R. W., & Chasin, B. H. (1997). Power to the
Review, 42(8), 28. Malayalee people. Economic and Political Weekly,
Arts, B. (1994). Nachhaltige entwicklung. Peripherie, 54, 32(48), 3061±3068.
6±27. Franke, R.W., & Chasin, B.H. (2000). Is the Kerala
Bryant, R., & Bailey, S. (1997). Third World political model sustainable? Lessons from the past, prospects
ecology. London: Routledge. for the future. In G. Parayil (Ed.), Kerala: The
Crook, R., & Manor, J. (1998). Democracy and decen- development experience: Re¯ections on sustainability
tralisation in South Asia and West Africa: Participa- and replicability (pp. 16±39). London: Zed Books.
tion, accountability and performance. Cambridge: George, J. (1997). Panchayats and participatory plan-
Cambridge University Press. ning in Kerala. Indian Journal of Public Administra-
Dreze, J., & Sen, A. (1995). India: Economic development tion, 18(1), 79±91.
and social opportunity. Delhi: Oxford University George, K. K. (1993). Limits to Kerala model of
Press. development an analysis of ®scal crisis and its impli-
Dreze, J., & Sen, A. (1997). Indian development: Selected cations. Trivandrum: Centre for Development Stud-
regional perspectives. Delhi: Oxford University Press. ies.
Evans, P. (1996). Government action, social capital and Ghai, D., & Vivian, J. M. (1992). Grassroots environ-
development: reviewing the evidence on synergy. mental action: People's participation in sustainable
World Development, 24(6), 1119±1132. development. London: Routledge.
Evans, P. (2000). Ecologies of local political actors and Gibbon, D., Lake, A., & Stocking, M. (1995). Sustain-
the struggle for livability in third world countries. able development. In S. Morse, & D. Gibbon (Eds.),
Paper prepared for the International Conference on People and environment (pp. 31±68). London: UCL
Democratic Decentralisation, Kerala State Planning Press.
Board, Thiruvananthapuram, 23±27 May. Harilal, K.N., & George, M.S. (2000). Prioritisation in
Fields, G. (1999). Distribution and development: a local-level planning: the Kerala experience. Paper
summary of the evidence for the developing world. prepared for the International Conference on Demo-
Background Paper prepared for the World Develop- cratic Decentralisation, Kerala State Planning
ment Report 2000. Cornell University, Ithaca, NY. Board, Thiruvananthapuram, 23±27 May.
616 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Heller, P. (1995). From class struggle to class compro- Ostrom, E. (1996). Crossing the great divide: Copro-
mise: Redistribution and growth in a south Indian duction, synergy and development. World Develop-
state. Journal of Development Studies, 31(5), 645±672. ment, 24(6), 1073±1087.
Heller, P. (2000). Social capital and the developmental Parayil, G. (1996). The `Kerala model' of development
state: Industrial workers in Kerala. In G. Parayil development and sustainability in the Third World.
(Ed.), Kerala: The development experience: Re¯ec- Third World Quarterly, 17(5), 941±957.
tions on sustainability and replicability (pp. 16±39). Pearce, D. W., & Warford, J. J. (1993). World without
London: Zed Books. end: Economics, environment, and sustainable devel-
Isaac, T. M. T., Franke, R. W., & Parameswaran, M. P. opment. Washington, DC: World Bank.
(1997). From anti-feudalism to sustainable develop- Prakash, B. A. (1994). Kerala's economy: Performance,
ment: The Kerala peoples science movement. Bulletin problems, prospects. New Delhi: Sage.
of Concerned Asian Scholars, 29(3), 34±44. Pretty, J. (1998). The living land: Agriculture, food and
Isaac, T. M. T., & Harilal, K. N. (1997). Planning for community regeneration in rural Europe. London:
empowerment: People's campaign for decentralised Earthscan.
planning in Kerala. Economic and Political Weekly, Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic
32(1±2), 53±58. traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton
Isaac, T. M. T. (with Franke, R. W. ) (2000). Local University Press.
democracy and development: People's campaign for Ramachandran, K. (1998). Dubious development:
decentralized planning in Kerala. New Delhi: Left Word. Petrochemicals complex at Cheemeni. Economic
Iyer, S.R.R. (1996). Social development in Kerala, India: and Political Weekly, 33(1-2), 14±15.
Illusion or reality? MPhil thesis, University of Hong Ramachandran, V.K. (1997). On Kerala's development
Kong. achievements. In: J. Dreze, & A. Sen (Eds.), Indian
Jagajeevan, N., & Ramakanthan, N. (2000). Grama development: Selected regional perspectives (pp. 205±
sabhas: A democratic structure for development plan- 356). Delhi: Oxford University Press.
ning. Paper prepared for the International Confer- Ratcli€e, J. W. (1978). Social justice and the demographic
ence on Democratic Decentralisation, Kerala State transition: Lessons from India's Kerala state. Inter-
Planning Board, Thiruvananthapuram, 23±27 May. national Journal of Health Services, 8(1), 123±144.
Joshi, V. (1996). India's transition: Progress, problems Sen, G. (1992). Social needs and public accountability:
and prospects. In C.H.H. Rao, & H. Linnemann the case of Kerala. In M. Wuyts et al. (Eds.),
(Eds.), Economic reforms and poverty alleviation in Development policy and public action (pp. 253±277).
India (pp. 119±125). New Delhi: Sage. Oxford: Oxford University Press for the Open
Kerala State Planning Board (1995). Economic review University.
1995. Trivandrum: Government of Kerala. Sessions, G. (1995). Deep ecology for the 21st century:
Lam, W. F. (1996). Institutional design of public Readings on the philosophy and practice of the new
agencies and coproduction: A study of irrigation environmentalism. Boston: Shambhala.
associations in Taiwan. World Development, 24(6), Smith, K. R. (1997). Development, health and the
1039±1054. environmental risk transition. In G. S. Shahi et al.
Leach, M., Mearns, R., & Scoones, I. (1997). Challenges (Eds.), International perspectives on environment,
to community-based sustainable development: development and health (pp. 51±62). New York:
Dynamics, entitlements, institutions. IDS Bulletin, Springer.
28(4), 4±14. Tendler, J. (1997). Good government in the tropics.
Lele, S. M. (1991). Sustainable development: A critical Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.
review. World Development, 19(6), 607±621. T
ornquist, O. (with Tharakan, P.K.M.) (1995). The next
Mohandas, M. (1994). Poverty in Kerala. In B.A. left? democratisation and attempts to renew the radical
Prakash (Ed.), Kerala's economy: Performance, prob- political development project: The case of Kerala.
lems, prospects (pp. 78±94). New Delhi: Sage. Copenhagen: Nordic Institute of Asian Studies.
Mohanakumar, S., & Girishkumar, K. G. (2000). Varma, A.K., George, R., Nair, A.S.K., Krishnakumar,
Labour and development under people's plan: The & Aniyan, P.V. (2000). Watershed master plan: An
experience of Kunnathukal grama panchayat. Paper approach to reinforce local level development. Paper
prepared for the International Conference on Demo- prepared for the International Conference on Demo-
cratic Decentralisation, Kerala State Planning cratic Decentralisation, Kerala State Planning
Board, Thiruvananthapuram, 23±27 May. Board, Thiruvananthapuram, 23±27 May.
Morris, D. M., & McAlpin, M. B. (1982). Measuring the Veron, R. (1999). Real markets and environmental change
condition of India's poor: The physical quality of life in Kerala, India: A new understanding of the impact of
index. New Delhi: Promilla. crop markets on sustainable development. Aldershot:
Nair, G. P. R., & Pillai, M. P. (1994). Impact of external Ashgate.
transfers on the regional economy of Kerala. Trivan- Veron, R. (2000). Sustainability and the `new' Kerala
drum: Centre for Development Studies. model. In G. Parayil (Ed.), Kerala: The development
Oommen, M. A. (1993). Essays on Kerala economy. experience: Re¯ections on sustainability and replica-
Oxford and New Delhi: IBH Publishing. bility (pp. 212±229). London: Zed Books.
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolu- WCED (World Commission on Environment and
tion of institutions for collective action. New York: Development) (1987). Our common future. New
Cambridge University Press. York: Oxford University Press.
THE NEW KERALA MODE 617

Weiner, M. (1999). The regionalization of Indian politics World Bank (1999). Decentralization. In World Devel-
and its implication for economic reform. In J.D. Sachs opment Report 1999/2000 (pp. 107±124). Washington
et al. (Eds.), India in the era of economic reforms DC: World Bank.
(pp.261±295). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Zachariah, M., & Sooryamoorthy, R. (1994). Science for
World Bank (1997). Expanding the measure of wealth: social revolution: Achievements and dilemmas of a
Indicators for environmentally sustainable develop- development movement: The Kerala sastra sahitya
ment. Washington, DC: World Bank. parishad. London: Zed Books.

View publication stats

S-ar putea să vă placă și