Sunteți pe pagina 1din 6

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/312327542

Bilateral Monopoly

Chapter · January 2016


DOI: 10.1057/978-1-349-94848-2_532-1

CITATIONS READS

0 1,379

1 author:

Robert Mcnab
Old Dominion University
51 PUBLICATIONS   893 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Culture View project

Defense Economics View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Robert Mcnab on 16 March 2018.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


bilateral monopoly
DOI: 10.1057/9781137294678.0047
Palgrave Macmillan

Please respect intellectual property rights


This material is copyright and its use is restricted by our standard site license
terms and conditions (see palgraveconnect.com/pc/info/terms_conditions.html).
If you plan to copy, distribute or share in any format, including, for the avoidance
of doubt, posting on websites, you need the express prior permission of Palgrave
Macmillan. To request permission please contact rights@palgrave.com.
bilateral monopoly entry prohibit potential competitors from entering
the market. A monopolist thus has significant, but not
Definition
A bilateral monopoly exists when there is a single buyer
unlimited, market power and faces a downward
and seller of a given product in a market. Bilateral sloping demand curve. The downward sloping
monopolies present specific challenges to managers and demand curve is important in that it implies the
policymakers alike, as the final price and quantity are monopolist can set price or quantity but not both, that
determined through negotiation. is, if the monopolist sets a market price, quantity is
determined by the demand curve and vice versa. In the

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to Palgrave Macmillan entitlement for Contributors - PalgraveConnect - 2013-11-21
Abstract
presence of monopoly power in the product market,
Bilateral monopolies present challenges to private and
public managers. In a market characterized by bilateral
the value of the marginal physical product of labour is
monopoly, the monopolist has an incentive to curtail always lower than the wage rate (Varian, 1992).
production to maximize profit while the monopsonist A monopsonist exists where there is one, and only
should use its market power to expand production and one, buyer of a good or service and significant bar-
lower unit cost. The final price and quantity are determined riers to entry prohibit other potential buyers from
through a negotiating process that may, in part, depend on entering the market. The classic approach to mono-
the risk preference of the negotiator. Public policy may psony involves a single buyer and multiple sellers.
restrict the ability of a government to take advantage of its The monopsonist establishes a market price and the
monopolist position. A government may, for reasons of multiple, price-taking sellers select an output quantity
political or public interest, subsidize the monopsonist to at which price is equal to the marginal cost of pro-
lower prices, increase supply, or both. A government may
duction. As with a market with a single producer, the
also shift the risk of procurement from the monopsonist to
the government, decreasing the ability of the government
market with a single buyer is inefficient relative to the
to negotiate on cost and schedule. Finally, laws, rules and perfectly competitive market.
regulations may explicitly prohibit the government from National governments, for example, are mono-
exercising monopolist power, even if such an exercise psonists for specific goods and services due to the legal
would be of benefit to the taxpayer. constraints imposed by the government. While private
militaries can (and do) exist, for example, governments
A bilateral monopoly exists when there is a single often retain the sole right for the legitimate use of
buyer (monopsonist) and seller (monopolist) of a lethal force (Stafford, 2000), although this line has
given product in a market. For managers in the become blurred since the 1980s. One could argue that
public sector, especially those in security establish- the use of private military contractors has led to a
ments, markets characterized by bilateral monopoly more competitive labour market for those who provide
dominate the procurement of large systems and military force (Leander, 2005), as evidenced by the
projects. If the United States Department of Defence, flight of higher quality personnel to private military
for example, desires to procure a new main weapon contractors.
system (aircraft, armoured vehicle, missile system)
built in the United States, it will recognize that the
number of potential suppliers has declined signifi- Bilateral monopoly
cantly over the last four decades (Hensel, 2010). Once Markets characterized by bilateral monopolies appear
a decision is made as to which manufacturer will to be on the rise over the past four decades, especially
produce the weapon system, the market shifts from when one considers the expanding role of the public
oligopolists interacting with a monopsonist to a sector in economic activity. Yet bilateral monopolies
monopolist interacting with a monopsonist. The may occur in private markets also. A geographical
monopolist has an incentive to curtail production to location with a single maritime port and a single
maximize profit while the monopsonist should (but maritime transport company would be considered
often does not) use its market power to expand a market characterized by a bilateral monopoly.
production and lower unit cost. Economic theory originally classified the bilateral
monopoly market price as ‘indeterminate’ since the
Monopolies and monopsonies final price resulted from a bargaining process
A monopolist exists where there is one, and only one, (Pigou, 1908; Bowley, 1928; Pen, 1952). The relative
seller of a good or service and significant barriers to bargaining strength of the monopsonist and

r Palgrave Publishers Ltd 1

10.1057/9781137294678.0047 - bilateral monopoly, Robert McNab


bilateral monopoly

monopolist reduced this indeterminacy to a solution, With regard to economic policy, the relative bar-
or at least a solution with bounds (Fellner, 1947; gaining power of the monopsonist can be altered by
Agapos and Dunlap, 1970). One bound is set where subtle changes in laws, regulations or procedures.
the seller fixes his price, that is, when the mono- Imposing a minimum domestic content requirement,
psonist has no bargaining power. The lower bound is for example, alters the resultant rent distribution
likewise set where the buyer fixes his price. As long as even if the content requirement is set to the free trade
the price is within this contract zone, the market is input proportion (Beghin and Sumner, 1992). The
characterized by bilateral monopoly (Fellner, 1947; imposition of the requirement increases the relative

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to Palgrave Macmillan entitlement for Contributors - PalgraveConnect - 2013-11-21
Pen, 1952). bargaining power of the supplier of the content,
Economic theory suggests that markets character- skewing the resulting rents. In defence procurement,
ized by bilateral monopolies consisting of two private for example, the government may ‘give away’ bar-
firms are likely to be relatively inefficient compared gaining power by transferring research and develop-
with markets where there are either numerous buyers ment risk from the supplier to the government. The
or sellers (Baker, Farrell and Shapiro, 2008). With government may also reduce its bargaining power by
private information, markets with one or more sellers guaranteeing the monopsonist receives ‘cost+profit’.
are relatively more efficient and have a relatively As cost overruns plague major weapons systems,
higher quantity of goods produced than markets from the F-22 Raptor (an advanced single-seat air-
characterized by one seller. Suppose, for example, superiority fighter aircraft) to new destroyers, one
that marginal cost is $1 and that the buyer’s value is may be drawn to the conclusion that the government
either $2 or $4 with equal likelihood. Competition is to blame, in part, for the creation of contracting
between the sellers will likely yield a price below $2 mechanisms that reward underperformance and cost
and an efficient level of trade. On the other hand, if overruns.
only one seller exists, the seller wishes to maximize In the case of a market of an exhaustible resource,
profits by selling at $4. Half the time, the buyer’s a bilateral monopoly may create greater uncertainty.
actual value will be $2 and no trade will occur, thus The most important issue in these markets may be
illustrating the inefficiency of a single supplier rela- one of commitment, that is, the ability of strategic
tive to multiple suppliers (Vickers, 1996; Baker, Far- players to commit themselves to a course of action to
rell and Shapiro, 2008). favourably influence their rivals (Lewis, Lindsey and
If, however, the purchaser of the goods and ser- Ware, 1986). If we assume that a perfect substitute,
vices is the government, the prevailing price is for example, is available for the exhaustible resource,
dependent upon the contractual mechanism. The then a lack of commitment induces the monopolist to
government may desire to seek the lowest possible extract the resource more quickly, which creates an
price but may face legal and regulatory impediments incentive for consumers to remain with the exhaus-
to doing so. Attempts, for example, to consolidate tible resource. Why would the monopolist not com-
purchases into fewer contracts of larger size may have mit? Commitment places the monopolist at a
the unintended consequence of consolidation among strategic disadvantage and lowers their profits over
suppliers, moving the market further away from a time. In essence, the monopolist has every incentive
competitive equilibrium (Agapos, 1971). to maximize profit, even if it means exhausting the
resource more quickly than would occur under
Strategic management market conditions.
From a strategic management perspective, bilateral Mergers may not produce the results that standard
monopolies offer significant challenges to policy- theory would predict. Mergers are often discussed in
makers and managers alike. For policymakers, the terms of reaping the benefits of economies of scale.
desire to intervene into these markets to move them The terms of the resulting transactions, however, are
towards a competitive equilibrium may, in fact, have determined through bargaining rather than by being
the unintended consequence of exacerbating the determined by one of the parties. The incentives for
market power of the monopolist or monopsonist. For mergers are sometimes significantly different than
managers, these markets often lack clear signals as to they would be if prices were not determined by
price and quantity, and negotiation is relatively more bargaining (Horn and Wolinsky, 1988). The implicit
important than in a competitive market. assumption that the merged firm would thus attempt

2 r Palgrave Publishers Ltd

10.1057/9781137294678.0047 - bilateral monopoly, Robert McNab


bilateral monopoly

to lower its per-unit costs may be incorrect if such an F-35 has increased by 75 per cent since 2001 and
action resulted in lower profits over time. shows no signs of abetting (GAO, 2012). Yet the
Yet to think that bilateral monopolies are only government has contracted to acquire hundreds of F-
characterized by interactions between two firms or a 35 before testing is complete, thereby decreasing its
government and a firm would be incorrect. Bureau- relative bargaining power. In essence, the government
cracy is a classic issue in public choice and can be apparently (and willingly) moved the price away
modelled as a bureau selling its services to govern- from cost minimization to profit maximization.
ment which, in turn, only buys services from the From a strategic perspective, this is sheer folly (and

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to Palgrave Macmillan entitlement for Contributors - PalgraveConnect - 2013-11-21
bureau (Niskanen, 1996, 2007). If we assume that regrettably avoidable) given the looming reductions
the bureaucrats attempt to maximize their budget, in discretionary expenditures in the United States.
the level of output may be inefficient. Monitoring ROBERT MCNAB
may thus be necessary to discern what are the true
See also
costs of the bureaucracy; and monitoring generates ACQUISITION STRATEGY; AGENCY PROBLEMS; INDUSTRY CONCENTRATION;
additional costs. This argument, however, may be MARKET STRUCTURE; PRINCIPAL-AGENT
sensitive to the assumption that the bureaucrats are a
discriminating monopoly. If this assumption is
References
relaxed, the bureaucrats’ preferred level of output is Agapos, A. M. 1971. Competition in the defense industry: an
equal to the sponsor’s preferred level (Casas-Pardo economic paradox. Journal of Economic Issues 5, 41–55.
and Puchades-Navarro, 2001). In other words, policy, Agapos, A. M. and Dunlap, P. R. 1970. The theory of price
not bureaucratic attempts to maximize profits, determination in government–industry relationships.
determines the level of output. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, 85–99.
Baker, J. B., Farrell, J. and Shapiro, C. 2008. Merger to
From a management perspective, price and quan- monopoly to serve a single buyer: comment. Antitrust Law
tity are determined through a negotiating process. Journal 75, 637–646.
Managers can thus directly attempt to maximize Beghin, J. C. and Sumner, D. A. 1992. Domestic content
profitability (for monopsonists) or minimize cost (for requirements with bilateral monopoly. Oxford Economic
monopolists). The personal characteristics of the Papers (new series) 44, 306–316.
Bowley, A. L. 1928. Bilateral monopoly. Economic Journal 38,
manager are an important (and oft ignored) input to 651–659.
the negotiating process. The archetype is a successful Casas-Pardo, J. and Puchades-Navarro, M. 2001. A critical
manager who is an extrovert, a risk-taker, and con- comment on Niskanen’s model. Public Choice 107, 147–167.
fident in his or her ability to maximize the payout Fellner, W. 1947. Prices and wages under bilateral monopoly.
from a negotiating process. The evidence, however, Quarterly Journal of Economics 61, 503–532.
GAO (Government Accountability Office). 2012. Joint Strike
suggests the archetype is more myth than reality. Fighter: Restructuring Added Resources and Reduced Risk, but
Relatively risk-adverse managers appear to be more Concurrency is Still a Major Concern, 20 March. Available at
able to obtain a higher payoff than risk-taking <http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-12-525T4 (accessed 12
counterparts (Harnett, Cummings and Hamner, January 2013).
1973). Risk-adverse managers appear to pursue more Harnett, D. L., Cummings, L. L. and Hamner, W. C. 1973.
Personality, bargaining style and payoff in bilateral monopoly
a more demanding negotiating strategy with a sig- bargaining among European managers. Sociometry 36,
nificantly higher starting price than extroverted, 325–345.
risk-loving managers. Thus, while economic theory Hensel, N. 2010. Can industry consolidation lead to greater
suggests that the relative power of a monopolist will efficiencies? Evidence from the U.S. defense industry. Business
determine the final market price and quantity, the Economics 45, 187–203.
Horn, H. and Wolinsky, A. 1988. Bilateral monopolies and
human factor may result in a different outcome. incentives for merger. RAND Journal of Economics 19,
These elements combine to suggest that govern- 408–419.
ments are ill-equipped to operate in markets char- Leander, A. 2005. The market for force and public security: the
acterized by bilateral monopoly, yet the government destabilizing consequences of private military companies.
is often one side of these markets. The F-35 provides Journal of Peace Research 42, 605–622.
Lewis, T., Lindsey, R. and Ware, R. 1986. Long-term bilateral
an excellent example of how the government, even monopoly: the case of an exhaustible resource. RAND Journal
though it is a monopolist, has been unable to employ of Economics 17, 89–104.
its market power to rein in costs and under- Niskanen, W. A. 1996. Bureaucracy and Public Economics (2nd
performance. The per-unit acquisition price of the edn). Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

r Palgrave Publishers Ltd 3

10.1057/9781137294678.0047 - bilateral monopoly, Robert McNab


bilateral monopoly

Niskanen, W. A. 2007. Bureaucracy and representative (and) the rules of deadly force. Army Lawyer, Department of
government. American Political Science Review 68, the Army Pamphlet 27-50-336, 1–25.
1775–1777. Varian, H. R. 1992. Microeconomic Analysis (3rd edn). New
Pen, J. 1952. A general theory of bargaining. American York: W. W. Norton.
Economic Review 42, 24–42. Vickers, J. 1996. Market power and inefficiency: a contracts
Pigou, A. C. 1908. Equilibrium under bilateral monopoly. perspective. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 12, 11–26.
Economic Journal 18, 205–220.
Stafford, W. A. 2000. How to keep military personnel from
going to jail for doing the right thing: jurisdiction, ROE &

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to Palgrave Macmillan entitlement for Contributors - PalgraveConnect - 2013-11-21

View publication stats

4 r Palgrave Publishers Ltd

10.1057/9781137294678.0047 - bilateral monopoly, Robert McNab

S-ar putea să vă placă și