Sunteți pe pagina 1din 36

THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW

Vol. LIV, No. 2


April 1979

The Demand for and Supply of


Accounting Theories:
The Market for Excuses

Jtoss L. Watts and Jerold L. Zimmerman

ABSTRACT: This paper addresses the questions of why accounting theories are pre- dominantly
normative and why no single theory is generally accepted. Accounting theories are analyzed as
economic goods, produced in response to the demand for theories. The nature of the demand is
examined, first in an unregulated, then in a regu- lated economy.
Government regulation creates incentives for individuals to lobby on proposed ac-
counting procedures, and accounting theories are useful justifications in the political lobbying.
Further, government intervention produces a demand for a variety of theories, because each group
affected by an accounting change demands a theory that suppons its position. The diversity of
positions prevents general agreement on a theory of ac- counting, and accounting theories are
normative because they are used as excuses for political action (/.e., the political process creates
a demand for theories which prescribe, rather than describe, the world).
The implications of the authors’ theory for the changes in the accounting literature as a result
of major changes in the institutional environment are compared with observed phenomena.

I. INTRODUCTION word “theory” as a generic term for the existing account-


ing literature.
ifc literature we commonly call financial
accounting theory is pre- dominantly prescriptive.'
Most writers are concerned with This research was supported by the Center for
what the contents of published financial state- Re- search in Government Policy and Business,
ments should be; that is, how firms should account. Graduate School of Management, University of
Yet, it is generally concluded that financial Rochester. The authors wish to acknowledge the
accñunting the- ory has had little substantive, direct suggestions of Ray Ball, George Benston, Richard
impact on accounting practice or policy Brief, Nicholas Dopuch, Nicholas Gonedes, David
Henderson, Robert Holthau- sen, Michael Jensen,
' For example, see Canning [1929 J, Paton [1922], Melvin Krasney, Richard Leftwich, Janice Maguire,
Edwards and Bell [1961], Sprouse and Moonitz William Meekling, Philip Meyers, Katherine Schipper,
[1962], Gordon [1964], Chambers [1966J, and William Schwert, Clifford Smith, and Jerold Warner.
American Ac- counting Association [1966]. We would We also acknowledge the sugges- tions received on
prefer to reserve the term “theory” for principles an earlier version of this paper pre- sented at the
advanced to ex- plain a set of phenomena, in Stanford Summer Research Colloquium, August 2,
particular for sets of hypoth- eses which have been 1977, and the comments of the anonymous
confirmed. However, such a defini- tion of theory reviewers.
would exclude much of the prescriptive literature and loss L. Watts is Associate Professor and
generate. a semantic debate. To avoid that Jerold L. 2 immerman is Assistant Professor,
consequence, in this paper (unless qualified) we use 273
both at the Universit y of Rochester.
the
Manuscript received October, 1977.
Rear.sions received January anal A pril,
1978. ACC*F!e d May, 1978.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


274 The Accounting Review, April 1979

formulation despite half a century of research. Often often, accounting theory is invoked more as a
the lack of impact is attributed to basic tactic to buttress one’s preconceived notions,
methodological weak- nesses in the research. Or, the rather than as a genuine arbiter of contending
prescrip- tions offered are based on explicit or implicit uiews (emphasis added).
objectives which frequently differ among writers.° Not
only are the re- searchers unable to agree on the Horngren [1973, p. 61] goes further and suggests an
objec- tives of financial statements, but they also explanation for accounting theory’s limited impact on
disagree over the methods of de- riving the thesetting of accounting standards: 7
prescriptions from the objec- tives.3
My hypothesis is that the setting of account- ing
One characteristic common to the prescriptions
standards is as much a product of political
and proposed accounting methodologies, however,
is their failure to satisfy all practicing accountants action as of flawless logic or empirical find-
and to be accepted generally by accounting ings.
standard-setting bodies. A committee of the Our tentative theory is consistent with both ZefPs
American Accounting Association recently concluded and Horngren’s observations. It predicts that
that “a single univer- sally accepted basic accounting accounting theory will be used to “buttress
theory does not exlst at this time. 4 preconceived notions” and further, it explains why.
The preceding observations lead us to pose the Our contri- bution to ZefPs and Horngren’s ideas is
following question : What is the role of accounting to give them more structure so that we can make
theory in determining accounting practice? Our additional predictions about accounting theory. The
objective in this paper is to begin building a theory of source of that structure is economics. We view ac-
the determinants of accounting theory. This theory is counting theory asan economic good and
intended to be a positive theory, that is, a theory
capable of ex- plaining the factors determining the
extant accounting literature, predicting how research
will change as the underly- ing factors change, and 2 For example, Chambers [1966, Chapters 9—11]
explaining the role of theories in the determination of ap- parently adopts economic efficiency as an
accounting standards.’ It is not norma- tive or objective while the American Institute of Certified
Other writers have examined the rela- Public Ac- countants (AICPA) Study Group on the
tionship between accounting theory and practice. For Objectives of Financial Statements [1973, p. 17’]
example, Zeff [1974, p. 177] examines the historical decided that “finan- cial statements should meet the
relationship and concludes: needs of those with the least ability to obtain
information.. .”
A study of the U.S. experience clearly shows Some writers (e.g., Chambers [1966]) make
that the academic literature has had remark- assump- tions about the world without regard
ably little impact on the writings of practi- tioners to/ormoJ empirical evidence and derive their
and upon the accounting policies of the prescriptions using those as- sumptions. Others
American Institute and the SEC. Too (e.g., Gonedes and Dopuch [1974]) argue that
prescriptions to achieve any given objective must be
based on hypotheses which have been subjected to
formal statistical tests and confirmed.
• American Accounting Association, [1977, p. IJ.
This report also reviews the major accounting
theories. The Committee on Concepts and
Standards for External Reports, American
Accounting Association [1977] examines many of
these same questions, and the interested reader
should refer to this committee report for an
alternative explanation of these phenomena,
specifically Chapter 4.
The terms “normative” and “prescriptive” are
used interchangeably. See Mautz and Gray [1970]
for an example of prescriptions to “improve”
accounting re- search and hence its impact on
practice.
See Sterling [1974, pp. 18fi181 ] for Horngren’s
response to Zeff’s initial remark.
Watts and Zimmerman 275

Copyright O 2001
276 The Accounting Review, April 1979

examine the nature of the demand for in which the only role of government is to enforce
and the supply of that good. contracts, and then in a regulated economy. In Section
Understanding why accounting the- ories are as III, we examine the nature of the supply of accounting
they are requires a theory of the political process. theo- ries. Because of the diverse demands for
We model that process as competition among prescriptions, we expect to observe a variety of
individ- uals for the use of the coercive power of normative theories. Further, we expect theories to
government to achieve wealth transfers. Because change over time as government intervention changes.
accounting procedures 8 are one means of effecting In Sec- tion IV we examine the effect of govern- ment
such transfers, indi- viduals competing in the political intervention on extant accounting theory during the
process demand theories which prescribe the last century. Section V summarizes the issues and
accounting procedures conducive to their desired presents our conclusions.
wealth transfers. Further, because individual interests II. THE DEMAND FOR ACCOUNTING
differ, a variety of accounting prescriptions, hence a
variety of accounting theories, is demanded on any THEORIES
one issue. We argue that it is this diversity of This section analyzes the demand for accounting
interests which prevents gen- eral agreement on theories in an unregulated economy (Part A) and the
accounting theory. additional demands generated by government inter-
While individuals want a theory which vention (Part B).
prescribes procedures conducive to their own
interest, they do not want a norma- tive theory which A. The Demand for Accounting Theories in an
has their self-interest as its stated objective. The Unregulated Econom y
reason is that information is costly to obtain. Some 1 Accounting in an Unregulated Econ- omy.
voters will not obtain information on political issues Audited corporate financial state- ments were
personally. Those voters are not likely to support voluntarily produced prior to government mandate.’
political actions which have as their stated objective Watts [1977] con- cludes that the original
the self-interest of others. The most useful theories promoters of
for persuading uninformed voters are theories with corporations or, subsequently, corporate
stated objectives appealing to those voters, e.p., the managers have incentives to contract to supply
“public interest.” As a result, individuals demand audited financial statements. Agreements to supply
normative accounting theories which make financial state- ments were included in articles of
prescriptions based on the “public interest.” In other incor- poration (or by-laws) and in private lending
words, the demand is for rationales or excuses. contracts between corporations
Because it arises from the political process, the
demand for normative, “public interest”-oriented
' Accounting “procedures,” ‘techniques,” and
accounting theories depends on the extent of the
government’s role in the economy. “prac- tices” are defined as any computational
Section II analyzes the demand for financial algorithm used or suggested in the preparation of
accounting and accounting theory first in an financial accounting statements. “Accounting
unregulated economy, standards” are those “proce- dures” sanctioned or
recommended by an “authorita- tive” body such as
the APB, FASB, SEC, ICC, etc.
Benston [1969a] reports that as of 1926 all firms
listed on the New York Stock Exchange published a
balance sheet, 55 percent disclosed sales, 45
percent dis- closcd cost of goods sold, 71 percent
disclosed deprecia- tion, 100 percent disclosed net
income, and 82 percent were audited by a CPA.
Watts and Zimmerman 275
and creditors.' 0 These contracts increase the The final element of agency costs is the utility of the
welfare of the promoter or manager (who is raising increase in perquisites, wealth transfers, etc., the
the new capital) because they reduce the agenc y manager re- ceives because of his actions as an
costs” which he bears. agent. An equilibrium occurs when the net costs of
Agency costs arise because the man- ager’s (the an agency relationship, the agency costs, are
agent’s) interests do not necessarily coincide with the minimized by trading- off the decreases in the
interests of shareholders or bondholders (the princi- promoter’s (or manager’s) utility due to the residual
pals). For example, the manager (if he owns shares) loss, the monitoring and bonding ex- penditures, and
has incentives to convert assets of the corporation the increased utility due to increased perquisites.
into dividends, thus leaving the bondholders with the The promoter or manager will write contracts for
“shell” of the corporation. Similarly, the manager has moni- toring and bonding as long as the margi- nal
incentives to transfer wealth to himself at the expense benefits of these contracts (e.q., reduction of the
of both the shareholders and bondholders (e.g., via residual loss) are greater than the marginal costs
perquisites). (e.g., the costs of contracting and the uulity of any
Bondholders and shareholders antici- pate the per- quisites foregone). Moreover, since he bears
manager’s behavior and appro- priately discount the the agency, costs, the manager or promoter will trv
price of the bonds or shares at the time of issue. to write the contracts and perform the bonding or
Hence, the promoter (or manager) of a new corpora- monitoring at minimum cost. In fact, the Jensen and
tion receives less for the shares and bonds he sells Meckling analysis suggests that the equi- librium set of
than he would if he could guaran- tee that he would contractual devices is the one which minimizes the
continue to act as he did when he owned the firm agency costs associated with the separation of man-
(i.e., when there were no outside shareholders or agement and control and with the con- flict of
bondholders). This difference in the market value of interests associated with the dif- ferent classes of
the securities is part of the cost of an agency investors.
relationship, it is part of agency costs, and is borne Promoters and managers voluntarily
by the promoter (or manager).’ 2 Jensen and
Meckling [1976, p. 308] call it the “residual loss.” ’° In the period 1862-1900, many U.K. companies
Because he bears the residual loss, the manager voluntarily adopted the optional articles included in
has incentives to make expendi- tures to guarantee Table A of the 1862 U.K. Companies Act. See Edey
that he will not take certain actions which harm the [1968], Edey and Panitpakdi [1956} and Watts
principal’s interest or that he will compensate the (1977]. Examples of private contracts can be found
principal if he does. These are “bonding” and today in any note or bond indenture agreement.
“monitoring” expenditures and are additional ‘ Jensen and Meckling [1976, p. 308] define an
elements of agency costs. Ex- amples of such agency relationship as “a contract under which one
expenditures include contracting to restrict dividend or more persons (the principal(s)) engage another
payments and expenditures to monitor such divi- nerson (the agent) to perform some serv’ice on their
dend covenants. behalf which involves delegating some decision
making author- ity to the agent.” There are at least
two agency relation- ships which cause corporate
promoters and managers to bear agency costs. The
first is the relationship between shareholders (the
principals) and the manager (the agent) and the
second is the relationship between the bondholders
(the principals) and the manager (the agent). " See
Jensen and Meckling [1976] for a formal proof
that he bears this cost.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


Watts and Zimmerman 277
included bonding covenants in corporate articles and However, a cash flow “profit” index is susceptible to
by-laws in the nineteenth century. Dividend shortrun manager manipu- lation. The manager can
covenants were volun- tarily included in company reduce repairs and maintenance expenditures and
charters as early as 1620.'' in- crease cash flows and “profits,”’ 6 which would
Watts’s [1977] analysis of agency relationships increase the manager’s compen- sation.’ 7 In
suggests that the function of audited financial addition, reduced mainte- nance increases the ability
statements in an unregu- lated economy is to reduce of the cor- poration to pay current dividends. Such
agency costs. This theory predicts that accounting dividends could reduce the value of the creditors’
practices (i.e., the form, content, fre- quency, etc., of claims and increase the share- holders’ wealth.’8
external reporting) would vary across corporations in To reduce these agency costs of equity and debt,
an unregu- lated economy depending on the nature several contractual devices were used to decrease
and magnitude of the agency costs. Agency costs, in the likelihood that managers and shareholders would
turn, are, among other things, a function of the run down the value of the capital stock.
amount of cor- porate debt outstanding and of the
rela- tive share of equity owned by the manager.'4 i) Dividends were restricted to a fixed
These variables affect the manager’s incentive to proportion of profits, thereby creating a
take actions which conflict with the interests of share- buffer.’ 9
holders and bondholders. Agency costs also vary ii) Reserve funds of fixed amounts had to be
with the costs of monitoring managers, which, in turn maintained if dividends were to be paid.20
depend on the physical size, dispersion, and iii) Fixed assets were treated as mer- chandise
complexity of the firm. Further, the practices under- accounts with changes in value (usually not
lying financial statements will vary across firms called depreci-
because an accounting practice which minimizes
agency costs in one industry may not minimize those ' 3 See Kehl [1941, p. 4].
costs in another. " Agency costs are also a function of the tastes of
As an example of the association between managers for non-pecuniary income, the extent of
agency costs and accounting procedures, consider man- agerial competition, the degree to which the
management com- pensation schemes in the capital markets and the legal system are able to
nineteenth century. Some management compensa- reduce agency costs, etc. See Jensen and Meckling
tion schemes in the nineteenth century were [1976, pp. 328—330]. '' The terms “shareholders”
included in corporate articles. Those schemes tied and “stockholders” are
management compensation to the firms’ “profits” used interchangeably.
[Matheson, 1893, pp. vii—viii] to reduce the " See Matheson [1893, p. 5] for a report that
divergence between the interests of the managers man- agers did in fact adopt this tactic in the
and shareholders." At that time “profits” were nineteenth cen- tury.
effectively operating cash flows, since accrual ' 7 See Matheson [1893, p. vii] for a statement that
accounting was not used. [Litherland, 1968, pp. managers did in fact resist depreciation charges
171—172]. because of the effect on their compensation.
" See Smith [1976, p. 42]. Also, we find labor
man- aged firms in socialist countries faced with the
same agency problem. Labor has less incentive to
maintain physical capital than an owner-manager.
Jensen and Meckling [1977].
" For example, the General Bank of India had a
provision in its charter limiting dividends to not more
than j of net (cash) profits [DuBois, 1938, p. 365].
" The Phoenix Insurance Company, 1781,
required a reserve fund of £52,000 before any
dividends could be paid. Ibid.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


278 The Accounting Review, April 1979

ation) closed to profits prior to dividend duce agency costs only if they include provisions for
distributions.21 monitoring. Since audited financial statements are
In the latter procedure, depreciation was treated useful devices to monitor these voluntary
as a valuation technique which had to be estimated agreements between owners and managers, these
only in profit- able years, since dividends were paid only statements serve a useful role in the capital markets
in these years. A typical company charter requiring and owner-managers will agree to provide them in
depreciation is: advance.
2. The Function of Accounting Theories
The directors shall, before recommending any
dividend, set aside out of the profits of the The preceding analysis suggests that accounting
company, but subject to the sanction of the theories will serve three over- lapping functions in an
company in general meeting, such sum as they unregulated economy.
think proper as a reserve fund for main- i) Pedagogic demand. Accounting pro- cedures
are devised in order to reduce agency costs of
tenance, repairs, depreciation and renewals.°2
contracts. Since these costs vary across firms,
accounting pro- cedures will vary, giving rise to
The court interpreted this article and the term “proper diversity of techniques, formats, efC. 2‘ However,
reserve” as a mechanism to account for declines in diversity in accounting procedures in- creases the
the capital stock.’3 Thus, the existence of a depreci- difficulty of teaching the
ation covenant (and hence the presence of
depreciation in the financial statement) or other
restrictions on dividends was a function of the 2 ' See Littleton [1933, pp. 223—227].
amount of fixed assets and the nature and magnitude ' 2 Dent v. London Trum ways Company, 1880, in
of the agency costs of debt. Brief [1976, p. 193].
Capital market participants contract to supply " “Take the case of a warehouse: supposing a
capital. Managers and owners seeking capital ware- house keeper, having a new warehouse,
have incentives to enter into contracts which limit should- find at the end of the year that he had no
the agency costs they incur. But these contracts occasion to expend money in repairs, but thought
must then be monitored and enforced since that, by reason of the usual wear and tear of the
managers have incentives to circumvent the warehouse, it was 1,000/. worse than it was at the
contracts. For example, the promoter or manager beginning of the year, he would set aside 1,000/. for
of a corporation may con- tract to restrict a repair or renewal or depreciation fund, bcfore he
dividends to, or base management compensation estimated any profits ; because, although that sum is
on, profits after a deduction for depreciation be- not required to be paid in that year, it is still the
cause such a covenant enables him to sell bonds sum of money which is lost, so to say, out of capital,
and shares at a higher price. How- ever, after the and which must be replaced.” Ibid.
contract is written the manager has incentives to ’* Prior to the creation of the Securities and
minimize that depreciation charge, thereby leading Exchange Commission (SEC) in 1934, much
to increased profits (and potentially in- creased variation existed in accounting procedures. See
management compensation) and dividends which Blough [1937, p. 7]. In an unregulated economy, the
transfer wealth from bondholders to shareholders market itself regulates the amount of diversity of
(including management). Thus, contracts will re- accounting procedures. There are economies
associated with using existing practices and
terminology. If the firm adopts previously unknown
ac- counting practices, then the users of the
statements (i.e., creditors monitoring shareholders
and shareholders monitoring management) will incur
costs in learning the new accounting procedures. If
creditors and shareholders have alternative uses of
their capital (i.e., capital markets are competitive) the
costs of the new procedures are ultimately borne by
the shareholders and managers. Hence, new
procedures (and increased diversity) u'ill be
implemented only if their added benefits offset the
added costs they impose.
Watts and Zimmerman 279
practice of accounting. Consequently, accounting of the auditor’s efficiency in monitoring
teachers develop pedagogic devices (rules-of-thumb) management. 26 Hence, the auditor again has an
to assist learning and to structure the variation found incentive to understand how man- agement’s choice
in practice. Theorists examine existing sys- tems of of accounting proce- dures affects agency costs,
accounts and summarize differ- ences and Auditors would value information in the form of
similarities. These descriptions of practice highlight theories predicting how agency costs vary with
the tendencies of firms with particular attributes to accounting pro- cedures. In particular, auditors
follow certain accounting procedures. would like to know how managers’ actions and
Nineteenth century accounting texts and articles hence agency costs would be affected by alternative
indicate that accounting the- orists recognized the accounting procedures.
diversity of practice and attempted to distill general iii) Justification Demand. Early ac- counting
tenden- cies from the diversity. For example: textbooks warned that man- agers would use
accounting to serve their own interests at the
No fixed rules, or rates of depreciation can be expense of share- holders. The second edition of
established for general use, because not only Matheson [1893] contains examples of such warn-
do trades and processes of manufacture differ, ings. Matheson provides illustrations of how
but numerous secondary circumstances have to managers can take advantage of deficiencies in the
be considered in determining the proper course. definition of depreci- ation, repairs, and maintenance
It may, however, be possible to lay down some charges to increase “profits” and their own
general principles which will always apply, or compensation at the expense of share- holders
which, at any rate, may with advantage be held and/or bondholders. For exam- ple, on page 5 he
in view in deciding par- ticular cases. writes:
[Matheson, 1893, p. I ]
The temptation to treat as Profit the Surplus of
Similarly, Dicksee and Tillyard’s [1906] treatise Income over Expenditure, without suffi- cient
describes current accounting practice for goodwill allowance for Deterioration, appears to be often
and the relevant court cases. Based on this irresistible. Thus, in the case of a Tramway
description, the authors “enunciate general business undertaking in its first years of working, a
principles and explain their practical application” dividcnd may be possible only by writing off little
[Dicksee and Tillyard, 1906, or nothing from the capital value of the cars, the
p. vii]. harness, and the horses. This, of course,
ii) Information Demand. In an un- regulated cannot last without the intro-
economy there is a demand for writers to do more
than just describe variations in accounting practice. 2’ See the Leer/s Bernie Building Company case
There is a demand for predictions of the effects of in Edwards [l96Sb, p. 148].
accounting procedures on both the manager’s and
" Share prices are unbiased estimates of the
auditor’s welfare via exposure to law suits. The
auditor con- tracts with the shareholders (and credi- extent to which the auditor monitors management
tors) to monitor management, and he is legally liable and reduces agency costs (sce Fama [1970] and
if he fails to report breaches of covenants in the Gonedes and Dopuch f 1974) for a review' of the
corporation’s articles or by-laws. 2’ Furthermore, the evidence on market efficiency). The larger the
demand for a given auditor’s services is a function reduction in agency costs effected by an auditor (net
of the auditor’s fees), the higher the value of the
corporation's shares and bonds and, cetrris parihus,
the greater the demand for that auditor’s services. If
the rn‹irket observes the auditor failing to monitor
management, it w'ill adjust downwards the share
price of all firms who engage this auditor (to the
extent to u hich the auditor does not reduce agency
costs), and this will reduce the deiiiand for his
services.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


280 The Accounting Review, April 1979

duction of new capital, but in undertakings long notice and for the support, where necessary, of
established there yet may be epochs of members of his own profession, and of those
fictitious profits due to various causes. For in- who, untrained in the practice of Audit- ing, are
stance there may be neglect of repairs, which, confronted with unfamiliar and specious
when the necessity for them becomes evident, pretexts for avoiding the unwelcome charge
will involve a heavy outlay for renewals ; or it against Profits [Matheson, 1893, pp. vii-viii]
may arise from actual fraud in postponing (emphasis added).
expenditure, so as to show large profits, which
will raise the value of shares for stock-jobbing B. The Demand for Accounting Theories in a
purposes. There are railways where the Regulated Economy
dividend income and the corresponding value of
the shares have fluctuated considerably, not This section extends the previous analysis of the
according to alterations in the real earn- ings, demand for theories to in- clude the effects of
but according to alternate neglect and attention government. We assume that private citizens,
in regard to plant. bureau- crats, and politicians have incentives to
employ the powers of the state to make themselves
Accounting texts (and theories) which detail how better off and to coalesce for that purpose. One way
managers seek to manipulate profits and the by which coali- tions of individuals are made better
consequent effects of those manipulations on off is by legislation that redistributes (i.e.,
shareholders and bondholders not only improve the confiscates) wealth.
audi- tor’s ability to monitor such behavior, but also
provide the auditor with ready- made arguments to 1. Accounting and the Political Process
use against such practices in discussions with Farm subsidies, tariffs, welfare, social security,
manage- ment. It is clear that Matheson’s work even regulatory commissions 2’ are examples of
fulfilled this role. William Jackson, a member of the special interest legislation which transfer wealth. The
Council of the Institute of Chartered Accountants in business sector is both the source (via taxes, anti-
England and Wales, stated that he used Matheson’s
book in that fashion: trust, affirmative action, etc.) and the recipient of
many of these wealth trans- fers (via tax credits,
tariffs, subsidies, etc.).
To those who honestly and from conviction Financial accounting statements per- form a
treat the subject on the only sound basis, it may central role in these wealth trans- fers and are
seem superfluous to urge due considera- tion of affected both directly and indirectly by the political
the arguments so convincingly set out in these process. The Securities and Exchange Commission
pages ; but Auditors, and especially those who (SEC) regulates the contents of financial statements
have to deal with joint-stock or other concerns directly (upward asset revalu- ations are not allowed,
where the remuneration of the management is statements of changes in financial position must be
made wholly or partly de- pendent upon prepared, etc.). The Federal Revenue Acts also
declared Profits, know in what varied forms affect the contents of financial statements directly
resistance to an adequate Charge against {e.g., LIFO). In addi-
profits for Depreciation is presented. The
fallacies underlying these objections present
themselves again and again with the 2’ See Stigler [1971], Posner [19741. and Peltzman
modifications caused by the lack of apprehen- [1976].
sion in some, or the ingenuity of others. Mr.
Matheson’sw ork pro side.s the Auditor with
true antidotes to these fallacies, and it ha.s
been in past times used by the writer iv'ith satis-
factor y e]fect, vt here hi.s awn less-reasoned
arguments haue failed to convince.
He therefore recommends it afresh to the
Watts and Zimmerman 281

tion, regulatory commissions (e.g., state 2. The Effect of Government Intervention


public utility boards, various banking on the Demand for Accountfng Theoi ies
and insurance commissions, the Inter- state The rules and regulations which result from
Commerce Commission, the Fed- eral Trade government regulation of business increase the
Commission) often affect the contents of financial pedagogic and information demands for accounting
statements. theories. Even beginning accounting textbooks
Besides these more direct effects, there are indirect report
effects. Government com the income tax requirements of LIFO,
missions often use the contents of finan- cial depreciation, etc. Practitioners demand detailed
statements in the regulatory process (rate setting, texts explaining SEC require- ments (e.q., Rappaport
antitrust, etc.). Further, Congress often bases [1972]), tax codes, and other government
legislative actions on these statements. 2 ' This, in regulations.
turn, provides management with incentives to select The justification demand for theories also
accounting procedures which either reduce the costs expands with regulation. The politi- ca1 process in
they bear or increase the benefits they receive as a the U.S. is characterized as an advocacy
result of the actions of government regulators and proceeding. Proponents and opponents of special
legislators. 29 interest legisla- tion (or petitioners before regulatory
Since public utilities have incentives to propose and administrative committees) must give arguments
accounting procedures for rate making purposes for the positions they advo- cate. If these positions
which increase the market value of the firm, their include changes in accounting procedures,
arguments are assisted if accounting standard- accounting the- ories which serve as justifications
setting bodies such as the Financial Accounting (i.e., excuses) are useful. These advocacy positions
Standards Board (FASB) mandate the same (including theories) will tend to be based on
accounting procedures for financial reporting. 30 contentions that the political action is in the public
Consequently, managers of utilities and other interest,''
regulated industries {e.g., insurance, bank and
transportation) lobby on accounting standards not " The reported profits of U.S. oil companies during
only with their regulatory commissions but also with the Arab oil embargo were used to justify bills to
the Account- ing Principles Board (APB) and the break up these large firms.
FASB. ” See Watts and Zimmerman (1978] for a test of
Moonitz [1974 a and b] and Horngren [1973 and this proposition. Also, see Prakash and Rappaport
1977] document instances of regulated firms [1977] for further discussion of these feedback
seekinp• or opposing accounting procedures which effects. See a bill introduced into the Senate by
affect the value of the firm via direct and indirect Senator Bayh (U.S. Congress, Senate,
wealth transfers. Examples of other firms lobbying Subcommittee on Anti-trust and Monopoly [1975, pp.
on accounting standards exist. Most of the major 5-13] and [1976, p. 1893]). Note that it is absolute
U.S. oil companies made submissions regarding the
size and profits which are used as a justification. On
FASB’s Discussion Memorandum on General Price
Level Adjustments [Watts and Zimmerman, 1978]. this point, see the “Curse of Bigness,” Barron’s
[June 30, 1969, pp. 1 and 8]. Also see Alchian
and Kessel [1962, p. 162).
'° The Interstate Commerce Commission based
its decision to allow tax deferral accounting on APB
Opinion No. 11. See Interstate Commerce
Commission, Accounting for Federal Inr.ome Taxes,
318 I.C.C. 503.
'' Other writers have also recognized the tendency
for advocates to use public interest arguments. For
example, Pichler [1974, pp. 64-651 concludes that
the accounting profession has increased its
economic power via control over entry “through
legislation justified as protecting the public interest”
(p. 64). “In most cases, puhlic rtither than
professional interest w as ctted as the primaly reason
for (the legislation]” (p. 65) (emphasis added).

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


282 The Accounting Review, April 1979

that everyone is made better off, that most are made applied for a hearing on the Federal Power
better off and no one is harmed, or that the action is Commission’s (FPC) Order 530 which allowed the
“fair,” since those contentions are likely to generate use of income tax allocation in setting rates. 32 Order
less opposition than arguments based on self- 530 increases the cash flow of electric utilities “at the
interest. Often, those public interest arguments rely expense of customers using elec- tricity” and hence
upon the notion that the unregulated market solution is harms the interests of Public Systems. But, Public
inefficient. The typical argument is that there is a Systems did not argue that it is in its self-interest to
market failure which can only be reme- died by oppose Order 530. Instead it argued that
government intervention. “normalization [income tax allocation] represents an
Politicians and bureaucrats charged with the inefficient means of subsi- dizing the public utility
responsibility for promoting the general welfare industry” [U.S. Congress, Senate, 1976, p. 683]
demand public interest testimony not only to inform (empha- sis added).
them of the trade-offs but also for use in justifying Bureaucrats also use public interest arguments
their actions to the press and their con- stituencies. to justify their actions.'° For example, the former
Consequently, when politi- cians support (or oppose) SEC Chief Ac- countant, John Burton, a bureaucrat,
legislation, they tend to adopt the public interest justified the disclosure regulations im- posed during
arguments advanced by the special inter- ests who his term in office by arguing:
promote (oppose) the legisla- tion.
i) Examples of Public Interest or Mar- ket In a broad sense we hope [that disclosure
Failure Justifications. The reported objective of the regulations] will contribute to a more efficient
Securities Exchange Act of 1934 and of required capital market. The way in which we hope
disclosure is stated by Mundheim [1964, p. 647]: that will be achieved is first by giving investors
more confidence that they are getting the
The theory of the Securities Act is that if in- whole story and second by encouraging the
vestors are provided with sufficient informa- tion development of better tools of analysis and
to permit them to make a reasoned deci- sion
more responsibility on the part of the profes-
concerning the investment merits of securities
offercd to them, investor interests can be sional analyst to understand what’s going on.
adequately protected without unduly restricting We think that by giving them better data we
the ability of business ventures to raise capital. can encourage them in the direction of doing
a better job, thus leading, we hope, to more
This objective stresses economic effi- ciency. The effective [sic] capital markets [Burton, 1975,
statement suggests that re- quired disclosure can p. 21 ].
increase investors’ welfare at virtually zero cost (i.e.,
that there is a market failure). Government regulation creates a de- mand for
Examples of “public interest”justifica- tions of normative accounting theories employing public
accounting procedures are ob- served in rate- interest arguments, that is, for theories purporting to
setting hearings for public utilities. For example, demon- strate that certain accounting procedures
Public Systems, an organization that represents should be used because they lead to better decisions
munici- palities and rural electrification agencies, by investors, more efficient capital markets, etc.
Further, the demand

" U.S. Congress, Senate [1976, p. 59]. “Metcalf


Staff Report.”
" McGraw [1975, p. 162]. Also, see U.S.
Securities and Exchange Commission [1945, pp. 1-
10].
Watts and Zimmerman 283

is not for one theory, but rather for di- verse terest assumption is consistent with ob- served
prescriptions. On any political issue such as utility phenomena. 3' They have pro- posed an alternative
rate determination, there will be at least two sides. In assumption—that individuals involved in the political
the FPC Order 530 example, Coopers & Lybrand, process act in their own interest (the self-interest
who opposed Public Systems, wanted a theory assumption). This assump- tion yields implications
which prescribed income tax allocation, while Public which are more consistent with observed
Systems wanted a theory which did not. When we phenomena than those based on the public interest
con- sider that accounting methods are rele- vant to assumption. 3’
taxes, antitrust cases, union negotiations, disclosure The costs and benefits to voters of becoming
regulations, etc., as well as utility rate-setting, we informed, of lobbying, of forming coalitions, and of
expect a demand for a multitude of prescriptions. monitoring their representatives’ actions are of cen-
With increased government interven- tion in tral importance in a self-interest model of the political
business, the demand for theories which justify process. Downs [1957] sug- gests that the expected
particular accounting pro- cedures (proposed in the effect of one individual’s vote on the outcome of an
self-interest of various parties) has come to eclipse election is trivial, and, hence, the indi- vidual voter
the demand for theories which fulfill the pedagogic has very little incentive to incur the costs of
and information roles. We present evidence to becoming informed on political issues. On the other
support this proposi- hand, individual voters do have incentives to act as
tion in Section V. groups in the political process. Economies of scale
in political action encourage group participation.
When several voters have similar interests on
ii) Rationalit y or “Theory Illusion.” Until particular issues (e.g., members of a trade union),
recently, it had been popular in the economics
those voters can share the “fixed” costs of becoming
literature to assume that politicians, elected officials,
informed and moreover can increase the likelihood
bureaucrats, etc., acted in the “public interest” (the
of affecting the outcome of an election by voting as a
public interest assumption). 3’ In order to determine
bloc.'8
which actions are in the public interest, politicians
require theories which predict the consequences of
alter- native actions. “Rational,” “public in- terest”- '* For a summary of this literature see Posner
oriented politicians/bureaucrats would tend to use [1974] and McCraw f 975).
the theories which best predict (i.e., the “best” ” By “best” theory, we mean the theory most con-
theories) 35 and hence those theories would sistent with observed phenomena. Such theories
predominate. Leading articles in the accounting allow public officials to predict the outcomes of their
litera- ture are implicitly based on the public interest actions, thereby helping them select actions which
premise (AAA [1966, p. 5], AICPA [1973, p. 17], increase social welfare.
Gonedes and Dopuch [1974, pp. 48—49 and pp. ’ 6 See Posner [19741
114— 118], Beaver and Demski [1974, p. 185]) that ' 7 For analyses of the political process based on
the “best” theories prevail. this assumption see Downs [19571. Jensen [1976],
In recent years, however, economists have Meckling [1976a and b], Mueller [1976], Niskanen
questioned whether the public in- (1971], Peltz- man [1976], Stigler [1971], and Leffter
and Zimmerman [1977].
" Stigler [1971] attempts to explain the regulation
of an industry on the basis of variation of coalition
costs, free-rider costs, e/c., with such variables as
group size, homogeneity of interests, etc.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


284 The Accounting Review, April 1979
The costs of political action also de- pend on the always lead to acceptance of the “best” theory. The
existing political institutions (e.g., whether political usefulness of that assump- tion depends on the
decisions are made by referendum or a vote of empirical consistency of its implications. It is an
elected representatives) [Leftler and Zimmer- man, empirical question. The work by Posner [1974],
1977]. If we call the sum of the costs of political action Stigler [1971], and Peltzman [1976] supports the
the “transactions costs” of political decisions, the assumption.
crucial question is “what is the magnitude of these The assumption that the transactions costs of the
transactions costs?” If the transac- tions costs of political process are non-zero is analogous to the
political decisions are high, self-interest motivated assumption of non- zero transactions costs in
government ser- vants will not always act in the capital mar-
public interest; if they are zero, they will. 3’ Hence, if kets. o In capital market theory it is
the transactions costs of the political process are typically assumed that transactions costs are zero
high, government officials will not use the “best” despite the fact they obviously are not, because that
theory available; if they are zero, they will. assumption yields empirically confirmed hypotheses.
As an example of the importance of Why then, should political transactions costs be
positive political transactions costs, con- sider the sufficiently more important than capi- tal market
manager of a utility advocating deferred tax transactions costs to warrant their inclusion in a
accounting because of its effects on utility rates. The political theory?
manager will argue that recognizing deferred taxes We suggest that there is an important difference
as current operating costs is in the public interest. between capital markets and the political process
The official responsible for allowing or not allowing which make trans- actions costs important in the
this practice has a greater incentive to resist the latter case. There is, in the capital markets, a direct
lobbying efforts of the utility manager if other market for control. If the manager of a corporation is
individuals (e.g., consumer advocates) lobby against not maximizing the market value of the corporation’s
the procedure. Whether those individuals lobby shares, then an individual can, by buying its shares,
depends on the costs of consumers being informed acquire control of the corporation in the capital
about the effects of the accounting procedures on markets and, therefore, obtain the right to make the
their welfare (which requires human capital), the decisions. That in- dividual can change the
costs of forming groups to oppose the procedure, corporation’s decisions and reap for himself the
etc. The man- ager’s public interest theory (which is capital gain from the increase in the value of the
an “excuse” to cover a self-interest motive and need corporation’s stock. If the Chairman of the Securities
not be valid) increases the costs of others being and Exchange Commission were not making
informed and will tend to be accepted by the public decisions in the public interest, an individual could
official if the transactions costs are large enough. not directly buy the right to make those decisions
We assume that political transactions costs are and capture the benefits of the changed decision.
large enough to cause the ac- ceptance of “invalid” Because direct payments to
theories, that the competition among excuses does
not °’ The social choice literature (see Mueller [1976])
discusses the conditions which guarantee Pareto-
efficient decisions by regulators.
“ 0 Sec Fama [1976] for a review of capital market
theory.
Watts and Zimmerman 285
elected officials are illegal and payments in kind are used to determine accounting practice and
generally more expensive, it is costlier to bribe standards.4 3 The ideal state of affairs to them is
Congressmen, Senators, etc., than to purchase a one in which theorists logically and objectively
controlling inter- est in a corporation. It is also costly determine the merits of alternative procedures.^4
to establish indirect ways of achieving the same For example, Hendriksen [1977, p. 1] writes: “ ... the
result.4‘ most important goal of aé- counting theory should be
Notice that in our model of the politi- cal process to provide a coherent set of logical principles that
everyone is rational. No one is being “fooled” by form the general frame of reference for the
accounting theories; they are not “fooled” by “theory evaluation and development of sound accounting
illu- sion.”*’ If people do not investigate the validity of practices.” Theorists tend to bemoan the fact that
theories, it is because they do not expect such this ideal state does not exist and that corporate
investigation to be worth- while. If the expected managers, auditors, and politicians do not allow
benefits of investi- gation to an individual are small, them to determine accounting stan- dards."
he will make only a limited investigation. Most theorists probably believe that an
Our assumption of high political costs is crucial to objective of their research and the reason they
our theory. As we shall see in the next section, the supply theories to provide know- ledge which will
assumption enables us to discriminate between the ultimately improve ac-
empirical implications of our theory and the impli-
cations of an alternative theory. This allows empirical t' See Zimmerman [1977] for further discussion of
testing. Ultimately, the test of the political cost this issue. Essentially, the reason it is costlier to
assumption is whether the implications of the theory purchase “control” of the political system (via a
based on the assumption are confirmed or not by system of bribes, payoffs, etc.) is that the legal
empirical tests. Thus, the merit of an assumption is system does not enforce these contracts to the
judged by the predic- tions it generates. Those same extent that the state enforces the property
accounting researchers who build theories on the rights of residual claimants in corpora- tions. Hence,
assumption that information is a pure public good
morc (costly) monitoring is required to enforce
(e.g., Gonedes and Dopuch [1974] and Beaver
contracts between politicians,/bureaucrats and other
[1976]) often assert that information is a pure public
good. Yet, no tests of these theories have been parties.
provided. In Section IV we argue that implications of *’ Buchanan and Wagner [1977, pp. 128—130]
our theory are consistent with the evidence. intro- duce the concept of “fiscal illusion” as a
systematic bias in indivkluals’ perceptions of the
III. Tire SUPPLY OF AccOuNTING differential effects of alternative taxing procedures.
THEORIES They hypothesize “that complex and indirect
payment structures create a fiscal illusion that will
Accounting theorists often view them- selves as systematically produce higher levels of public outlay
expert critics or defenders of accounting than those that would be observed under simple-
prescriptions {e.g., replace- ment cost, historical payment structures.” (p. 129) It could be argued that
cost, etc.). They argue that accounting theory should individuals also suffer from “theory illusion” {i.e., that
be more complex theories obscure political behavior).
We do not subscribe to this phenomenon, bitt otter it
as an alternative explanation.
‘ 3 Mautz [1966, p. 6] and Sterling [1973, p. 491
a* Ijiri [1971, p. 26] states, “Accounting theorists
are scientific observers of accounting practices and
their surrouding environment. Their theories are
required to have the highest degree of objectivity.”
^’ Moonitz [1974b] does not belie\’e that
accounting research should be the sole source for
setting practice, but that it should have a role,
“Almost everyone agrees that research is an
essential component of the process of establishing
accounting standards” (p. 58). He goes on to suggest
that “accountants must curb the power of the
management” (p. 68).

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


286 The Accounting Review, April 1979
counting practice. They would not regard themselves salary and a plenitude of research funds.46
as supplying “excuses.” But we suggest that the Practitioners, regulators, and those teaching future
predominant con- temporary demand for accounting practitioners are more likely to read or hear of the
theo- ries (the demand for accounting in a regulated output of an accounting researcher if it bears on
economy) is the demand for justifications— topics of current interest. As a result, the researcher
“excuses.” If that empiri- cal proposition is correct, who is motivated by pecuniary and non-pecuniary
the question is: How responsive is the supply side factors (e.g., “free” trips to conferences) will tend to
(accounting research) to changes in the nature and write on the current controversies in accounting.
quantity of the economic good being demanded? Therein lies the connection to the de- mands of
As long as there exists a large number of vested interests. Controversies arise in accounting
individuals who are able to supply a wide diversity of when vested interests disagree over accounting
theories (i.e., as long as numerous close substitutes standards. For example, the LIFO controversy arose
exist) at rela- tively low cost, then supply will be very when the Supreme Court outlawed the base stock
responsive to demand. Stigler’s observa- tion method of valuing inventory for tax purposes and the
succinctly summarizes this point: American Pe- troleum Institute recommended LIFO
to replace it, thereby reducing the present value of
. consumers generally determine what will be its members’ taxes. The Internal Revenue Service
produced, and producers make profits by resisted because of the effect on revenues. The
discovering more precisely what consumers parties demanded pro and con LIFO theories which
want and producing it more cheaply. Some may were eventually produced [Moonitz, 1974, pp. 33-
entertain a tinge of doubt about this proposition, 34].
thanks to the energy and skill of Professor Accounting researchers often include a
Galbraith, but even his large talents hardly set of policy recommendations as part of their
raise a faint thought that I live in a house rather research project." Those recom- mendations, made
than a tent because of the comparative on the basis of some objective assumed by the
advertising outlays of the two industries. This researcher, may never have been intended to serve
Cambridge eccentricity aside, then, it is useful as an “excuse” for the corporate manager,
to say that consumers direct proJuctio and practitioner or politician who prefers the
therefore, do they not direct the production of recommended procedure for self-interest reasons.
the words and ideas of in- tellectuals, rather Nevertheless, the research find- ings will be
than, as in the first view, vice-uersa? [Stigler, favorably quoted by those with vested interests.^'
1976, p. 347] (emphasis added). The more read-

The consumers (“vested interests”) determine the " Even though we have argued the existence of
production of accounting research through the close substitutes, all researchers will not be earning
incentives they pro- vide for accounting theorists. the same compensation. Higher compensation will
The greater the prestige and articulation skills of an accrue to the most prolific, articulate, and creative
accounting researcher, the more likely practitioners, advocates—to those who are able to establish early
regulators and other aca- demics will know his work property rights in a topic and thus must be cited by
and the greater the flow of both students and funds to later theorists.
his university. Researchers have non-pecuni- ary ^’ See Beaver [1973 J for an example of policy
incentives to be well-known, and this reputation is prescrip- tions based on accounting research.
rewarded by a higher ^' An interesting case in point is the work of Ijiri
[1967 and 1975]. Ijiri claims to be a positivist—“...
the
Watts and Zimmerman 287
able the research, the more frequently it is quoted, we do not necessarily expect accounting researchers
the more the researcher’s fame increases. Similarly, to be inconsistent from issue to issue. Academic
criticisms of alterna- tive accounting practices will be evaluation and criti- cism create incentives for each
quoted by vested interests and will also increase the researcher to be consistent. However, the rationales
researcher’s reputation. given for observed accounting standards may well
The link between suppliers of account- ing theory be inconsistent across issues and different sections
and consumers goes further than mere quotation. of the same ac- counting standard.
Partners in ac- counting firms, bureaucrats in Rationales differ (and are inconsistent) across
govern- ment agencies and corporate managers will accounting standards because a standard is the
seek out accounting researchers who have eloquently result of political action. The outcome depends on
and consistently advo- cated a particular practice the relative costs which the various involved parties
which happens to be in the practitioner’s, are willing to incur to achieve their goals. And these
bureaucrat’s, or manager’s self-interest and will ap- costs will vary with the ex- pected benefits. The
point the researcher as a consultant, or expert rationale given for a standard will be the successful
witness, or commission him to conduct a study of party’s rationale; and if it is a compromise, such as
that accounting problem. Consistency in the APB Opinion 16 on business combina- tions,
researcher’s work allows the party commissioning the mixtures of rationales will be used.’° The same party
work to predict more accurately the ultimate is not successful in every issue; indeed many are not
conclusions. Thus, research and consulting funds will even involved in every issue. Further, vested
tend to flow to the most eloquent and consistent
advocates of accounting practices where there are
vested interests who benefit by the adop- tion or purpose [of this book] is a better understanding of
rejection of these accounting practices. the foundations of accounting as it is and not as
The tendency of vested interests to seek out someone thinks it ought to be.” [1967, p. x] He states
researchers who support their position produces a
survival bias.^’ The bias is introduced by the vested that his work “is not intended to be pro-establishment
interests. We do not mean to impugn the motives of or to promote the maintenance of the status quo.
accounting researchers who advocate particular The purpose of such an exercise is to highlight
practices. In fact, the more consistent the positions of where changes are most needed and where they are
the researcher and the greater his integrity, the more feasible.” [1975, p. 281 But, then, in the same
support he lends to the vested interest’s position. monograph (pp. 8W90), Ijiri presents a defense of
Given the rewards for supplying theo- ries on historical costs, saying, “Our defense of historical
controversial issues, we expect to observe cost should not, however, be inter- preted to mean
competition in the supply of accounting theories that historical cost is without any flaw” (p. 85). Ijiri
related to those issues. The prescriptions for an concludes this defense with a statement, “We should
issue are likely to be as diverse as the po@tions of in fact try to improve the accounting system based
vested interests. But despite this diversity, on historical cost not by abandoning it, but by
modifying it [e.g., through price level adjustments)
and supplementing it with data based on other
valuation methods” (p. 90). Despite being a
professed positivist, Ijiri is making a strong normative
statement. No wonder the AAA [1977, p. 10]
committee when summarizing Ijiri [1975] concludes,
“[he] defends historical cost against the criticisms of
current-cost and current value. ” At least part of the
“market” views Ijiri as a
defender of the status quo.
*’ Just as in any market, those who produce what
is demanded have a better chance of survival than
those who do not.
’° See Zeff (1972, pp. 212-216J for an account of
this compromise.

Copyright 2001 All Ri0hts Reserved


288 The Accounting Review, April 1979

interests (e.g., an insurance company) are less are attempting to explain accounting theory as it is
constrained to give consistent rationales across represented in the account- ing literature (see
issues. Hence, we ob- serve a party supporting footnote 1). It is con- ceivable that an accounting
historical cost valuation in some cases and market theory could be produced and used in the political
valuation in others.5’ process to institute a regulation, but not appear until
If political transactions costs are high so that later in the accounting literature. In other words, the
there is a demand for excuses which are useful “public interest” could, in fact, motivate the theory
weapons in the political arena, if the demand for and the regulation, but the publi- cation of the theory
accounting theory is dominated by that demand for nonetheless, could, lag legislation. In that case,
excuses, and if demand determines pro- duction, neither the public interest theory nor our theory could
accounting theories will be generated by, not explain the accounting literature. In essence, we
generate, political debates. We will observe the would be left without a theory of the literature.
nature of accounting theory changing as political However, those who would argue such a scenario
issues change. Accounting theory will change must then produce another explanation for, or theory
contemporaneously with or lag political issues. We of, the accounting literature.
will not observe accounting theory generally leading In Section IV we compare the timing of
po- litical action. general movements in the accounting literature to
Contrast the preceding predictions to what we the timing of regulation to see if a priori the evidence
would expect under alternative theories of supports our theory or the public interest theory. We
accounting theory. The only alternative theory which do not present any formal tests which discriminate
we can even partially specify is that theories in the between the two theories, although we believe such
accounting literature are used to further the “public tests could be performed (e.g., by using citation
interest” {i.e., they assist politicians or bureaucrats in tests). However, the serious problem in doing a
producing regulations to further the “public inter- formal test is that the public interest theory, like other
est”). In order for politicians or bureau- crats to use alternative theories, is poorly specified. Hopefully,
that literature we would have to observe the theories this paper will cause others to specify the public
appearing in the literature before or, at best, at the interest theory better or specify alterna- tive theories
same time as the relevant regulation. The of the accounting literature so that testing is
appearance of the theories in the litera- ture could facilitated.
not lag the regulation. Thus, we can discriminate One or two papers discussing a topic
between our theory and the alternative public prior to the time the topic becomes politically active
interest theory if the appearance of theories in the is not sufficient to reject our theory, just as one or
litera- ture tends to lead or lag regulation. If it tends two “heads” is not sufficient to reject the hypothesis
to lead, the public interest hypothe- sis is supported. that a given coin is “fair.” It is important to remember
If it lags, our theory is supported. On the other hand, that as in all empirical theories we are concerned
if the literature and regulation are contempo- with
raneous we cannot discriminate between the two
hypotheses. ' Ernst & Ernst [1976] has proposed that
It is important to remember that we replacement cost be used for depreciable assets
while historical costs be continued for other assets.

Right's ese /e“d ”***


Watts and Zimmerman 289

general trends. Our predictions are for the theory: the laws regulating railroads, the income tax
accounting literature in general. We are not laws, and the securities acts. In this section we do
purporting to have a theory that explains the not purport to present an exhaustive list of
behavior of all accounting researchers or the legislation which has created a demand for account-
acceptance, or lack of acceptance, of every ing “excuses” or to present a complete analysis of
published paper. There are many interesting each type of legislation. Our objective is merely to
phenomena that this theory, at this stage of develop- present prima facie support for the hypothesis that
ment, cannot yet explain. But this does not ipso facto account- ing theory haschanged after theintroduc-
destroy the value of the theory. tion of government regulation.
Our analysis suggests that the account- When dealing with historical events such as
ing literature is not the simple accumula- tion of government regulation, the “evi- dence” presented is
knowledge and consequent development of always subject to interpretation and the ex post
techniques. It is not a literature in which, as Littleton selection bias of the researchers. Critics can always
suggests.5° concepts become better understood charge that “strategic sampling” of references
and consequently leads to “better” account- ing produced the results. In fact, much of the economic
practices. Instead it is a literature in which the theory of regulation suffers from this ex post
concepts are altered to permit accounting practices rationalization. However, at this early stage in the
to adapt to changes in political issues and development of the theory, an ex post case study
institutions. approach has yielded insights [Posner, 1974] and
In this section, the existence of close substitute ap- pears to be the logical and necessary precursor
suppliers of theories was shown to make the supply to a general theory of regula- tion. We are aware of
of accountinp• “excuses” very responsive to the de- these methodologi- ca1 problems. Even though the
mand. In the next section we argue that the evidence we present is somewhat “casual,” and not
evidence we have gathered is con- sistent with the as “rigorous” as we would like, it is, nonetheless,
proposition that the market for accounting research evidence.’° Furthermore, we have endeavored to
is the market for “excuses” and suggests that the choose the refer- ences from the standard, classical
theory will be confirmed in formal testing. ac- counting literature. Undoubtedly, con-
IV. THE EMPIRICAL RELATIONSHIP
’ 2 There is little evidence of fresh idcas regarding
BETWEEN GOYERNMENT INTERVEN- depreciation until the middle of the nineteenth
TION AND AccOUNTING THEORY century. The appearance of steam railroads at that
If the demand for “excuses” is impor- tant in time directed attention as never before to fLxed
determining the output of ac- counting theorists, we assets and their asso- ciated problems of
expect to observe changes in accounting theory maintenance, renewal and improve- ment. Out of the
when a new law is passed which impinges on ac- discussion and experience which fol- lowed, new
counting practice. This section examines how ideas about depreciation took form and the ground
accounting practice and theories were affected by was prepared for a better comprehension of the real
several major types of legislation. We have selected nature of depreciation itselP’ [Littleton 1933, p. 227
three types of legislation which we believe have had ].
a pronounced impact on accounting ' It is tempting to suggest citation tests of the
theory
{i.e., the frequency of articles on a subject increases
with regulation). Bcsides the obvious cost of such a
test, it suffers front the interpretation bias of the
researchers. Also, how should changes in
terminology be controlled? We would welcome
anyone u ho can overcome these methodological
diflicul ties to perform the tests.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


290 The Accounting Review, April 1979

flicting citations and references exist. Critics can, bate arise with the railroads (i.e., was there some
will, and should raise these conflicting citations, government regulation or political action present in
keeping in mind the statistical fallacies of drawing the case of the railroads that was not present for
inferences based on sample sizes of one. We do not earlier corporations); and if so, (2) did that
contend that all issues are settled, but rather government regulation or political action precede the
encourage others to pursue, cor- rect, and extend literature?
our analysis. (1) The reason for the debate was investigated
by Littleton [1933]. He asserts that two conditions
A. Railroad Legislation were neces- sary to the development of depreciation
The growth of railroads is considered by many accounting—corporations with limited liability and
accountants to have been very important in the long-lived assets. He suggests that limited liability
development of ac- counting theory, Hendriksen was a necessary condition, because it led to
[1977, p. 40] lists it as one of the main influences on covenants restricting dividends to profits and there-
accounting theory in the period from 1800 to 1930. by created the demand for financial state- ments
Littleton [1933, pp. 239— 241] is more specific; he which report profits (see Section II). Long-lived
ascribes the development of depreciation accounting assets were important because, if they had not
and the concern with depreciation in the literature in existed, there would have been no necessity to
the nineteenth century to the growth of railroads. calculate depreciation to determine profits.
There is no doubt that the development of railroads We think that Littleton’s analysis is incomplete.
both in the U.S. and the U.K. affected the accounting First, agency costs of debt and equity exist whether or
literature on the nature of depreciation, including the not a corpora- tion has legally limited liability. Limited
question of charging depreciation as an expense liability merely shifts some of the risk [Jensen and
[Pollins, 1956; and Boockholdt, 1977]. Holmes Meckling, 1976, pp. 331— 332]. Given that the
[1975, p. 18] writes: function of dividend covenants is to reduce the
agency costs of debt, it is not surprising to observe
Depreciation was a knotty problem for these them existing as early as 1620 for U.K. com- panies,
early railroad accountants. They argued over it, long before limited liability was generally recognized
scorned it, denied it, anatomized it, and for companies. We can easily amend Littleton’s
misused their own concepts. But in the end it argument for this defect; for the first condition of
was from the very ashes of their disagree- limited liability, we substitute the exis- tence of
ments that our modern concepts of deprecia- dividend covenants.
tion rose Phoenix-like hfty years later. Second, dividend covenants and long- lived
assets would not necessarily lead to depreciation
This literature existed at least by 1841 in the U.K. being treated as an expense. The dividend
[The Railway Times, October 30, 1841, quoted in covenants put a lower bound on the equity
Pollins, 1956) and by 1850 in the U.S. [Dionysius participation of
Lardner’s book quoted in Pollins, 1956]. Although
the debate did not result in depreciation being
’• The general practice in both countries came to
treated as an expense in either the
be the writing-off of the value of fixed assets at the
U.S. or U.K.,’* theories of depreciation were
enunciated. Consequently, given our theory, we time of retirement of the asset.
have to answer two ques- tions: (1) why did this
depreciation de-
Watts and Zimmerman 291

shareholders. As long as sufficient earn- ings have and forts did not receive consideration in the
been retained in the past to cover the depreciation of trading companies’ bookkeeping, while the
fixed assets to the current time, there would be no railroads, as has been seen, did give consider-
necessity to deduct depreciation syste- matically able attention to the problem of wear and tear
each year. We do not observe depreciation being of roadway and equipment. Apparently
treated as an expense prior to this century. Instead it .some third element was also needed, which
was treated as an allocation of profits. was present in f/ie case of //ie railroads but not
This suggests that Littleton’s analysis has not earlier (emphasis added).
been supported empirically. Observation of his two
conditions would not necessarily be accompanied by Littleton [1933, p. 240) suggests that the missing
de- preciation being treated as an expense. variable is knowledge, that it took 200 years for the
Littleton’s two conditions existed in the seventeenth nature of the cor- poration to become known. We
and eighteenth centuries (dividend covenants can suggest that a more plausible explanation is that, in
be observed as early as 1620 and were included in the case of railroads, fares and rates were regulated
com- pany charters as a general practice in the by government on the basis of “profits.”
eighteenth century). Limited liability for Both in the U.S. and the U.K., some
U.K. companies existed de facto at least by the transportation prices were regulated be- fore the
l730sand was explicitly recognized by 1784.5 5 The existence of railroads. For example, the rates of the
U.K. trading companies of the seventeenth and Fort Point Ferry (U.S.), incorporated in 1807, were,
eighteenth centur- ies certainly had long-lived according to its charter, to be fixed by the court. [Dodd,
assets—forts and ships. Yet, we do not observe any 1954, p. 258]. However, railroad rates came to be
real concern with depreciation expense until the tied to profits. The early U.S. railroad charters often
nineteenth century. had provisions for the adjustment of their rates based
Littleton recognized that his analysis was on profits. For example, the charter of the Franklin
inconsistent with observed phe- nomena and that Railroad Company, incorporated in Massachu- setts
some other variable was necessary to explain the in 1830, included the following provision:
absence of concern about depreciation expense in
both accounting theory and practice. He eloquently if at any time after the expiration of four years from
expresses the inconsistency [Littleton, 1933, p. 240] the completion of the Road, the net in-
:
” See DuBois f 938, pp. 94—95) for a report on
The simultaneous appearance of these two the incorporation proceedings of the Albion Flour Mill
elements—active, long-lived assets and a in 1784. In thosc proceedings, the Attorney General
special need for the careful calculation of net gave an opinion on limited liability which caused
profit—seems to be essential to the recogni- DuBois to conclude that, “for England at any rate,
tion of the importance of depreciation. Before the fact of in- corporation either by the Crown or by
these two are joined depreciation is incidental Parliament came to be the criterion for the extent of
to the profit calculation; afterward it be- comes limited liability” (p. 96). Note, however, that it was
indispensable. First in the trading companies, theoretically possible for shareholders of insolvent
later in the railroads, these two elements were companies to be made subject to calls. (See
united and the foundations for depreciation DuBois, pp. 98—103). DuBois (p.
accounting were laid. But, so far as could be 95) recognized that de facio limited liability existed in
learned, the depreciation of ships the 1730s and 1740s: “it should be noted that
through the financial tribulations of the Charitable
Corporation, the York Buildings Company, and the
Royal African Com- pany, which in the thirties and
forties were making life miserable for their creditors,
there was no suggestion of any attempt to proceed
against the personal estates of the members of the
corporations.”

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


292 The Accounting Review, April 1979

come shall have amounted to more than ten company which was formed under special
percent per annum, from the date of the Parliamentary sanction to carry on an under-
completion aforesaid, upon the actual cost of taking of a special public nature. Since for this
said Road, the Legislature may take measures purpose it had special powers, it should there-
to alter and reduce the rates of toll and in- fore be subject to special scrutiny and (if
come, in such manner as to take off the over- necessary) control by the Srate on behalf of the
plus for the next four years, calculating the public.
amount of transportation and income to be
the same as the four preceding years; and, at The question of railroad profits and the public
the expiration of every four years thereafter interest was raised in the political process in both
the same proceeding may be had [Dodd, the U.S. and the
1954, p. 260]. U.K. in the nineteenth century. Hence, it is not
surprising that questions of calculating profits and
The charters of three other railroads in- corporated whether depreci- ation should be charged as an
in Massachusetts in the same year included a similar expense were raised. The accounting methods of
provision. [Dodd, 1954, p. 261]. treating capital additions, depreciation, repairs
The private acts of Parliament in- corporating the and renewals, etc., could affect reported profits
early U.K. railroads typically fixed the maximum and hence the rates and market values of
rates ex- plicitly; but, in one notable exception, the railroads. Thus, there was a demand for
Liverpool and Manchester Rallway Act in 1826 rationalizations of alternative procedures.
limited the company’s divi- dends to ten percent of The political issue of railroad profits led several
the capital and required that its rates be reduced by U.S. states (Virginia (1837), New Hampshire and
five percent for each one percent of dividend above Rhode Island (1841), New York (1855),
ten percent [Pollins, 1956, pp. 337—338]. Parliament Massachusetts (1869) and Illinois (1869)) to pass
soon began regu- lating railroad profits. In 1836, legis- lation which in some way regulated railroads,
James Morrison sought to have Parliament restrict usually by “controlling ex- tortionate rates.”
the profits of all railways. Clauses in Gladstone’s [Boockholdt, 1977, p. 13; Johnson, 1965, p. 218;
1844 Bill, and Nash,
1947, 2]. According to Nash [1947,
authorized the Board of Trade to consider the p. 3), Several of the early state laws called for
position and profits of any railway which had a statements of provision for depreciation in annual
charter for fifteen years and to decide whether reports but with- out definition as to what such
to buy it up on prescribed terms or, provisions should be.” Arguments for depreciation
alternatively, to revise all its charges if it had are expected to follow such regulations. Finally, in
made a profit of more than ten percent on its 1887 federal legislation estab- lished the Interstate
capital for three consecutive years [Cooke, Commerce Com- mission to prohibit unreasonable
1950, p. 135]. rates and price discrimination, control mer- gers, and
prescribe a uniform system of accounts. The
Though these clauses were weakened in the actual Interstate Commerce Commission adopted an
Railways Regulation Act of 1844, a principle was accounting pol- icy of charging “repairs or renewals
established. Cooke [1950, p. 136] explains, of ties, rails, roadway, locomotives and cars under
the classification ‘operating
The Act therefore fell short of the designs of
Gladstone’s committee and it is notable not for
any reform it accomplished but rather for the
principle embodied in it, that railway companies
were one example of a class of

...-. . . .-. .-. . . .-. .-.-. . . .-. .- •• g .•. . • •••••••••


.-.-.-.-. . . . . . . . . . . . . .-.-.-
-+

h
Watts and Zimmerman 293

expenses’ [which typically results in higher reported action generated accounting theory, not vice-versa.
expenses than depreci- ation) but did not mention As we have seen, the early
depreciation” [Littleton, 1933, p. 236]. U.S. railroad charters in the 1830s included
Although railroads were the prime target of provisions for regulation of profits. Those charters
regulation, the rates of other public utilities were also precede the de- bates observed in the accounting
regulated in the nineteenth century. A Gas litera- ture. The move by Morrison to have
Commission was established in Massachusetts in Parliament regulate the profits of U.K. railroads also
1885 and two years later was expanded to regulate precedes the debates.
electric companies. Later, it was given control over
capitalization and rates [Nash, 1947, p. 3]. B. Income Tax Acts
Municipalities regulated water company rates The influence of the income tax laws on financial
(Spring Valley Water Works r. Schottler (1883)) reporting practice is well known and much lamented
[Clay, 1932, p. 33] and such regulation led to legal by academ- ics." That influence is very obvious in
disputes over whether depreci- ation should be the practice of charging depreciation to net income,
considered in determin- ing rates (Sait Diego Water rather than treating it as an allocation of profit.
Co. v. San Diego) [Riggs, 1922, pp. 155—157]. In Saliers [1939, pp. 17—18] describes the effect of the
addition, states regulated the charges for grain 1909 Excise Tax Law, the forerunner of the 1913
elevators (Munn v. Illinois (1877)) [Clay, 1932, p. 30]. Income Tax Law:
It is our hypothesis that rate regulation (primarily “Financial looseness” describcs the account-
of the railroads) created a demand for theories ing practices of industries in general at that
rationalizing depre- ciation as an expense. time. The company bookkeepers, when clos-
Furthermore, we expect that the more popular of ing their books, based the amount of the
these theories would stress that it is in the “public depreciation charge on the amount of profit
interest” for depreciation to be treated as an earned in that year. A lean year caused the
expense. Without regulation there was no necessity property to receive little or no charge for
for depreciation to be a charge, systematically depreciation, while a prosperous year caused a
deducted each year in determining net income. liberal allowance to be made. The author- ities
However, because rate regulation was justified in had reason for either action at their fingertips,
terms of restricting the eco- nomic profits of shifting one side to the other as conditions
monopolists (or elimi- nating “ruinous” competition), warranted. But after the year 1909 the shift was
regula- tion created a demand for justifications to the side of larger depreciation charges, for in
arguing for depreciation to be treated as an annual that year the Corporation Excise Tax Law was
charge to profits. Furthermore, because regulatory enacted. This law levied a 1% tax on net
legislation was often based on economic income of corporations in excess of $5,000.
arguments, theories of depreciation came to be This net income was said to be the figure
couched in terms of economic costs. resulting after deducting ordi- nary and
(2) The timing of the debate appears to necessary expenses and all losses, including
confirm our hypothesis that political an allowance for depreciation, from gross profit.
Depreciation expense was made

’ 6 Hendriksen [1977, p. 491 states, “The effect on


ac- counting theory of taxation of business incomes
in the United States and in other countries has been
consider- able, but it has been primarily indirect in
nature....
While the revenue acts did hasten the adoption of
good accounting practices and thus brought about
a more criti- cal analysis of accepted accounting
procedures and concepts, they have also been a
deterrent to experimenta- tion and the acceptance
of good theory.”

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


294 The Accounting Review, April 1979

an allowable deduction and was universally determining “profits available for divi- dends.” The
deducted by those corporations affected by legal decisions were con- sistent: if the corporate
the act. The effect of this act on the growth of articles required a provision for depreciation, it had
the use of the depreciation charge cannot be to be taken; if not it did not. As Litherland [1968, p.
overemphasized. It was the first instance in 171] states, “the question of depreciation was a
which the writing off of depreciation a.s expense matter of internal management with which the law
had nothing to do. The Articles of the given company
wa.s definitely aduantayeous. That fact alone were to govern.”
insured its general ayylication (emphasis We suggest that the reason a general concern
added). with the depreciation for all corporations (and not
The influence of tax laws on accounting theory just railroads) appeared in the U.K. literature in the
appears to be as dramatic as Saliers’ description of 1880s and not before is that, prior to 1878, the U.K.
the U.S. tax laws’ effect on accounting practice, tax laws made no allow- ance for depreciation. “In
particu- larly with respect to depreciation. Con- cern 1878 the law was modified to permit the deduction of
with depreciation as an expense existed only in the a reasonable amount for the diminished value of
railroad accounting literature until the 1880s. In that machinery and plant resulting from wear and tear.
decade we observe a spate of U.K. journal articles Depreciation was not mentioned in the law and no
and textbooks on the question of depreciation for amount was permitted for obsolescence” [Saliers,
corporations in gen- eral. We do not observe the 1939, p. 255]. Now there was an addi- tional reason
same concern in the U.S. at that time. This raises the for arguing over the concept of annual depreciation
question of why the sudden concern with and its level— taxes [Leake, 1912, p. 180].
depreciation in the U.K., not just for public utilities, The income tax explanation for the
but for all corporations. Further, why did such a late nineteenth century depreciation de- bate also
concern with depreciation for all corporations not explains the absence of that debate in the U.S.
manifest itself in the U.S.? Briefs hypothesis does not. The first effective U.S.
Brief [1976, p. 737] suggests that the corporate income tax law was the Excise Tax Act of
U.K. literature was motivated by a con- cern with 1909 (which went into effect before it was delared
“paying dividends out of capital” and that unconstitutional).5’ Thus, in 1880 there was no
“accountants sought first of all to clarify theory, and federal tax motiva- tion driving a debate over
second, to understand their responsibility in these depreciation. There was in the U.S. in 1880 the
matters. However, they were offered little assistance problem of determining “profits available for
from judicial and statu- tory authority which failed to dividends.”
The tax laws affected not only the timing of
specify rules of accounting behavior.” Although the
depreciation discussions, but
accounting authors of the time may have suggested
that was the problem, we think it is a very
unsatisfactory answer to the question of what really ’ 7 An increase in the effective corporate tax rate
motivated the literature for two reasons. First, we from less than 1 percent in 1909 to over 7 percent in
have already noted that the “profits available for 1918 further stimulated the concern for
dividends” question had existed for 260 years. depreciation in the
Second, there was no uncer- tainty in the law as to U.S. (Source: Historical Survey of the United
when depreciation should or should not be States,
U.S. Department of Commerce [1975, p. 1109]).
deducted before
Watts and Zimmerman 295

also the resulting concepts of depreci- ation and of It might appear that the development of the
accounting income. In the legal cases on “dividends profession could explain the differ- ence in the timing
out of profits,” depreciation was regarded as a of the concern with depreciation in the U.K. and U.S.
valuation procedure (see p. 278). Whether the The professional bodies did not really develop until
amount of depreciation taken was suffi- cient would the 1870s in the U.K. and until the 1890s in the U.S.
be decided in the event of a dispute. Administering [Edwards, 1968a, pp. 197—199). Hence, we could
the tax laws is less costly if the periodic valuation is not observe depreciation debates in either country
replaced by an arbitrary proportion of historical cost. until those times. However, this alterna- tive
This saving was recognized in the early literature hypothesis is unsatisfactory on sev- eral counts.
[Matheson, 1893, p. 15] and was the likely reason First, while the first profes- sional society was not
that both U.S. and U.K. income taK allowances for formed in the
depreciation were based on historical cost. The U.K. until 1854, Littleton [1933, p. 265] reports
demand for a rationalization of this procedure and evidence of individuals (primarily lawyers)
other accruals under the tax law eventually resulted practicing accounting in the
in the concept of income based on matching and the U.K. in the eighteenth cent’ury and sug- gests it is
realization concept. Storey [1959, highly likely that accounting was practiced by
p. 232] reports this effect of the tax law as follows: lawyers in earlier times also. Similarly, there were
[The realization concept] probably did not exist public ac- countants in the U.S. at least as early as
at all before the First World \Var, and at least 1866 [Edwards, 1968a, p. 198]. Second, the lack
one writer states that the first official statement ofa/orrid/accounting profession did not prevent the
of the concept was made in 1932 in the appearance of the railroad depreciation literature in
correspondence between the Special Com- both the U.S. and U.K. in the 1840s and 1850s. Third,
mittee on Cooperation with Stock Exchanges of the formation of professional societies, itself, is likely
the American Institute of Accountants and the to be due, at least partly, to political action. Ac-
Stock List Committee of the New York Stock countants have incentives to lobby on government
Exchange. The letter referred to rejects the prescription of accounting practices. Given some
method of determining income by the in- economies of scale in lobbying, government
ventorying of assets at the beginning and end intervention in accounting would be expected to
of each period in favor of the recognition of produce professional bodies.
profit at the time of sale. This concept of profit C. Securities Acts
was gradually taking form during the period
after the First World War and had be- There appear to be at least two major effects of
core dominant in the field of accounting the U.S. Securities Acts of 1933—34 on the
determination of net income by the late 1930’s. accounting literature: they caused the objective of
That it was influenced hy the concef›t of income accounting to shift to what we call the “information
laid down by the Supreme Court in curly income objective” ; and they stimulated a search for
tax litigation is obvious (emphasis added). accounting principles. Both follow the Securities
Acts.
The timing of the depreciation debates in the U.K. (1) The Information Objective. Prior to the
also appears to confirm our hypothesis that political Securities Acts accounting theo-
action caused the observed change in accounting
the- ory. The tax allowance of the depreci- ation
deduction (1878) precedes the 1880s debates.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


296 The Accounting Review, April 1979
rists tended to describe and base their prescriptions [1924, p. 1] defines accounting as a
or the multiple objectives of accounting, and they
listed the numer- ous users. Consistent with our mechanism and body of principles by means of
analysis of accounting in an unregulated econ- omy, which the financial data of the particular
the control, or stewardship role, was frequently concern are recorded, classified, and periodi-
stressed. For example, Leake [1912, pp. 1-2] cally presented and interpreted, with a view,
includes as reasons for calculating profit and loss: thereby, to the rational administration of the
enterpri.se (emphasis added).
1. the stewardship role of manage- ment to
“uphold the value of the capital investment After the Securities Acts the providing of
and to ascertain and distribute the annual information to investors and credltOrs in order to aid
profits with due regard to the differential them in making rational investment choices became
rights” of the various classes of capital; the dominant objective in the literature. We call this
the information objective. One of the earliest
2. profit sharing schemes between capital and documents which illustrates this new emphasis on
labor; the investor’s decision is the AAA’s 1936 “Tentative
3. income taxes; and Statement on Accounting Principles.” A number of
4. public utility regulation. “unsatisfactory” accounting procedures are
discussed, including upward asset revaluations:
Daines [1929, p. 94] describes the “ortho- dox” or
dominant objective of account- ing as being “to
reflect that income which is legally available for Occasional uncoordinated “appraisals” pro-
dividends.” Sweeney [1936, p. 248] states that “the duce in the average financial statement a
fundamental purpose of accounting should consist of hodgepodge of unrelated values of no explica-
an attempt to distin- guish between capital and ble significance to the ordinary investor, if
income.” indeed they have any to the managements of
In his book based on his doctoral dissertation, the enterprises affected [American Account- ing
Sweeney adds other func- tions to the stewardship Association, 1936, p. 189] (emphasis added).
role:
Notice the emphasis given to investors. Hendriksen
Business management guides the affairs of [1977, p. 54] also supports our contention that the
business. For its own guidance it depends objective changed “from presenting financial
heavily on reports submitted to it by its em- information to management and creditors to that of
ployees. Periodically it renders reports of its providing financial information to inves- tors and
stewardship to the owners of the business. stockholders.” In a more recent example, A
From time to time it also renders reports to Statement ofBasi€'Arcowttinq Theory [American
bankers who have lent money to the business, Accounting Associ- ation, 1966, p. 4), the
to federal and state governments that tax or information objec- tive is listed first among four
regulate business, and to the general financial objectives of accounting. The objectives are:
public.
The whole system of business, therefore, 1. to provide information for deci- sions
de- pends upon reports. Reports are made concerning limited resources by “individuals
acting in their own behalf, such as the
up largely of accounting statements stockholders or creditors of a firm, by agents
[Sweeney, 1936, p. xi]. serving in fiduciary capacities, or by indi-
Managers were frequently cited as
important users of accounting. Paton
Watts and Zimmerman 297

viduals or groups in business firms, in vene, or actually intervening in the stan- dard-setting
government, in not-for-profit organizations process whenever the Com- mittee on Accounting
and elsewhere” [p. 4]. Procedure (CAP) or the APB proposed a standard of
2. to effectively direct and control an which it did not approve. Consequently, pro-
organization’s human and material resources, ponents advocating particular account- ing
3. to maintain and report on the cus- procedures would justify those pro- cedures in terms
todianship of resources, of the SEC’s stated objective—the public interest
(which “re- quires” the information objective).
4. “to facilitate the operations of an organized
society for the welfare of all” [p. 5]. The hypothesis that the dominance of the
information objective was caused by the Securities
Recent writers no longer even list management Acts is supported not only by the tendency of modern
as a principal user of financial statements. The writers to cite the public interest as an objective along
dichotomy of internal and external accounting has with the information objective [e.q., the fourth
become complete. The recent statement on objective of A Statement of Basic Accountinq Theory
accounting objectives, the FASB’s Conceptual listed above], but by the tendency to argue that
Framework Study [1976], also excludes fulfillment of the information objective is necessary to
management: the “public interest.” An example of that latter
tendency is provided by the FASB [1976, p. 3]:
Financial statements of business enterprises
should provide information, within the limits of Financial accounting and reporting is an im-
financial accounting, that is useful to present portant source of information on which in-
and potential investors and creditors in making vestment, lending, and related decisions are
rational investment and credit decisions (FASB, based. Confidence in financial information is
1976, p. 10]. vital not only to ensure that individual deci-
sions result in an equitable allocation of capi-
The dominance of the information objective tal but to ensure continuing public support of
arose, we suspect, as a public interest justification the free enterprise system as a whole.
consistent with and in support of the raison d’étre of
the Securities Acts. The SEC was justified in terms The close relationship between the information
of, and charged with, maintain- ing the orderly objective and the “public interest” is eKemplified by
functioning of the capital markets. In particular the the argument recently raised in the literature that in-
SEC was to protect the public from another stock formation provided in accounting re- ports is a public
market crash. That crash was alleged to have been good and that as a conse- quence, there may be an
underproduction of information from society’s
caused in part by inadequate corporate disclosure, viewpoint (i.e., there may be a market failure). If
although very little evidence exists to support this there is a market failure, the argument proceeds, the
claim. 5 ' “public interest” may require disclosure laws
Although the SEC delegated the power to requiring the
determine accounting standards for corporate
disclosure to the accounting profession, there is
evidence that it still eKercised control over that " See Benston [1969a and b]. The U.S. Securities
determina- tion. According to Horngren [1973] and and Exchange Commission [1945, pp. 1-3 and Part
Zeff [1972, pp. l5H-160] the SEC man- aged by X l makes this claim, although Sanders [1946, pp.
exception, threatening to inter- fi10] disputes much of their argument.

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


298 The Accounting Review, April 1979

provision of information to investors 1929; and Paton, 1922] is that both were based on
[Beaver, 1976, p. 66]. doctoral dissertations written in economics
(2) The Search for Accounting Princi- ples. departments [Zeff, 1978,
Before the Securities Acts most of the accounting p. 16]. Undoubtedly, both authors were influenced
literature did not stray far from practice, and heavily by economists as well as accountants.
prescriptions were usually based on rationalizations Canning himself writes, “I need not declare my
of prac- tice (e.g., the matching concept). Even obligation to Professor [Irving] Fisher for the influence
Sweeney’s price-level accounting pro- posals of the of his writings upon my thought—that obligation
1920s were based on prac- tice. According to the appears throughout the whole book” [Canning, 1929,
author [Sweeney, 1936, p. xii] the work “has its roots p. iv].
in methods that were developed in Ger- many and If Paton and Canning were harbingers of a
France during the late inflation periods in those change in accounting thought, we would expect to
countries.” There was, with the notable exceptions of observe a shift in the orthodox accounting view
during the 20s, following publication of their books.
Paton [1922] and Canning [1929], little effort devoted
Alternatively, if Canning’s and Paton’s views were
to establishing a theory of ac- counting. 5’ Indeed,
outliers or aberrations due to their economics
Chambers [1955a,
training, we would ex- pect to observe them
p. 18] claims that except for Paton [1922] the word
modifying their views towards the orthodox position
theory was not attached to any work in the to ensure their survival as accounting aca- demics.
accounting literature until after World War II.
Zeff [1978] presents evidence that
Taggart describes the general situation in 1922
as follows: Paton’s views, at least, moved more towards the
orthodox view during the 1920s and 1930s, than the
Some of the writers on theory, notably Sprague orthodox view moved towards Paton’s. Thus, it is
and Hatfield, not satisfied merely to describe difficult to argue that Paton and Canning were
practice, had earnestly addressed themselves representative of a change in the accounting
to exposition of pure theory; but the textbook literature which influenced the passage of the
writers, for the most part, had quite naturally Securities Acts. In- stead, we suspect that much of
concerned themselves pri- marily with practice the attention which Paton’s and Canning’s views
and with not much more than an occasional nod received after the Securities Acts was a result of the
toward theory, where it seemed to bolster Acts themselves.
practice. Paton’s Ac- counting Theory is The literature’s concern with practice
concerned only with theory ; it touches on
practice only for illus- tration or contrast ; and it ” The Federal Reserve Board published a 1917
is quite the oppo- site of an apologia for bulletin (Unjorm Accounting) written by Price, Water-
practice, [Foreword in the 1962 re-issue of house & Co. in response to the Federal Trade
Paton, 1922, p. v. ]. Commis- sion thrcatening to establish a federal
accountant’s register, but the bulletin “consisted of
Canning [1929, p. 160] himself wrote, “accountants mainly audit pro- ccdures” [Carey, 1969, pp. 1 :129-
have no complete philo- sophical system of thought 135).
about in- come; nor is there evidence that they have ‘° Canning’s principal intentions were not to reform
ever greatly felt the need for one”‘ 0 (emphasis existing practice or to construct a general theory but
added). rather to make “the work of the professional
A potential explanation for the two famous accountant more fully intelligible to those in other
departures from the orthodox ac- counting thought of branches of learning” [1929, p. iii].
the 1920s [Canning,
Watts and Zimmerman 299

before the Securities Acts is not sur- prising (given Zeff [1972, pp. 133—173] documents the
our theory). Prescriptions based on AICPA’s initial search for accounting principles and
rationalizations of practice are to be expected in the SEC’s passing the responsibility for the
an economy in which corporate reporting is not determination of principles to the profession in SEC
regulated. Theorists would base their prescriptions Accounting Series Release No. 4 [U.S. SEC, ASR
for individual firms on the current insti- tutional 4].“ Zeff also documents the search for accounting
arrangements determining prac- tice (i.e., in the principles (or standards) by the succession of
terms of the agency or stewardship relationships, standard- setting bodies established by the profes-
utility regula- tion, taxes, etc.). Hence, theory would sion. As noted, the SEC exercised control over the
be very concerned with practice. Further, because standard-setting bodies’ .search for accounting
the advantages are to the indi- vidual firins, the principles. Thus, we ex- pect these bodies (like the
theorist would not require all firms to follow his SEC) to search for or demand accounting principles
prescrip- tions, but expect his prescriptions to be which do not describe existing practice.
adopted because of self-interest. The theorist We expect accounting theorists, who are
would not try to specify account- ing principles accustomed to developing rules based on practice,
which all firms should adopt. to be perplexed by a demand for accounting
As we have noted, the Securities Acts were principles not based on practice. After the SEC’s call
based on the argument that required disclosure is (in ASR 4) for accounting principles for which there
necessary to the “public is substantial authoritative support (1938], the
accounting literature begins to discuss the nature of
interest.” The idea was that without required
principles [Scott, 1941 ; Wilcox and Hassler, 1941 ;
disclosure capital markets would be less efficient. We
and Kester, 1942].6 ° Further, as theorists come to
do not observe this theory being generally advanced
observe less emphasis being placed on the
in the accounting literature prior to the Securities
practicality of their ap- proach, we observe
Acts."
philosophical works becoming far removed from
The justification for required dis- closure is that practice such as Chambers [1955a, 1955b, 1966],
the private incentives to adopt accounting
prescriptions are in- sufficient. Hence, current
accounting practice cannot serve as a basis for
prescriptions. This justification sets ac- counting " The theory does appear in Yhe Journal of
theory free from practice. It makes it possible to Accoun• tanc y in October, 1930 (see Hoxsey
“build up a theory of accounting without reference to [1930], but the au- thor is not an accounting theorist ;
the practice of accounting” [Chambers, 1955a, p. instead he is an em- ployee of the New York Stock
19]. Further, the justification caused the SEC to Exchange. The theory also appears in the writings of
demand such theories. Because they were to reform Ripley in the popular financial literature in the 1920s
existing accounting practice, the SEC commis- (e.g., Ripley [1926]). However, Ripley isalso not
sioners could not base regulations on practice; they representative of the financial literature. " ASR 4
required a theory or a set of accounting principles to stated that “financial statements filed with this
justify their rulings. Commission ... [which] are prepared in accordance
with accounting• principles for which there is no s«6-
.stantial authoritative support, will be presumed to be
misleading or inaccui-ate” (emphasis added). ASR 4
created a demand for some procedure or device to
pro- vide “substantial authoritative” support.
‘ 3 Storey {1964, p. 3] supports our contention that
the Securities .Acts were “landmark evcnts” and
directly related to the search for accounting
principles.

Copyright O 2001 All Riohts Reserved


300 The Accounting Review, April 1979

Mattessich [1957] and Edwards and Bell [1961). mention and that accounting theory satis- fies the
It is instructive to compare the search for demand for excuses. The evidence appears to be
accounting principles in the U.S. to that in the U.K. inconsistent with what we have called the “public
where there has not been a government regulatory interest” hy- pothesis. Undoubtedly there are alterna-
body with the statutory power to prescribe tive theories which can also explain the timing of the
accounting procedures [Benston, 1976, pp. 14—30; accounting literature. The challenge is to those who
Zeff, 1972, pp. 1—69]. 64 Until recently there has would support those alternative theories to specify
been considerably less “prog- ress” in the U.K. in the them and show that they are more consistent with
search for accounting principles [Zeff, 1972, p. 310 the evidence than ours.
and Shackleton, 1977, pp. 17-21] and further, “the
English began late” [Zeff, 1972, p. 310]. The evidence V. CONCLUSIONS
suggests that the U.K. search for principles is also a In our view, accounting theories have had an
response to government pressure which arose out of important role in determining the content of financial
various financial crises [Zeff, 1972, pp. 39—40; statements—al- though it might not be the role
Benston, 1976, envisioned by the theorists. Instead of providing “an
pp. 15—17; and Shackleton, 1977, pp. underlying framework” for the promul- gation of
17—21]. “sound” financial reporting practices by standard-
The difference in the timing of the search for setting boards, accounting theory has proven a
principles in the two countries is reminiscent of the useful “tactic to buttress one’s preconceived notions”
30-year difference in the timing of the general [Zeff, 1974, p. 177]. While accounting theories have
depreciation debates in the U.K. and the U.S. always served a justification role in addition to informa-
That 30-year difference also coincides with a tion and pedagogic roles, government intervention
difference in the timing of government regulation has expanded the justifica- tion role. The
(i.e., corporate income tax laws allowing predominant function of accounting theories is now
depreciation as a deduc- tion). The difference in to supply excuses which satisfy the demand created by
timing cannot be explained per se by the fact that we the political process; consequently accounting
are comparing two different countries. In the theories have become in- creasingly normative.
depreciation debates, the U.K. led, while the U.S. led We are not offering any judgments on the
in the search for principles. The discussion in this desirability of accounting theories fulfilling an excuse
section has sug- gested that much of accounting role. What we are arguing, however, is that given the
theory (e.q., the concepts of depreciation, ac- crual exist- ing economic and political institutions and the
accounting, the application of the concept of incentives of voters, politicians, managers, investors,
economic income, and the idea that the objective of etc. to become in- volved in the process by which
financial state- mentsisgenerally to provideinformation accounting standards are determined, the only ac-
to investors rather than to control agency costs), counting theory that will provide a set of
followsgovernment intervention. Thus, the evidence is
consistent with our hypothesis that much of " See Sanders [1946) for an overview of the
accounting theoryisthe product ofgovernment inter- different prevailing attitudes in the U.S. and U.K. in
the 1940s.
Watts and Zimmerman 301
predictions that are consistent with ob- served sues; and
phenomena is one based on self-interest. No other 3. different vested interest groups pre- vail on
theory, no norma- tive theoty currently in the different issues.
accounting literature, (e.g., current value theories)
can explain or will be used to justify all accounting While a self-interest theory can explain accounting
standards, because: standards, such a theory will not be used to justify
accounting stan- dards because self-interest
1. accounting standards are justified using the theories are politically unpalatable. As a conse-
theory (excuse) of the vested interest group quence, not only is thet e no generally ac- cepted
which is bene- fitted by the standard; accounting theory to justify ac- counting standards,
2. vested interest groups use different theories there will never be one.
(excuses) for different is-

REFERENCES
Accounting Principles Board, Opinion 16: Busine.xs Combinations, American Institute of Certified Public
Accountants, 1970).
Alchian, Armen and Reuben Kessel, “Competition, Monopoly and the Pursuit of Money,” in Aspects of
Lahor Economics, (Princeton University Press: N.B.E. R., 1962), pp. 157 175.
American Accounting Association, “A Tentative Statement of Accounting Principles Affecting Corporate
Reports,” Trie ACCOUNTING REVIEW, (June 1936), pp. 187-191.
— , Committee on Basic Accounting Theory, A Stateriient of B‹isic Accounting Theory (American
Accounting Association, 1966).
, Committee on Concepts and Standards for External Reports, Statement on Accoun fing Theory
and Theor y Acceptance (American Accounting Association, 1977).
American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, ObJectirfs of Financial Statements, (Trueblood) Re-
port of the Study Group on the Objectives of Financial Statements (American Institute of Certified
Public Accountants, 1973).
Beaver, William H., “What Should Be the FASB’s Objectives?”, Journal of Accotintanc y, (August, 1973),
pp. 49-56.
, “The Implications of Security Price Research for Disclosure Policy and the Analyst Community,” in
A. R. Abdel-khalik and T. F. Keller (eds.), Financial Information Requirements for Securit y Analysis,
Duke Second Accounting Symposium, Duke University (December 1976), pp. 65-81.
and Joel S. Demski, “The Nature of Financial Accounting Objectives: A Summary and Syn-
thesis,” Studies on Financial Accounting Objectives, supplement to the Journal of Accounting Research
(1974), pp. 170-187.
Benston, George J., “The Value of the SEC’s Accounting Disclosure Requirements,” THE ACCOUN’fING
REVIEW, (July 1969a), pp. 515-532.
, “The Effectiveness and Effects of the SEC’s Accounting Disclosure Requirements,” in Henry G.
Manne (ed.), Economic Policy and the Regulation of Corporate Securities, (American Enterprise Insti-
tute, 1969b), pp. 23-79.
, Corporate Financial Disclosure in the UK and the USA (Saxon House, 1976).
Blough, Carman G., “Some Accounting Problems of the Securities and Exchange Commission,” The
New Work CertifieJ Public Accountant, (April 1937), pp. 3—14.
Boockholdt, James L., “Influence of Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Century Railroad Accounting on
Development of Modern Accounting Theory,” unpublished working paper 31, University of Alabama
(July 1977).
Brief, Richard P. (ed.), The Late Nineteenth Century Debate Over Depreciation, Capital anJ Income
(Arno Press, 1976).
Buchanan, James M. and Richard E. Wagner, Democrac y in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes,
(Academic Press, 1977).

Copyright O 2001 All Rights Reserved


302 The Accounting Review, April 1979

Burton, John C., “An Interview with John C. Burton,” Mancigement Accounting, (May 1975), pp. 19 23.
Canning, John B., The Economics of Accountanc y (Ronald Press, 1929).
Carey, John L., The Rise of the A ccouttfing Profession, Vols. 1 & 2 (American Institute of Certified Public
Accountants, 1969-70).
Chambers, Raymond J., “Blueprint for a Theory of Accounting,” Accounting Research, (January 1955a), pp.
17-25.
, “A Scientific Pattern for Accounting Theory,” An.stralian Accountant (October 1955b), pp.
428—434.
, Accounting, Ei alu‹ition and Economic Behavior (Prentice-Hall. 1966).
Clay, Cassius M., Regulation of Public Utilities, (Henry Holt and Company, 1932). Cooke, C.
A., Corporatioti, Trust and Compun y (Manchester University Press, 1950). “Curse of Bigness,”
Barron’s, (June 30, 1969), pp. 1 and 8.
Daines, H. C., “The Changing Objectives of Accounting,” Tire ACCOUNTING REVIEw, (June 1929), pp. 94—110.
Dicksee, Lawrence, Depreciation, Reserves and Reserve Funds (1903), reprinted by Arno Press, 1976. Dodd,
Edwin M., American Business Corporations Until 1860 (Harvard University Press, 1954).
Downs, Anthony, An Economic Theor y of Democrac y (Harper and Row, 1957).
DuBois, Armand B., The English Busine.ss Compan y After the Bubble Act I 720—1800 (The Commonwealth Fund,
1938).
Edey, Harold C., “Company Accounting in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries,” reprinted in Michael
Chatfield (ed.), Conteinporar y Studies in the Evolution of Accoiuitiny Thought (Dickenson Pub- lishing Co.
Inc., 1968), pp. 135-143.
and Prot Panitpakdi, “British Company Accounting and the Law 1844-1900,” in A. C. Littleton and B. S.
Yamey (eds.), Studies in the Hi.story ofArcounting (Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1956), pp. 356--379. Edwards, Edgar
O. and Philip W. Bell, The Theory and Measureitletit o] Business Income (U niversity of’
California Press, 1961).
Edwards, James D., “Some Significant Developments of Public Accounting in the United States,” Bu.si- ness
History Review (June 1956), reprinted in Michael Chatfield (ed.), Contemporary Studies in the Evolution of
Accounting Thuuyh t (Dickenson Publishing Co., 1968a), pp. 196—209.
, “The Antecedents of American Public Accounting,” Accounting Research (January 1956), reprinted in
Michael Chatfield (ed.), Conteinporur y Stuilies in the Evolution of Accounting Thought (Dickenson
Publishing Co., 1968b), pp. 144-166.
Ernst & Ernst, Accounting Under Inflationury Cotiditions, (Ernst & Ernst, 1976).
Fama, Eugene F., “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work,” Journal of Finance
(May 1970), pp. 38 lW17.
, Foundations of Finance (Basic Books, Inc., 1976).
Financial Accounting Standards Board, An Analysis of Issues Related to Conceptual Framework for Financial
Account ing and Reporting.‘ Elements of Financial Statements anJ Their Measurement (FASB, 1976).
Gonedes, Nicholas and Nicholas Dopuch, “Capital Market Equilibrium, Information Production and Selecting
Accounting Techniques: Theoretical Framework and Review of Empirical Work,” Studie.s on Financial
Accounting Objectives, supplement to the Journal of Accounting Research (1974), pp. 48-129.
Gordon, Myron J., “Postulates, Principles and Research in Accounting,” THE ACCOUNTING RfVIEW
(April 1964), pp. 251-263.
Hendriksen, Eldon, Accounting Tlieot‘y, 3rd Edition (Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1977).
Holmes, William, “Accounting and Accountants in Massachusetts,” Massachu.setts CPA Reliciv (May— June
1975), pp. 18—21.
Horngren, Charles T., “The Marketing of Accounting Standards,” Journal of Accotin/ancy, (October
1973), pp. 6lfi6.
— , “Setting Accounting Standards in the 1980’s,” in Norton Bedford (ed.), Accountaric y in the 1980’s
—Some Issues, (The Council of Arthur Young Professors, 1977).
Hoxsey, J. M. B., “Accounting for Investors,” Journal of Accountanc y (October 1930), pp. 251—284. Ijiri, Yuji,
The Foundations of Accounting Measurement (Prentice-Hall Inc., 1967).
, “Logic and Functions in Accounting,” in Robert Sterling and William Bentz (eds.), Account ing in
Perspective, (South-Western Publishing Co., 1971).
, Theory of Accounting Measurement (American Accounting Association, 1975).
Watts and Zimmerman 303

Interstate Commerce Commission, Accountitig for Federal Income Taxes, 318 I.C.C. 803, U.S. Govern- ment
Printing Office.
Jensen, Michael C., “Towards a Theory of the Press,” unpublished paper, Graduate School of Manage- ment,
University of Rochester, June 1976.
— and William H. Meckling, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Owner- ship
Structure,” Journal of Financial Economics, (October 1976), pp. 305—360.
and William H. Meckling, “On ‘The Labor Managed’ Firm and the Codetermination Movement,” Public
Policy Working Paper Series GPB 77-2, Center for Research in Government Policy and Business, Graduate
School of Management, University of Rochester, February 1977.
Johnson, Arthur M., Government-Business Relations (Charles E. Merrill Books, 1965). Kehl,
Donald, Corporate Dividends (The Ronald Press Company, 1941).
Kester, Roy B., “Sources of Accounting Principles,” Journal of Accountanc y, (December 1942), pp. 531— 535.
Leake, P. D., Depreciation and Wasting Asset.s and Their Treatment in A.ssessing Annual Profit and Loss
(1912), reprinted by Arno Press, 1976.
Lefller, Keith and Jerold Zimmerman, “A Theory of Municipal Government Agency Costs, Organiza- tional
Form, and Scale,” working paper, Graduate School of Management, University of Rochester (July 1977).
Litherland, D. A., “Fixed Asset Replacement a Half Century Ago,” reprinted in Michael Chatfield (ed.),
Contemynrary Studies in the Evolution of Accounting Thought (Dickenson Publishing Co., Inc., 1968), pp.
167-175.
Littleton, A. C., Accounting Evolution to 1900 (1933), reprinted by Russell & Russell, 1966.
Matheson, Ewing, The Depreciation of Factories, Mines and Indu›trinl Undertakings and Their Valuation
(1893), reprinted by Arno Press, 1976.
Mattessich, Richard, “Towards a General and Axiomatic Foundation of Accountancy; with an Introduc- tion to
the Matrix Formulation of Accounting Systems,” Accounting Re.search, (October 1957), pp. 328-355.
Mautz, Robert K., “The Role of the American Accounting Association in Accounting Research,” Re- search in
n ccounfing Measure+nent, Robert Jaedicke, Yuji Ijiri and Oswald Nielsen (eds.) (American Accounting
Association, 1966).
and Jack Gray, “Some Thoughts on Research Needs in Accounting,” The Journal of Accountanc y,
(September 1970), pp. 54-62.
McCraw, Thomas K., “Regulation in America: A Review Article,” Business Histor y Reuiew, (Summer 1975),
pp. 159-183.
Meckling, William H., “Towards a Theory of Representative Government,” presented at the Third An- nual
Conference on Analysis and Ideology, Interlaken, Switzerland, June 4, 1976 (1976a).
, “Values and the Choice of the Model of the Individual in the Social Scienccs,” Heroe Suisse
J’Economic Politique et de Statistique (December 1976b), pp. 545—560.
Moonitz, Maurice, “Accounting Principles—How They are Developed,” in Robert Sterling (ed.), Insti-
/uifonaf Issue.s iii Public Accaunting, (Scholars Book Company, 1974a), pp. 143-171.
, Obtaining A yreement on Standards in fhe Accounting Profession (American Accounting Associa- tion,
1974b).
Mueller, Dennis C., “Public Choice: A Survey,” The Journal of Economic Literature (June 1976), pp. 39M33.
Mundheim, Robert H., “Foreword, Symposium on Securities Regulation,” Law and Contemporary Problems
(Summer 1964), pp. 647—652.
Nash, Luther R., Anatomy of Depreciation (Public Utilities Reports, Inc., 1947).
Niskanen, William A., Bureaucrac y and Representative Government (Aldine-Atherton, 1971).
Paton, William A., Accounfing Theor With Special Reference to the Corporate Enterprise (New York: The
Ronald Press Company, 1922). Re-issued in 1962 by A.S.P. Accounting Studies Press, Ltd. Re- printed by
Scholars Book Co., 1973.
, Accounting (Macmillan Company, 1924).
and A. C. Littleton, An Introduction to Corporate Accounting Standards (American Accounting
Association, 1940).
Peltzman, Sam, “Towards a More General Theory of Regulation,” Journal of Law anJ Economics,
(August 1976), pp. 211—240.

Copyright O 2001 All Ri0hts Reserved


304 The Accounting Review, April 1979

Pichler, Joseph A., “An Economic Analysis of Accounting Power,” in Robert Sterling (ed.), Institutional Issues in
Public Accounting (Scholars Book Co., 1974), pp. 45-73.
Pollins, Harold, “Aspects of Railway Accounting Before 1868,” reprinted in A. Littleton and B. Yamey (eds.),
Studies in the History of Accounting (Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1956), pp. 332-355.
Posner, Richard A., “Theories of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science
(Autumn 1974), pp. 335-358.
Prakash, Prem and Alfred Rappaport, “Information Inductance and Its Significance for Accounting,”
Accounting, Organi-nations and Societ y, Vol. 2, No. 1, (1977), pp. 29-38.
Rappaport, Louis H., SEC Accounting Practice and Procedure, Third Edition (Ronald Press, 1972). Riggs,
Henry E., Depreciation of Public Utilit y Properties (McGraw Hill Book Co., 1922).
Ripley, William Z., “Stop, Look, Listen!”, The Atlantic Monthly (September, 1926), pp. 380—399.
Saliers, Earl A., Depreciation; Principle.s and Applications, Third Edition (Ronald Press Company, 1939).
Sanders, Thomas H., “A Review of Reviews of Accounting Progress,” Journal of Accountanc y (January
1946), pp. 9—26.
, Henry R. Hatfield, and Underhill Moore, A Statement of Accounting Principles (American Insti- tute of
Accountants, 1938).
Scott, DR, “The Basis for Accounting Principles,” THE ACCOUNTiNG REViEw (December 1941), pp. 341— 349.
Shackleton, Ken, “Government Involvement in Developing Accounting Standards: The Framework,”
Management Accounting (U.K.), (January 1977), pp. 17-21.
Smith, Clifford, “On the Theory of Lending,” unpublished paper, Working Paper Series No. 7635, Graduate
School of Management, University of Rochester, 1976.
Sprouse, Robert T. and Maurice Moonitz, “A Tentative Set of Broad Accounting Principles for Business
Enterprises,” Accounting Research Study No. 3 (American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, 1962).
Sterling, Robert R., “Accounting Research, Education and Practice,” Journal of Accountanc y (September
1973), pp. 44-52.
(ed.), Institutional Issues in Public Accounting (Scholars Book Co. 1974).
Stigler, George J., “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science
(Spring 1971), pp. 3-21.
, “Do Economists Matter?”, !Southern Economic Joldrnal (January 1976), pp. 347-363.
Storey, Reed K., “Revenue Realization, Going Concern and Measurement of Income,” Trtc ACCOUNTING
REYIEw (April 1959), pp. 232—238.
, The Search for Accounting Principles (American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, 1964).
Sweeney, Henry W., StubilizeJ Accounting (Harper & Bros. Publishers, 1936).
U.S. Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly of the Committee on the Judiciary,
Hearings, The Petroleum Industr y, Part I, 94th Congress, 1st Session, 1975.
U.S. Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Reports, Accounting and Management of the Committee on
Government Operations, The Accounting Establishment. A Staff Study (Metcalf Staff Report), 94th
Congress, 2nd Session, 1976.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial
Times to 1970 (U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975).
U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, “Administrative Policy on Financial Statements,” Accounting Series
Release No. 4, (April 25, 1938).
U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, Tenth Annual Report of the Securities and Exchange Commis-
sion. Fiscal Year Ended June 30, 1944 (1945).
Watts, Ross L., “Accounting Objectives,” working paper series no. 7408, Graduate School of Manage- ment,
University of Rochester, April 1974.
, “Corporate Financial Statements, A Product of the Market and Political Processes,” Australian Journal
of Management (April 1977), pp. 53-75.
and Jerold L. Zimmerman, “Towards a Positive Theory of the Determination of Accounting
Standards,” THE AccOuNTINc Review (January 1978), pp. 112-134.
Wilcox, E. B. and R. H. Hassler, “A Foundation for Accounting Principles,” Journal of Accountanc y
(October 1941), pp. 308—314.
Zeff, Stephen A., Forging Accounting Principles in Five Countries.’ A History and an Analysis of Trends,
Arthur Andersen Lecture Series (Stipes Publishing Co., 1972).
Watts and Zimmerman 305

, “Comments on ‘Accounting Principles—How They are Developed’,” in Robert R. Sterling (ed.),


Institutional Issues in Public Accounting (Scholars Book Co., 1974), pp. 172—178.
, “Paton on the Effects of Changing Prices on Accountinp• : 1916—1955,” unpublished manuscript (March
1978).
Zimmerman, Jerold L., “The Munic-ipal Accounting Maze: An Analysis of Political Incentives,” Studies on
lvteasurement and Eunluatioti of the Economic Efficienc y of Puhlic and Private Nonyrofit Institutions,
supplement to the Journal of Accounting Research (1977), pp. 107-144.

Copvri0ht O 2001 All Riahts Reserved


Copyright of Accounting Review is the property of American Accounting Association and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites
or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for
individual use.

S-ar putea să vă placă și