Sunteți pe pagina 1din 124

les Nouvelles

September 2017
XCELL
IP E E JOURNAL OF THE LICENSING EXECUTIVES SOCIETY INTERNATIONAL

N
Yea

55

CE
rs
Volume LII No. 3 September 2017

Denn
em
ey

up
er o

LES NOUVELLES
• The IP Gr Advancing the Business of Intellectual Property Globally
SMEs And The Patent Challenge
Introduction: SMEs—What We Know And Don’t Know PATRICK TERROIR — PAGE 139
Part 1: Main Challenges
SMEs And Patent Valorization JOSEP MARIA PUJALS — PAGE 149
SMEs And Open Innovation (OI) PAUL GERMERAAD — PAGE 156

JOURNAL OF THE LICENSING EXECUTIVES SOCIETY INTERNATIONAL


SMEs & Patent Litigation: European Perspective EMMANUEL GOUGÉ & VALICHA TORRECILLA — PAGE 162
Creating SEPs­— A Risky Business For SMEs MENNO TREFFERS, MATTEO SABATTINI &
ALESSANDRA MOSCA — PAGE 167

55 years of Dennemeyer
SMEs & Standard Essential Patents: Licensing Efficiently In IoT
HARRIS TSILIKAS & CLAUDIA TAPIA — PAGE 170
Part 2: A Journey Around The SMEs’ IP World
Europe: France EMMANUELLE FORTUNE — PAGE 177 | Germany TOBIAS WUTTKE — PAGE 179
Italy MATTIA DALLA COSTA — PAGE 181 | IP Manager For SMEs? ERCOLE BONINI — PAGE 184

Thanks for 55 years UK CHRISTI MITCHELL & ROBERT LOOKER — PAGE 186
U.S.A. JOHN CABECA & IVAN CHAPEROT — PAGE 189
Asia: China QINGHONG XU — PAGE 192

of entrusting your IP ASEAN & Singapore AUDREY YAP — PAGE 195


India SUNITA K. SREEDHARAN — PAGE 197

Latin America: Brazil CÂNDIDA CAFFÉ & MARIANA VICENTINI — PAGE 199 | Chili FELIPE CLARO — PAGE 202
Colombia FERNANDO TRIANA SOTO & MARCELA GÓMEZ RUBIO — PAGE 203

to Dennemeyer. Mexico ROXANA AISPURO & HECTOR CHAGOYA — PAGE 206 | Peru RENZO SCAVIA — PAGE 209
Africa: South Africa MADELEIN KLEYN — PAGE 210
Conclusion: Do Not Focus Only On SMEs, Make The Knowledge Economy Work PATRICK TERROIR — PAGE 214

The Exhaustion Theory Is Not Yet Exhausted: Part 4 ERIK VERBRAEKEN — PAGE 216
Licensing Standards Essential Patents JOSEPH A. ALFRED — PAGE 223
Magic Bullet: Determining Royalties With Corporate Discounts Rates BRIAN DIES & JOEL WACEK — PAGE 229
• Client-oriented • Self-funded • Owner-managed • Global A Guide To Commercial Innovation In Artificial Intelligence DEEPA RAVINDRANATH — PAGE 237
Disruption In The IP Services Industry? JOHN WALKER — PAGE 241
Intangible Asset Market Value Study? CATE M. ELSTEN & NICK HILL — PAGE 245
Software IPR Valuation Model SANTOSH MOHANTY & KAUSHIK GALA — PAGE 248
Recent U.S. Decisions Affecting Licensing JOHN PAUL & BRIAN KACEDON — PAGE 255 $62.50/Issue
g
or
8.
01
I2
ES
.L
w
w
!w
W
O
N
Landscape?

R
TE
IS
G
RE
or LESI 2018 ANNUAL CONFERENCE
Strong IP Drives the Bottom Line

Futurescape? April 29 – May 2 l


Manchester Grand Hyatt San Diego,California l

Advertising in
les Nouvelles
We have issued new pricing for
advertising in les Nouvelles. You can
now advertise through a ¼ page ad,
in color or black and white. See www.
lesi.org/content/advertiseinlesNou-
velles.aspx
Although we do not have a Jobs
and Employment section of les Nou-
velles as yet, employers can advertise
to fill important positions through
les Nouvelles. We reach over 12,000
 Patent Search Services  Technology/Innovation Research potential candidates, worldwide.
 White Space Analysis  Claim Charting/Infringement Analysis
Reach us
USA: 1-888-247-1618
 Portfolio Analysis  Patent Licensing Support Services
India: +91-44-2231 0321
 Portfolio Management  Patent Due Diligence
 Landscaping Studies contact@e-mergeglobal.com
 Patent Drafting
Introduction

SMEs And The Patent Challenge—Introduction


By Patrick Terroir

T
his special issue of les Nouvelles aims to pave the Part 2: A Journey Around the SMEs’ IP World
way within LESI (Licensing Executives Society
1. Europe:
International) to a broad and international reflec-
tion on the practice of small and medium-sized enter- a. France by Emmanuelle Fortune
prises (SMEs), which represent an increasing share of b. Germany by Dr. Tobias Wuttke
innovation in all economies, as regards their relations c. Italy by Mattia della Costa and Barbara Sartori
with the systems of intellectual property. d. Italy2 by Ercole Bonini
This issue is the result of an international collabora- e. UK by Christi Mitchell and Robert Looker
tion with the cooperation of the LESI. The introduc-
tion presents the current research and knowledge on 2. USA: by John Cabeca and Ivan Chaperot
the subject. The first part consists of expert analysis 3. Asia:
about some of the most essential challenges for SMEs
regarding IP. The second part intends to be a beginning a. China by Qinghong Xu
of LESI “country sheets” about the specific measures b. Asean and Singapore by Audrey Yap
to support SMEs in the different countries. c. India by Sunita K. Sreedharan
Introduction: Patent and SMEs. What Do We Know 4. Latin America:
And Do Not Know? a. Brazil by Cândida Caffé and Mariana Vicentini
Part 1: Main Challenges b. Chile by Felipe Claro
1. SMEs and Patent Valorization by Josep Maria Pujals c. Colombia by Fernando Triana and Marcela Gómez
2. SMEs and Open Innovation by Paul Germeraad
d. Mexico by Roxana Aispuro and Hector Chagoya
3. SMEs and Patent Litigation by Emmanuel Gougé
and Valicha Torrecilla e. Peru by Renzo Scavia
4. SMEs and SEP: Creating SEPs—A risky business 5. Africa:
for SMEs by Menno Treffers, Matteo Sabattini
a. South Africa by Madelein Kleyn
and Alessandra Mosca
5. Licensing In IoT And How SMEs Can Benefit From Conclusion—A different perspective: do not focus
It by Harris Tsilikas and Claudia Tapia only on SMEs, make the knowledge economy works. 

Patent And SMEs. What Do We Know And Do Not


Know? (A Review Of The Literature)
By Patrick Terroir

The Importance of SMEs for the Economies ed.2 Micro firms constitute the

E
ven if there are no standard definitions of what bulk of MSMEs in all coun- ■ Patrick Terroir,
SMEs are, it is generally considered that small tries. In Europe for example, Innovation Legal;
and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are firms within the SME population,
Sciences Po Paris,
employing between 10 and 250 (or 500) people and micro-enterprises accounted
for 92.7 percent of all enter- Lawyer, Professor ,
that firms with up to 10 employees are referred to as
micro firms (it is often added as reference to a maxi- prises active in 2014 in the Paris, France
mum turnover, like less than EUR 50 million € in Eu- non-financial business sector, E-mail: pterroir@gmail.com
rope). The two categories constitute Micro, Small and and small and medium enter-
Medium Enterprises (MSMEs) in the statistics.1
1. IFC’s MSME Country Indicators http://www.ifc.org/
In OECD economies MSMEs account for over 95 wps/wcm/connect/Industry_EXT_Content/IFC_External_
percent of firms and 60 percent-70 percent of employ- Corporate_Site/Industries/Financial+Markets/msme+finance/
ment; they generate a large share of new jobs and pro- sme+banking/msme-countryindicators.
vide around 45 percent of business sector value add- 2. http://www.oecd.org/cfe/leed/1918307.pdf.

September 2017 139


Introduction
develop after some years (25 percent only after six
Figure 1. Size Of Enterprises In years according to some studies).4 See Figure 1.
Different Economies
If we look at international comparisons, when it
1-9 10-19 20-49
comes to the number of SMEs, the EU28 and the
50-249 250+ U.S.A. are roughly comparable with 1.65 and 1.5
SMEs per million GDP. In contrast, the importance of
100 SMEs in providing employment is similar in the EU
90 and Japan (6.6 and 7.1 persons employed per SME),
and much lower in the U.S.A., where SMEs account
80
for slightly more than half (52 percent) of total employ-
70 ment in the non-financial business economy (see 3).
60 These micro, small and medium enterprises (MSMEs)
are distributed differently along the different sectors of
50 the economies.
40 A classification often used is to distinguish between
30
two typologies based on technology intensity or knowl-
edge intensity to characterize the activities of SMEs.7
20 (for a definition of these typologies see page 151 of the
10 Annual Report on European SMEs 2014/2015).
0
From the survey in Europe8 we learn that:
USA JPN Euro area • Within the SMEs, medium-sized enterprises are
Source: entrepreneurship-at-a-glance-2016, OECD very often part of a group.
• The knowledge-intensive busi-
Table 1. Sectoral Distribution ness services sector consists
Of MSMEs (%) mostly of SMEs.
Manufacturing Trade Services Agriculture/other • The large enterprises and de-
pendent SMEs dominate the high-
Share of micro enterprises tech sector across all countries.
• The low and medium-low tech-
Developed 8.0 35.0 56.0 1.0 nology sector is composed of a
roughly even proportion of large
enterprises and SMEs,
Developing 11.5 44.3 39.9 5.3
• The ‘other services’ sector con-
Source: WTO 2016 report. 6 sists mostly of SMEs (in particular
in wholesale and retail trade).
prises for only 6.1 percent and 1.0 percent.3 As regards The New Innovation Economy and the Impor-
to employment micro SMEs accounted for 29.2 per- tance of SMEs
cent of total employment, and small and medium-sized
SMEs for 20.4 percent and 17.3 percent respectively. As OECD observes9 from the 1940s to the 1970s
As regards to value added micro SMEs accounted for the innovation model is dominated by large corpora-
21.1 percent of total valued added, and small and me- tions able to exploit large economies of scale in pro-
dium-sized SMEs for 18.2 percent and 18.5 percent
respectively (see 3).
5. http://www.keepeek.com/Digital-Asset-Management/
However, research show that despite the crucial oecd/industry-and-services/entrepreneurship-at-a-glance-2016_
importance of the SME sector for the economy as a entrepreneur_aag-2016-en#page36.
whole, the harsh reality is that few SMEs survive and 6. World Trade Organisation 2016 report, Levelling the
trading field for SMEs.
3. Annual Report on European SMEs 2014/2015, http://www. 7. Annual Report on European SMEs 2014/2015, http://www.
pmievolution.it/wp-content/uploads/2016/04/annual-report- pmievolution.it/wp-content/uploads/2016/04/annual-report-
SME-2015.pdf. SME-2015.pdf.
4. “Accounting For Intangibles: Financial Reporting And Value 8. Eurostat, http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/
Creation In The Knowledge Economy,” The Work Foundation/ index.php/Statistics_on_small_and_medium-sized_enterprises.
Research Republic, August 2009. 9. SMEs entrepreneurship and innovation, OECD, 2010.

140 les Nouvelles


Introduction
duction, distribution, management and R&D producing • The functioning of the global value chains which
standardised products in large volumes at low cost. In assemble many diverse actors in the new techno-
this period SMEs participated only to a limited degree logical process
in innovation, reflecting their low R&D expenditure. • Correlatively the growing part of networks where
But with the introduction of new technologies, the distributed knowledge and open innovation are
globalization and the transformation of the global value feeding mostly SMEs and start-ups which use them
chain, the role of new and small firms in innovation as a raw material.
and economic development has increased tremen- Hence, if the large companies still remain innovative,
dously since the beginning of the ‘80s (the so called and the SMEs become more and more a main compo-
“new economy”) to today. Within the reasons for these nent of the innovations in what is called the “knowl-
changes, we should note with OECD: edge economy” where knowledge is becoming a true
• The diversification of the responses to the (encour- factor of production. This does not mean that SMEs
aged) diversified needs of the consumer and hence are relatively specialised in non-technological innova-
the emergence of multiple market niches, which tion compared with larger firms. Rather the evidence
new and small firms are quick to fill suggests that they tend to lag behind larger firms in
• The reduction of products’ lifetime and their more both.10 So the presentation of the SBIR program before
rapid creation (the pace of “progress” is feeling as the Small Business Technology Council underlined that
ever accelerating and products are not conceived an analysis of R&D 100 awards shows that SBIR/STTR
to last) Programs have resulted in 22-25 percent of all key in-
• The diminishing entry cost in the invention pro- novations in the United States.11 See Table 2.
cess as the computer simulation possibilities has The innovative SMEs—start-up and spin-off
widened and as a growing part of the new services SMEs are, on average, more innovative than one
relates to the digital economy (SAAS) might think: according to the 4th Community Innova-
• The role of venture capital which seeks to invest in tion Survey (Parvan 2007; see also: Eurostat, 2004),
every opportunity to leverage new sources of value about 33 percent of the enterprises who have 10-49
and profit employees and around 40 percent of the enterprises
• The boundaries of the firm can no longer be assessed with 50-249 employees can be considered innovative
independently of the cooperative relationships that (i.e. they introduced new or significantly improved
the firms get with their suppliers or partners products or processes in the time frame of 2002 to
2004).12

Table 2. Where Do Key Innovations Come From?

10. Acs and Audretsch, 1990;


Total Fortune 500 Universities SBIR Firms and Audretsch, 1995, for R&D
Number of Innovations Out of Top 100

intensities and Chapter 2 for non-


technological innovation rates.
11. Jere Glover, Robert
50 Schmidt, and Alec Orban, “Small
Business Technology Council
45
reauthorization of the SBIR/STTR
40
Programs—The Importance of
35 Small Business Innovation to
30 National and Economic Security,”
25 28 January, 2016, https://www.
20 sbc.senate.gov/public/?a=Files.
15 Serve&File_id=57625744-A72A-
10 424D-8B0B-90E3385108EF.
5 12. Report: Benchmarking
0 national and regional support
1971 1975 1979 1982 1984 1988 1991 1995 1997 2002 2004 2006 services for SMEs in the field
of intellectual and industrial
property, http://ec.europa.eu/
Year DocsRoom/documents/4722/
attachments/1/translations.

September 2017 141


Introduction
when large firms deliberately use
Table 3. The Patent System Tradeoffs SMEs as laboratories, acquiring and
integrating the technologies that in-
terest them the most and then make
Effects on: Benefit Cost
their acquisition in case of success.
SMEs and Patenting
Creates an incentive for Impedes the combination of
Innovation R&D; promotes the diffusion new ideas & inventions; raises The patent system has been de-
of ideas. transaction costs. signed to give protection to economic
actors who are in a relative “weak”
Facilitates entry of new small position—because its benefits to so-
firms with limited assets; Creates short- term ciety are stronger than the disadvan-
Competition
monopolies, which may tages it entails. As Phelps Marshal
Allows trading of inventive become long-term in network quoted in his famous “Burning the
knowledge, markets for industries. ship” essay, “the real genius of the
technology.
Founders…was to create a patent
Source16 system that encourage innovation on
a truly mass scale.” This goal of acces-
If we refer to the R&D tax credit in France as anoth- sibility for all is central in the patent system as it gives
er example,13 in 2011, 75 percent of the declarations to the society the guarantee that the invention reward
came from independent enterprises with less than 250 is not a matter of dominance but talent. See Table 3.
employees Why should SMEs patent?
As OECD underlined,14 “new and small firms have IPRs (Intellectual Property Rights) are instrumental
become critical innovation players because of their for SMEs for a number of reasons:17
ability to recognise and exploit the commercial op-
• the most important one is certainly the freedom to
portunities emerging from technological, competitive
operate as it protect its very existence,
and market changes. Furthermore, economies of scale
in research and development are no longer the barri- • to protect from copying,
ers they once were to small firm participation in in- • to position themselves competitively vis-à-vis larger
novation” and “one of the reasons that new start-ups enterprises in global markets,
and small firms have become more important today is • to gain access to revenues (licensing),
that innovation in the knowledge economy is coming • to signal current and prospective value to investors,
from creativity and the unexpected, and this is more competitors and partners,
likely to be found in new and small operations than in
the systematic research that characterises large firm • to access knowledge markets and networks,
R&D laboratories.” • to open up new commercial pathways; or segment
One of the phenomena that attenuates the bound- existing markets.
aries between firms is actually the multiplication of On the economic side, the studies in both the Unit-
spin-off creations where individuals leave universities, ed Kingdom and the United States have found that in-
research organisations and large corporations to start creased patenting is related to increased growth and
enterprises based on knowledge they developed there jobs creation and “for start-up high-tech businesses
in the form of “spin-off” companies. However, this re- that have invented the core idea of a new technology,
mains limited as studies show that academic spin-offs it is critical.”18
accounted for no more than two percent of new firm Companies that own registered IPRs have in general
creation across eight OECD countries, and that even 29 percent higher revenue per employee, about six
in the United States, which seems to have one of the times as many employees and pay wages that are up
highest rates of university spin-offs, only two spin-offs
were created per research institution per year.15
Another practice is the growing “spin-in” process 16. Hall, B. H., and D. Harhoff, “Recent Research on the
Economics of Patents.” National Bureau of Economic Research
13. http://www.ccomptes.fr/Publications/Publications/L-evolution- Working Paper No. 17773, NBER, Cambridge (MA), (2012).
et-les-conditions-de-maitrise-du-credit-d-impot-en-faveur-de-la- 17. OECD (2011), “Intellectual Assets and Innovation: The
recherche). SME Dimension, OECD Studies on SMEs and Entrepreneurship,”
14. SMEs entrepreneurship and innovation, OECD, 2010. OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264118263-en.
15. Callan, “Generating Spin-Offs: Evidence from Across the 18. International Patent Protections For Small Businesses,
OECD,” OECD Science Technology and Industry Review, 2001. USPTO, January 2012.

142 les Nouvelles


Introduction
to 20 percent higher than firms that do not own IPRs. to account for the vast majority of patent applicants,
Moreover the SMEs that own IPRs have 32 percent in fact the relative proportion of small and medium
higher revenue per employee (compared to the 29 enterprises applying for at least one patent over the
percent for all companies).19 period considered remains very low. Percentages
It must be stressed that registration protection range between 1 percent (Spain and Canada) and 4.9
against copying is a very important objective for SMEs, percent (Finland) in the case of firms of 20-49 em-
as many of them report having suffered from infringe- ployees, and between 1.8 percent (Ireland) and 12.5
ment the most. “Almost one-third of SMEs registering percent (Switzerland) in the case of medium firms.”21
IPRs declare having suffered an infringement. This See Figure 2 and 3.
proportion increases with the size of the SME, with SMEs often do not maximise the gains from their
medium-sized SMEs being affected most (39 percent) assets; either by not registering or licensing IPRs, or by
and micro SMEs suffering least from IPR infringement not enforcing their IPRs, especially in comparison to
(24 percent). The top three of IPRs infringed are trade- larger companies. According to a report of the EUIPO
marks, patents and designs.”20 through the European Observatory on Infringements
Why do SMEs patent so little? of Intellectual Property Rights, large companies are
As a number of studies indicate, patenting activity four times more likely to own registered IPRs than small-
is relatively uncommon among small businesses and, er companies—40 percent of larger firms have regis-
where it does occur, is concentrated in high technol- tered rights, compared with nine percent of SMEs. 22
ogy sectors. However, the Patenting Propensity of SMEs
A recent OECD study précises: “Evidence suggests Varies Along Sectors and Some Patents a
that only 0.1 percent-9.3 percent of firms apply for Lot More.
patents, with marked differences that exist between The SMEs, however, are an extremely heterogene-
industries and across countries. Small and medium ous group. “In certain high-technology sectors, such as
enterprises account for the majority of patenting semiconductors and biotechnology, innovative SMEs
firms, while big firms of more than 250 employees have been a key to the growth and dynamism of these
account for the majority of patent applications and of sectors. In such sectors, patenting activity is compar-
patent families. atively much higher than in other sectors and small
Whereas in terms of overall numbers SMEs, seems firms rely heavily on patents to signal expertise, either

Figure 2. Patenting Firms And Non-Patenting Firms


By Employee Size Class (2009)
20 to 40 employees 50 to 240 employees 200 to 400 employee 500 and more

100%

75%

50%

25%

0%
Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms
Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms
Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms
Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms
Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Patenting Firms

Non-Patenting Firms

Austria Belgium Canada Finland France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands Norway Spain Sweden Switzerland United
States
Note: Patenting firms are firms having filed for at least one patient application to the EPO, USPTO or through the PCT since 1978.
Source: OECO calculations based on EPO Worldwide Patient Statistical Database (April 2012) and OECO-ORBIS 2011, October
2012.

21. Squicciarini, M. and H. Dernis (2013), “A Cross-Country


Characterisation of the Patenting Behaviour of Firms based on
Matched Firm and Patent Data,” OECD Science, Technology and
19. Intellectual Property (IP) SME Scoreboard, EUPTO, 2016. Industry Working Papers, 2013/05, OECD Publishing, Paris.
20. Ibid. 22. Intellectual Property (IP) SME Scoreboard, EUPTO, 2016.

September 2017 143


Introduction

Figure 3. Share Of Patenting Firms In Total Firms, By Employee Size Class (2009)
20 to 40 employees 50 to employees 200 to 400 employee 500 and more All
30%

20%

10%

0%

es
s

ay

nd
en
y
da

ce

ly
m

n
nd
d
ria

nd

at
an

pa

ai
Ita
an

w
iu

an

la
ed
na

St
rla
st

la

Sp
m

or
lg

Ja

er
nl
Au

Sw
Fr

Ire
Ca

d
er

he
Be

N
Fi

itz

te
G

et

Sw

ni
N

U
to attract research partners or investment.”23 13-14 times more patents per employee as large pat-
These specific SMEs could be identified through the enting firms. For good measure, small patent firms are
statistics reports which give complementary visions. on average more technically important than large firm
The OECD study evidences that with the international patents, in that the smaller businesses produce more
standard classification (ISIC) the share of SMEs are the highly cited patents.” It also was observed that “small
highest in the following classes: computer, electronic firm innovation is twice as closely linked to scientific
and optical products (sector 26), machinery and equip- research as large firm innovation on average, and so
ment (sector 28), wholesale and retail trade, repair of substantially more high-tech or leading edge.”
motor vehicles and motorcycles (sector 45-47)—as at Anthony Breitzman and Diana Hicks authored a
the same time this last sector (45-47) is the one where 2008 study—“An Analysis of Small Business Patents by
there is the higher share of non-patenting firms (of all Industry and Firm Size”26 “[S]mall (technology) firms
sizes). are much more likely to develop emerging technolo-
According to Eurostat study24, the share of SMEs is gies than are large firms. Small firms are a significant
important in the following patent areas: analysis of bi- source of innovation and patent activity. Small busi-
ological materials (23 percent of SMEs among patents nesses develop more patents per employee than larger
filed by companies), biotechnology (21 percent), phar- businesses, with the smallest firms, those with fewer
maceuticals (17 percent), medical technology (14 per- than 25 employees, producing the greatest number of
cent), games (14 percent), IT methods (13 percent), patents per employee. Furthermore, small firm patents
food chemistry (13 percent), civil engineering (13 tend to be more significant than large firm patents,
percent), handling (11 percent), nano-technology (10 outperforming them in a number of categories includ-
percent), chemical engineering (10 percent). The oth- ing growth, citation impact, and originality. Finally,
er areas have a share of SMEs between nine and three small firms tend to specialize in high tech, high growth
percent (digital communication). These proportions industries, such as biotechnology, pharmaceuticals, in-
may vary according to the industrial specialization of formation technology, and semiconductors. Specifical-
each country. ly, although small firms account for only eight percent
These SMEs have a remarkable behavior as regards of patents granted, they account for 24 percent of the
to patenting. In the study conducted by the small patents in the top 100 emerging clusters.”
business and entrepreneuship council,25 R. Keating
Too Many Challenges Impede SMEs Patenting
citing a report of February 2003 titled “Small Serial
Innovators: The Small Firm Contribution to technical Despite these sectors of excellence, the global
Change” noted that “small patenting firms produce picture is that SMEs do not protect their innova-
tion for top three reasons: “not seeing any benefit
in protecting innovations, lack of knowledge on how
23. Intellectual Property (IP) Rights And Innovation In Small to protect innovations and the cost of procedures.”27
And Medium-Sized Enterprises, WIPO.
See Figure 4.
24. Patent statistics at Eurostat. Mapping the contribution of
SMEs in EU patenting, 2014.
25. Raymond J. Keating, “Unleashing Small Business Through
IP,” Chief Economist Small Business & Entrepreneurship Council, 26. Anthony Breitzman and Diana Hicks., “An Analysis of
2013. http://www.sbecouncil.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/06/ Small Business Patents by Industry and Firm Size,” Haddonfield,
IP+and+Entrepreneurship+FINAL.pdf. NJ 08033 2008.

144 les Nouvelles


Introduction
If we focus on patents
specifically, different studies
Figure 4. Costs And Lengthy Procedures Are The Key
show that the main reasons Reasons Why SMEs Refrain From Court Procedures As
for not filing are: A Means To Solve IPR Infringement Conflict
• Patent filing is complicate Too expensive court fees 58%
and expensive.
• Patent and especially port- Too lengthy 55%

folio of patents are too ex- Too expensive lawyers’ fees 53%
pensive to maintain. Low likelihood of being compensated 47%
• Patent protection is diffi- Risk of losing the case and having to 41%
cult and their enforcement pay high fees or compensation
is too costly and their effec- Difficulty in dealing with legal actions taken 38%
tiveness too low. Low likelihood of stopping the infringement 37%
• Competitors can legally in- Insufficiency of available legal remedies 36%
vent around most patents. Small chance of succeeding against
big companies or organizations 33%
• Rapid changes in technolo- Reluctance to publicly expose the case and suffer
gy limit patent protection. potential damage to the company’s reputation 18%

The Question of the Costs Risk of losing company trade secrets


disclosed to the court 15%

Patent costs are different Other 5%


among the countries—with
no rationale explaining those different national patent systems, as everyone of them
differences—and these costs represent a heavy burden have their particularities and a specific doctrine (a pat-
for the SMEs: See Table 4. ent could be granted in one economy, but rejected in
(Note: Process costs are the costs associated with the another). They also face the limited time in which to de-
drafting of the application and with the monitoring of cide where to pursue international stage patent protec-
the procedure (interaction with examiners and the pat- tion and in which countries, in a period of time when
ent office) on the applicant’s side. These costs can be they have financial constraint and few experience.
incurred in-house or externalized.) Yet for “small businesses trying to compete in global
However, to get a more precise view on patent markets, securing patent protection overseas can be a
cost, it is necessary to take into account the weight critical precondition to successfully internationalizing
of each market: the cost of a U.S.
or a Chinese patent relative to the
size of their market is then very low
Table 4. Patent Costs 2011
compared to the cost in any other
Patent Cost Structure
country.
Administrative Maintenance 20 years Process
Compexity of the Procedures
Coming just after the cost prob- France 742 5,608 12,414
lem, the complexity of the proce- Germany 550 13,170 11,443
dures is considered by the SMEs as Italy 1,935 6,620 11,294
the most important obstacle. See
UK 323 5,244 11,827
Table 5.
This barrier is all the more impor- Six EU countries 5,987 46,659 12,727
tant when it comes to filing patent China 379 9,162 5,736
internationally, as the small busi- India 407 2,959 3,423
nesses not only face higher costs
Japan 2,124 13,971 14,236
(estimated to several thousand eu-
ros/$) but are confronted with the South Korea 881 9,233 8,153
impossibility to understand the U.S.A. 3,453 5,446 10,573

Numbers are in euros.


Source: Patent costs and impact on innovation, Publications Office of
27. Intellectual Property (IP) SME the European Union, 2015.
Scoreboard, EUPTO, 2016.

September 2017 145


Introduction
and developing into the productivity powerhouses of access to patenting, but the new system where the
tomorrow”28 but the current system is too penalizing enterprises will have to choose between three types
for SMEs. of patent protection (national, several European coun-
“In Europe the consequences of the ‘fragmentation’ tries or the whole European EPO countries) and to
of the European patent system are more dramatic than decide to use or not the possibilities of some opting
the mere prohibitive costs of maintaining a patent in out provisions, introduce a new degree of complexity
force in many jurisdictions.”29 The reform to be intro- and have certainly not been conceived to simplify the
duced by the Unitary Patent will certainly improve the patent landscape for the SMEs.
How do the SMEs try to pro-
Table 5. Main Barriers For Patenting For SMEs, tect their inventions?
PROs And Universities SMEs Most SMEs protect their intan-
gible assets not through the IP sys-
Main barriers found during the process of patent filing tem but through informal methods
Country of origin Information (1) Costs (2) Language (3) Complexity (4) such as developing high-trust rela-
China 77% 23% 38% 62%
tionships or maintaining lead-time
advantages. Often, IP protection in
France 0% 94% 0% 36% SMEs relies upon the simple inimi-
Germany 36% 64% 9% 45% tability of their intangibles.
India 50% 83% 33% 17% These “rustic” means have
gained more attraction as the re-
Japan 37% 74% 47% 37% cent uncertainty on the validity of
Poland 50% 33% 0% 33% patent, exacerbated by some judi-
cial decision and new procedures,
South Korea 29% 57% 43% 57%
make trade secret more easy to
Spain 31% 85% 27% 69% assert in front of investors than a
Sweden 0% 84% 11% 58% patent which could always be chal-
lenged and drive to long and com-
UK 7% 86% 7% 50% plicate due diligences.
U.S.A. 7% 100% 20% 33% We use hereunder a study30 made
Source: (13) Patent cost and impact on innovation. for UK because it is more complete
on the means that SMEs use to pro-
tect their inventions—and at the
same time it is representative of the
Figure 5. Protecting Innovation: common behavior of the SMEs: See
Techniques Preferred By UK Firms Figure 5.
The fact that many SMEs con-
Large Firms SMEs sider lead time as the true protec-
Confidentiality agreement
tion of an invention correspond of
course to the acceleration—in cer-
Secrecy tain domains—of the innovation
process where one innovation re-
Lead-time place another in a very short peri-
od of time. This observation should
Trademarks

Patents 28. International Patent Protections


For Small Businesses, USPTO, January
Registration of designs
2012.
29. Economic Incongruities in the
Copyright European Patent System, M.Mejer and
B. van Pottelsberghe (2009).
Complexity of design 30. Alan Hughes and Andrea Mina,
“The Impact Of The Patent System On
0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% SMEs,” Centre for Business Research,
University of Cambridge, Working Paper
No.411, September 2010.

146 les Nouvelles


Introduction
SMEs through discounted filing and
Table 6. Ways To Enhance SMEs Patenting maintenance fees.
Price reductions of the overall costs
Conditions For Registering Company Size are significant for the USA, Brazil and
in the Future Micro Small Medium
Canada where costs reductions are
available for both in pre-grant (admin-
Reduction of costs 27% 19% 21% istrative costs) and for every annuity
Easier to access 29% 25% 26% of the maintenance fees. The rest of
Easier to understand 31% 28% 26%
the national patent offices offer reduc-
tions that only affect pre-grant fees
Certitude of adequate protection 32% 29% 30% and, in some cases, the first years of
Easier to take legal action 31% 28% 30% the renewal fees. The most favorable
Other 28% 31% 29%
system seems to be for the USA: the
SMEs (companies with less than 500
employees which have not assigned,
lead to consider new ways to accelerate the delivery of
granted, conveyed a license to an entity which does
invention acknowledgment. As such alternative meas-
not fulfil the SMEs requirements) will only pay 50 per-
ures such as Internet domain registration are mostly
cent of the pre-grant fees and maintenance fees to the
described as ‘easy’ or ‘very easy,’ with a greater pro-
USPTO.35 See Figure 6.
portion of micro SMEs finding it ‘very easy.’ 31

Hence we could conclude as an European study For Europe the system is about to change dramatical-
does: “From the study findings, we can infer that no
32 ly: “After decades of negotiations on the unitary pat-
preference should be given priority to any particular ent, on 24 June 2015 EU countries agreed on the level
means of protecting and/or appropriating a company’s of renewal fees of the unitary patent. The renewal fees
IP, be it large or small.” But it would be necessary to will be equal to the sum of national renewal fees in
agree with this assertion that all companies for which four countries (Germany, France, the United Kingdom
patenting is the appropriate solution, can file it in an and the Netherlands). This means that an inventor pro-
accessible and cost affordable process. As we have tecting their innovation with the unitary patent will
seen, this is certainly not the case today. pay less than €5,000 in renewal fees over 10 years for
What Policies exist for Enhancing SMEs Pat- a territory that covers 26 EU countries, instead of the
enting? The Challenge Ahead current level of around €30,000, which has proven
All around the world (see part 2 of this issue) the to discourage companies from patenting in Europe.”36
governments and public institutions have implemented However the impact of cost reduction is not straight-
policies to support SMEs as they identified evidence of forward. As a survey concludes: “we have not found
true market failures of the IPR system regarding SMEs. any quantitative evidence on the positive impact of
The Most Effective and Desired Ways to Enhance such special pricing on patenting activity. This could
SMEs Patenting: Some Paths be based on the fact that most NPOs (with the excep-
Simplification and shortening of procedures and tion of the USA, Brazil and Canada) offer reductions
better access to IPR databases are seen as the most that only affect pre-grant fees and, in some cases, the
effective support measures to help SMEs protect first years of the renewal fees. Although this special
their Intellectual Property assets. Yet few studies
33 pricing may be an incentive, it must be stressed that
explained how this could be done. maintenance costs are the most relevant ones for SMEs
Less important, but nevertheless generally consid- and may not be fully incurred if the economic value of
ered moderately effective, are reduction of costs or the patent does not compensate for them.” The study
financial support (25 percent high effectiveness), concludes: “As mentioned, there is no strong evidence
and information, guidance and support services to suggesting that patent costs can be a constraint for pat-
SMEs (19 percent). See Table 6.
34 enting… respondents consider patent costs a burden,
Cost Reduction: A Necessity but Not a Mira-
cle Remedy 34. Intellectual Property (IP) SME Scoreboard, EUPTO, 2016.
Some countries only granted some advantage to 35. Patent costs and impact on innovation, International
comparison and analysis of the impact on the exploitation of R&D
31. Intellectual Property (IP) SME Scoreboard, EUPTO, 2016. results by SMEs, Universities and Public Research Organisations;
32. Benchmarking National And Regional Support Services European Commission, 2014. http://ec.europa.eu/research/
For SMEs In The Field Of Intellectual And Industrial Property, innovation-union/pdf/patent_cost_impact_2015.pdf.
PRO INNO Europe paper N° 4, EC 2007. 36. https://ec.europa.eu/growth/industry/intellectual-property/
33. Intellectual Property (IP) SME Scoreboard, EUPTO, 2016. patents/unitary-patent_fr.

September 2017 147


Introduction
relevance of a system of protection of the
Figure 6. Cost Reductions In Overall Patent Costs IPR for the SMEs.
For SMEs in EUR (2011) Bringing More Support to SMEs:
We Can do Better
18,000 € In most countries, national patent offices
14,000 € and governmental administration for SMEs
provide various means of support to SMEs.
12,000 €
In terms of type of services, the services
Overall costs 20 years

12,000 € identified can be classified into five categories:39


10,000 € (a) Awareness-raising and training in IP
8,000 € (b) Technological information services
6,000 € (c) Financial assistance
(d) Customized advisory services in IP
4,000 €
(e) Assistance for IP exploitation and
2,000 € technology transfer
0 € These services bring significant support
to the SMEs and must certainly be en-
ce

ia

da
ay

ia
an

A
an

pa
rw

il

ss
na

US hanced. Some studies gives indications on


m

az
Fr

Ru
Ja
No

Ca
Ro

Br

General case SMEs


the way to proceed: “most of the services
are rather small offerings, operated by few
people and endowed with rather low fund-
ing. The performance of the present IPR
but it does not mean that lower fees will increase the support system are highly ambiguous. Despite a rather
issuing of high quality patents. Following this com- large number of identified services, fairly few services
ment, one question that could be answered in future can be described as high performers. Some “islands”
studies could be: what is the right balance between of well-designed programmes exist, but the majority of
patent costs and patent application quality?” measures do not seem to have a strong track record.”40
The Accessibility to Enforcing Patent Conclusion
IP rights can only work to the extent to which they Although our knowledges are incomplete, there is a
are enforceable. In case a competitor infringes the IPR certainty that SMEs do not use the patent system as they
of a firm, the firm should be able to litigate successfully, should, because the system that was designed to protect
at sufficiently low costs and in a timely manner. In prac- inventors of any size—but in a limited space—seems to
tice, however, litigation often turns out to be difficult.37 become ineffective in too many cases and is now being
An expert group “making IPR works for SMEs, IPR challenged by profound changes in the conditions of in-
enforcement expert group report” has made some novation and the globalization of the economy.
recommendations. In this regards, the Unitary Patent However, there are still more precise analysis to
Court which will be implemented in the European EPO be made concerning the nature and number of in-
countries is certainly a progress. As far as we know, novative enterprises within the SMEs, the nature of
the court fees will be made up of a fixed fee, com- inventions, the means of protecting and enhancing
bined with a value-based fee when the value of a case them, and the functioning of exchanges and circula-
is above the set ceiling of 500,000 €. The value-based tion of inventions. ■
fees rise according to the value of a case. Small and Mi-
cro-entities will benefit from a 40 percent reduction
in court fees.38 But as for the patent procedure, the Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
cost of a litigation is not the only factor to evaluate the https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009015

38. https://www.unified-patent-court.org/faq/fees.
39. Intellectual Property (IP) Rights And Innovation In Small
And Medium-Sized Enterprises, WIPO.
37. Benchmarking National And Regional Support Services 40. Benchmarking National And Regional Support Services
For SMEs In The Field Of Intellectual And Industrial Property, For SMEs In The Field Of Intellectual And Industrial Property,
PRO INNO Europe paper N° 4, EC 2007. PRO INNO Europe paper N° 4, EC 2007.

148 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patent Valorization

SMEs And Patent Valorization


By Josep Maria Pujals

E
ven though Small Medium Entities (SMEs) rep- embrace open innovation and
resent almost 95% of businesses and contribute to leverage its market position
■ Josep Maria Pujals,
significantly to global GDP1 not all type of SMEs across Global Value Chains.
own or manage Intellectual Property rights to support Super Monetisation Enti-
Ponti,
their business. It depends on their size, the type of ties contribute to economic IP Lawyer,
activities that contribute to their competitiveness and growth by introducing com- Barcelona, Spain
also the sector in which they operate.2 Thus small busi- mercial, scientific and techno- E-mail: pepepujals@
nesses carrying out R&D activities in the life science logical knowledge embedded
sector or in other industries that are innovation inten- yahoo.com
in inventions and capital 1 as
sive are more likely to be aware of the strategic role of intellectual Property to the
Intellectual Property. By contrast, small retail compa- markets.
nies usually own one or two trademarks and domain Super Monetisation Entities challenge established
names protecting their business and main product or businesses and monopolies by creating more efficient
service identity at a national level, as their customer customer relationships, adding disruptive features to
base is only domestic or local. They do not use Intellec- existing products and services or by introducing new
tual Property to i.e. access new markets or to collabo- ones, thus improving client’s satisfaction and expe-
rate with others to develop new products and services rience, gaining competitive advantage and driving eco-
because of their lack of sophistication. 3
nomic growth and technological change.
But in the so-called 21st century knowledge-based Intellectual Property Management and Valori-
economies, where intellectual capital is key for the sation are at the heart of the Super Monetisation
development of added value technologies and services, Entity’s strategy.
the use of Intellectual Property is crucial for innovative
SMEs to successfully link R&D and innovation efforts Super Monetisation Entities are relevant holders of
with commercialisation and internationalisation. Intellectual Property assets in accordance with their
capabilities and intensive focus on innovation and new
Those innovative Small Medium Entities are what product development. According to some innovation
we call “Super Monetisation Enterprises,” as they metrics, they are found to produce more than twice
are able to introduce disruptive, niche innovations into as many innovations and file more patents and trade-
global markets and are aware of the vital contri-
bution of Intellectual Property assets creation and Table 1. IP Intensity, Relative To Assets, Of SMEs Versus
management to their business strategy and capita- Large UK Firms. (Rogers, Helmers & Greenhalgh, 2007)
lising on differentiation.
Large Films SMEs
Intellectual Property management and owner- 0.45
ship then allows the Super Monetisation Enter- 0.40
prise to appropriate internal R&D developments, to
0.35

0.30
1. Stanley P. Kowalski Director ITTI, Franklin Pierce Law
0.25
Center, “SMES, Open Innovation and IP Management:
Advancing Global Development” (Concord, NH) 0.20
http://www.wipo.int/edocs/mdocs/sme/en/wipo_smes_ 0.15
rom_09/wipo_smes_rom_09_b_theme02_2.pdf.
0.10
2. “Intellectual Property (IP) SME Scoreboard,”
EUIPO (2016) https://euipo.europa.eu/tunnel-web/secure/ 0.05
webdav/guest/document_library/observatory/documents/ 0.00
sme_scoreboard_study_2016/seme_scoreboard_ UK Community UK Patents EPO
study_2016_en.pdf. Trademarks Trademarks Patents
3. Suzanne S. Harrison, Patrick H. Sullivan, “Edison
in the Boardroom Revisited: How Leading Companies 4. Intellectual Property: Powerhouse for Innovation and
Realise Value from Their Intellectual Property,” (2nd Economic Growth https://cdn.iccwbo.org/content/uploads/
Edition) http://eu.wiley.com/WileyCDA/WileyTitle/ sites/3/2011/02/Intellectual-Property-Powerhouse-for-
productCd-1118004531.html. Innovation-and-Economic-Growth.pdf.
September 2017 149
SMEs And Patent Valorization
marks applications per employee than large firms.4 the fact that Super Monetisation Entities’ management
Thus, Super Monetisation Entities sustainably drive is extremely focused on creating new Intellectual Pro-
the Darwinian innovation cycle of creative destruction, 5 perty linked to radical innovations, makes its advanta-
because of their ability to change market rules through geous market position and leadership inevitable.
the introduction of disruptive technologies and inno- The IP marketplace9 or the market for inventions6
vations and also due to the fact that established compa- plays a vital role for Super Monetisation Entities to le-
nies “experience innovative inertia because of limited verage codified and tacit knowledge and experience, to
management attention to new business, management strengthen their competitive advantage, and to deliver
misperceptions of competitive threats and opportu- new products and services, creating new markets and
nities, organisational rent seeking and bureaucratic gaining clients via IPRs.
routines.”6 Thus, we find many examples of leading We define IP monetization-valorisation as the dif-
companies who have introduced disruptive technolo- ferent options available to Super Monetisation Entities
gies and monopolise their objective market but then in the IP Market to leverage internal or external codi-
are unable to find the path for sustainably delivering fied knowledge for competitive advantage: “Preventing
new innovations and products, or anticipate their cus- others from copying products or services, improving
tomers’ new likes. “While Kodak invented many of chances of securing investment, obtaining licensing re-
the core technologies underlying digital cameras, its venues, improving chances/quality of liquidity (e.g. ac-
management was too addicted to the steady flow of fat quisition/IPO) preventing patent infringement actions
profits from its film, paper, and chemical franchises to
risk cannibalising it. Hence,
Kodak let others pioneer the
field, waking up too late to Table 2. Optimized Allocations
catch up.” Established firms Technology categorisation
7
Start- up New entrant Leading
also face The Innovator’s (moderate size) company
Dilemma when managing (high mkt share)
IP. Thus, big firms are very Sustaining technology 10% 20% 50%
conservative when creating (improvement to existing market)
and managing their IP port-
folios.8 Their IP assets mainly Sustaining technology 20% 50% 35%
(applied to new market)
relate to technologies and
services that already contri- Disruptive technology 70% 30% 15%
bute to sales and incomes Total Budget 100% 100% 100%
but not to future options
linked to disruptive techno-
logies and R&D efforts that Table 3. ICT SMEs’ Reported Goals For Using IPR. (IDC, 2008)
can win the next markets to
the detriment of alternatives Patents Copyright Trademarks Registered Utility
Designs Models
developed by newcomers
and competitors. This gap in Launch new products 69% 81% 71% 67% 63%
and services; exploit
IP management can deter big new innovations
firms’ ability to take advan-
Exchange, license, 10%46% 21% 19% 23% 18%
tage of their market supre- collaborate
macy and is a further signal
of complacency. By contrast, Gain access to funding 34%% 27% 18% 26% 16%
Block competitors 32% 23% 12% 16% 14%

5. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Creative_destruction. 8. “Welcoming ‘The Innovator’s Dilemma,’” IAM Magazine


http://www.iam-media.com/Search?qs=Welcoming+%E2%80%
6. “The Innovative Enterpreneur: Daniel F. Spulber.”
98the+innovator%E2%80%99s+dilemma+IAM+Magazine.
7. “Polaroid, Kodak, Apple: No One Escapes the Winds of
9. “Shortcomings on the Market for IP.” http://tinyurl.com/
Creative Destruction.” https://www.forbes.com/sites/billfrezza/
ybtuxrwu
2012/09/05/polaroid-kodak-apple-no-one-escapes-the-winds-of-
creative-destruction/#22aa9a75d002. 10. Stuart J. Graham, Ted Sichelman, “Why do start up
patent?” http://scholarship.law.berkeley.edu/cgi/viewcontent.
cgi?article=1757&context=btlj.

150 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patent Valorization
Thus govern-
ments are increa-
singly trying to pro-
mote the strategic
use of IP by inno-
vative firms in the
new knowledge-
based economies,
where the ability to
appropriate tech-
nological and mar-
ket differentiation
is crucial for new
companies’ abi-
lity to growth and
conquer new mar-
kets.
“The key role of
IP in the success
against the company; improving the company’s nego- of start-ups and innovative SMEs has long been reco-
tiation position with other companies (e.g. cross-licen- gnised: it allows innovative businesses to appropriate
sing) and enhancing the company reputation image.”10 the results of their creativity, inventiveness and R&D
But, despite all the existing empirical evidence avai- investments, and creates an incentive for further in-
lable on the advantages that IP management can bring vestment in innovation3. Recent data from the EU Intel-
to innovative firms for accessing new clients and mar- lectual Property Office (EUIPO) show that businesses
kets, seeking investment, building strategical partner- using IP rights perform better, and this is particularly
ships and collaborations or enhancing its reputation, true in the case of SMEs. SMEs owning IP rights have
not too many innovative SMEs are engaged with the almost 32 percent higher revenue per employee than
patent system.11 SMEs that do not. They also expand their workforce
One of the reasons for innovative SMEs not faster and pay higher salaries. IP is therefore key for
being fully aware of the opportunity that IP mar- smart and sustainable growth.”13
kets offer is the current transition from the manufac- Also, the phenomenon of the so-called Gazelles enti-
turing age—towards the age of innovation. ties (all enterprises up to five years old with average
In such context, IP systems differences, lack of smart annualised growth greater than 20 percent per annum
capital, costs and access to expertise amongst other over a three-year period) is associated with Intellectual
problems in the IP market6 reduces or limits innova- Property use and great innovation potential.14
tive SMEs’ ability to develop internally sustained IP Super Monetisation Entities’ ability to align its
strategies and fully deploy the role of intangible assets organisational and management operations towards
for value capture from a very early stage.
12. “Lack of Access to Patent Advice Is a Huge Problem for
Putting IPRs to Work for Sustained Innovation Start-ups and SMEs in Europe.” IAM http://www.iam-media.com/
and Competitive Advantage Blog/Detail.aspx?g=36616482-6fce-41fe-bb35-fd7264376412.
Super Monetisation Entities are rich in IP assets and 13. “Commission Staff Working Document” Accompanying
IP management capabilities developed both internally the document Communication from the Commission
and outsourced. They also tend to be specialised in to the European Parliament, the Council, the European
niche areas and are flexible, thus needing and being Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of
the Regions Europe’s next leaders: the Start-up and Scale-
able to scale up into new international markets. up Initiative Putting intellectual property at the service of
SMEs to foster innovation and growth (COM, 2016) 733.
http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/
10. Stuart J. Graham, Ted Sichelman, “Why do start up TXT/?uri=SWD:2016:373:FIN.
patent?” http://scholarship.law.berkeley.edu/cgi/viewcontent. 14. David B. Audretsch, University of Indiana, U.S.A.,
cgi?article=1757&context=btlj. “Determinants of High-Growth Entrepreneurship Report.”
11. “Delivering Agile Innovation,” E&Y http://www.ey.com/ prepared for the OECD/DBA International Workshop on ―
Publication/vwLUAssets/EY-DeliveringAgileInnovation-exec- High-growth firms: local policies and local determinants.
summary/$File/EY-DeliveringAgileInnovation-exec-summary. (Copenhagen, 2012). https://www.oecd.org/cfe/leed/
pdf). Audretsch_determinants%20of%20high-growth%20firms.pdf.

September 2017 151


SMEs And Patent Valorization
the development of new technolo-
Table 4: U.S. Gazelles And High-Impact Firms gies and innovations in very specific
Number of Period Number Of Job Change Revenue Change niche markets place them in a better
Employed Gazelles ($1,000s) position to deliver a more agile res-
1994-1998 309,160 3,018,440 $577,533,025
ponse and reaction to different cus-
1-19 tomer demands and change of needs.
1998-2002 301, 275 3,573,918 $716,504,242 “In some particularly fast-paced and
2002-2006 283,308 2,883,475 $589,072,471 innovative industries, which include
20-499 1994-1998 43,342 3,014,683 $762,963,829 process control equipment and infor-
1998-2002 42,390 3,291,048 $957,923,241
mation technology, capital intensity
is a less important constraint. An
2002-2006 39,617 2,138,682 $1,014,653,361
innovative SME may be more easily
500-plus 1994-1998 1,547 5,063,517 $$1,195,977,664 able to focus on a narrow range of
1998-2002 1,665 4,515,417 $1,841,396,607 specific inventions. Organisational
2002-2006 1,485 2,514,558 $1,663,635,336 differences—such as a less bureau-
cratic, more innovation-focussed ma-
1994-1998 354,049 11,096,640 $2,536,474,518
Total
nagement structure or more direct
1998-2002 345,330 11,380,383 $3,515,824,090 incentives to succeed—may also give
2002-2006 324,410 7,528,715 $3,267,361,168 SMEs a relative advantage over their
Number of Period Number Of High- Job Change Revenue Change larger counterparts in developing
Employed Impact Firms ($1,000s) innovations.”4
1994-1998 327,397 3,170,729 $346,038,292 When Super Monetisation Entities’
1-19
1998-2002 278,190 3,577,111 $423,042,570
products and technologies are domi-
nant and irreplaceable in a specific
2002-2006 359,289 4,041,099 $425,041,975
industry, they became “indispensable
1994-1998 23,464 2,788,969 $503,059,203 and non-substitutable in the whole
20-499 Global Value Chain (GVC).” Such
1998-2002 20,601 2,966,647 570,102,604
2002-2006 16.523 2,001,835 $549,674,434
firms can be described as the “bott-
leneck” of the GVC (Jacobides et al.,
1994-1998 1,253 5,501,049 $1,110,073,562
500-plus
2006). Example of such bottlenecks
1998-2002 1,182 5,192,558 $1,657,759,197 are the so-called “hidden champions”
2002-2006 793 2,966,826 $1,060,128,527 (Simon, 2009): firms that capture
1994-1998 152,114 11,460,747 $1,959,171,057 high shares of the world market in
Total specific products (Table 5). Hidden
1998-2002 299,973 11,737,316 $2,650,904,371
champions usually have state-of-the-
2002-2006 376,605 9,009,7760 $2,034,844,936 art technology and superior product
Source: Corporate Research Board, American Corporate Statistical Library (2007). Ace, Parsons and Tracy (2008) quality in niche products, both of

Table 5: Examples Of “Hidden Champions”


Company Main Product World Share
Dr. Suwelack Collagen 100%
Skysails Towing kite wind propulsion system 100%
Ulvac LCD panel coating 96%
Nivarox Regulating mechanism for wristwatch 90%
GKD- Gebr. Kufferath Metal fabrics 90%
Saes Getters Barium getters 85%
alki-Technik Special screw systems 80%
Delo Adhesives for chip modules on smart cards 80%
Nissha Small touch panel 80%
Kern-Liebers Springs for safety belts 80%
Weckerie Lipstick machines 80%
Omicron Tunnel grid/tunnel probe microscopes 70%
Source: Simon (2009), Hidden Champions of the 21st Century, Springer Publishing. Supporting Investment in Knowledge Capital, Growth and Innovation OECD 2013

152 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patent Valorization
which rivals find very hard to match.”15 adopt their technology: “The action that the pledgor
In terms of patent ownership, while “large corpora- seeks to induce in others can vary, but it is generally
tions have six patents per 1000 employees, the Hidden related to third parties’ adoption of certain technology
Champions have 31. The costs of a Hidden Champion choices that are favoured by the pledgor. There are
patent are only about one-fifth of those in a large cor- three principal sub-categories of inducement pledges:
poration.”16 those intended to induce other firms to adopt and
Super Monetisation Entities also use Intellectual Pro- make investments in products that comply with one or
perty strategically. For instance, “lead firms in electro- more interoperability standards, those intended to in-
nics GVCs have deployed standards not only to enhance duce other firms to adopt a particular technology plat-
knowledge transfer to their suppliers, but also to lower the form favoured, if not actually sold, by the pledgor, and
barriers to entry in the corresponding segment of the those intended to induce market participants to adopt
GVC and increase competition among suppliers (Shapi- a broad platform technology. In each of these cases,
ro and Varian, the pledgor calculates that it is likely to derive greater
Figure 6. The Confluence Of The Driv- 1999).”15 benefit from the behaviour that it seeks to induce in
ers Of Productivity Growth In 21st others than from using its patents to exclude others
Century Knowledge Economies Thus, accor- from the market.”
ding to Jorge
L. Contreras,17 The Super Monetisation Entity and the Digital
innovative Challenge and Opportunity
companies As innovations can be codified via IPRs in the new
KBC GVC deactivate Connected-4.0 knowledge-based economy, where a
Productivity strategically number of connected questions rapidly arise, “inclu-
growth their ability ding those relating to the models for successful exploi-
to enforce tation of digital intellectual property, the future of
ICT their patents patent law vis-àvis creative computers, or the regime
Source20 to induce of data ownership and privacy in the big data environ-
other firms to ment,”18 Super Monetisation Entities are best placed

Figure 7. Intensity And Development Speed In ICT-related Technologies, 2000-12

Note: Data refer to patent applications filed at the EPO or the USPTO that belong to IP5 families, by filing date, using fractional counts. ICT-related patents
are defined on the basis of their International Patent Classification (IPC) codes. Source: OCED (2015c) Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2015,
OECD Publishing , Paris, http://dx/doi/org/10/1787/888933273469.
16. “Who are the Hidden Champions?” https://www.anca.
15. “Supporting Investment in Knowledge Capital, Growth com/Files/Editorials/MannMonthly_Oct2013.pdf.
and Innovation.” OECD. http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/indus- 17. Jorge L. Contreras, “Patent Pledges.” http://arizonas-
try-and-services/supporting-investment-in-knowledge-capi- tatelawjournal.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/12/Contreras_Fi-
tal-growth-and-innovation_9789264193307-en. nal.pdf.

September 2017 153


SMEs And Patent Valorization

Figure 8. 4th Year Maintenance Rate vs. Forward Citation Rate


As a percentage of all ICT- related patent applications also belonging to other technology fields

% 2010-12 2000-02

16

12

.
y
s

en als
oa .

s
ac s

m ines
Po es

ha al d y

ch
ch cs

s
ics
y

ch ng.

er rs

, tu h
gy

.
& ting

s
y

rt

ica y

ce

En ma istr
t
ng

l
re rol

rg
he Ma ame
log

od
o
er

nic men
ec
c

em str
i

hin

e
Su io-v spo

l te
c
l te pt

cia e to
olo

te

ist

i
er allu
M nsu lym
le

le

ev
itu nt
hin

on euti
t
rb
go

m
no

Ch emi

-
O

pu ano
ce ual

log

ta
o
,g
Ba Civi
hn

Ph che
le
in
ac

t
nd d c

C
Au Tra

c
e
lm

Or al e
ch
is
ec

n
lm

ps

m
Ha an

m
ot

d
g

sic

ls,

nic
m

ar
gi - an
ica

lin
ica

rn
Bi

ga
d

ia

Th
pe

vir
o
Fu
ctr

rfa

er
ed

o
rc
rs

s,

ec
icr

at
M
Ele

ne
he

M
M
Ot
Ot

En
Note: Patent counts are based on the priority date. Source:OECD (2015a) Digital Economy outlook, OECD Publishing, Paris,
based on OECD, Patent Database, February 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787.888933224483.

for benefiting from the intangible nature of intellectual


property assets, allowing them to deliver innovative Figure 9. Economic Characterization of IP:
products and services in new markets and gaining cus- Value Chain IP Economic
tomers directly or through partner collaborations, ie. Bio-Technology Intensity Characterization Strategy
through 3D printing. “The potential advantages of 3D
Routine Joint Venture
printing are numerous for innovation-intensive compa-
Market
nies. In particular, 3D printing allows them to reduce
their overheads when developing, designing and tes-
ting new products or improving existing ones. They no Routine Outsource
longer have to pay for costly prototypes but can rapidly Manufacture

and cheaply undertake multiple iterations of complex


elements in-house using 3D printers.”19 Entrepreneurial Internal
Develop
In the new hyper-connected industry, where Development

knowledge-based capital, Global Value Chains and ICT


are the drivers of productivity growth in the 21st cen-
Discover
tury,20 Super Monetisation Entities profit from IP asset Entrepreneurial License

management to retain competitive advantage and seek


complementarities.
“The concept of complementary assets is a very But exceptions clearly exist as in the case of Dell,
relevant one since it highlights the fact that the suc- and its innovative manufacturing processes.

cessful commercialisation of an innovation requires


manufacturing, marketing and after sales capabilities, 18. Intellectual Property And Digitalisation—Challenges for
among other factors. This means that appropriability Intellectual Property—A conference jointly organised by CEIPI
cannot be entirely dependent on the more or less suc- / BETA / I3PM. http://www.i3pm.org/files/misc/Conference_on_
cessful features of the technology to be protected, but intellectual_Property_and_Digitalization.pdf.
is heavily based on the firms’ other capabilities.”21 19. WIPO Magazine. 3D http://www.wipo.int/wipo_maga-
zine/en/2017/01/article_0006.html.
IP: Towards a Recognised Valuable Asset 20. “Stimulating Digital Innovation for Growth and Inclu-
siveness.” http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/science-and-technology/stimulat-
As governments move toward IP Systems harmonisa- ing-digital-innovation-for-growth-and-inclusiveness_5jlwqvhg3l31-en.
tion, traditional institutions, legal, banks, stakeholders 21. “Innovation and Appropriability, Empirical Evidence and Re-
through the innovation value chain, will be more likely search Agenda.” http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplay-
to recognise the economic value of IP assets and thus documentpdf/?cote=DSTI/ICCP(2015)18/FINAL&docLanguage=En.

154 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patent Valorization

Figure 10. Valuation Purposes & Standards


Transaction-M&A/Licensing Financial Reporting Bankruptcy/Reorganization
Audience: Audience: Audience:
Management Investors Bankruptcy Judge
Investors SEC Creditors
Standards: Standards: Standards:
Company Specific GAAP Statute/Case law
FASB Bank requirements
Tax Legal Financing/Securitization
Audience: Audience: Audience:
IRS, Foreign Tax Authority Trial court Creditors
Standards: Investors
Standards: “Georgia Pacific” Standards:
Per Tax Code (367; 482; 350; “Panduit” Factors Statute/Case law
197; 170) Statute/Case Law

the importance of IP markets and IP valorisation will financial distress.”24


increase for extracting-realising value from innovation Conclusion:
activities.
Because innovative SMEs are stronger at integrating
This inertia will help to develop new economic dy- technology and customer needs than big firms but lack
namics based on intangible capital ownership, on the other complementary assets, they need to recognise
acknowledgement that IP mainly: and institutionalise intangible capital management as
• Allows innovative firms to appropriate market and a principal means to valorise—capture strategic value
technology differentiation and protect and expand from—their innovation efforts.
market share; When doing that, they become Super Monetisation
• Allows innovative firms to collaborate with exter- Entities, and are best positioned to leverage their po-
nal firms with complementary assets. sition within the innovation ecosystem and navigate
“SMEs can use patents as enablers of open innova- through the current “extreme uncertainty” 25 towards
tion in order to connect their technological innovations sustained benefits. ■
with the complementary assets needed for commercia- Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
lisation (e.g., Chesbrough, 2003, 2006; Chesbrough et https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009019
al., 2006; Enkel et al., 2009; Gassmann et al., 2009;
Dahlander and Gann, 2010; Bogers et al., 2012+ ).23
And therefore, IP represents a signal of innovation
capacity for investors and a source of finance.
“First, IPRs help to reveal to investors the quality of
the firm’s management and of its technological capabi-
lities. Second, as legally protected economic resources,
IPRs can raise the projected profitability of a firm, and
can be separated from the business and sold in case of

22. “Intangible Asset & Intellectual Property Valuation: A


Multidisciplinary Perspective.” http://www.wipo.int/sme/en/ 24. “Enquiries Into Intellectual Property’s Economic
documents/ip_valuation_fulltext.html. Impact” (Chapter 9) Ip-Based Financing of Innovative Firms
23. Marcus Holgersson, “Patent Management in http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplay
Entrepreneurial SMEs: A Literature Review and an Empirical documentpdf/?cote=DSTI/ICCP(2014)17/CHAP9/FINAL&
Study of Innovation Appropriation, Patent Propensity, docLanguage=En.
and Motives.” http://www.ip-research.org/wp-content/ 25. Eric Ries, “The Lean Start-up.”
uploads/2012/09/PAM11-20120814a-with-publ-info.pdf. http://theleanstartup.com/principles.

September 2017 155


SMEs And OI

SMEs And Open Innovation (OI)


By Paul Germeraad

Abstract cal solution. It also involves being clear on how “new”


The trick in using Open Innovation (OI) to augment any and “unfamiliar” the technology they seek must be in
corporation’s (large and small) business development order to meet their business objectives. Once a SME
programs is typically not in the decision of whether or is clear on what it is looking for, the three steps in
not to consider OI as an option, but rather the challenge SMEs finding technologies from external partners are
of how to best use OI. This paper provides insights and (1) Searching for Technology Solutions, (2) Evaluating
tools specific to the latter challenge for Small and Me- and Choosing Solutions, and (3) Negotiating for Tech-
dium Enterprises (SMEs). nology and IP Solutions.
II. Clarity on what kind of technology SMEs
I. Introduction should obtain via OI strategies

S
MEs differ in their use of OI from large compa- Studies on OI continually highlight the need for or-
nies in that they are typically looking for compo- ganizations to be able to specifically state the problem
nents and new features to enable and improve they seek to solve.1 This point is critical for SMEs with
their company’s primary product offerings. In contrast limited resources. Being able to articulate what exactly
larger companies are often using OI as a means to offer is the organization trying to address/solve is imperative
completely new products and services that are typical- for a good OI outcome. Once the problem is clearly
ly adjacent to or differentiated from their current offer- stated, the market growth in the SME’s targeted mar-
ings. This differentiation exists because of where each ket and SME market share constrain the innovation
company is in their business lifecycle. options available to SMEs. Utilizing a standard market-
This distinction in the use of OI by SMEs versus ing position graph of SME and competitor positions
large companies is important because to date much of as shown in Figure 1, an SME can double check its
the published literature and conference presentations search criteria for the newness and unfamiliarity re-
focus on the use of OI by large companies. The conclu- quired of a technology it seeks. In Figure 1, innova-
sions and recommendations of these papers and pres- tion posture contours (maverick, offensive, defensive)
entations somewhat miss the mark when it comes to are super-imposed on market growth rate and relative
what is best to help SMEs. For example OI studies on
large companies find that inbound practices utilize cus- Figure 1. Innovation Postures
tomer co-creation, informal networking, and universi- Derived from Market Growth
ty grants. Use of crowdsourcing and OI intermediary and Relative Share
services are rated of lowest value. The three leading oi
partner categories large companies use are customers, 20%
File/Maintain File/Maintain
universities and suppliers. Finally, and most important- 18%
Broad & Deep Broadly

ly, the three leading reasons given for using OI in large


organizations are (1) establishing new partnerships, (2) 16%
Offensive Long Range R&D-
exploring new technological trends, and (3) identifying 14% Maverick- Next Generation
new business opportunities. Breakthrough
12%
These three leading reasons for OI don’t apply to
Market Growth

SME’s. For SMEs the key driver for using OI is to get 10%

access to critical technology that it can’t otherwise ob- 8%


Defensive
tain because of time or money constraints. More suc- Maintenance R&D-
Next Generation
cinctly, the business goal for SME OI is to obtain a sus- 6%
&Incremental Offensive
tained advantaged market position that it can’t obtain 4%
Short Term
utilizing only its own capabilities. Maintenance R&D-
Withold R&D- Incremental
2%
Thus the OI Reality for SME’s is that SME’s are Customer Tech Support
File/Maintain
Lightly
more constrained and must carefully and thoughtfully 0%
0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2
understand what technology they are looking for. This
Relative Market Share To Largest Competitor
is more complex than just stating the desired techni-

156 les Nouvelles


SMEs And OI
SME market share positions. Once an SME determines er Nature” when it comes to OI. This is because for
the appropriate innovation posture for its project, the SMEs in particular you not have the time or money to
innovation posture can be combined with patent land- ever “Mess with Mother Nature.”
scape densities (described below) to arrive at the best Another distinction between large and small com-
OI approach. panies when it comes to OI has to do with the rate at
To provide some detail on how IP density determ- which all entities are investing in the SME’s technol-
ines any corporations’ entry business development ogy of interest. In this context patent velocity is an
scenario, consider the following: (1) If there is little excellent analogue for investment rate. As such it is
art (called an IP “Desert”), a company has to invest its the “Father Time” for OI
own R&D and/or use OI co-development with typically in that “Time is the Ene-
a university or research institute. In contrast if there my.” Figure 4 shows three ■ Paul Germeraad,
are hundreds of documents (called an IP “Forest”) a typical patent velocity pat- President,
company has the option make, buy or ally with oth- terns that come from plot-
ers. Here the best OI option is to license “almost com- ting patent family counts Intellectual Assets, Inc.,
plete” technology from another entity. Finally, if there per year. Saratoga, CA, USA
are tens of thousands of patent family documents in These graphs can be E-mail: germeraadgroup@
the technical area of interest (called an IP “Jungle”), it created by SME personnel gmail.com
is best for the company to buy or license this art from starting with simple Inter-
an individual or another for-profit company. net search engines like
These “innovation posture” and “patent density” Google. A more sophisticated investigation of patent
concepts were introduced in order to allow segmenta- databases can be accomplished using tools like Google
tion of R&D and business development initiatives into patents using free text, Questel and Innography us-
those which are best or ill-suited for an OI approach. ing concepts, and Questel, Innography, Thompson,
A high level summary of such approaches is shown in etc. by using of similarity engines. Depending upon
Figure 2. in the technology being sought, selected science da-
Utilizing the recommended R&D approaches shown tabases such as chemical abstracts, STN, IEEE etc. are
in Figure 2 the OI sweet spot for SME’s is at the bot- also useful. Utilizing multiple approaches assures the
tom left of the matrix shown in Figure 3. When SMEs best chance of finding technologies that will meet the
try to work in the upper rows or right hand side of this SME’s project needs.
matrix they often find their OI initiatives do not pro- Looking first at the overall number of patent families
duce favorable business outcomes. This is in contrast in a field and using an approximation of $1 million in-
to the recommended sweet spot for large companies vested by a company for each patent family published,
who can utilize approaches on the diagonal from lower the overall number of patent families shows the extent
left upper right. For SMEs, IP Density is like “Moth- to which a field has attracted enough investment to

Figure 2. Innovation Posture and IP Landscape Sets the OI Approach

Posture vs. IP Position IP Jungle IP Forest IP Desert

Kill Project Proposal Screen for Start-Ups Fund Internal or Academic


Maverick - Breakthrough Technology

Offensive Long Range - Next Fund to Find and Re- Fund External or Internal Fund Internal Technology
Generation (New Feature or purpose External Technology or Screen for Start-ups
Big Cost Savings) Technology

Offensive Short Term Use External Already Fund to Find and Re- Fund to External or Internal
Maintenance - Incremental “Baked” Technology purpose External Technology
(New but Familiar Feature Technology
or Solid Cost Savings)

Defensive Short Term Screen for Low Cost Use External Already Fund to Find and
Maintenance - Next External “Baked” “Baked” Technology Re-purpose External
Generation or Incremental Technology Technology
(Familiar Feature)

September 2017 157


SMEs And OI

Figure 3. Sweet Spot for SME OI Innovation Initiatives

Posture vs. IP Position IP Jungle IP Forest IP Desert

Fund Internal or Academic


Maverick- Breakthrough Kill Project Proposal Screen for Start-Ups
Technology

Offensive Long Range- Next Fund to Find and Re-


Fund External or Internal Fund Internal Technology
Generation (New Feature or purpose External
Technology or Screen for Start-ups
Big Cost Savings) Technology

Offensive Short Term Use External Already Fund to find and


Maintenance- Incremental “Baked” Technology Re-purpose External Fund to external or internal
(New But Familiar Feature Technology Technology
or Solid Cost Savings) Open Innovation
Defensive Short Term
Sweet Spot
Screen for Low Cost Fund to Find and Re-
Maintenance- Next Use External Already
External “Baked” purpose External
Generation or Incremental “Baked” Technology
Technology Technology
(Familiar Feature)

match the SME’s needs. This initial step


Figure 4. Tough Areas for should ideally produce a small number of
SME OI Innovation Initiatives potential options.
For the final candidates selected, the
methodology then switches to estimating
the IP “freedom to operate” risk and “IP’s
ability to exclude other competitors” for
each option. This is necessary as some IP
environments have inherently more ag-
gressive and well-funded participants than
others (compared to the SME).
The last step in the process is to careful-
ly summarize the strengths, weaknesses,
opportunities, and threats so the negoti-
ating team is well prepared to negotiate a
make finding an OI opportunity likely. Returning now to mutually beneficial agreement. The six steps follow.2
Figure 4 (showing the pattern by which the overall num- The first step is to understand the IP landscape: De-
ber of patent families have been created) only the left termining investment rates. The goal of this step is
and right patterns offer OI promise for SME’s because to determine whether the product or service will be
of the time and financial constraints typical of SMEs. launched in a favorable commercial environment. The
Assuming that an SME has looked for the technology key questions to be answered are: (1) Which entities
it wants and has found that the environment is in the have invested the most R&D money in this field? (2)
sweet spot of both Figures 3 and 4, the next step is What are the most common technical approaches and
to begin evaluating and choosing technology solutions. associated products? Patent database mining is an ex-
III. Searching, Evaluating and Choosing Tech- cellent tool to answer such questions.
nology Solutions The second step is to understand recent trends:
A six step process has been found to most quickly Heat and bubble maps of the technical domains. This
and productively screen and evaluate technology solu- step checks whether there is consistency between the
tions. The logic behind this six-step process is that technical and commercial lifecycle positions. The key
information sources should first be analyzed at the questions are: (1) Which technologies are emerging
broadest level to ensure that investigators understand and falling out of favor? and (2) Which entities are en-
the overall technology landscape before focusing close- tering or leaving this field?
ly on those individual technology options that closely A heat or bubble map of patents in the overall tech-

158 les Nouvelles


SMEs And OI
nical field shows individual technology domains which
helps an SME to reduce the number of technology areas Figure 5. Frequency Distribution of
it needs to investigate. Plotting the number of patent Potential OI Opportunities
families in each technology domain that were filed annu-
ally shows the relative rates of investment in each one.
Shrinking fields (where the number of patents/year de-
creases over time) represent subsets of the overall tech-
nology in which a technical alternate to membranes has
been discovered. Growing fields indicate where mem-
brane technology is likely to be of value in the future.
Likewise, the change in number of companies entering
and leaving specific technology domains provides insight
into potential competitors and partners.
What the SME can learn from heat and bubble di-
agrams is whether other people think the technology
has commercial value and if the SME is betting correct-
ly with its R&D and IP investments. This is validation
of a good idea, but on the flip side there is a caution
that in attractive areas there will also be determined
competitors.
The third step is to focus on and understand the
best performance/cost technology option. The goal of
this step is to evaluate potentially relevant technol-
ogies for their quality and ability to speed the intro-
duction of a new product or service. The key question
is: “Which technology option is the best suited for a
company to utilize?” been spun-out from original work at a university. The
follow-on R&D efforts of the small company, combined
Typically the overview set of patent documents is too
large to be mined manually. Therefore, patent meta- with university patents and know-how, make such en-
data is used to narrow the opportunities to those that tities a true nugget for an OI scouting project. Tools
are: (1) Relatively recent, with the presumption that such as top-cited-by-art, IP landscape white space, etc.
older technologies have either already been exploit- all serve to quickly identify such options if they exist.
ed or have poor performance versus cost ratios; (2) The fifth step is to estimate legal threats and op-
Aligned with the company’s core competencies; and portunities. The goal of this step is to estimate from
(3) Aligned with the company’s strategic/risk profile a business—not legal—perspective the likely degree
for incremental (“baked”), next-generation (engineer- of overlap between proposed technical solutions and
ing needed) or breakthrough (science needed) options. those already existing in the literature. The overlap
This is done by sorting patents based on a combination must be small enough to bring the risk of intellectual
of four patent related segmentation criteria: patent property infringement below an acceptable level.
ages, radicalness, generality, and citation rate. The key questions are: (1) In which countries are
In an exemplary case study, 77 patents were iden- patents being filed? (2) Will you have freedom to prac-
tified by these segmentation criteria to be the “most tice? (3) Will you have the ability to exclude others? (4)
likely scouting opportunities” within a dataset of 9,056 Are IP sharks and trolls present?
patents (see Figure 5). Important for an SME is that This “business-person perspective” can be rapidly
77 documents can be manageably reviewed by subject formed by utilizing patent and business metrics de-
matter experts to determine which have the best rela- veloped to assess at a high level the ownership, validity
tive performance vs. relative cost ratios. and enforceability of patents. If the assessment raises
The fourth step is to expand your perspective to uti- red flags a subsequent legal assessment is warranted
lize all potential options. The goal of this step is to prior to negotiations (3). This is particularly important
ensure that all sources of potentially relevant technolo- for an SME that doesn’t have the resources to engage
gy—individual, commercial and academic—have been in an IP dispute.
explored for their ability to contribute to the quality The sixth and last step is to prepare for negotiat-
and speed of introducing the new product or service. ing purchase/access to desired technology. The goal
The key question is, “What other entities have technol- of this step is to ensure that the project and manage-
ogy that might help the SME?” ment teams know how to negotiate for the desired ex-
It often occurs that a small company’s technology has ternal technology. The key question to be answered is,
September 2017 159
SMEs And OI
“Which gaps, strengths and weaknesses exist in the and scope of copyrights, and withheld, embedded/im-
IP portfolio the company will possess upon license or plied use rights. Without knowing the SME’s IP strat-
acquisition?” egy a fair win-win negotiation for the OI technology is
The SME must obtain the technology at a fair price unlikely.
along with a commitment to transfer the know-how. To Since IP strategies vary depending upon the indus-
ensure that the negotiations are conducted in a man- try sector in which the SME participates, it is impor-
ner that yields the expected results, the negotiating tant that the SME’s IP strategy be based on the R&D /
team uses individual patent-based metrics that enable IP Game Type as shown in Figure 6.4
it to negotiate point by point. Particularly important during negotiations are the de-
This statistical process involves more than 40 patent tailed metrics that inform the SME on how much value
metrics covering the probable strength and validity of the to-be-acquired OI patents are really worth to them.
the patent portfolio, the strength and breadth of the An example of such metrics is shown in Figure 7.
technology and uses covered, and finally, the geo- For negotiations a short strategy document can be
graphic coverage of the portfolio. Spider diagrams are summarized as a four page word document. The sec-
often used to understand the statistical significance of tions include: (1) business strengths, weaknesses,
any one metric when preparing for negotiations.3 threats & opportunities, (2) business vision, mission
statement, values, (3) business objectives, (4) key IP
IV. Negotiating for Technology and IP Solutions strategies, (5) IP strengths, weaknesses, threats & op-
When preparing for negotiations it is imperative to portunities, and (6) strategic IP action programs.
remember that all OI projects must have an IP Strate- V. Summary
gy. Such an IP Strategy describes how the project will
In summary Lessons learned from SME OI Imple-
be managed to gain an advantaged position derived
menters are:
from patents, trade secrets, trademarks, copyrights
and know-how versus key competitors. Such a strate- • Leverage IP Databases To Find, Assess, And Place A
gy should specifically describe the advantaged position Value Upon, OI Opportunities
that can be gained via the number and scope of claims – Ensure projects are in the Sweet Spots of Mother
coverage, geographic coverage, filing velocity, size of Nature and Father Time before proceeding with an
IP portfolio, number and scope of trademarks, number OI project.

Figure 6. Each IP Game Type Has a Slightly Different Patent Portfolio Sweet Spot
Technology Creation Dynamism
High (Science) Average (Engineering) Low (Application & Design)
Biotech, Fuel Cells, Pharmaceutical Drugs, Medical Electric Power, Gas, Petrochemicals, Mining,
High Nanotechnologies Equipment, Aerospace Regulated Telecom
(Government
Rules and Largest portfolio size with Key Grandfather patent with
A small number of next- generation patents
Regulations) multi-generation patent multi-generation patent
proactively pruned
fences fences

Drug & Biotech Research and Chemical Products &


Mass Software, Computers,
Discovery Tools, Specialty Polymers, industrial Gas Automobile, Snowmobile,
Internet and Telecom
Cosmetic Research Tools, Products, Packaging Farm Equipment, Mass
Services, Networking
Engineering Test Materials, Building Materials, Consumer Product
Market Control

Average Equipment, Semiconductors


Equipment Pharmaceutical Carriers
(Industry
Standards)
One of the largest
Average size portfolio Average size portfolio
portfolios with a Average size portfolio with
with limited patent fences, with no patent fences,
grandfather patent and some patent fences
proactively pruned proactively pruned
patent fences

Specialty Food, Ingredients,


MIS, Specialized Newspapers,
Specialty Consumer Specialty Chemicals,
Telecom Systems, Clothing,
Products, Toys Electronic Equipment,
Enterprise Solutions Food
Low (Customer Industrial Controls
Expectations)
Average size portfolio with Average size portfolio
Dominating portfolio size One of the largest portfolios
no patent fences, with no patent fences,
and focused patent fences with few patent fences
proactively pruned proactively pruned

160 les Nouvelles


SMEs And OI

Figure 7. Example of Patent Metrics for Mass Software, Computers, etc.

IP Environment Battles for Architectures

Patent Density Jungle


Innovation & Patent Growth Rate High
Landscape
Desired IP

Typical Number of IP Holders Many


Competitor’s Citation Position Present but no Predators

Non-Competitor’s Citations Many with trolls and predators but no sharks

IP Aggregators Presence Trolls Present

Size of Portfolio Within 20% of Average; Participating Portfolio for standards control

New Patent Velocity Faster than Average First non- self Cite Time
Portfolio Attributes
Desired Patent Owner

Self Citation Position Patent Fences

Portfolio Management Posture Building

Claim Quality High


Behavior

Claim Scope for Technology and Uses Broad


Geographic Coverage Broad
IP Holders’ Posture versus Infringers Aggressive
IP Holders’ Posture When Challenged Proactively Defend Challenge

– Find and qualify the best potential partners and Notes and References
sources of external technology with the aid of patent i. IRI Community Forums, Industrial Research Insti-
databases.
tute, (April 28, 2017) web forum.
– Value OI assets and negotiate agreements appro-
priately. ii. Paul Germeraad and Wim Vanhaverbeke, “How to
Find, Assess and Value Open Innovation Opportu-
• Use IP based Business Analysis tools to support
nities by Leveraging IP Databases,” les Nouvelles,
high-quality, fast and sticky decisions.
Vol LI No. 3, (September 2016) p 154 and at http://
• Use commercial resources for term sheets and www.intellectualassetsinc.com/openinnovation.
royalty rates.
iii. Arvin Patel and Paul Germeraad, “How to Value
• Fight for Win/Win Negotiations.
IP Portfolios for Acquisition,” Intellectual Assets
– Win/Lose Is Really Lose/Lose. Management Magazine, Issue 63 (2014). This ar-
• Use Licensing databases to arrive at fair rates. ticle first appeared in IAM issue 63/57, published
– Avoid Asymmetrical Deals. by Globe Media Group­—IP Division. View the is-
• Don’t Kill A Good Project By Insisting On A Perfect sue in full at www.IAM-media.com.
Deal. iv. Paul Germeraad, “All In The Game: R&D Games
– Keep A Business Head That Values Speed and Pro- Theory Can Be a Valuable Tool in Working Out
ductivity. How IP Issues Have an Impact On OI,” Intellectual
– Utilize Different Deal Structures and Terms as IP Assets Management Magazine, Issue 39, (2010).
Licensing Enables Many Good Business Options. This article first appeared in IAM issue 39/63,
• SME’s have the advantage over large companies here. published by Globe Media Group—IP Division;
• Metrics Count. View the issue in full at www.IAM-media.com.
– Use Simple Metrics that include IP and Know-how.
• Recognize Success Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
– Extrinsic Measures Are More Powerful Than Fi- https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009020
nancial. ■

September 2017 161


SMEs And Patent Litigation

SMEs And Patent Litigation:


A European Perspective
By Emmanuel Gougé and Valicha Torrecilla

S
mall and medium-sized enterprises (“SMEs”) are Studies and reports from various OECD countries re-
defined in the European Union (“EU”) Commis- veal, however, that SMEs face a number of difficulties
sion Recommendation of May 6, 20031 as “enter- in using the intellectual property system at large.5 This
prises which employ fewer than 250 persons and which
2
may be explained by their limited knowledge of the ins
have an annual turnover not exceeding EUR 50 million, and outs of the intellectual property system (they fre-
and/or an annual balance sheet total not exceeding EUR quently lack in-house counsels and employees who are
43 million.” Globally, according to a report from the familiar with intellectual property issues) and the lack
World Intellectual Property Organisation, SMEs ac- of clarity about its relevance to their business strategy
count for 95 percent of companies and 60 to 70 per- and competitiveness. Another critical issue for SMEs
cent of employment in the OECD countries.3 with regard to the protection of their intellectual prop-
SMEs are important players in innovation (notably in erty is their lack of capital. For all these reasons, pro-
the field of emerging technologies) and are therefore tecting intellectual property rights appears expensive
more and more the subject of policy support in many and time-consuming to SMEs.
countries. This support come from public authorities, Even when SMEs decide to invest in intellectual
such as intellectual property offices who allow SMEs to property rights, they may not be, because of limited
protect their inventions by obtaining and maintaining budget and human resources (e.g. 9 out of 10 Europe-
their patents at lower costs,4 but also from other enti- an SMEs are micros—less than 10 employees6), in a
ties such as universities who support SMEs upstream. strong position to defend them properly when need-
In the UK for instance, Oxford University created the ed. The acquisition and maintenance of an intellectual
“SME Smart Intellectual Property Scheme” to help property right is, however, meaningless if that right
SMEs at the stage of developing innovative technol- cannot be enforced in the marketplace. If SMEs do
ogy by giving them access to its intellectual property not use their patents to threat and actually sue in-
under licence. Oxford University is known for having fringers, the latter will take advantage of this absence
a large portfolio of inventions. With access to them, of reaction and unduly benefit from their innovations
SMEs have an opportunity to develop new and im- and inventions. It could in the end impede, or even
proved products and thus gain a decisive competitive annul, any return on investment.
advantage. Governments also intend to help SMEs by Consequently, the current fragmented European pat-
creating investment funds dedicated to the licensing ent litigation landscape is not always suited for SMEs
of patents, human and financial resources which are who are cost-conscious enterprises (A.). The upcoming
mobilized for innovation. Unified Patent Court (“UPC”) may bring responses to
some of the issues to which SMEs are confronted when
it comes to litigate for or against a European patent (B.).
In any case, patent infringements may also be settled
1. EU Commission Recommendation of May 6, 2003 out of courts, as long as both parties agree. Arbitration
concerning the definition of micro, small and medium-sized and mediation are alternative ways of resolving a dis-
enterprises, 361/EC, Art. 2. (2003).
pute that may be more appropriate for SMEs (C.).
2. The term “enterprise” shall be understood as “any entity
engaged in an economic activity, irrespective of its legal A. The Current European Patent Litigation
form. This includes, in particular, self-employed persons and Landscape
family businesses engaged in a craft or other activities, and The current European patent litigation landscape is
partnerships or associations regularly engaged in an economic a fragmented one. An infringement claim or a revoca-
activity” (EU Commission Recommendation of May 6, 2003
concerning the definition of micro, small and medium-sized
enterprises, 361/EC, Art. 1. (2003).
3. “Intellectual Property Rights and Innovation in SMEs,” 5. “The Intersection of Intellectual Property Rights and
WIPO Report, (2005). Innovation Policy Making—A Literature Review,” WIPO Report,
4. For instance, the French Intellectual Property Office (INPI) (July 2015).
offers a reduction of 50 percent on the procedural fees and on 6. “European Commission,” 2015/2016 Annual Report on
the maintenance fees. European SMEs.

162 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patent Litigation
tion action has indeed to be filed before every national asymmetries existing between SMEs and larger en-
patent court of the European member state where the tities about the intellectual property process (larger
patent is infringed, or—in the case of a revocation ac- entities are well informed and may better anticipate
tion—where the patent is an obstacle to the SME’s intellectual property related issues), and finally the
business. fact that some SMEs attach less importance to their
This European patent litigation structure reflects the patents and inventions.
functioning of the European patents system. Once a The conclusion that can be drawn is that a good in-
European patent has been granted by the EPO, it is tellectual property litigation system (which would not
broken in as many national patents as there are con- be seen as an obstacle
tracting states of the European Patent Convention by SMEs) should resolve
(“EPC”)7 designated in the application. Every post- cases fast and at low cost, ■ Emmanuel Gougé,
grant enforcement and litigation procedures are there- which is no surprise. Partner,
fore national procedures and, obviously, the litigation One of the risks of a
practice differs widely across contracting States. Pinsent Masons LLP,
too expensive litigation
This leads to a diversity of decisions, which may cre- system is notably the Paris, France
ate some legal uncertainty. For instance, a patent may possible development of E-mail: emmanuel.gouge@
be revoked in the UK whereas held valid in Germany. “patent assertion entities” pinsentmasons.com
This also implies a multiplication of procedures, and (“PAE”), or “patent trolls,”
consequently, a multiplication of costs. considered as “firms that ■ Valicha Torrecilla,
From the SME’s perspective, intellectual property primarily acquire patents Associate,
enforcement’s costs work against the enforcement of from third parties [they
often buy cheap patents Pinsent Masons LLP,
patents, even though, according to a report from the
UK Intellectual Property Office (“UKIPO”), the vast from bankrupt companies] Paris, France
majority of European SMEs (around 75 percent) have and seek to generate rev- E-mail: valicha.torrecilla@
experienced some sort of intellectual property abuse, enue by asserting them pinsentmasons.com
including infringement.8 against accused infringers.
Although available specific data on patent litigation […] Patents are a PAE’s
remains limited, the above-mentioned UKIPO report principal asset; a PAE does not manufacture, distribute,
provides some interesting information. It states that or sell products.”9
the number of patent cases depends on the costs of This phenomenon initially started in the U.S. and
litigation related to the size of the market. (UK has has now become an emerging issue in Europe as well.
high litigation costs and a low level of litigation cases Among European countries, it should be noted that
compared, for instance, to France, the Netherlands or most PAE typically commence patent infringement
Germany, where litigation costs are lower.) Further- lawsuits in Germany10 (where they benefit from bifur-
more, it shows that litigation rates vary significantly by cation).11 Furthermore, it appears that PAEs favourite
sector and firm size. SMEs, which tend to have small- “victims” are SMEs which,12 most of the time, may not
er patent portfolios, are more vulnerable to litigation be in a position to bear the costs associated to patent
and tend to be the ones who are sued (by larger firms) litigation.
than the ones to sue. Possible reasons of such a finding This makes patent trolls a real threat to innovative
could be the lower bargaining power of SMEs (larger SMEs, which are more likely to settle and enter into
entities seem usually less adverse to entering litigation a settlement agreement in order to avoid costly and
and have stronger financial resources), the knowledge time-consuming litigation.

7. There are 38 EPC contracting states: Albania, Austria, 9. “Patent Assertion Entity Activity,” Federal Trade
Belgium, Republic of Bulgaria, Switzerland, Cyprus, Czech Commission Study, (October 2016).
Republic, Germany, Denmark, Republic of Estonia, Spain, 10. “Digital Innovation Downturn as Patent Trolls Invade
Finland, France, United Kingdom, Hellenic Republic (Greece), Europe,” IP2I Press Release, (April 4, 2017).
Hungary, Croatia, Ireland, Iceland, Italy, Liechtenstein,
11. The German bifurcation system means that the
Lithuania, Luxembourg, Latvia, Monaco, Former Yugoslav
infringement issue and the validity are each dealt with in two
Republic of Macedonia, Malta, Netherlands, Norway, Poland,
distinct court procedures, so that a decision on infringement
Portugal, Republic of Romania, Serbia, Sweden, Slovenia,
may be obtained before a decision on the validity of the patent.
Slovakia, San Marino, and Turkey.
12. “SME Patenting—An Empirical Analysis in Nine
8. “The Impact of the Patent System on SMEs,” UKIPO
Countries,” Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation
Report, commissioned by the Strategic Advisory Board for
Research ISI, (October 2013).
Intellectual Property, (September 2010).

September 2017 163


SMEs And Patent Litigation
Among possible responses to tackle the above- responsibility of monitoring the use of their invention
mentioned problem, the following ones have been in the marketplace, of identifying any infringers and
considered: improving transparency regarding patent sometimes even of deciding whether, how and when
ownership (PAEs usually use complicated corporate to take action against them, to such entities.
structures to hide their true identity), improving the B. The New EU Patent Litigation Landscape
quality of issued patents (litigated patents are general- The aim of the upcoming UPC,15 established by the
ly low quality because patents that are vague, unclear UPC Agreement (“UPCA”) of February 19, 2013,16 is
and have an overly broad scope are more likely to be to harmonise the European patent litigation system.
allegedly infringed), and providing information to con- The UPC will have exclusive jurisdiction concerning
sumers and retailers regarding the risks and benefits of infringement and validity issues relating to European
litigating or settling a patent suit.13 patents (unless they have been opted-out from the
As of today, there has been no official study lead by UPC jurisdiction by their owners) and European pat-
national European governments, as regards the impact ents with unitary effects (so-called “unitary patents,”)
of PAEs, and in particular as regards their negative im- which will offer protection in all member States having
pact on SMEs and innovation. The European Commis- entered the new UPC system.17
sion has, however, recently published a report according The UPC presents a number of potential advantag-
to which the quality of the patent asserted is “the most es for SMEs: it will not be necessary anymore to file
decisive factor” in the impact of patent assertion.14 a claim in every European member State where the
A number of national initiatives from European gov- patent is infringed, or where the SME needs it to be
ernments show how their interest is in relation to sup- revoked. Furthermore, the procedure will be unique
porting SMEs when it comes to litigation. and decisions of the UPC will have effect on every con-
In some EU member States, specialised courts have tracting member State.
been created, such as the Intellectual Property Enter- Another important practical aspect relates to the
prise Court (“IPEC”) in the UK. The IPEC, established timing of proceedings: the preamble of the draft UPC
in October 2013, hears less complex cases than the rules of procedure18 provides that the final hearing
traditional UK High Court (Patent Court) and sets mon- on the issues of infringement and validity at first in-
etary caps on claims. The IPEC is a fast and cost-effec- stance should take place within approximately one
tive intellectual property litigation forum, and should year (“complex actions may require more time and pro-
therefore become attractive to SMEs. When litigating, cedural steps and simple actions less time and fewer
to generate any revenue, a PAE must either settle procedural steps.”)19
with the defendant or ultimately prevail in litigation Finally, the UPC court fees are intended to be re-
and obtain relief from the court. Thanks to courts like duced for SMEs. Rule 370.8 of the UPC rules of pro-
the IPEC, SMEs could be less reluctant to go to court cedure provides that small enterprises and micro-en-
when being attacked by a patent troll, notably in cases terprises are required to pay only 60% of the court
where the validity of the patent at stake seems ques- fees. Notwithstanding the above-mentioned, the UPC
tionable (which is often the case). may, of its own motion, deny this reduction of fees
Another public investment which has proved to be if it appears that it is manifestly disproportionate and
supporting SMEs is represented by public investment unreasonable having regard to the financial capacities
funds, such as “France Brevets” in France. It has already of the party.20
been observed that SMEs have limited knowledge in One of the main disadvantages of the UPC, which
the patent systems and have low financial capacities. is a direct counterpart of its advantages, is that once
On the contrary, funds like France Brevets may have a patent is litigated before the UPC, it risks a central-
the sufficient financial resource to sue potential in-
fringers (at the time of its creation in 2011, France
Brevets was awarded 100 million euros by the French
15. The UPC should enter into force by end of 2017 or
State), and benefits of a team composed of profession- beginning of 2018.
als with a longstanding experience in monetizing intel-
16. The UPCA has been signed by all the European member
lectual property. Thus, some SMEs prefer to shift the states except Spain, Poland and Croatia.
17. Regulation (UE) No. 1257/2012 implementing enhanced
cooperation in the area of the creation of unitary patent
13. “Patent Assertion Entity Activity, Government Interest protection.
in and Response to PAE Activity,” Federal Trade Commission
Study, (October 2016). 18. Latest available version of the Rules of Procedures: 18th
draft, of October 19, 2015, as updated on March 15, 2017.
14. “Patent Assertion Entities in Europe—Their impact on
Innovation and Knowledge Transfer in ICT Markets,” European 19. Preamble of the UPC rules of procedure, Paragraph 7.
Commission Report, (October 2016). 20. UPC Rules of Procedure, Rule 370.8 (d)(i).

164 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patent Litigation
ised revocation. The patent holder could therefore at In his response,23 Andrus Ansip agreed on the fact that
once lose its protection in all the contracting member the phenomenon of patent trolls is increasing in Europe
States. As a result, some companies will consider opt- and that “it should be fully monitored.” He, however,
ing-out of these patents in order to avoid the UPC’s disagreed on the fact that new actions are needed as
jurisdiction. The opt-out procedure is set out in article the existing system and the upcoming new UPC system
83 of the UPCA and supplemented by a number of pro- already provide safeguards. According to him:
visions in Rule 5 of the UPC rules of procedure, ena- • The EPO opposition procedure is sufficient to re-
bling the owners of a European patent (granted or still voke unjustified patents;
pending) to remove it from the exclusive jurisdiction of • A strong power of discretion is given to UPC judges
the UPC, that would otherwise apply to it. (This exclu- in the UPCA, which means that they will be able
sion from the UPC’s jurisdiction will only be possible to weight up the interests of the parties before
during the transitional period of seven years as of the granting injunction (no automatic injunction shall
entry into force of the UPC.)21 Once a patent has been be granted); and
opted-out, it will last for the whole life of the patent,
unless the opt-out is withdrawn. It should be noted • The Court of Justice of the European Union
that once an opt-out has been withdrawn, a further (CJEU)’s caselaw already prevents patentees, in-
opt-out is impossible. cluding standard essential patent holders, from ab-
using injunctions.24
Moreover, the UPC is a self-financially sustained
court, which means that the plaintiffs will have to pay C. Alternative Dispute Resolution
court fees for each action they want to lodge before Mediation or arbitration is sometimes the best way
the UPC. An infringement action will cost a fixed fee to resolve intellectual property related disputes. Al-
of 11.000 euros and a revocation action may cost up ternative disputes resolutions enables the parties to
to 20.000 euros. Most importantly however, and what retain control of the dispute resolution process which,
should be kept in mind of the SMEs, is the fact that in many instances, may even help preserving business
a part of variable costs could be added and calculated relationship between parties. Arbitration definitively
according to the value of the case (close to the German offers a procedural flexibility that is likely to be una-
legal concept of “Streitwert,”) on top of which come vailable in judicial courts.
the other litigation costs, such as counsels fees. One other key advantage of arbitration is the confid-
Another potential disadvantage of the UPC, point- entiality of the information disclosed during the pro-
ed out by industry players in innovative technologies, cedure and of the arbitration awards.
is the fact that it could be (mis)used by patent trolls. Furthermore, the possibility to enforce arbitration
Recently, a new industry body called “IP2Innovate,” awards in multiple jurisdictions, as a result of the 1958
which is a coalition of small and larger innovative New York Convention, is also very appealing to com-
companies, also including larger companies such as panies. Pursuant to article III of the New York Conven-
Daimler, Intel, Google and Spotify, has been created to tion, “Each Contracting State shall recognize arbitral
bring together policy makers and the legal profession awards as binding and enforce them in accordance with
to fight against abusive patent lawsuits and its effect the rules of procedure of the territory where the award
on innovation in order to work towards a strong and is relied upon […].”
balanced patent legal system. On February 21, 2017, Arbitration or mediation may therefore be of particu-
said coalition sent a letter to Andrus Ansip, Vice Pres- lar interest to SMEs which intend to maintain the viab-
ident for the European Digital Single Market, raising ility of their intellectual property rights at reasonable
his attention on the negative consequences that the costs and in a time-effective manner.
UPC could bring to the European patent litigation sys-
tem if the threat of PAEs is not properly recognized. In In the current landscape of international disputes re-
their letter, they first recognize the above-mentioned lated to intellectual property, patent owners may refer
advantages of the UPC over today’s system, but they to the WIPO Abitration and Mediation Centre, based
also warn about the fact that “its EU wide enforcement in Geneva and established in 1994.25
opportunities, including EU wide injunctions covering
a market larger than the U.S., will offer PAEs a fertile
ground.”22
23. http://ip2innovate.eu/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/IP2I_
VPAA-reply_170329.pdf. (March 29, 2017).
21. This period of seven years could be extended for another 24. See notably, CJEU, Huawei v. ZTE, CJEU, C-170/13 (July
seven-year period. 16, 2015).
22. http://www.ip2innovate.eu/wp-content/uploads/2017/ 25. Since 2010, the WIPO Arbitration and Mediation Centre
04/IP2I_Letter-VP-ANSIP_210217_FINAL.pdf. has a further office at Maxwell Chambers in Singapore.

September 2017 165


SMEs And Patent Litigation
In relation to future proceedings in Europe, patent
cases may also be referred to the Mediation and Ar-
bitration Centre set forth under the UPCA,26 located
in Ljubljana and Lisbon, bearing in mind that a patent
may not be revoked or limited there.
Conclusion
Compared to larger entities, SMEs are not yet well
equipped to properly deal with patent litigation. They
often lack intellectual property knowledge and finan-
cial capacities. On the contrary, large entities fre-
quently have significant financial and human capacities
to invest in their research and development, to file
patents and monetize their patent portfolio, as well as
to face any patent dispute that may arise from their
patents portfolio or from their activities.
Because of their low financial capacities and their
dependence on a few patents, SMEs are often reluc-
tant to use the current (and possibly upcoming as well)
patent litigation system (the costs of a patent litigation
could slow down the SME’s activity, or even some-
times put it out of business) and seem therefore to be
easier targets for PAEs.
As a result, governments and public authorities,
aware of the fact that the majority of innovative com-
panies remain SMEs, have initiated various solutions to
support SMEs when it comes to litigation for instance,
specific time and cost-effective courts. In Europe, the
upcoming Unified Patent Court will have to show that
it is fit for purpose for SMEs. ■

Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):


https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009023

26. Article 35 of the UPCA, likely to enter in force early


2018.

166 les Nouvelles


Creating SEPs

Creating SEPs­—A Risky Business For SMEs


By Menno Treffers, Matteo Sabattini and Alessandra Mosca

S
tandard Essential Patents (SEPs) can be huge- A Long Bet
ly valuable. In particular, when the standard is Contributing to standards ■ Menno Treffers,
used in mass-market consumer products, pat- development is not only a
ents that are necessarily used create significant value Treffers Alliance
drain on engineering resourc-
for their owners. For companies large and small, the es, it also takes years, some- Management,
challenges are, first of all, to get their ideas used in times more than 10 years, Managing Director,
the standards and then, if the standard is successful, before the company benefits Eindhoven, The Netherlands
to extract value (e.g. in the form of royalties) from from its contribution with the
their essential patents. E-mail: menno.treffers@
significant risk that the stand- treffersam.com
These are tough challenges, even for large compa- ard is not adopted and all in-
nies. For small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), vestments lost. ■ Matteo Sabattini,
an attempt to benefit from participating in standards SMEs will only be able to
development can threaten the survival of the company Ericsson,
afford such a long term bet Director IPR Policy,
if not managed carefully.
when their cost of capital is
SMEs Creating Essential Patents low, and their investors are Washington D.C., USA
Standards development is a slow process and, even extraordinarily patient. These E-mail: matteo.sabattini@
when the standard is ready, it usually takes years be- conditions are not optimal ericsson.com
fore a standard is used in mass-market products. For for venture capital funded
example, work on the Wi-Fi standard (IEEE 802.11) start-ups. SMEs with an es- ■ Alessandra Mosca,
started in 1991, the first specification was released in tablished and profitable busi- Sisvel Group,
1997,1 and only around 2003/2004 the installed base ness stand a better chance of R&D Engineer,
reached 100 million units.2 That slow adoption curve is gaining benefits from creat- Turin, Italy
typical for standards that specify an interface between ing SEPs.
products that are subject to strong network effects.3 E-mail: alessandra.mosca@
The Complexity of SDOs sisveltech.com
The time scale for development standards CD-R,4
GSM,5 Wi-Fi,6 Bluetooth,7 and Qi8 are similar. It took Negotiating technology
these standards between five and nine years to reach contributions in a standards
100 million units sales. development organization (SDO) is a specialized skill.

1. http://www.ieee802.org/11/Reports/802.11_ Sales Of Products That Use The Standard In Million Units


Timelines.htm. (Log Scale) Years After Finalizing The First Specification
2. http://www.scribd.com/doc/173132403/13-
10-03-Innovatio-v-Mult-Def-WiFi-Patents-FRAND- 10000
Determination#page=78.
3. Carl Shapiro and Hal R. Varian, “Information
Rules,” Harvard Business School Press, ISBN
1000
0-87584- 863-X (1999).
4. Source for CD-R disc market: TSR – http://
www.t-s-r.co.jp/e/.
5. Source for GSM: http://www.gsma.com/ 100
aboutus/history.
6. Source for Wi-Fi: ABI Research, http://
www.scribd.com/doc/173132403/13-10-03- 10
Innovatio-v-Mult-Def-WiFi-Patents-FR AND-
Determination#page=78.
7. Source for Bluetooth: https://www.bluetooth.
com/about-us/our-history. 1
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
8. Source for Qi Wireless Power Standard:
https://technology.ihs.com/584705/wireless- CD-R disc (1988) GSM (1989) Wi-Fi (1997) Bluetooth (1999) Qi (2010)
power-market-tracker.
September 2017 167
Creating SEPs
There are the difficulties of negotiating with foreign the standard. When the standard is ready, adoption is
cultures, but dealing with the complexity of internal usually slow to begin with. In that phase, SMEs are
procedures of an SDO can be just as daunting. The particularly well positioned to serve niche applications
procedures and terminology of an SDO is established for users with special needs who are willing to pay a
when its first specification is developed and, by the premium for products that support the standard.
time the group works its 2nd or 3rd generation specifi- Despite the challenges that SMEs face to actively
cation, the way of working is often understood only by participate and contribute technologies to major in-
people who have participated for many years. ternational standards, there are several examples of
An example of cultural complexity is the use of Rob- smaller companies or even research centers that have
ert’s Rules of Order9 to conduct meetings. It may come been very successful in navigating the standardization
naturally for someone with a U.S. college education activities, and have monetized their SEPS effectively.
“to move a motion,” or “second a motion,” but for Eu- Examples in the ICT (Information and Communica-
ropean or Asian participant adhering to Robert’s Rules tions Technology) industry are TeamCast and Dektec.
of Order makes it difficult to influence meetings, let TeamCast is a medium-size company offering technol-
only chair such a meeting. ogy solutions for digital television and radio broad-
An SME with the ambition to contribute technology casting. Since its foundation in 2003, TeamCast has
in a long established SDO should consider hiring an been contributing to the definition and validation of
expert with a multi-year history of contributing and a many standards for the worldwide broadcast ecosys-
personal network in that SDO. tem: DVB, WorldDAB, CMMB, ATSC among others,
also leading some technical working groups. Founded
Some SDOs have governance rules that make it eas-
in 2000, Dektec is a small company serving the profes-
ier for large companies to influence standards devel-
sional digital television market with a complete range
opment. If, for example, voting rights are restricted of professional equipment. DekTec is an active mem-
to a membership class with a high membership fee, ber of different standards committees such as DVB,
smaller companies will usually opt for a lower cost HDMI, IABM, PCI-SIG, SMPTE, USB Forum and VSF.
and less influential membership class. Another, more
subtle, governance rule that creates an advantage for SMEs Extracting Value from SEPs
large companies is to assign voting rights to individual The standard is successful, used in a hundred mil-
participants, because that allows large companies to lion products, and an SME believes it owns patents
“buy” voting rights simply by sending more people to that are necessarily infringed by all these products.
meetings. An SME will find it easier to have its propos- How can this SME benefit from owning these patents?
als accepted by an SDO when decisions are influenced SMEs have the same options as large companies. The
more by technical merit of proposals and less by the obvious methods are: (i) license and collect royalties;
amount of money companies are willing to spend on (ii) sell the patents; (iii) use patents to gain freedom to
voting rights. operate; or (iv) participate in a patent pool.
Some SMEs Are Successful in Standards Develop- SMEs are at a disadvantage when trying to operate
ment their own SEP licensing program because it is not suf-
ficient to own a couple of essential patents. A success-
Despite the challenges, some SMEs participate suc-
ful licensing programs needs multiple patents that are
cessfully in standards development. In our experience,
suitable for litigation. That means they need to survive
the successful SMEs usually operate a profitable busi-
validity challenges and it must be easy to determine
ness in the same technology with products that do not infringement by products that use the standard. In
suffer from network effects—typically low volume, practice, only a small percentage of essential patents
high margin, professional applications. The profitable are suitable for litigation. An SME will, therefore, only
business gives them the expertise and the long-term be able to license their own portfolio if that portfolio
viability to contribute technology to an SDO. is large or if the portfolio contains some exceptionally
Other successful SMEs started with the rights on a strong patents. And even then, the manpower need-
portfolio with university patent that cover solutions for ed to operate an SEP licensing program and the cost
fundamental problems in the standard. That portfolio and risks of litigation make this option unattractive for
then gives these SMEs the possibility to obtain license most SMEs. Moreover, the current licensing environ-
income earlier and makes them an attractive partner ment, which in some jurisdictions has favoured im-
for joint product development. plementers over technology providers and condoned
More often, SMEs benefit from participating in practices like efficient infringement,10 requires costly
standards development not by contributing technolo- litigation sometimes to even start licensing discussions
gy, but by being first to market with products that use
10. http://www.iam-media.com/magazine/issue/79/Features/
Efficient-infringement-and-the-undervaluation-of-standard-
9. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Robert’s_Rules_of_Order. essential-patents.
168 les Nouvelles
Creating SEPs
with large players. On one hand, SMEs rarely have Group and the ISO/IEC Moving Picture Experts Group
enough resources and investors willing to embark in (MPEG). Many companies, research centres and uni-
costly litigation. On the other hand, companies unwill- versities contributed to its development: Columbia
ing to acquire license exploit the limited resources that University, ETRI, France Telecom, Fujitsu, LG Elec-
SMEs can invest in litigation to drain them in court tronics, Matsushita, Mitsubishi, Microsoft, Motorola,
while continuing to infringe on their IP. Nokia, Philips, Robert Bosch GmbH, Samsung, Sharp,
Participating in a patent pool, selling the portfolio, or Sony, Toshiba, JVC, Apple, Dolby, FastVDO, Fraun-
selling sub-licensing rights for a limited field of use are, hofer-Gesellschaft, IBM, LSI Logic, Microsoft, Motoro-
generally, better options for SMEs. However, let us an- la, Polycom, Real Networks, etc.
alyse a few exemplary SMEs who have taken different FastVDO owns several Standard Essential Patents
approaches in order to monetise their IP assets. and successfully joined in the H264 patent pool of
Sell the Patents or Sell The Right To License/Enforce Via Licensing.15
Inside Secure,11 a French company that worked on Conclusion
the development and the standard definition of Near- The challenges for SMEs and large companies are
Field Communication (NFC) technology, has generat- not fundamentally different. It is the level of commer-
ed a sizeable portfolio of SEPs covering fundamental cial risk that makes failure, or even delay in adoption of
aspects of NFC. Although the company was relatively the standard, potentially lethal for smaller companies.
successful to license its technology to some OEMs, a And even when the standard is successful, generation
large percentage of the market remained unlicensed, value from an SEP portfolio is challenging, in particular
despite the licensing offers and negotiations that for SMEs.
were initiated. Inside Secure then decided to assign Fortunately, alternative approaches to licensing do
the rights to its portfolio to France Brevets,12 a French exist. This paper addresses some of these options that
patent investment fund that was created to leverage could help de-risk investments in standards develop-
French technologies and whose mission it is to mone- ment and patent monetization by SMEs.
tize IP assets developed or owned by French entities. Ultimately, participation by SMEs to the standard-
France Brevets invested several millions of Euros—a ization process should be encouraged, as it provides
sum that a company the size of Inside Secure would specific advantages to the SMEs themselves but it also
have never been able to cover—in the promotion of benefits the society as a whole. The larger the partici-
an NFC licensing program, and initiated litigation with pation of stakeholders to the standardization activities,
several Original Equipment Manufacturers (OEMs.) the more efficient and advanced the standards so de-
These efforts resulted in license agreements with sev- veloped will be.
eral large OEMs, most notably Samsung,13 that were SMEs can make a business success from partici-
using Inside Secure’s NFC technology. pation in standards development when (a) they un-
Incidentally, the example of Inside Secure highlights derstand that adoption will be slow and may never
the importance of Patent Assertion Entities (PAEs) as a happen, and (b) their business case for participation
fundamental element in the innovation ecosystem, and is primarily based on selling products that implement
represents a necessary market intermediary to serve the the standard and license income from SEPs is consid-
needs of several stakeholders that, like Inside Secure, ered an optional extra.
would otherwise have no access to the licensing market. We contend that SDOs should not discourage
Participate in a Patent Pool smaller entities to participate by making voting
FastVDO14 is a small company based in Melbourne. rights expensive, by increasing the cost for, mone-
Founded in 1998, FastVDO has developed technologies tization and enforcement of SEPs. More specifical-
on media communications and actively contributed to ly, SDOs’ patent policies should not interfere with
the development of well-known video coding standards commercial and licensing discussions between pat-
such as ITU/H.264 and ISO/IEC MPEG-4, ITU/H.265 ent owners and implementers, and should not place
and ISO/MPEG HEVC. unnecessary burdens on patent owners favouring a
The H.264/AVC standard was the result of a joint few, large implementers. ■
project between the ITU-T’s Video Coding Experts
Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009034
11. https://www.insidesecure.com.
12. http://www.francebrevets.com.
13. https://www.insidesecure.com/Company/Press-releases/ 15. “Understanding MPEG-4, Diepold K., Moeritz S.,”
France-Brevets-licenses-NFC-Patents-to-Samsung. Focal Press (2005). https://books.google.it/books?id=Vz3IQ
14. http://www.fastvdo.com. WZz7msC.

September 2017 169


Internet Of Things

SMEs And Standard Essential Patents:


Licensing Efficiently In The Internet Of Things
By Harris Tsilikas and Dr. Claudia Tapia1

I. Introduction This has only been possible thanks to the commit-

M
odern knowledge-based economies increas- ment of contributors to make their technology essen-
ingly rely on standards upon which innova- tial to the standard accessible on Fair, Reasonable and
tive products are built. Standards allow busi- Non-Discriminatory (FRAND) terms and conditions.
nesses to benefit from economies of scale, to specialise Its significant benefits notwithstanding, collaborative
in what they do best and invest in product differenti- standardisation is a costly and risky affair. Meaning-
ation. Standards reduce barriers to trade, create open ful involvement in SDOs and their working groups re-
markets and a level playing field, thus spurring compe- quires substantial investment in R&D and in human
tition and innovation. Consumers also reap substantial capital, including highly specialised and experienced
benefits from standardisation, in terms of lower prices, standardisation experts. Such challenges to effective
wider and interoperable product variety and more in- participation are especially pronounced for small and
novation. Standards can be arrived at either through medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).4 SMEs form the
unmediated market competition processes as de fac- backbone of European economies. The 23 million
to standards, or through industry coordination within European SMEs account for 98 percent of businesses
standards-development organisations (SDOs.) and provide for around 80 percent of private-sector
jobs in Europe.5 But SMEs’ involvement in standard-
In a consensus-driven process SDOs select the best isation fails to reflect their paramount importance for
technologies amongst technical contributions result- jobs and growth; SMEs lag behind bigger companies in
ing from substantial R&D investment, with a view to standardisation.6 A major reason for SMEs’ secondary
solving complex technical problems raised in standards role in collaborative standardisation is technological
development.2 Although open and accessible to all in- complexity and the scale of investment needed to de-
terested parties to implement, standards often com- velop a competitive technological platform.
prise proprietary technologies contributed by techno-
logy sponsors. In particular, innovative ICT standards Yet at the same time standardisation offers an open
involve hundreds or even thousands of patents reading ecosystem within which SMEs can successfully contrib-
on standards specifications, without access to which ute their innovative technologies.7 This is largely due to
implementation is technically impossible.
Standard-essential patents (SEPs) enable innovators 4. The term SMEs refers to businesses employing less than
and contributors to benefit from positive externalities 250 employees. SMEs are further distinguished between
from standardisation and earn a fair return on their micro enterprises, employing fewer than 10 employees, small
investment in R&D. Standardisation has facilitated the enterprises employing between 10 and 49 employees and medium-
emergence and growth of a vibrant and open innov- sized enterprises employing between 50 and 250 employees.
ation marketplace, bringing together contributors of “Thinking Big for SMEs,” European Commission, Luxembourg:
cutting-edge technologies and suppliers of innovative Publications Office of the European Union (2011) 1. http://www.
google.de/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=2&
consumer products and services.3 cad=rja&uact=8&ved=0ahUKEwjDtfSxr5LUAhXGEVAKH
ZKFDNwQFggqMAE&url=http%3A%2F%2Fec.europa.eu
%2FDocsRoom%2Fdocuments%2F874%2Fattachments%
1. The views expressed herein belong to Dr. Claudia Tapia, 2 F 1 % 2 F t r a n s l a t i o n s % 2 Fe n % 2 Fr e n d i t i o n s % 2 F p d f & u s g
LL.M. alone and do not necessarily represent Ericsson’s views. =AFQjCNGrPSSkUhODkhke4hdLRTIo5pWpfA.
2. Claudia Tapia, “Securing a Competitive Future in Europe, 5. “Thinking Big for SMEs,” European Commission.
The Patent Lawyer,” explaining that in only one Working Group See also Franc Le Gall and Martin Prager, “Participation of SMEs
of the several ones established to develop the LTE Standard in Standardization,” (ETSI White Paper no. 6, (2011) http://
23,235 technical contributions were submitted, from which www.etsi.org/images/files/ETSIWhitePapers/WP_No_6_SME_
less than 16% were selected to become part of the standard. FINAL.pdf.
(January/February 2016). 6. Henk de Vries, Knut Blind, Axel Mangelsdorf, Hugo
3. Haris Tsilikas, “Collaborative Standardization and Verheul and Jappe van der Zwan, “SMEs Access to European
Disruptive Innovation: The Case of Wireless Telecommunication Standardization: Enabling Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises
Standards,” Max Planck Institute for Innovation and Competition to Achieve Greater Benefit from Involvement in Standardization,”
Research Paper No. 16-06 (May 17, 2016). Summary available (2009) https://www.erim.eur.nl/fileadmin/default/content/erim/
at http://www.4ipcouncil.com/download_file/view_inline/163 content_area/news/2009/smeaccessreport%202009.pdf.

170 les Nouvelles


Internet Of Things
SDOs’ high due process standards that many propriet- ive growth and the Digital Single Market Strategy.10
ary ecosystems fail to observe. Nonetheless, once their EU standardisation policy is closely intertwined with
technology is selected to become part of a standard, the establishment and operation of the three official
SMEs depend on effective intellectual property protec- European standardisation organisations (ESOs), ETSI,
tion in order to earn a return on their R&D investment. CEN and CENELEC.
SMEs have hitherto enjoyed the potential of the patent The ESOs develop mandated European Standards,
system for incentivising innovation and commercialisa- but they also engage in cutting-edge market-driven
tion of knowledge only to a limited extent.8 standardisation, in particular in ICT sectors. ESOs are
SMEs can enhance their competitiveness and repu- expected to observe strict
tation not only by contributing but also by implement- standards of openness
ing formal standards in their products. However, SMEs to all interested parties, ■ Harris Tsilikas, LL.M.,
which are purely implementers are said to often lack transparency and consen- Junior Research Associate,
the skills necessary to identify the key players in the sus in decision-making
field, and the reasonable compensation for the techno- and voluntary application Max Planck Institute for Inno-
logy they are using, and do not know how to react to li- of standards, in accord- vation and Competition,
censors that fail to offer FRAND terms. In the context ance with standardisation Munich, Germany
of the Internet of Things, in particular, where billions best practices elaborated E-mail: haris.tsilikas@ip.mpg.de
of devices are interconnected, it is crucial for SMEs to in the WTO Agreement
establish a good IP strategy. on Technical Barriers to ■ Dr. Claudia Tapia, LL.M.,
The present article will attempt briefly to outline the Trade.11 Standardisation is
also particularly relevant Director IPR Policy,
challenges SMEs face in licensing within the field of
ICT standardisation and provide some practical solu- from an EU competition Ericsson,
tions that might contribute to overcoming them. In policy perspective. The Munich, Germany
part II we discuss the EU policy framework for stand- EU Commission in its E-mail: claudia.tapia@
ardisation and SMEs; in part III the scenario of SMEs Horizontal Guidelines has
set out a comprehensive ericsson.com
as technology contributors and licensors, and our
recommendations; in part IV the issues for SMEs as framework for assessing
implementers of standards and licensees, and possible the impact of standardisation agreements on compe-
solutions; in part V the IoT new licensing model and in tition and has provided a safe harbour from liability
part VI the conclusions of the present article. under Article 101 TFEU for agreements with the ob-
II. EU Policy for Standardisation and SMEs ject or effect of restricting competition;12 SDOs that
observe the aforementioned principles of transparen-
Standards and collaborative standardisation are a cy, openness, due process and voluntary accessibility,
valuable instrument of international market integra- as well as the principle that essential IPRs (Intellectual
tion and of lowering non-tariff barriers to international Property Rights) are to be made accessible on fair, rea-
trade.9 Hence they are also central to the integration sonable and non-discriminatory (FRAND) terms, are
of the internal market of the EU and they have been immune from competition law liability under Article
at the centre of a wide array of EU policies, such as 101 TFEU.13
the Europe 2020 Strategy for sustainable and inclus-
EU policymakers pay close attention to the issue of
SME participation in collaborative standardisation.14
Regulation 1025/2012 “on European standardisation”
7. Kirti Gupta, “The Role of SMEs and Startups in the
Standards Development Process,” showing a probability of
approval of 33.37 percent for SMEs/Start-ups contributions 10. Regulation on European Standardisation, recital 5. See also
versus a 29.06 percent probability if the submission is made by Communication from the European Commission, A Strategic
non-SMEs/non-Startups. (forthcoming, 2017). Vision for European Standards: Moving Forward to Enhance and
8. According to an SME scoreboard, 35 percent of SMEs Accelerate the Sustainable Growth of the European Economy
do not take any measures to protect their innovations, citing by 2020, COM (2011) 311 final: 3. Communication from the
various reasons, such as the cost and complexity of the patent European Commission, A Digital Single Market Strategy for
system. See European Union Intellectual Property Office Europe, COM (2015) 192 final, 15-16.
(EUIPO), IP SME Scoreboard (2016). https://euipo.europa.eu/ 11. “WTO Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade,” Annex 3.
tunnel-web/secure/webdav/guest/document_library/observatory/
documents/sme_scoreboard_study_2016/sme_scoreboard_ 12. Communication from the European Commission,
study_2016_en.pdf “Guidelines on the Applicability of Article 101 TFEU to Horizontal
Cooperation Agreements,” C3/2, 2001, paras 257-335.
9. “Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade,” Annex 3,
World Trade Organization. See also “Regulation of the European 13. Ibid. para 280.
Parliament and of the Council,” (October 25, 2012) on European 14. European Parliament Resolution (October 21, 2010) on
Standardisation OJ L 316/12, recital 6. (2012). “The Future of European Standardisation,” [2010/2051(INI)].

September 2017 171


Internet Of Things
calls for ESOs to adopt concrete and specific measures costs for SMEs and they enable interoperability and
to enhance the accessibility of standards and of the compatibility between products and components.22
standards development process to SMEs.15 Moreover, Yet significant challenges to a meaningful SME parti-
SMEs can benefit from a congenial regulatory frame- cipation remain. An important weakness of EU support
work, such as the Small Business Act,16 and a variety measures to SMEs in standardisation is their general-
of public funding, including subsidies by the Horizon ist nature: they mostly attend to the collective needs
2020 project, the European Structural and Investment of SMEs, they enhance for instance their collective
Funds17 and reduced SDO membership fees. SDOs representation in SDOs, and they are not tailored to
have also undertaken steps to lower participation individual SME needs. More importantly, a generalist
costs, in particular through the use of online working outlook fails to grasp the heterogeneity of incentives
group meetings and online communication that reduce and interests of SMEs that wish to engage in stand-
travelling costs for SME representatives. ardisation. In particular, collective support measures
SMEs engaged in standardisation also benefit from lose sight of the significant distinction between SMEs
collective representation by industry bodies and or- that are active in the development of standards by con-
ganisations, such as the Small Business Standards, an tributing their technologies and SMEs that are mainly
organisation established in 2013 to represent SMEs in interested in implementing the standards in their
European standardisation bodies.18 Additionally, the EU, products and services.
the European Patent Office (EPO) and national patent III. SMEs as Technology Contributors—
offices within the EU have taken measures to reduce Licensors
the cost and enhance the accessibility of the patent A. Costs
system to SMEs. Support to SMEs may include lower
patent filing and renewal fees, IP training for SME ex- SMEs contributing to standardisation must bear the
ecutives, IP helplines and the creation of the IPR Help- substantial costs of patent development, licensing and
desk which offers assistance and expertise to SMEs.19 enforcement. Since standardisation involves interna-
tional or even global markets, patent protection and
It is true that such policy measures have had some enforcement must also be on an international scale,
effect in boosting SME participation in standardisa- further raising costs: a PCT application for instance
tion. In ETSI, for instance, SMEs now account for 28 costs between EUR 10,000 and 40,000.23 An OECD
percent of its membership, and of participating SMEs survey shows that 24 percent of firms in Europe de-
65 percent are active—both as contributors and imple- clare having patents that they would be willing to li-
menters—in standardisation committees. Moreover, cense out but could not. Some factors mentioned were
SMEs have managed to hold 10 percent of ETSI work- the complexity and cost of drafting and negotiating
ing group elected positions, such as chair, vice-chair contracts, the low royalty rates offered and the diffi-
and rapporteur.20 Moreover, SMEs may have strong culty of identifying partners.24
private incentives to participate in standardisation.
Engagement in standardisation and implementation of Moreover, monitoring infringement, negotiating li-
standards present significant business opportunities censing deals and drafting contracts might require an
for SMEs: they can benefit from access to cutting-edge investment of EUR 2 million to 3 million.25 Added to
technologies, from interaction with some of the most that, licensing negotiations might break down, bringing
important technical experts in their field, from the
opening-up of new markets and economies of scale,
from increasing visibility and opportunities for benefi- 21. “Small Business Standards, Best Practices on Small
cial partnerships, and from signalling their innovation and Medium-sized Enterprises in Standardisation,” (2015).
capacity.21 Standards also lower regulatory compliance http://www.sbs-sme.eu/sites/default/files/publications/Best%20
practices%20towards%20SMEs_with%20footer.pdf.
22. Ibid.
23. ECORYS and Eindhoven University of Technology,
15. Article 6, Regulation on European Standardisation. “Patents and Standards: A Modern Framework for IPR-
16. Communication from the European Commission, “A based Standardization,” Study carried out for the European
Small Business Act for Europe,) COM, 394 final (2008). Commission, Ref. Ares 917720 - 25/03/2014, 66, (2014).
http://ec.europa.eu/DocsRoom/documents/4843/attachments/1/
17. A Digital Single Market, 18. translations/en/renditions/native.
18. “Small Business Standards, Who are We?,” http://www. 24. Pluvia Zuniga and Dominique Guellec, “Who Licenses
sbs-sme.eu/who-are-we. out Patents and Why?: Lessons from a Business Survey,” OECD
19. Philippe Deléarde and Séverine Ouvry, “Exploitation of IP Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, 2009/05,
for Industrial Innovation,” Report to the Commission Ref. Ares (2009). http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/224447241101.
4677128, 13 (2015). 25. ECORYS and Eindhoven University of Technology,
20. Le Gall and Prager, “Participation of SMEs,” 5. “Patents and Standards,” 112.

172 les Nouvelles


Internet Of Things
high litigation costs, possibly in many jurisdictions, into cumulative payments of well over $100 million.29
the picture.26 Despite widespread perceptions that own- Fourthly, an SME undertaking a FRAND commit-
ership of SEPs automatically confers the opportunity to ment should offer access on FRAND terms. For that
reap supra-competitive rents by holding up implement- it should establish a mechanism to determine FRAND
ers,27 when transaction costs are taken into account it accurately. Otherwise an SME patent holder risks not
becomes apparent that patent holders with insufficient obtaining an injunction against an infringer from a
resources often struggle to license their technologies court. To determine the value that its technology has
and earn a return on their investment.28 for the end product, an SME first needs to determine
B. Recommendations a reasonable cumulative royalty rate. This can be done
To begin with, it is crucial that SMEs achieve adequate by looking at former declarations made by main con-
IP protection for their technologies. It is important that tributors of the standardisation,30 as well as at studies
promising ideas be protected by well-drafted, strong that estimate the cumulative rates by analysing pub-
patents that can provide value in subsequent licensing lished declared rates, companies’ annual reports and
negotiations. Most SMEs lack dedicated employees other reliable data (such as information disclosed in
that could manage in-house patent development and court cases and rates published by patent pools.)31
portfolio building. When contacting external patent However, SMEs should view with scepticism studies
lawyers, SMEs should identify those experienced in based on purely theoretical models which are often far
the technology field they wish to protect. Otherwise from marketplace realities.32 As a next step the patent
the SME may not be able to show infringement of its holder needs to determine which is the proportion of
patent by some products that, if well drafted, its patent that cumulative rate that it is entitled to. Some ques-
could have covered. tions when determining the value of the contribution
Secondly, SMEs could contact SME associations are the following: Does my contribution belong to the
specialised in standardisation and their SDO repres- core of the standard, or is it an option that need not be
entatives to inform themselves of the benefits that implemented? Who else has contributed to the stand-
they can enjoy by participating in a standard develop- ard, and how much? How much is their understanding
ment process. of their proportional share and which is the method
applied for such determinations?
Thirdly, SMEs would also need support in the com-
mercialisation phase of their technologies. They typ-
ically lack the experience of larger corporations in
complex and resource-draining negotiations, monitor- 30. For instance, major contributors in standardization,
ing and enforcement of their IPRs. Since access to pri- Alcatel-Lucent, Ericsson, NEC, NextWave Wireless, Nokia,
Nokia Siemens Networks and Sony Ericsson supported publicly
vate-sector professional services is expensive, it would
in 2008 that a reasonable maximum aggregate royalty level for
be advisable to aim for additional financial support. For LTE essential IPR in handsets should be a single-digit percentage
instance, Fractus, a Spanish company specialised in op- of the sales price. See Wireless Industry Leaders commit to
timised antennas, raised as a start-up a total of EURO framework for LTE technology IPR licensing (April 2008). https://
20 million in venture capital investment, part of which www.ericsson.com/en/press-releases/2008/4/1209031-wireless-
it reinvested in licensing and enforcement, leading to industry-leaders-commit-to-framework-for-lte-technology-ipr-
licensing. See also Ericsson’s FRAND licensing terms for 5G/NR
in 3GPP Release 15 at https://www.etsi.org/about/how-we-work/
intellectual-property-rights-iprs/ex-ante-disclosures/list-of-ex-
26. “Making Intellectual Property Rights Work for Small and ante-disclosures qualified by deputy chief judge of IP division at
Medium-size Enterprises—Preparation and Enforcement,” IPR Shanghai High People’s Court Ding Wenlian as a possible signal
Enforcement Expert Group (2009) 25. of a reform of the mechanism for licensing SEPs. See MLEX,
27. Marc Lemley and Carl Shapiro, Patent Holdup and Ericsson’s FRAND offer on 5G network welcomed by senior
Royalty Stacking, Texas Law Review 85, 2006: 1991; Joseph Chinese antitrust judge (May 2017).
Farrell, John Hayes, Carl Shapiro and Theresa Sullivan, Standard 31. Alexander Galetovic, Stephen Haber, Lew Zaretzki, “A
Setting, Patents, and hold-up, Antitrust Law Journal 74.3, 2007, new Dataset on Mobile Phone Patent License Royalties,” IP²
603-670. Working Paper No. 16011 (2016).
28. Thus, it is not surprising that an empirical study on 32. See e.g. Mallinson criticising estimated cumulative rate
patents declared to some of the world’s most significant SDOs of 120 USD on a hypothetical 400 USD smartphone. Keith
found that for a substantial 30 percent of the sample, the patent Mallinson, “WiseHarbor, on cumulative mobile-SEP royalties,”
owners failed to pay the renewal fees and their declared patents For IP Finance, (August 2015). http://www.ip.finance/2015/08/
were left to lapse. See ECORYS and Eindhoven University of cumulative-mobile-sep-royalty-payments.html http://www.
Technology, Patents and Standards, 263. wiseharbor.com/pdfs/Mallinson%20on%20cumulative%20
29. Joff Wild, “Fractus Proves the Power of Patents to mobile%20SEP%20royalties%20for%20IP%20Finance%20
Deliver Sustained, Game-changing Success to Tech Start- 2015Aug19.pdf ; Ann Armstrong, Joseph J. Mueller, and Timothy
ups (March 2017). http://www.iam-media.com/blog/detail. D. Syrett, “The Smartphone Royalty Stack: Surveying Royalty
aspx?g=8b79a108-0a83-4610-b906-ac4f89a17811 Demands for the Components Within Modern Smartphones.”

September 2017 173


Internet Of Things
Fifthly, it would be advisable for SMEs to prepare claim their R&D and standardisation activities.39
charts to demonstrate the essentiality of the patent. In the EU a strong commitment to patent protection
C. Effective patent protection is enshrined in EU law, in Member States’ national pat-
For SMEs contributing to standards development it ent laws and it is also part of the Union’s international
is very important to know they can rely on an effective obligations under the WTO TRIPS Agreement. The
patent system that adequately protects their contribu- Enforcement Directive establishes the framework for
tions and allows them to earn a fair return on their in- IP protection in the EU, and in particular IPR holders’
vestment in R&D.33 The operation of the patent system rights to preliminary and injunctive relief.40, 41 The right
in the standards-setting context has been a subject of to injunctive relief is also established under articles 28
controversy in the past decade. Several commentators and 44 of the TRIPS Agreement to which the EU and
allege that ownership of SEPs and the threat of injunct- its members are parties. Patent protection in the EU is
ive relief against implementers of standards results in further streamlined and enhanced by the formation of
patent hold-up, raising the cost of commercialisation a single market for IPRs and in particular by the estab-
of technology and increasing prices for consumers.34 lishment of the unitary patent and the unified patent
It is not the subject of the present article to assess in court system.42 The unitary patent may substantially
detail the merits and shortcomings of the patent hold- improve the accessibility and affordability of the patent
up theory.35 However, to the extent it influences public system in the EU to SMEs;43 it is estimated that today
policy in the EU and abroad it is useful to stress the the cost of patent protection for the whole duration of
value of an effective patent system to contributors to the right in all EU Member States is EUR 200,000.44
standards and in particular to SMEs. Moreover, the unified patent court has the potential to
A weakening of patent protection and in particular a provide for more legal certainty, in allowing for a more
prohibitive rule on injunctions for SEPs does not only harmonised patent protection throughout the EU.45
diminish the return on investment on R&D for con- To the extent injunctive relief for SEPs confers mar-
tributors by unfavourably skewing bargaining power,36 ket power to patent holders, enforcement of SEPs is
it also diminishes incentives to share one’s own tech- also relevant from an EU competition law perspec-
nologies and contribute to standards in the first place. tive and Article 102 TFEU on abuse of a dominant
An effective patent system is all the more important to position.46 In its recent landmark ruling in Huawei v
SMEs contributing to standards. For SMEs and start- ZTE, the Court of Justice of the EU (CJEU) provided
ups in particular, strong IPR protection is crucial for a balanced, market-oriented framework for licensing
attracting funding by venture capitalists and banks.37 negotiations for SEPs.47 Specifically, the CJEU set out
Often IPRs are the most valuable business asset SMEs
hold.38 Moreover, patent monetisation is a valuable
source of income for SMEs, with which they can fund 40. Ibid.
41. Directive 2004/48/EC of the European Parliament and of
33. “Making enforcement rules fit for innovative SMEs.” IP the Council of 29 April 2004 on the enforcement of intellectual
Europe, http://www.iptalks.eu. property rights [2004] OJ L 157/45, Article 11.
34. Le Gall and Prager, “Participation of SMEs,” 8. 42. See all relevant documents of the Unified Patent
Court and the Unitary Patent at About the Unified Patent
35. For a critical view on the patent hold-up theory see Court, https://www.unified-patent-court.org/about. See also
among many: Gregory Sidak, “Holdup, Royalty Stacking, and Communication from the European Commission, “A Single
the Presumption of Injunctive Relief for Patent Infringement: A Market for Intellectual Property Rights Boosting Creativity and
Reply to Lemley and Shapiro, Minn. L. Rev. 92 (2007): 714. See Innovation to Provide Economic Growth, High Quality Jobs and
also Damien Geradin, and Miguel Rato, “Can Standard-setting First Class Products and Services in Europe,” COM (2011) 287
Lead to Exploitative Abuse? A Dissonant View on Patent Hold- final (2011): 7.
up, Royalty Stacking and the Meaning of FRAND,” European
Competition Journal 3.1 (2007): 101-161; Einer Elhauge, “Do 43. Small Business Standards, “SBS Answers.”
Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking Lead to Systematically 44. See also Communication from the European Commission,
Excessive Royalties?,” Journal of Competition Law and “A Single Market for IPRs.”
Economics 4.3, 2008, 535-570. 45. Ibid, 8.
36. Zuniga and Guellec, “Who Licenses Out,” 8. 46. It should be noted that ownership of SEPs does not
37. Sabattini and Mosca, “Standard Development,” 50. Zuniga automatically infer a dominant position. See Case C170/13,
and Guellec, “Who Licenses Out,” 22. ECORYS and Eindhoven Huawei v. ZTE [2014], Opinion of the AG Wathelet, paras 57-
University of Technology, “Patents and Standards, “65. 58; for a detailed discussion of the issue of dominance and
38. European Commission, “Thinking Big for SMEs,” 16. SEPs ownership see Unwired Planet Ltd v. Huawei Technologies
[2017] EWHC 711 (Pat), paras 630-670.
39. Small Business Standards, “SBS Answers to Public
Consultation on Patents and Standards,” (2015). http://www. 47. Case C-170/13 Huawei v. ZTE [2015] . For a summary of
sbs-sme.eu/publication/sbs-answers-public-consultation-patents- the court cases post Huawei interpreting the CJEU ruling see
and-standards http://www.4ipcouncil.com/search/case-law.

174 les Nouvelles


Internet Of Things
the conditions under which pursuit of injunctive relief It should be noted that the issue of IPR licensing
from an SEP holder against a potential licensee willing might not be as troubling as it appears at first sight.53
to conclude a licence on FRAND terms might amount IPRs enforcement entails substantial transaction costs.
to an abuse of dominant position. Under exceptional Monitoring costs for infringement by SMEs are par-
circumstances, the exercise of an SEP holder’s other- ticularly high. Moreover, even large firms’ licensing
wise legitimate rights to injunctive relief might breach department capacities are constrained and they typi-
Article 102 TFEU if the patent holder has failed to cally target large competitors first.54 Many SMEs stay
alert the alleged infringer of his infringement of spe- below the SEP holders’ radar and make unlicensed use
cific SEPs and to submit a detailed, written licence of essential IPRs.55 For many SEP holders it might also
offer on FRAND terms.48 make more business sense to allow SMEs and start-ups
On the other side, the prospective licensee must es- some breathing space in the early stages of their devel-
tablish his willingness by replying to the offer in due opment and allow them first to succeed and establish a
time, without delaying tactics, and if the initial offer is more durable market presence and later reap licensing
considered non-FRAND to submit a FRAND counterof- rewards. In the end these high investments in stand-
fer, whilst providing appropriate security.49 The CJEU ardisation belong to a long-term project where SEP
Huawei ruling provides clarity to parties to SEP licens- holders benefit from their future licensees’ success in
ing negotiations, and establishes a fair and predictable implementing the standardised technology.
framework within which the patent holder is immune B. Recommendations
from competition law liability and the implementer is Firstly, SMEs could benefit from the expert advice
safe from injunctions. The Huawei ruling also provides provided for by their industry associations, but they
strong incentives for both parties to engage in good- would benefit even more from access to a pool of ex-
faith licensing negotiations.50 perts. Professionals with experience in SEP licensing
IV. SMEs as implementers of standards agreements might prove particularly helpful for both
A. Costs determining essentiality in an SEP portfolio and for as-
The majority of SMEs with an active interest in stand- sessing a technology’s actual merit and contribution to
ardisation are users of standards: small firms that build a standard, and hence the compliance of a licensing
innovative products on top of standards. However, they offer with FRAND.
too face significant constraints in the effective imple- Secondly, SMEs should reject any FRAND determ-
mentation of standards. A first hurdle is substantial ination based exclusively on SDO databases of patents
information costs to trace and implement a relevant declared as potentially essential. Since SDOs publish
standard.51 Many SMEs find it particularly challenging voluntary declarations of essential IPRs (without any
to navigate through the abundance of standards pro- assessment of the actual essentiality of declared IPRs)56
duced by SDOs. this may create confusion to SMEs. SMEs need to be
To the extent standards cover complex technologi- aware that a database is not a list of all essential pat-
cal platforms including a multitude of essential IPRs, ents for a standard but rather a commitment that any
the transaction costs of licensing might be substan- of those patents, if they become essential, will be ac-
tial. Moreover, SMEs might find it difficult to assess cessible on FRAND terms.57
whether a licensing offer presented to them by an SEP Thirdly, SME implementers should also have an un-
holder is compliant with FRAND. SEP licensing negoti- derstanding of what is an appropriate reasonable rate
ations are typically confidential and third parties have to which an SEP holder is entitled. For this purpose,
no access to agreed terms by competitors in similar the same recommendations as mentioned above for
situations.52 An SME with no experience in licensing the SME contributors apply.
negotiations might have a hard time in evaluating an Fourthly, SME implementers should identify the
offer and coming back with a FRAND counteroffer. most important patent holders in the relevant stand-
ardisation field and, in parallel, negotiate a FRAND li-

48. Case C-170/13 Huawei v. ZTE [2015], paras 61 and 63. 53. An empirical survey of SME users of standards reports
49. For example by providing bank guarantee or depositing that the costs of IPRs licensing is a deterring factor for only
an appropriate amount in escrow. Ibid., paras 65-66. the 25 percent of correspondents. See Le Gall and Prager,
“Participation of SMEs,” 9.
50. Haris Tsilikas, “Huawei v. ZTE in Context - EU
Competition Policy and Collaborative Standardisation in 54. ECORYS and Eindhoven University of Technology,
Wireless Telecommunications,” IIC 48(2): 151-178 (2017). “Patents and Standards,” 66-67.
51. De Vries et al, SMEs Access, 12. 55. Ibid.
52. AVANCI, “Accelerating IoT Connectivity,” White Paper 56. Ibid, 114.
(2017) 5, http://avanci.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/01/2016- 57. Usually FRAND commitments are made provided there is
Avanci-WP-Final-_-Jan-24.pdf reciprocity from the side of the licensee.

September 2017 175


Internet Of Things
cense. This would allow them to recognise reasonable The goal is to provide access to the vast majority of the
negotiation practices and FRAND terms. To identify standard-essential cellular patents and to enable compa-
the key players in a standard, SMEs can consult reports nies to innovate faster. Licensors and licensees benefit
from agencies such as Signals Research Group or ABI from reduced licensing costs allowing discounts on roy-
Research, or alternatively extract the information from alty fees. Some of the considerations in determining the
the 3GPP website, showing which companies have value of a licence for a particular application include the
made the most approved contributions to a standard. need for wide-area connectivity and mobility, the fre-
Although not offering one-to-one accuracy in identifi- quency of use, and the required bandwidth.
cation of SEPs, approved contributions provide an in- Since the platform has attracted strong portfolios60
formative picture of the most important contributors SME implementers could also use the AVANCI rate as
and thus the strongest patent portfolios. a benchmark in their FRAND determination when ap-
Fifthly, SMEs should request claim charts to have a proached by unreasonable licensors.61 Moreover, mak-
better understanding of the essentiality of the techno- ing a counteroffer using as AVANCI rates as a benchmark
logy which is to be negotiated. would protect SMEs from the threat of an injunction.
Sixthly, the SME implementer should understand its For SME licensors using AVANCI could also be a great
rights and obligations established in the CJEU ruling alternative to bilateral and costly licensing negotiations.
Huawei v ZTE mentioned above. VI. Conclusion
V. SMEs in the Internet of Things Standardisation would benefit greatly from increased
Although a Digital Single Market consolidating al- and more meaningful SME participation and contribu-
most 30 national markets into one is expected to tion. SMEs can offer disruptive and targeted innova-
contribute EURO 415 billion per year to our economy tions that bring substantial value to consumers. SMEs
and create hundreds of thousands of new jobs in Eu- on their behalf would also benefit from increased
rope, concerns have been raised on whether existing involvement in standards development. Standards
licensing models in standardisation are still efficient or provide the opportunity to SMEs to compete with lar-
even relevant in the Internet of Things (IoT).58 Wire- ger firms in an open innovation market emphasising the
less connectivity will enable billions of products, smart merits and qualities of proposed technologies. SMEs
meters, connected cars, remote surgery equipment, also internalise significant benefits from implement-
etc. to build the IoT. These products incorporating ICT ing standards in their products, including economies
standards will have one thing in common: their pri- of scale, better access to large international markets,
mary function will not be connectivity. Nevertheless, reduction in compliance costs and increased consumer
they will all benefit from wireless connectivity devel- demand for standard compliant products.
oped in standards. In order to obtain the fruits of its participation
As mentioned above, in determining FRAND the in standardisation (as contributors and/or as im-
SEP holder must ensure that FRAND terms reflect plementers), SMEs need to develop an efficient IP
the value of its standardised technology to the end strategy. Recognising the multiple challenges that
product. However, this could be highly challenging SMEs face on both sides of the negotiating table, in
when product use and capability differ. For instance, the present article we have provided some guidance
fully autonomous vehicles require consistent and for SMEs to engage in licensing negotiation of standard
high-bandwidth coverage, where data transfers occur essential patents (as licensor and/or licensees) in an
in milliseconds (i.e. low latency). The quality of service efficient manner.
in terms of speed and volume needs to be very high. For the Internet of Things where billions of devices
However, other vertical uses and devices like smart will be interconnected, new licensing models, such as
meters are far less demanding. AVANCI, will be critical. Only then will we achieve a suc-
Taking into account the different uses of connectivity cessful networked society, where everyone, everything
in IoT there was a need to initiate a new licensing plat- and everywhere will be connected in real time. ■
form as the first marketplace for licensing patented cel- Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
lular technology to the Internet of Things. An independ- https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009039
ent platform, AVANCI, provides a forum for SEP holders
to share their innovations, and for IoT companies one-
60. Currently the companies in the AVANCI marketplace are
stop-shop access to those connectivity-enabling technol-
Sharp, Qualcomm, Ericsson, InterDigital, Panoptis, KPN, Sony,
ogies for a flat per-unit rate consistent with FRAND.59 Unwired Planet, and ZTE.
61. The cumulative rate can only be used as a benchmark
58. On the role of standardisation for the success of the since royalty rates resulting from bilateral negotiations of
Digital Single Market, see Claudia Tapia, “Securing a Competitive AVANCI patents will likely be higher. The benchmark applies
Future in Europe,” The Patent Lawyer, (January/February 2016). then to products where the value of the standardised technology
59. See more about AVANCI at http://avanci.com. is similar.

176 les Nouvelles


SMEs In France

SMEs In France
By Emmanuelle Fortune

T
o encourage the protection of IP (industrial prop- of an INPI tutor, an IP specialist from a major French
erty) rights in small and medium enterprises company and experts including patent attorneys, law-
(SMEs), an array of public policies has been imple- yers and corporate IP spe-
mented in France during the last few years. The French cialists. Coaching compris- ■ Emmanuelle Fortune PhD,
Patent and Trademark Office (INPI)1 has developed es collective workshops, a
Institut National de la Pro-
its role of supporting sustained growth among SMEs personalised diagnosis and
through IP. These public policies consist of subsidised four individual coaching priété Industrielle (INPI) and
coaching, support, financial aids and tax incentives. sessions designed to help Observatoire de la Propriété
The first type of public policy to encourage the pro- the SME set up an indus- Intellectuelle (OPI),
tection of industrial property rights by SMEs comprises trial property strategy. To Lille, France
coaching sessions proposed by the French Patent and quote Jacques Wolff, head
of SEWOZY, “After the E-mail: efortune@inpi.fr
Trademark Office. The first of these, called the “IP
Booster,” is a free pre-diagnosis of the SME’s industrial Master Class, we set up
property2 which provides a list of recommendations an in-house patent monitoring system and we currently
in response to the company’s specific needs based on manage all French trademarks.”
the risks, costs and stakeholders associated with the After the coaching described above, a second type
enterprise’s industrial property. The “IP Booster” de- of public policy supports SMEs in their industrial
termines possible courses of action and identifies the property actions. If the “IP Master Class” detects an
company’s in-house skills for the implementation of international development need, assistance abroad
an industrial property policy. Nicolas MILLE, head of may be proposed by Business France and funded by
GASTON MILLE, explains that he “used the IP Booster the INPI.6 Since April 2017, SMEs receiving export
report as a guideline for implementing recommenda- assistance from Business France have been given eas-
tions on how to combat patent infringement, on know- ier access to the dedicated business advisory servic-
how and on ownership of inventions.”3 es set up in forty-two regional customs departments
After the pre-diagnosis has been carried out, SMEs across France. The customs department thus offers
looking to implement an industrial property policy can SMEs assisted by Business France personalised help
ask to enroll in the “IP Pass” coaching sessions. They and advice free of charge and simplified and appropri-
are given access of up to three sessions proposed by the ate customs procedures.7 To provide better support to
INPI at minimal cost thanks to 50 percent funding by SMEs looking to export, INPI experts are present in
the INPI.4 The “IP Pass” consists of a wide spectrum of 10 French embassies abroad.8
services ranging from patent monitoring and document- The third type of public policy designed to encourage
ary research, joint industrial property contracts and con- the protection of industrial property in SMEs concerns
tractual support to strategies, protection and pre-litiga- financial aid. The INPI offers subsidies to SMEs when
tion export analyses relating to patents and trademarks. filing their first patent, via Bpifrance, the public invest-
To take their industrial property strategy a step fur- ment bank,9 which can cover up to 80 percent of patent
ther, the head of an SME can ask the INPI for a third attorney fees. The grant is paid directly to the patent
type of coaching session called the “IP Master Class.”5 attorney. The INPI also offers SMEs a 50 percent re-
This consists in providing industrial property support duction in its main patent procedure and renewal fees,
for six months including six days of training, the help
6. The purpose of the Business France agency is to
promote the international development and success of French
1. The French Patent and Trademark Office, https://www.inpi. companies abroad and foreign companies in France: http://www.
fr/fr. businessfrance.fr.
2. For more information: https://www.inpi.fr/fr/booster-pi. 7. See http://www.douane.gouv.fr/articles/a13278-signature-
3. See https://www.inpi.fr/fr/valoriser-vos-actifs/le-mag/gaston- d-un-accord-inedit-avec-business-france-pour-l-accompagnement-
mille-un-chausseur-sachant-innover. des-entreprises.
4. The three sessions can cost up to 10,000 euro, half of 8. INPI experts are present at the French embassies in China,
which is funded by the INPI. See https://www.inpi.fr/fr/pass-pi. Brazil, Morocco, the United Arab Emirates, the United States,
5. See https://www.inpi.fr/fr/services-et-prestations/master- Korea, Singapore, Turkey, Russia, and India.
class-pi. 9. The public investment bank: http://www.bpifrance.fr.

September 2017 177


SMEs In France
in order to encourage innovation in SMEs.10
In addition to financial aid for initial patent
applications and follow-ups, Bpifrance’s “in-
novation loan” is an unsecured loan available
to SMEs who can provide proof of a patent
application filed, significant R&D expend-
iture, recent RDI (research, development
and innovation) aid or a research tax credit.
The aim is to finance the industrial property
protection expenditure in France and abroad
needed to launch a new product or service on
the market.11 As Christophe Camperi-Genest-
et, one of the founders of Sunwaterlife, ex-
plains, Bpifrance’s innovation loan “meant we
could develop the cases [portable, self-stand-
ing cases that convert contaminated water
into drinking water] and file our two patent
applications.”12
The fourth type of public policy relates to
industrial property taxation.13 Like any other
company, an SME that invests in R&D can
obtain a tax credit on its corporate tax. R&D
expenditure includes patent application, re-
newal and defence fees, in addition to depre-
ciation charges for patents acquired to car-
ry out research. In the case of an SME that
does not have a taxable income, the research
tax credit is refunded the year following the
actual expenditure and not after the three-
year period that applies to other companies.
Thanks to Bpifrance, SMEs that are more
than three years old and have benefited at tion of industrial property by SMEs have enabled the
least once from a research tax credit can have the tax percentage of SMEs in corporate patent applications
credit pre-financed starting in the year in which the to be maintained at the same level since 2011. The
industrial property expenditure was actually incurred. same is true with regard to extending patents to other
This measure is aimed at boosting the cash flow of territories such as those of the European Patent Office
SMEs during the year in which the expenditure is dis- and the Patent Cooperation Treaty. And, since 2011,
bursed without waiting until the research tax credit is the average number of patent applications per SME
declared and refunded the following year. has been a steady 1.4.
In France, despite the latent economic instability In 2015, SMEs, which represent the majority of
that has existed since the last financial crisis, these dif- private sector companies incorporated in France (67
ferent public policies designed to support the protec- percent), filed 2,592 patent applications published
by the INPI. The percentage of SMEs having filed
patent applications remains stable at 22 percent of
10. See https://www.inpi.fr/fr/services-et-prestations/aides- total applications made by French legal entities. In
aux-pme-et-aux-centres-de-recherche. the same year, SMEs are specialised in medical tech-
11. The unsecured loan is available to SMEs that are more nology, handling, furniture and games, and civil engi-
than three years old and are developing or marketing a new neering.14 ■
product, process or service for which they can prove that they
have filed a patent application. The loan can be anywhere
between 50,000 euro and 5,000,000 euro. See http://www. Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
bpifrance.fr/Toutes-nos-solutions/Prets/Prets-sans-garantie/Pret- https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009269
Innovation-FEI.
12. See http://www.bpifrance.fr/A-la-une/Actualites/ 14. For more information, see Emmanuelle Fortune, Mickaël
Environnement-de-l-eau-potable-partout-grace-aux-valises- Chion, “Les PME, ETI et Grandes Entreprises Déposantes
Sunwaterlife-31601. de Brevet”, ANALYSES INPI, 2016-5, (November 2016).
13. See https://www.inpi.fr/sites/default/files/fiscalite_de_la_ https://www.inpi.fr/sites/default/files/inpianalyses_pme_
propriete_industrielle.pdf. eti2015_161122_0.pdf.

178 les Nouvelles


SMEs And The Patent Challenge

SMEs And The Patent Challenge


By Tobias Wuttke

After the Pre-diagnosis Has Been Carried Out ing to protect their R&D results by patents for the first

I
n Germany, SMEs have an increasing patent aware- time ever. Eligibility under the program is, however,
ness. This is due to the fact that Germany is the also given if the last pat-
most important venue for patent litigation in the ent filing dates back more ■ Tobias Wuttke, PhD,
EU. Many landmark patent litigation cases attract the than five years. Under the
Meissner Bolte
attention of the media so that the patent world is no WIPANO program the en-
tire process of a patent Partnerschaft mbB,
longer a hidden world for most SMEs. The main driver
filing is sponsored, that Certified IP Lawyer, Partner,
for the increasing patent awareness is risk management,
whereas securing exclusivity for generated innovation is from the discussion of Munich, Germany
comes second. the idea until its moneti- E-mail: wu@mb.de
zation provided, however,
II. “WIPANO”—A New Governmental Policy that third party provid-
Since January 1, 2016 ers are retained (in particular patent attorney, attor-
The German Ministry for Economy and Technology ney-at-law). Each milestone during such process can be
paved the way for a new governmental patent policy for sponsored up to the maximum levels in Table 1.
SMEs. This policy was launched under the brand “WIPA- It is very important to note that the WIPANO pro-
NO” (=Knowledge and Technology Transfer through gram is not available with retroactive effect. Hence,
Patents and Standards) and became effective on January the request for sponsoring (and its subsequent approv-
1, 2016. The underlying rationale of WIPANO is to ena- al) must precede any patent filing. The filing of the
ble SMEs to gain a strategic understanding of the patent request for sponsoring can be made online with the
system and to increase patent awareness. average duration for the approval process being four
The WIPANO policy is directed at SMEs, i.e. any weeks.
company having an establishment or factory in Ger- III. The situation at the German Patent and
many with a maximum of 250 employees and a max- Trademark Office and the German Patent Act
imum yearly turnover of EUR 50 million or a yearly The German Patent and Trademark Office (“GPTO”)
balance sheet of no more than EUR 43 million in total. does not have any specific provisions regarding SMEs.
These ceilings apply to the figures for individual firms However, the GPTO—with its three service locations
only. A firm that is part of larger group may need to Munich, Berlin and Jena—together with the 22 na-
include staff headcount/turnover/balance sheet data tional “patent information centers” (Patentinforma-
of said group too. The definition of SME as used by tionszentren) offers support directed to the needs and
WIPANO corresponds to the official EU definition (cf. requirements of SMEs. In this respect, the cost-free
Recommendation 2003/361/EC). “first advice for inventors” (Erfindererstberatung) is
WIPANO only supports “first-timers.” This means noteworthy. This institution is organized by the Cham-
that only such SMEs are eligible for promotion intend- ber of the German Patent Attorneys (Patentanwalt-

Table 1. Patent Milestone Sponsorship Levels

Package 1 Rough review of the invention EUR 375


Package 2 Detailed review of the invention: EUR 1.200
Part A: Comprehensive review of the invention over the prior art
Part B: Cost-benefit-analysis (inter alia review of the potential for com-
mercialization)
Package 3 Strategy - advice and coordination of patent filing (first filing and one EUR 2.000
further filing)
Package 4 Patent filing (official fees + fees for patent attorneys) EUR 10.000
Package 5 Activities concerning monetization EUR 3.000

September 2017 179


SMEs and the Patent Challenge
skammer) in cooperation with the national patent in- for patents and utility models.
formation centers on a regular–at least monthly–basis. IV. How Do SMEs Use IP in Germany?
Under the framework of the first advice for inventors, The way the patent system is used by SMEs in Ger-
patent attorneys educate inventors free of charge on many is changing. In former times, SMEs used the pat-
general principles of the patent landscape. ent system mostly to ensure their freedom to operate.
The German Patent Act contains the following provi- Nowadays, SMEs are also interested in conveying a
sions which are of interest to SMEs: twofold message to the market with their patent filing:
In the first place, the principle of “procedural aid” firstly, such filing shall signal to the market that this
(sections 129 et seq. German Patent Act in connection company is able to break new ground and secondly, that
with sections 114 et seq. German Procedural Code) such new ground is exclusively protected (deterrent
is to be mentioned. If the relevant statutory require- effect). Ultimately, many SMEs are financed by inves-
ments of this principle are met, the official patent of- tors. Insofar, building investor value is a further aim of
fice fees and the fees of the patent attorney in charge the patent filing. In this respect, the above-mentioned
are paid by the state treasury. The principle of proce- German Utility Model system plays an important role.
dural aid is available for examination, opposition, lim- In light of the low filing and annuity fees it is possible
itation and revocation proceedings, as well as annuity to build up a large portfolio at a very reasonable price.
payments. An SME is eligible for procedural aid if (i) V. SMEs and Patent Enforcement
it cannot afford the costs due to its financial situation SMEs are still rarely seen in court proceedings re-
and (ii) if there is a sufficient probability for success. In lating to patent matters. This is due to the fact that
practise, however, in particular the first requirement such proceedings are still too expensive for SMEs.
proves to be a very high hurdle which is difficult to Under the German bifurcated system, proceedings for
overcome for SMEs. infringement on the one hand and invalidity on the
In addition, Section 23 German Patent Act offers a other hand are separated. This entails that for most
fee reduction for annual fees of 50 percent if the ap- patent disputes two proceedings are conducted in par-
plicant/patentee files a corresponding written “License allel, also meaning a duplication of costs. Theoretically,
of Rights-declaration” (Lizenzbereitschaftserklärung) the German Patent Act offers some relief in section
with the GPTO. This License of Rights-declaration en- 144. This rule relates to the amount of the “value in
tails that the applicant/patentee must license its pat- dispute” (Streitwert). Under German procedural law,
ent application/granted patent against payment of a the value in dispute is used to determine the statutory
reasonable royalty to anyone who is interested in using court fees and the statutory attorney fees. Pursuant
the technology for which protection is sought for. Of to section 144 German Patent Act, a party which due
course, the available discount of 50 percent comes at to its economic situation is not able to pay the court
a high price for SMEs, since they lose the exclusivity fees and its attorney fees based on the actual value in
of their innovation which is oftentimes the key driver dispute may request that the value in dispute be low-
for their commercial success. It is thus not surprising ered for this party (not for the adverse party.) Under
that SMEs do not often make use of such instrument the governing case law it is, however, very difficult to
(which in practice is mostly used by industries where obtain such reduction of the value in dispute under
the patent litigation activity is still conceived as low). section 144 German Patent Act. Consequently, this
Last, but not least, it is important to mention the rule has more textbook character and no real practical
“German Utility Model” system in the context of SMEs. scope of application.
The German utility model is available as a (cheap) al- VI. Conclusion
ternative to the patent system. A German utility model Germany supports SMEs in various aspects of their
is an unexamined exclusivity right for technical teach- journey through the patent jungle. However, what is
ings having the same protection requirements as pat- missing is a provision in the German Patent Act ad-
ents. However, it is not available for method claims dressed specifically to the situation and needs of SMEs.
and has a limited term of protection of 10 years. The Such provision should provide a fixed discount on all
official fees for filing a German utility model are very official fees and a fixed discount for patent enforce-
affordable, namely EUR 40 for traditional and EUR 30 ment (= guaranteed reduction of the value in dispute)
for e-filing. From an enforcement perspective, the Ger- with a clearly foreseeable cost risk. If such provision
man utility model is a sharp weapon affording the same were to be introduced, it would be easy to predict that
remedies to its owner as a German patent. In prac- the patent awareness of SMEs and their use of the
tice, it is oftentimes recommendable to combine both patent system would dramatically increase. ■
systems, since it is possible to protect one invention
with one patent and one (or even more) utility models.
Thus, there is no prohibition rule of double protection Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009272

180 les Nouvelles


SMEs In Italy

SMEs In Italy
By Mattia Dalla Costa*

Introduction and SMEs3 (Edition 2016)

T
he fourth Industrial Revolution, currently expe- confirms the results of the
■ Mattia dalla Costa,
rienced by global economy, displays a melting- Startup Manifesto Policy
Tracker: Italian ecosystem has CBA Studio Legale e
pot of a wide range of new technologies com-
bined with one another, impacting on every aspect of grown in terms of number of Tributario,
economy, industry and society by progressively blur- start-ups recorded (+41 per- Founding Partner,
ring the borders of the physical, digital and biological cent on the previous year),
Padova, Italy
spheres. of human resources involved
(+47.5 percent,) of average E-mail: mattia.dallacosta@
The growth of robotics, of artificial and virtual in- value of production (+33 per- cbalex.com
telligence, of connectivity among objects and of the cent) and, finally, of funding
latter with humans, are contributing to strengthening
raising (+128 percent, con-
the virtual side of economy, made of its intangible as-
sidering access to credit via the SME Guarantee Fund).
sets. Even trade is tending more and more towards a
trade of intellectual property rights rather than trade This growth is the outcome of both the inventiveness
of physical objects. and the attention to innovation that have always charac-
terized Italian entrepreneurs, as well as of the progress
In such a scenario, protection of intellectual property
made by Italian legislation over the past years: changes
is becoming increasingly important: the value of innov-
were introduced in order to boost the national system
ation embedded in any product is likely to increase as
for business start-ups and, in some cases, to promote
compared to the value of the physical object itself. In
innovative entrepreneurship as a whole.
other words, protection of intellectual property could
significantly affect economic growth and trade and Adopted measures include, for example: the imple-
shall necessarily go forward as the economy becomes menting of Ministerial decrees on tax credits for R&D
more and more virtual. investments; the ITA Service Card for innovative SMEs,
Future growth of the 4.0 economy depends on main- the multimedia, bilingual online platform #ItalyFron-
taining policies that, on one hand allow connectivity tiers (the aim of which is to promote capital investment
among millions of objects and, on the other, provide for and encourage open innovation projects involving in-
strong patent protection mechanisms, thus, encouraging novative Italian businesses); Italia Startup Visa and Ita-
large and risky investments in technology innovation. lia Startup Hub (the renewal, under the 2016 Decree
on Immigration Flows, of a preferential procedure for
Are SMEs, which represent the beating heart of the the granting of visas and the conversion of permits to
Italian economy, ready for all this? Has Italy adopted stay for self-employed for non-EU citizens wanting to
any policy aimed at boosting innovation and the relev- move to Italy or remain there to start up an innovative
ant protection for SMEs? enterprise); the launch of a new simplified online com-
After more than four years since the launch of the pany incorporation procedure that enables innovative
Startup Act1, Italian legislation confirms being among start-ups to be opened as limited liability companies,
the most internationally advanced programs for in- granting significant time and cost reductions; the ex-
novative business support strategies. If we look at the tension (until 2016) and the reinforcement of fiscal in-
Startup Manifesto Policy Tracker2 (a manifesto for centives available for investment in innovative start-ups;
entrepreneurship and innovation to power growth in finally, the extension of the free, simplified access to
the European Union), published in March 2016, Italy the Guarantee Fund to include innovative SMEs in or-
is in second place among the 28 EU Member States, der to make it easier for them to obtain credit.
in terms of the take up rate of recommendations made
by the European Commission on the innovative entre-
The Importance of Intellectual Property in
preneurship issue.
the Modern Economy
The Annual Report to Parliament on the implemen- A national policy that has a target of incentivizing
tation of legislation in support of innovative start-ups the use of Intellectual Property is a policy that will
have beneficial effects on the entire national (and in-
*The author would like to thank the contributions and support ternational) economy.
of Barbara Sartori, and Matteo Roiz. Proof of this are the results of the studies carried

September 2017 181


SMEs In Italy
out by the European Observatory on Infringements of The success of the Startup Act brought the Italian
Intellectual Property Rights and the European Patent legislator to extend with the Investment Compact5
Office (EPO) on the contribution of intellectual prop- most of the benefits provided for innovative start-ups
erty rights (IPR) on the EU economy 4. also to innovative SMEs.
The study analyzed the effects of intellectual prop- By the Investment Compact the Italian Government
erty on the EU in terms of gross domestic production, recognized that innovative start-ups and innovative
occupation, wages and trade. Here are some of the SMEs represent two sequential stages of the same
most interesting data: continuous and coherent growth path. In a context as
• 42 percent of the total economic activity in the EU the Italian one, dominated by SMEs, it is fundamental
(approximately EUR 5.7 trillion) and 38 percent of to strengthen this kind of enterprises.
occupation (approximately 82 million workplaces) The measures in question apply only to SMEs, as de-
is attributable to IPR-intensive industries; fined by the European Commission Recommendation
• IPR-intensive industries pay significantly higher 361/2003 (companies with less than 250 employees
wages than other industries, with a wage premium and with a total turnover that does not exceed €43
of 46 percent; million), which have, as well as other requirements, at
• IPR-intensive industries tend to be more resilient least two of the following requirements:
against the economic crisis; • At least 3 percent of either the company’s expenses
• IPR-intensive industries account for about 90 per- or its turnover (the largest value is considered) can
cent of EU trade with the rest of the world, genera- be attributed to R&D activities;
ting a trade surplus for the EU of EUR 96 billion; • At least one-fifth of the total workforce are PhD
• About 40 percent of large companies own IPRs. students, PhD holders or researchers; alternatively,
The data gathered by this study should raise social one-third of the total workforce must hold a Mas-
and political awareness as to the importance of stimu- ter’s degree;
lating not only large companies, SMEs and start-ups in • The enterprise is the holder, depositary or licensee of
general, but also those which use intellectual property. a registered patent (industrial property) or the owner
The Innovation Criteria of a program for original registered computers.
An interesting measure that is showing good results Unfortunately, to this day, the Investment Compact
in relation to the dissemination of IPR companies in has not produced the expected results: on one hand,
Italy is the introduction, thanks to the Startup Act, of there is a problem connected to the not well-defined
the concept of innovative start-up. concept of “innovative SMEs,” differently from what
happened with start-ups; on the other hand, there are
The Startup Act provides facilitating measures (e.g.:
structural shortcomings in the communication of gov-
incorporation and following statutory modifications by
ernment incentives: these communication issues are
means of a standard model with digital signature, cuts
particularly significant if we consider that the policy on
to red tape and fees, flexible corporate management,
innovative SMEs is a series of self-selecting, non-auto-
extension of terms for covering losses, exemption from
matic incentives.
regulations on dummy companies, exemption from the
duty to affix the compliance visa for compensation of Patent Box
VAT credit) applicable to companies which have, as Another important measure related to the IP exploit-
well as other requirements, at least one of the follow- ation is the Patent Box, the optional tax rule applicable
ing requirements: to income derived from the exploitation of intellectual
• At least 15 percent of the company’s expenses can property rights.
be attributed to R&D activities; The Patent Box rules were introduced by the 2015
• At least one-third of the total workforce are PhD Stability Act 6 and give to businesses, from 2015 on-
students, the holders of a PhD or researchers; or, al- wards, the option of tax-exempting up to 50 percent
ternatively, two-thirds of the total workforce must of the income derived from the commercial exploita-
hold a Master’s degree; tion of software protected by copyright, industrial pat-
• The enterprise is the holder, depositary or licensee ents for inventions, utility models and complementary
of a registered patent (industrial property), or the protection certificates, designs, models, company in-
owner and author of a registered software. formation and technical/industrial know-how, provid-
ed that they can be protected as secret information
The Startup Act is still having positive effects on the
according to the Italian Code of Industrial Property:
start-ups demographic trends. As a matter of fact, during
meaning patented intangibles or assets that have been
the first six months of 2016 there has been a growth rate
registered and are awaiting a patent.
of 15.5 percent in the number of registered companies.

182 les Nouvelles


SMEs In Italy
Originally, the exploitation of trademarks also al- An Italian section of the UPC would certainly bring
lowed entrepreneurs to choose the Patent Box optional a higher awareness, also of smaller enterprises, in rela-
tax rule, but a very recent Decree 7 erased that provi- tion to the importance of IP protection.
sion by excluding trademarks from the Patent Box re- Conclusion
gime. This exclusion has just been introduced in order A disruptive and unprecedented transformation is
to align the Italian Patent Box to the prescriptions of
taking place involving industry, economy and society,
the Organization for Economy Co-operation and De-
with its main driver being the relentless ascent of its
velopment (OECD).
intangible component.
Said policy has a dual purpose: on one hand, it seeks
What we have to do, as a society, is follow this trans-
to encourage Italian entrepreneurs to develop, protect
formation by changing our way of thinking and work-
and use intellectual property; on the other hand, it in-
tends to make the Italian market more attractive for na- ing, abandoning the old paradigms of the analogic era.
tional and foreign long-term investment, while protect- Policy measures as the Startup Act, the Investment
ing the Italian tax base. The incentive encourages the Compact and the Patent Box are surely important ini-
placement, and preservation in Italy, of intangibles that tial steps that are bringing certain positive effects, but
are currently held abroad by Italian or foreign compan- they are not enough and they have not yet achieved
ies and also fosters investments in R&D. the maximum results.
The Patent Box is certainly of great importance for As pointed out by the #StartupSurvey, the first
Italian economy and has relevant merits, but it can be national statistical survey of innovative start-ups,
further improved. During the convention held on the launched by the Italian National Institute of Statistics
8th of May 2017 in Milan entitled “Fiscal levers for and the Ministry of Economic Development (the data
business development: the patent box example,” or- were gathered by a mass mailing to all the innovative
ganized by Indicam, the institute for fighting against start-ups listed in the special section on December 31,
counterfeiting established by Centromarca, it was 2015), the majority of Italian start-ups and SMEs (52.3
highlighted that one aspect to improve is that of the percent) have not adopted any formal mechanism, as
Patent Box’s appeal to SMEs: there is a need for this the ownership of an industrial patent, to protect their
policy, which was thought mainly for large companies, innovation. Only 16.1 percent of the respondents
to be really effective. One solution, proposed by the owned a patent and only 11.8 percent owned a regis-
Vice-Minister of Finance and Economy Luigi Casero, tered software.
guest of the convention, is to “introduce some statis- Among the reasons that bring start-ups to not adopt
tical clusters, a kind of sector studies, an intervention protection mechanisms, the majority of the entrepre-
of analysis and evaluation of the fiscal indicators of a neurs (48.4 percent) claimed to be convinced that the
specific type of company.” innovation of their enterprise could not be taken away
The Unified Patent Court by third parties. On the other hand, a considerable
The last matter that deserves to be mentioned is number (25.5 percent) said that they were not aware
that of the Unified Patent Court: Italy has ratified the of the necessary strategies.
United Patent Court Agreement on February 10, 2017. The data gathered by the survey confirm that there
As it is known, in order to start its operations the is a communication and information issue, as noted in
Unified Patent Court needs the ratification also of the the paragraph above, to be solved.
United Kingdom. Moreover, one of UPC’s central di- An interesting initiative relating to this problem is
visions should be located in London in addition to the the new questionnaire realized by the Head Office
ones in Paris and Munich. After Brexit, this maintain- for the fight against counterfeiting of the Ministry of
ing of the London Court appears inappropriate both Economic Development. This new and free service has
under a juridical and an EU opportunistic point of view. been conceived, in particular, for start-ups and SMEs,
As provided for by the UPC Convention, a section allowing them to carry out an online self-assessment in
of the central division should be in Italy because it is relation to intellectual property.
the fourth EU member state (after France, Germany The aim of the questionnaire is to make the
and the UK) as to the number of validated European enterprises aware of their intellectual property
patents in its territory: the London Court should be range and to direct them towards the adoption of ap-
therefore relocated to Milan. propriate strategies for the valorization of their intan-
Moreover, Italy is one of the main countries in the gible assets. ■
EU applying for not only European patents but also
trademarks and designs (and so contributes substantial Available at Social Science Research Network
fees) yet it does not host any European IP institutions. (SSRN):https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009273

September 2017 183


IP Manager For SMEs?

IP Manager For SMEs? An Italian Contribution


By Ercole Bonini

A
lthough SME companies do not lack the will to ate capital entry opportunities stimulating the growth
innovate their products, they seem to have no of the company.
awareness of the importance of exploiting their Meanwhile, what are the main features of an IP
own innovations, first by setting up a patent portfo- Manager or Innovation Manager?
lio and then by the implementation of in-licensing or Usually, an SME has between 20 and 50 employees
out-licensing strategies. who are always very busy.
The result of this lack of protection is that some An IP Manager certainly cannot be a person com-
companies, without realizing it, give away their innov- pletely dedicated to this new task, both for the costs
ations to their competitors. This is particularly true in that this would imply, and because this person could
the design field. Italian design is appreciated all over not devote full-time to this activity.
the world, both in the East and West.
In my opinion, an IP Manager should be a person
Unfortunately, it often happens that after the first already working in the company with specific tasks,
supplies arrive abroad, a copy made by a local company possibly in the commercial sector or even in marketing
arrives on the market. Normally, these counterfeits are or technical departments.
offered at prices reduced by up to 30 percent or 40
percent and you can’t claim their property without an This person should be trained in everything con-
adequate protection strategy. Entrepreneurs and man- cerning Intellectual Property. From our tests, we real-
agers must be aware that it is important for them not ized that in order to understand what patents, brands
only to protect innovations, but also their exploitation, and designs are all about, a two-day course can suffice.
which inevitably goes through the creation of IP assets. These first concepts can also help the IP Manager to
understand when an appropriate protection strategy is
Creating and growing a good portfolio of patents, recommended for a new product and to talk about it
and implementing licensing, provides companies with with the company’s management and call on their ded-
the opportunity to acquire and manage the finance re- icated company expert/dedicated expert consultant to
sources necessary to grow their business. This will also handle the case. So, the safer way to face the market
allow them to gather the necessary capital to invest in for a company is to understand if and how to activate a
qualified people and adequate manufacturing facilities. protection package for a new product.
Unfortunately, most Italian SMEs know very little What personal characteristics should an IP Manager
about patents and even less about licensing. So how have?
can we activate this virtuous circle?
I think the first and most important characteristic is
I believe that the direction we have begun to take as curiosity. If an IP Manager is not curious he will never
Executive Committee of LES Italy is the right one. be able to think forward enough into the future. In oth-
We delivered very successful training courses for IP er words, one of the essential tasks of an IP Manager
Managers. The courses were held in various parts of is to constantly look for what’s new in the competition
Italy such as Milan, Turin, Florence, and Rome. and he cannot do it simply through the participation in
Before starting the course we gathered some in- the Trade Fairs. He has to constantly consult the pat-
dustry decision makers in the trade associations, ex- ents databases. Through this information he can see
plaining to them the need to give IP the proper atten- what is going to enter the market, he can look at the
tion. Let’s keep in mind that these small and medi- technical designs and then see the solutions adopted
um-sized companies export to about 30/50 countries by his competitors; he can see what can and cannot be
around the world, especially outside Europe. Then, done. Above all, an IP Manager can alert the compa-
we asked every decision maker to identify, within the ny’s management of where the competition is going,
company, the person to be trained on the various in- so to prevent technical people from designing obsolete
dustrial property assets, such as patents, trademarks and useless things or, worse, things in conflict with
and design. In this way, the company management can the rights of other companies. In this way, they will
understand that IP assets are not just costs but rep- be able to take advantage of competitors’ experience
resent an investment in the future of the company. In an research.
fact, often, IP assets go up in value over time and cre- The second characteristic required of an IP Manager

184 les Nouvelles


IP Manager For SMEs?
is to have good knowledge of the English language. The From what we have just said, another quality of an IP
patent databases are in English and consultation of da- Manager is to be authoritative and thus credible, but
tabases must be at least on a weekly basis. Patent DBs not authoritarian.
are the main and most valuable source to understand So far, we have seen the IP Manager in his out-licens-
what’s going on in the world. If an IP Manager notes ing business, which is perhaps what all companies wish.
that in a certain country there are few patents on the
product that the company wants to promote, maybe it There is still another
will be easier for him to find a licensee interested in very important aspect
that an IP Manager can ■ Ercole Bonini,
taking an exclusive license in that country.
detect: he can Identify President,
A very useful and detailed database is ESPACENET,
the database developed by the European Patent Office interesting products for Studio Bonini SRL,
(EPO). It is free of charge, and there you can find all the company that are Vicenza, Italy
the patents of the most industrialized countries, such patented by other com-
E-mail: e.bonini@ipbonini.com
as South Korea, Japan, China, etc. whose descriptions panies and may possibly
can also be read in English through the automatic be subject to licensing. For
translating machine. example, a Japanese or an American company that has
As you can see, patent databases do not show only a European patent, might wish to find a company in the
who does what. An IP Manager looking for more in- same industry with which to forge mutually beneficial
formation can find out both what can be done and what business relationships.
cannot be done, towards which markets the company An IP Manager is the most suitable person to identi-
can target its new products, and who can potentially fy innovations patented by competitors that cannot be
be its partner for selling or licensing its new products. produced or sold unless licensed, and a company that
Consulting the patent databases comprises a funda- produces and sells under license can increase its sales
mental part of an IP Manager’s role, but this cannot volumes and gain respectability on the market. Why
take more than 2-3 hours per week, the other tasks are not try it? Nobody can be so powerful as to produce
occasional. As a matter of fact, it is not easy to design and sell everywhere without the help of local compa-
a new product or to know who should be consulted to nies. Therefore, an IP Manager is a professional who
acquire a license. gradually acquires the right sensitivity to do company
Another characteristic of an IP Manager is the ability business with IP assets. He will always work closely
to create strong relationships with his colleagues and with the company’s management and the Patent At-
associates: an IP Manager is a pro-active person ready torney, and, at the same time, he can gain ever greater
to break new ground, he sees opportunities where confidence in proposing the most convenient solu-
others see troubles. He is always in touch with the tions. Basically, with an IP Manager, SMEs can only
management, but also with the marketing, the tech- “risk” to grow in size and finance. So why not try it? ■
nical office and the commercial offices and, last but not
least, with the IP consultant with whom he develops Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
the best protection and licensing strategy. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009285

September 2017 185


IP Services For SMEs In The UK

Intellectual Property Services For SMEs In The UK


By Christi Mitchell and Robert Looker

T
he UK Government recognises the importance There are 39 LEPs. They vary widely in size, capability
of innovation and IP protection to the SME busi- and level of funding and resources. Levels of support
ness community. Government has, for many equally vary considerably with each LEP and their de-
years, offered a variety of schemes that aim to support termination of the needs in their individual areas.5
and enhance the spirit of invention and its protection. Equally, universities (“encouraged” by the Dowling
These support systems do fluctuate as governments Review) seek to be more active in business engage-
and their priorities and budgets change. Although we ment and support. Often they work in partnership
find ourselves in a positive climate today, there are with the LEPs but can also have access to independ-
many navigational challenges that must be faced by the ent funding through funding streams from HEFCE6
average SME. and EU funds/projects.7,8
In the UK the Department for Business, Innovation Other provision is fragmented through some provi-
and Skills (BIS) and the Department of Energy and sion from local authorities, some remaining independ-
Climate Change (DECC) have merged to form the De- ent enterprise agencies and thereafter the advice and
partment for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy support comes from the private sector providers.
(BEIS). This department today works with 46 agencies The Enterprise Europe Network continues to oper-
and public bodies and those of relevance to innovation ate and is managed by Innovate UK—the intention is
and IP protection for SMEs includes The Intellectual to make service provision more joined up.9
Property Office (IPO) and Innovate UK.1
The provision of education, training and support on
BEIS is also responsible for the strategy develop- IP therefore mirrors the rather fragmented structure
ment, budget, funding and implementation of business and provision above. It is dependent upon the avail-
support from start-ups through to high growth com- ability of business advisors and their expertise and
panies. Given the current government’s policies, the experience in IP. More often than not businesses will
structure and level of business support has radically be signposted to the IPO website and the information
changed in the last decade. and support available through the IPO and its staff and
The Regional Development Agencies and the Busi- services or local commercial providers.
ness Link service in England have been abolished and Dependent on funding and bids, there can be pro-
disbanded in England. grammes and projects that will specifically include IP
Under the devolved governments and assemblies advice and support. These vary from one region to
in Scotland and Wales, provision has been made for the next.
the encouragement of IP learning and practice within The IPO Corporate Plan 2017-202010 has an introduc-
the SME business community. The IP Wales model of tion by Jo Johnson, Minister of State for Universities,
business support serves the needs of the regional eco- Science, Research and Innovation. The report indicates
nomy by providing Welsh SMEs with the knowledge continued support for UK business with an emphasis
and financial means to commercialise their IP assets. on education and providing support to enable business
The threefold mission of IP Wales can be viewed on the to understand, manage and protect their IP. With refer-
WIPO website.2 Scotland offers a number of IP services ence to SMEs the report says, “Even a modest increase
for SMEs; these can be viewed at Enterprise Europe
Network3 and Scottish Enterprise.4
In England, business support is principally delivered
through the Local Enterprise Partnerships (LEPs). 5. http://www.lepnetwork.net/the-network-of-leps.
6. http://www.hefce.ac.uk.
7. http://www.raeng.org.uk/policy/dowling-review/the-dowling
-review-of-business-university-research.
1. https://www.gov.uk/government/organisations#department 8. https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/local-enterprise-
-for-business-energy-and-industrial- strategy partnerships-map.
2. http://www.wipo.int/sme/en/best_practices/ip_wales.htm. 9. https://www.gov.uk/government/organisations/innovate-uk.
3. http://www.enterprise-europe-scotland.com. 10. https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/intellectual-
4. https://www.scottish-enterprise.com. property-office-corporate-plan-2017-2020.

186 les Nouvelles


IP Services For SMEs In The UK
in the registration, protection and exploitation of IP the service on April 6, 2018 (the common commence-
would contribute to UK jobs and growth.” This report ment date). The new service will give UK businesses,
identifies areas that have been addressed in 2016: especially SMEs, a simpler and more cost-effective way
• The IPO launched the updated Lambert Toolkit. to register and manage their rights across multiple ju-
This toolkit and model agreements can help users risdictions.
from research and industry to negotiate IP-creating The UK Patent Box ena-
collaborative projects.11 bles companies to apply a
• Business Outreach uses Facebook Live broadcasts. lower rate of Corporation ■ Christi Mitchell,
The first live broadcast looked at IP’s deadly sins Tax to profits earned after 1
IP Director,
and reached over 8,000 people in seven days. April 2013 from their pat-
ented inventions and equiv- Highbury Ltd.,
• IPO approved funding for 250 IP Audits to be deli-
alent forms of intellectual Hitchin, England
vered through their partners. This includes our
company—Highbury Ltd. property. The lower rate of E-mail: christi@highburyltd.com
Corporation Tax under the
• Continued targeting of businesses with IP messages Patent Box is 10 percent.12
to increase the number who better understand how ■ Ercole Bonini,
to manage IP, reaching over 200,000 in 2016. • In 2013-14, 700 com- Business Development
panies claimed relief
• Provision of education, advice and specific case sup- under the Patent Box Director,
port to nearly 5,500 UK businesses during 2016, with a total value of Highbury Ltd.,
helping them in their export activity. £342.9 million. Hitchin, England
Ensuring IP Rights are Respected and Appro- • Just under one-third of E-mail: robert.looker1@
priately Enforced: the companies (225 or googlemail.com
• Practice sets out agreed targets for reducing the 32.1 percent of total)
prominence of infringing links in search results, as were large and togeth-
well as specifying other areas such as autocomplete er they claimed £327.2 million of relief under the
and domain hopping. Patent Box (95.4 percent of the total).
• As part of the IPO Enforcement Outreach program, Research and Development (R&D) Tax Credits and
it held an IP awareness and education workshop the Patent Box relief are designed to encourage great-
with 20 representatives from the IP Crime Group. er Research and Development spending by companies,
The workshop identified the awareness and educa- greater investment in innovation and exploitation of
tion was being undertaken by members, through intellectual property (IP) in the UK.
messages, guidance and campaigns, as well as areas R&D tax credits reduce a company’s tax bill by an
where members and the IPO can collaborate/sup- amount equal to a percentage of the company’s allow-
port. able R&D expenditure. A company can only claim R&D
Under the plan, the IPO has key targets that rein- tax credits if it is liable for Corporation Tax. There are
force the commitment to innovation and increasing three schemes for claiming relief: The Small or Medi-
knowledge and maximisation of IP and its growth val- um-sized Enterprise (SME) Scheme; The Large Com-
ue. The key targets are: pany Scheme; and Research and Development Expend-
• Promoting UK growth through IP policy iture Credits. An SME can claim a higher rate of relief
• Delivering high quality rights than a large company. Also, an SME which has no tax
bill to reduce is able to claim a cash payment instead.
• Ensuring IP rights are respected and appropriately
R&D tax credits were introduced for SMEs in 2000
enforced
and extended to large companies from 2002.
• Educating and enabling businesses to understand,
R&D Tax Credits; claims may include:
manage and protect their IP
• Subcontractor costs
• The other targets are focused on developing the IPOs
people, skills and efficiency and quality of services • R&D employee salaries
The IPO will have ratified the Geneva Act of the • Testing
Hague Agreement for international registration of de- • Prototype materials
signs by March 31, 2018 and be in a position to launch • Software licenses

11. https://www.gov.uk/guidance/university-and-business- 12. https://www.gov.uk/guidance/corporation-tax-the-


collaboration-agreements-lambert-toolkit patent-box

September 2017 187


IP Services For SMEs In The UK
R&D here includes: There is a clear commitment and desire from Govern-
• Advancing the field of science and technology ment to promote, increase awareness and strengthen
protection of IP and thereby enable UK businesses to
• Developing a new product or service
maximise their intellectual capital and assets. There is
• Improving existing product or service a clear recognition of the need and value of innovation
• Improving efficiency of processes both for resilience, especially in the light of Brexit, and
By the end of 2014-15, 39,360 different companies growth. No system of education, training and support
had made claims under SME scheme since it began in is perfect, and there is undoubtedly room for develop-
2000-01. ment, but businesses can gain some initial advice and
The total amount of R&D support claimed grew to guidance and in certain areas funding and provision
£2.45bn in 2014-15—an increase of £675m (38 per- permits more specialist support for businesses. ■
cent) from the previous year. During this period the
cost of support for the SME scheme increased by Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
£325m to just over £1bn.13 https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009302

13. https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
attachment_data/file/577859/160914_R_D_publication_
commentary_v1-1.pdf

188 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patents In The U.S.

SMEs And Patents In The United States


By John Cabeca and Ivan Chaperot

Executive Summary Economic Working Paper, The

W
ithin the U.S. economy, many small and Bright Side of Patents, bridges
■ John Cabeca,
medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are in- the gap between the large cul-
tural assumptions listed above West Coast Region,
tensely aware of the need to protect intel-
lectual property (IP) and to incorporate IP strategy and solid statistical evidence Director,
into their business growth and development plans. that supports these assump- San Jose, CA, USA
Due to the expense, complexities, and laborious tions. The paper suggests: E-mail: john.cabeca@
process, unfortunately, many SMEs do not effec- “Our analysis shows that uspto.gov
tively build out a baseline IP strategy early enough. patent approvals have a
With the rise of global competition and a more inter- substantial and long-lasting ■ Ivan Chaperot,
connected economy, IP rights are critical assets for impact on start-ups: firms
that receive their first pat- Novalto Capital,
SMEs to compete effectively.
ent create more jobs, enjoy Co-Founder and
The good news is there are many resources across
the innovation ecosystem to support SMEs, enhance higher sales growth, inno- Managing Director,
IP awareness and foster innovation. From incubators, vate more, and are more Palo Alto, CA, USA
accelerators, venture capitalists (VCs), and the United likely to go public or be E-mail: ivan@
States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO), SMEs acquired. These positive
novaltocap.com
have access to mechanisms to effectively participate effects of patent rights ap-
in the IP economy, thereby enabling sustained growth pear to be due to their role
and long-term investment in R&D. in facilitating start-ups’ access to capital which helps
them turn ideas into products and products into
SMEs Need to Be Aware of the Importance of revenues. Our findings further suggest that the fa-
Patents and More Broadly of IP cilitating role of patents is strongest for early-stage
Patents were early recognized as such a significant firms, for start-ups founded by inexperienced entre-
part of the nation’s economic landscape that the power preneurs, and for firms in the IT sector. Thus, we
to grant them was enshrined in the U.S. Constitution. conclude that patent rights help overcome informa-
During the over 225 year history of a patent system tion frictions between start-ups and financiers.”2
in the United States, their importance has steadily
The USPTO, now with its expanded reach through
grown in the world economy. In fact, the Intellectual
its regional offices, works closely with trade organiza-
Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update report
tions, industry groups, and inventor associations to fo-
demonstrates “that IP-intensive industries supported
cus on educating small businesses and start-ups on the
45.5 million jobs and contributed $6.6 trillion in value
potential advantages and pitfalls of pursuing, or choos-
added in 2014, equivalent to 38.2 percent of U.S. GDP.
ing not to pursue, an IP strategy as a significant part of
In addition, the current report reinforces the earlier
their business development and strategy. For instance,
finding that IP use permeates all aspects of the econo-
the United Inventors Association of America (UIA) re-
my with increasing intensity and extends to all parts of
cently coordinated the Inventors Spotlight pavilion at
the U.S.”1 Often, securing patent rights are considered
the National Hardware Show which took place from
a hallmark of success. Further, the success of broad
May 9–11 in Las Vegas, Nevada. The Inventors Spot-
cultural influencers, such as the television show Shark
light afforded start-ups and small businesses emerging
Tank, have served to underscore the essential nature
in the marketplace the opportunity to showcase their
of protecting one’s intellectual property when starting
products alongside established exhibitors at the show.
a new business and the important role patents play in
The UIA also hosted an educational forum focused on
securing the venture capital needed to commercialize
helping start-ups and small businesses succeed in com-
an invention.
mercializing their ideas. The USPTO participated exten-
A recent United States Patent and Trademark Office sively at the Inventors Spotlight through hands-on IP

1. https://www.uspto.gov/sites/default/files/documents/ 2. Ibid.
IPandtheUSEconomySept2016.pdf, 30.

September 2017 189


SMEs And Patents In The U.S.
assistance and information sessions highlighting USPTO counterfeiting and piracy—while supporting U.S. ef-
resources designed to help innovators and SMEs. forts to improve IP laws internationally.
Private sector views about the propensity to file pat- The Recently USPTO Opened Regional Offic-
ents differ by industry. Pharmaceutical and biotech es to Serve as Hubs of Education, Outreach,
SMEs are generally more IP savvy and thus prone to and Innovation
file patent applications in earlier stages of development In pursuit of its mission to foster innovation, com-
than similarly sized software based companies. Anoth- petitiveness and economic growth, the USPTO recent-
er factor in the awareness of patents is the general ly opened regional offices in Detroit, Michigan; Den-
knowledge of the executive management team. For ver, Colorado; Dallas, Texas; and San Jose, California
instance, a CEO who had direct exposure in his or her in Silicon Valley. These regional offices work in con-
career with patent litigation will emphasize the need cert with USPTO headquarters in Alexandria, Virginia,
for patent protection, which will result in enhanced and serve as hubs of education, outreach, and innova-
IP awareness and more patent filings for the company. tion. In this way, the USPTO is more effectively able
The USPTO Offers SMEs Mechanisms to to reach a wide spectrum of communities, including
Effectively Participate in the IP Economy SMEs, emerging enterprises, independent inventors,
One of the USPTO’s priorities is to provide train- intellectual property practitioners, and to further
ing and education about the United States’ IP system its Science, Technology, Engineering, Mathematics
and the importance of developing strong IP protection. (STEM) education and outreach efforts to students
Independent inventors and SMEs sometimes struggle and educators. The regional offices also provide educa-
with how to file for and obtain IP protection for their tion programs, hands-on information and easier access
innovations due to a lack of financial resources. to USPTO resources and services for under-resourced
Through no-cost programs, reduced fees and inter- independent inventors and SMEs. By strengthening
national assistance for U.S. companies protecting their relationships with communities across the country,
intellectual property abroad, the USPTO is committed the USPTO, through its regional offices, now can more
to helping these innovators as they serve a vital role in nimbly tailor its resources and programs to better
the future economic development of the United States. serve the needs of the these communities to overcome
For instance, under-resourced independent inventors their unique challenges.
and small businesses may secure free legal representa- For instance, since the Silicon Valley Regional Office
tion through Patent Pro Bono Programs across the opened in October of 2015, SMEs have been taking
country. Another way for small businesses to secure advantage of outreach and education programs held
free legal services is through the Law School Clinic both in the regional office and throughout the Pacific
Certification Program, where law students help inno- region. Through the efforts of the Silicon Valley USP-
vators with either the patent or trademark prosecution TO last year alone, the regional office reached over
process under the supervision of law school faculty. 15,000 participants, most of which were independ-
Further, many independent inventors and small busi- ent inventors, start-ups, and small business owners.
nesses file patent applications without the assistance These programs continue to grow in popularity and
of a registered patent attorney or agent—also known cover a wide spectrum of intellectual property top-
as “pro se” filing. Through the Pro Se Assistance Pro- ics. They also highlight USPTO resources available to
gram, the USPTO has tools to assist pro se applicants help entrepreneurs successfully navigate the process
and employs a dedicated team that is available to an- and obtain intellectual property rights. In addition to
swer filing questions and help simplify the process. To outreach and educational programs, the regional office
help keep costs low, the USPTO offers independent routinely offers in-person services, such as one-on-one
inventors and small businesses reduced patent filing consultations with a patent examiner, search training
fees, where under-resourced inventors can receive up on USPTO patent and trademark databases, and patent
to a 75 percent discount on the USPTO’s fees. examiner interviews to help patent applicants resolve
Competing globally can be challenging, particularly issues during prosecution.
for U.S. businesses that lack the in-house resources SMEs Use Patents to Ensure Freedom to Op-
and expertise they need to deal with foreign IP reg- erate, Licence Their Inventions and to Build
ulations and protect their IP abroad. To help navigate Investor Value
the global IP landscape, the USPTO has IP Attachés For SMEs, securing patent protection is attractive
stationed around the world, working directly with U.S. for a variety of reasons and is often a core aspect of
businesses on IP issues—including helping to stop a successful business strategy. For example, patents

190 les Nouvelles


SMEs And Patents In The U.S.
serve to attract investors and buyers, deter infringe- Patent Litigation is Particularly Challenging
ment, increase leveraging power and add value to a for SMEs
company’s assets. Patents can also be used to help gain Patent litigation, either as a defendant or a plaintiff,
entry in and deter others from a market. They are also is challenging for SMEs as their limited financial re-
useful as a marketing tool to promote unique aspects sources can reduce their possibility of success.
of a product and to generate a revenue stream through
While it is not lost on anyone’s mind that many SMEs
the licensing of patented technology. The USPTO fre-
do not have the resources to finance patent litigations
quently delivers outreach and education programs on
in the U.S., the existence of patent rights in the U.S.
securing patent protection, and partners with organ-
still present a risk that larger competitors take serious-
izations on ways to leverage the variety of uses and
ly and, as a result, deter them from recklessly infring-
benefits of the patent system for SMEs.
ing known patent rights held by smaller companies.
From an SME perspective, patents are used to devel-
Some actors prey on SMEs, exploiting the imbalanc-
op a culture of innovation, clarify ownership of intel-
es in resources. To counter abusive litigation practic-
lectual property rights with employees and play a stra-
es, new business models have emerged that can help
tegic role in joint-venture, partnership and acquisition
start-ups defend themselves against patent litigation.
discussions. Many companies of all sizes incentivise
These models include joint defensive patent litigation
disclosure through patent filings for their employees
alliances (e.g., Unified Patents), patent pools (e.g., Via
to encourage product evolution and company security.
Licensing) and other mechanisms to acquire patents,
By disclosing their work, potential later conflicts can
which can be used as a deterrent against potential pat-
be avoided if an employee moves on to a competitor.
ent litigation from established players.
For investors, and particular VC investors, good busi-
To help curb abusive litigation practices for SMEs,
ness practices around patents is a sign of good business
practices in general. A prominent VC investor coined the USPTO launched an online toolkit aimed at em-
the expression “IP hygiene” when referring to possible powering consumers with answers to common ques-
reasons to file patents for a company. Indeed, for most tions, information about patent suits and details about
VC investors, the patent situation in early stage compa- patent infringement. The toolkit includes information
nies is a reflection of the team’s strength and ability to and links to services and websites that are designed to
carry their mission forward and build a business. help consumers understand the risks and benefits of
litigation, settlement, and to help them to pick their
During an exit, patents are an important consider-
best course of action.
ation. A prominent VC firm reported that a wireless
mesh-networking company was about to be acquired The USPTO’s Patent and Trial Appeal Board (PTAB)
by a larger company when a red flag was raised around hears appeals of examiner decisions in patent appli-
the ownership of patents. The acquisition target only li- cations and reexamination proceedings, and renders
censed its technology from a third party but didn’t own decisions in interferences. With the implementation
the patent rights, thus reducing the value of the acqui- of the Leahy-Smith America Invents Act of 2011 (AIA),
sition. Patents also protect investors against downside the PTAB now offers administrative trial proceedings,
risks. For companies who are not going to be the next including inter partes, post-grant, covered business
unicorns, there is an exit known as “acqui-hire” where method reviews and derivation proceedings, where the
a small company is acquired by a larger company for validity of a patent may be challenged. These expanded
its team and its assets. In the event of an “acqui-hire,” PTAB proceedings can provide SMEs cheaper and fast-
the company’s patents enable investors to recoup all or er alternatives in resolving patent disputes compared
some of their investment. to seeking relief through U.S. court proceedings. ■

Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):


https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009315

September 2017 191


SMEs: Patent Challenges In China

SMEs: Patent Challenges And Policies In China


By Qinghong Xu

I
n China, when referring to SMEs, micro-size en- The definitions are applicable to all legal entities
terprises are also often taken into account. These established in accordance with Chinese law, and set
businesses play an important role in China’s eco- the designations based on parameters of industry
nomic development. In 2015, the micro, small, and sector, number of employees, operating income, and
medium enterprises accounted for 99 percent of the financial assets. See the National Bureau of Statistics
total number of enterprises, and their contributions [2011] No. 75.
to national gross domestic product, industrial gross For example, for entities in agriculture, timber, an-
output value, total sales, taxes, and exports were 58 imal husbandry, and fishing industries, only operating
percent, 74 percent, 59 percent, 48 percent, and 68 income will be considered for designations. Entities
percent, respectively.1,2 with yearly operating income of less than CNY500,000,
When it comes to innovation, these enterprises can- between CNY500,000 and CNY5,000,000, and
not be overlooked, as they are engaged in the devel- between CNY5,000,000 and CNY200,000,000 are
opment and commercialization of innovations them- respectively qualified as micro, small, and medium en-
selves, and also are adopters of innovations developed terprises. Id.
by other organizations. However, they often face larger In another example, for entities in software and in-
barriers on capital and labor markets than bigger estab- formation technology service industry, both the num-
lished businesses. ber of employees and operating income will be consid-
Chinese national IP policies have seen the growth of ered while for micro enterprises satisfying one param-
the micro, small, and medium enterprises, and IP-fo- eter would be sufficient and for small and medium en-
cused businesses in particular, as a route to improve terprises, both parameters must be met. Entities with
the state of national economy. For example, see “Opin- less than 10 employees or operating income of less
ions on Further Support of Healthy Development of than CNY500,000, 10 to 100 employees and between
Micro and Small Enterprises” the State Council, GuoFa CNY500,000 and CNY 10,000,000 income, and 100
[2012] No. 14; and “Outline of the National Intellec- to 300 employees and between CNY10,000,000 and
tual Property Strategy” the State Council, June 5, 2008. CNY100,000,000 income are respectively qualified as
micro, small, and medium enterprises. Id.
What Are SMEs in China?
What Are Patent Challenges for SMEs in China?
The definitions of micro, small, and medium enter-
prises are provided by the National Bureau of Statistics While SMEs in China have spent more and more in
[2011] No. 75,3 effective September 2, 2011, which R&D,5 the patent filings have not kept the pace with
is in accordance with the regulation of “Notice on Defi- the spending.6 Even worse, according to a survey (the
nitions of Small and Medium Enterprises” [2011] No. “Survey”) conducted by the Department and Econom-
3004 jointly issued by Ministry of Industry and Infor- ics, Tianjin University, Chinese micro, small, and medi-
mation Technology, by the National Bureau of Statis- um enterprises have done poorly in terms of patenting
tics, the National Development and Reform Commis- technologies. In the Survey, 258 businesses in Tianjin
sion, and the Ministry of Finance. that were qualified as the national definitions of mi-
cro, small, and medium enterprises were interviewed.
“Empirical Study on the Intellectual Property Policy for
1. “Empirical Study on the Intellectual Property Policy for Micro, Small, and Medium Enterprises,” National In-
Micro, Small, and Medium Enterprises,” National Intellectual- tellectual-Property Strategy, June 3, 2015.7
Property Strategy, (June 3, 2015). http://www.nipso.cn/onews. The Survey found that among these businesses, 48
asp?id=26273.
2. In 2011, SMEs accounted for over 97.2 percent of Chinese
industrial enterprises in total, producing 58.4 percent of Gross 5. In 2011, the number of SMEs’ researchers and R&D
Industrial Output Value. “Government-Backed Patent Funds in expenditure has rapidly grown with a rate of 47.78 percent and
China,” Tech Monitor, (October-December 2013), 24-30. 40.30 percent respectively from previous year. “Government-
3. http://www.stats.gov.cn/statsinfo/auto2073/201310/ Backed Patent Funds in China,” Tech Monitor, (October-
t20131031_450691.html. December 2013), 24-30.
4. http://www.miit.gov.cn/n1146290/n4388791/c4245959/ 6. Id.
content.html (June 18, 2011). 7. http://www.nipso.cn/onews.asp?id=26273.

192 les Nouvelles


SMEs: Patent Challenges In China
percent of them do not own any granted invention pat- enterprises with small profits. Article 4 details the es-
ents at all and only 12 percent own 10 or more granted tablishment of a national SME Development Fund, to
invention patents, and not surprisingly, that over 90 which the central government funds CNY 15 billion,
percent of these businesses never had any experiences five years in place, together with other resources such
in buying, selling, or licensing patents. The Survey also as donations and fund income. Id.
found that only 43 percent of these businesses have To promote the micro
in-house IP professionals. Id. and small enterprises’
In addition to the barriers on capital and labor mar- innovation and develop- ■ Qinghong Xu,
kets for SMEs, the Survey also identified the following ment, Article 12 specifies Lung Tin Intellectual Property
difficulties that Chinese SMEs are facing: an increase in the central Agent Ltd.,
(i) Ineffectiveness of intellectual property protection, government budget for
micro and small enterpris- Partner,
which are exemplified by proliferation of infringe-
ment and counterfeits, time-consuming and ex- es to support innovation Beijing, China
pensive enforcement process, all resulting in high and technology transfor- E-mail: LTBJ@lungtin.com
cost and ineffectiveness of enforcement. mation, and Article 13
(ii) Imperfection in implementing patent support pol- lays out the tax deduction
icies, where enterprises are concerned about, for policy for the research and development costs. Id.
example, cumbersome procedures for reimburse- Since then, many government agencies have pub-
ment of patent funds, lack of transparency for poli- lished various polices to implement these measures
cy implementation process, and lengthy patent ex- from different aspects. The State Intellectual Property
amination process. Office (“SIPO”) issued policies for supporting innova-
(iii) Lack of knowledge for intellectual rights acquisi- tion and improving intellectual property related ser-
tion and enforcement in foreign jurisdictions. vices for micro and small enterprises.
(iv) Lack of understanding and usage of intellectual Policies Provided by the State Intellectual Prop-
property financing and relevant policies on it. erty Office (“SIPO”)
What Innovation Policies in China Relate SIPO issued “Opinions on Supporting the Growth of
to SMEs? Micro and Small Enterprises through Intellectual Prop-
erty Rights” [2014], No. 57,10 on October 8, 2014, for
In view of the importance of SMEs to the economic the purpose of implementing the IPR protection poli-
growth in China, the government has issued series of cies set forth in “Outline of the National Medium-and
policies especially on the support of micro and small Long-Term Human Resources Development Planning”
enterprises,8 as they (about 11.7 million) account for (2010-2020), stimulating the innovations of micro and
about 77 percent of the total number of enterprises, small enterprises, and fully supporting the entrepre-
and are of great strategic significance to the national neurship and innovative development of micro and
and social development especially in increasing em- small enterprises.
ployment rates, and promoting economic growth and
scientific and technological innovation. The SIPO Opinions provide the following major
policies:
Policies Provided by the State Council
(i) Enhancing the core competitiveness by acquiring
The State Council, on April 19, 2012, published patents in a timely manner. SIPO specifies a pri-
“Opinions on Further Support of Healthy Develop- oritized process for core patent applications from
ment of Micro and Small Enterprises” GuoFa [2012] micro and small business applicants, and supports
No. 149 that, the first in history, articulates 10 policy projects for acquiring overseas patents via fast
measures for supporting the development of micro and tracks.
small businesses.
(ii) Reducing the cost of patenting by increasing finan-
The measures include financial support, tax incen- cial support for patent applications from micro and
tives, public service, policy and information intercon- small enterprises;11 for example, a reward given to
nection, and other aspects. For example, Article 2 spec- the first granted invention patent.
ifies the increase of the threshold for the value-added
tax and business tax and deduction of business tax for 10. http://www.sipo.gov.cn/tz/gz/201410/t20141011_
1020001.html.
11. Since the establishment of patent law system, China
8. Interpretations of “Opinions on Supporting the Growth adopts a preferential policy that allows patent applicants
of Micro and Small Enterprises through Intellectual Property or patentees, who are, indeed, in financial difficulties, to
Rights,” (October 23, 2014). http://www.sipo.gov.cn/zcfg/ pay official fees at a reduced amount (a reduction of 70-85
zcjd/201410/t20141022_1023740.html. percent depending on whether the applicant is an individual or
9. http://www.gov.cn/zwgk/2012-04/26/content_2123937.htm. enterprise) or at a delayed payment.

September 2017 193


SMEs: Patent Challenges In China
In 2015, the total number of invention
Figure 1. Patent Application Filings patent applications, utility models and de-
signs filings reached 2,798,500, among
which China’s patent office received
1,101,864 filings for patent applications
4,000,000 for inventions, making it the first office to
3,500,000 receive more than a million applications in
3,000,000 a single year—including both filings from
4,500,000 residents in China (968,251), as well as
2,000,000 from overseas innovators seeking patent
1,500,000 protection inside China (133,613). This
1,000,000 totalled almost as many applications as the
500,000 three major offices combined: the U.S.
0
(589,410), Japan (318,721) and the Re-
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 public of Korea (213,694).13 In 2016, the
total applications
filings continued to grow. The total number
invention utility model design
arrived at 3,464,824 and both filings for in-
vention patent applications and utility mod-
(iii) Easing the financing difficulties by establishing els surpassed one million.
a demand investigation system for intellectual Turning to Chinese SMEs who play an important role
property financing. in China’s economic development, they are regarded
(iv) Improving the self-development capability by en- as a main contributor to the patenting activities, es-
couraging micro and small enterprises to imple- pecially to the growth of patent filings.14 However, as
ment the national standard of “Enterprise Intel- discussed above, they face larger barriers than bigger
lectual Property Management.” established businesses. Undoubtedly, current govern-
(v) Encouraging innovation by guiding universities ment policies will help SMEs to focus more on inno-
and research institutions to collaborate with vations and technology developments, and encourage
micro and small enterprises for developing tech- them to file more patent applications, which will drive
nologies, encouraging state-owned corporations Chinese patent filings continually to surge.
to license and transfer patents, and guiding in- In conclusion, Chinese government policies indeed
tellectual property model enterprises to license have great positive impacts on promoting innovations
patents with minimal royalties. for SMEs in China, which we will be able to observe in
(vi) Supporting the business growth by providing in- many years to come. ■
tellectual property services.
(vii) Implementing a service network by establishing Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
an intellectual property service system at provin- https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009319
cial, municipal and county levels and promoting
government purchase services.
(viii) Strengthening the intellectual property protec-
tion by accelerating the establishment of a fast-
track mediation mechanism for patent infringe-
ment disputes.
What Are Our Observations?
Given all policies provided by the Chinese govern-
ment, in particular “Outline of the National Intellec-
tual Property Strategy” issued by the State Council on 13. “Global Patent Applications Rose to 2.9 Million in 2015
on Strong Growth from China; Demand Also Increased for
June 5, 200812 which made the intellectual property Other Intellectual Property Rights,” WIPO, (Geneva, November
issue as one of the basic national strategies for Chi- 23, 2016). http://www.wipo.int/pressroom/en/articles/2016/
na’s overall social and economic development, we have article_0017.html.
observed Chinese patent application filings have been 14. In 2011, the share of SMEs‘ patent filings accounted for
continually surging these years. See Figure 1. 58.8 percent of the total filings. However, due to the different
definitions for SMEs since September 2, 2011, the share may
be different and decrease. “Government-Backed Patent Funds
12. The State Council of China, Doc. No. 18 [2008]. in China” Tech Monitor, (October-December 2013), 24-30.

194 les Nouvelles


SMEs In ASEAN And Singapore

SMEs In ASEAN And Singapore—IP Perspectives


By Audrey Yap

S
mall medium-sized enterprises, or SMEs, form to promote Singapore as an IP
the backbone of most economies but are particu- hub for Asia which includes
■ Audrey Yap,
larly important in Asia where the majority of busi- developing stronger reasons
nesses still lack the scale and reach of their western for both SMEs and MNCs Yusarn Audrey,
counterparts in developed economies as multination- (Multi National Companies) Co-Founder and
als. SMEs across Asia Pacific contribute 20-50 percent to file IP in Singapore, as Managing Partner,
of their respective nation’s gross domestic product, ac- well as creating a vibrant IP Singapore, Thailand,
count for 97 percent of all enterprises and employ half marketplace and facilitate IP
the workforce across Asia. transactions. The IP office of Malaysia.
It follows that the significance of Intellectual Proper- Singapore (IPOS) has been a E-mail: audrey@yusarn.com
ty (IP) to business as a whole in Asia requires an assess- significant driver of the trans-
ment of how this community perceives the subject. formation process. The transi-
ASEAN tion has not been easy to educate and inform SMEs,
but increasingly enterprises in Singapore, and across
A significant landmark event for the 10 countries ASEAN, are beginning to embrace IP as an important
that form the Association of Southeast Asian Natives tool for protection and for business value. Indeed as
ASEAN was the implementation of the ASEAN Eco- the companies become more sophisticated in their
nomics Community (AEC) 2015 Blueprint, which in- understanding, the approach has moved from purely
cludes, inter alia, standardizing economic regulations protection of IP for IP’s sake to looking at monetization
covering trade, capital market regulatory frameworks and commercialization of IP. In a recent press release
and protection of intellectual property rights. The ob- in May 2017 by IPOS and the Ministry of Law, new
jective of the 10 member states of Singapore, Malay- initiatives were announced to help IP-rich companies
sia, Thailand, Indonesia, Brunei, Philippines, Vietnam, scale up and use the same to leverage international
Cambodia, Laos and Myanmar, when ASEAN was first growth. This includes enhancing an existing IP Finan-
established in 1967, was to forge an independent bloc cing Scheme that is already in place for patents as col-
in Southeast Asia and to ensure peace and stability in lateral for debt financing by banks, to expand to all
the region. Fast forward, today ASEAN collectively is other forms of IP such as trademarks and copyright.
the third largest market in the world with a popula-
Singapore’s IP Financing Scheme was rolled out to
tion of over 625 million people. World Bank projects
help IP-rich companies monetize their IP for business
that ASEAN will be the largest economy in the world
growth and expansion and S$ 100-million was set aside
by 2050. The top five trading partners of ASEAN are
by the Government to partially underwrite the loans
China, Japan, EU, U.S.A. and South Korea. For SMEs in
by participating financial institutions, which includes
the region therefore, appreciating and harnessing the
AFC Merchant Bank, DBS Bank Ltd., United Overseas
AEC has become an activity that is increasingly central
Bank and Oversea Chinese Banking Corporation. IPOS
to business growth and accordingly awareness of IP as
has seen its role in this evolving landscape, transfor-
well, given it was identified as a pillar in the AEC 2015
ming from pure registry and regulator to becoming an
action plan. It now appears for the first time in history
innovation agency.
that Asia is leading the world in terms of patent and
trademark filings. WIPO Statistics show a significant SMEs are assisted based on stage of development
rise in the past five years. (start-ups, midsize, listed company) and/or industry seg-
ment (manufacturing, oil & gas, pharmaceuticals, elec-
Singapore
tronics). The Ministry of Trade & Industry through its
Singapore is a successful free market economy, open, various agencies launched several initiatives including
highly developed with a GDP per capita compatible that which promotes innovation and commercialization
with leading European nations. Businesses, particularly of new technologies and IP such as “SG­—innovate” to
SMEs in Singapore, are acutely concerned about their connect and match start-ups, researchers and innova-
vulnerabilities and opportunities in ASEAN and Asia. tors with potential investors, mentors and to facilitate
The Government of Singapore actively promotes access to new markets. There are also various policies
innovation and IP and have launched a strategy map and grants schemes to encourage SMEs to adopt E-Com-

September 2017 195


SMEs In ASEAN And Singapore
merce and to acquire and manage IP. For example, a government incentives and policies are shaping how
tax deduction allowance is made for IP expenses or IP IP is viewed, protected and used by SMEs particularly
purchased/acquired by SMEs. under the ASEAN Economic Community agreements.
The SME in Singapore that exemplifies a local enter- Singapore is leading the race in IP monetization in
prise that is IP focused is the award winning company the region, drawing from its central location and open
Innosparks. Their key product is an adjustable mask business environment, as well as reputation as a finan-
with attachable micro fan and smart valve, protected cial hub. SMEs in Singapore are no longer just filing
by a slew of patents, trademarks and design registra- IP for protection but leveraging innovation and IP as a
tions. By ring fencing their IP, Innosparks was able to business tool and enterprise value.
establish a monopoly and leverage its IP for licensing An IP marketplace is slowly but surely emerging
and joint venture into a key market like China with the in Singapore, and IPOS, IP intermediaries and pro-
former Reckitt Benckiser now renamed RB-Dettol. fessionals are playing a role in pushing the agenda of
Singapore’s initiative to promote patent and tech- growing the business of licensing and sale of IP, as well
nology transfer includes recognizing the role of IP as collateralization of patents and trademark portfolios
intermediaries and professionals in providing spe- for IP financing by banks, private equity players and
cialised support services that help SMEs understand venture funds. ■
the business, products and services and translate Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
innovation objectives into specific IP and technology https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009338
requirements. Government funded IP Intermediary
(IPI) Network provides search, sourcing and matching Useful References
based on IP needed by SMEs. ASEAN­—www.asean.org
Summary Special ASEAN Issues—www.iseas.edu.sg
ASEAN is a fast changing landscape and IP aware- Economic Data—www.worldbank.org
ness is rising but not at the same rate across Southeast History of ASEAN—www.aunsec.org
Asia. Unlike in the Western developed economies, IP Office of Singapore—www.ipos.gov.sg

196 les Nouvelles


Patent And SMEs In India

Patent And SMEs In India


By Sunita K. Sreedharan

SMEs in India items, which are being man-

T
he Ministry of Micro, Small and Medium En- ufactured by the small enter-
■ Sunita K. Sreedharan,
terprises (M/o MSME) set up on May 9, 2007 prises in India. After agricul-
ture, the MSE sector provides SKS Law Associates,
by the merging of two ministries i.e. erstwhile
Ministry of Small Scale Industries and the Ministry of the maximum opportunities Founder & CEO,
Agro and Rural Industries, has been on the forefront to for both self-employment and New Delhi, India
creaste awareness of IPR among the MSMEs in differ- jobs in the country. E-mail: sunita@skslaw.org
ent parts of India. The MSMEs in manufacturing and The promotion of innova-
service sectors have been defined on the basis of their tion among the MSME sector
investments as follows:1 has received additional filip under the present Govern-
ment. Elected into power in May 2014,
the present Government shifted focus on
Definition of MSMEs in India “innovation” by creating the Ministry of
Skill Development and Entrepreneur-
ship on November 9, 2014 to coordinate
Manufacturing Enterprises – Investment in Plant & all skill development efforts across the
Machinery country with programmes such as “Skill In-
Description INR USD($) dia” and “Make in India.” Industrial train-
ing and apprenticeship as well as other
Micro up to Rs. 25Lakh up to $ 62,500 skill development responsibilities in exist-
Enterprises
ing jobs as well as potential new jobs were
Small above Rs. 25 Lakh & above $ 62,500 & up transferred from the Ministry of Labour
Enterprises up to Rs. 5 Crore to $ 1.25 million and Employment on April 16, 2015 with
Medium above Rs. 5 Crore & above $ 1.25 million & an aim:
Enterprises up to Rs. 10 Crore up to $ 2.5 million • To remove disconnect between demand
and supply of skilled manpower;
Service Enterprises – Investment in Equipments
• To build the new skills and;
Description INR USD($) • To develop innovative thinking.
Micro up to Rs. 10 Lakh up to $ 25,000 The Start-up India Initiative:
Enterprises
In early 2015, the “Start-up India” ini-
Small above Rs. 10 Lakh & above $ 25,000 & up tiative was notified2 where new entities
Enterprises up to Rs. 2 Crore to $ 0.5 million
would have tax benefits. According to the
Medium above Rs. 2 Crore & above $ 0.5 million & Government Notification, an entity will be
Enterprises up to Rs. 5 Crore up to $ 1.5 million identified as a “Start-up.”
1. Till up to five years from the date of its
Contribution of MSME: incorporation/registration;
According to a recent WIPO Study, the MSME sector 2. If its turnover for any of the financial year does not
in India is estimated at about 12.8 million units (over exceed INR 25 crores (approx 3,873,567 USD @
90 percent of total industrial units) employing nearly 64.54 INR to one U.S. dollar) in the said five years,
31 million people. This sector contributes nearly 39 and;
percent of the total industrial production and accounts 3. It is working towards innovation, development, de-
for approximately 33 percent of the total exports. This ployment, and commercialisation of new products,
sector has consistently registered a higher growth rate processes, or services driven by technology or intel-
than the rest of the industrial sector. There are over lectual property.
6500 products ranging from traditional to high-tech
2. http://dipp.nic.in/English/Investor/startupindia/Definition_
1. http://www.smechamberofindia.com/about_msmes.aspx. Startup_GazetteNotification.pdf, 3.

September 2017 197


Patent And SMEs In India
To obtain tax benefits a start-up must obtain a certif- IPR” as well as “Enforcement and Adjudication” as
icate of an eligible business from the lnter-Ministerial top priority to ensure that the focus on IPR creation
Board of Certification consisting of Joint Secretary, De- is followed through with adequate enforcement and
partment of Industrial Policy and Promotion, as well as protection mechanism.
one Representative each of Department of Science and In Conclusion:
Technology, and Department of Biotechnology. Accordingly the Patent Rules were amended3 to add
The National IPR Policy: a category of “Start-ups” as “Applicants” to the exist-
That the Government was serious in shifting focus ing three tiers of applicants who pay differentiated
from mere improvement in manufacturing capacity to fees namely the “Natural Person(s),” “Small Entity”
innovation was highlighted when the National IPR Pol- and “Not a Small Entity.” The Start-up can be in any
icy was adopted by the present Government in May of the three categories including an individual, pro-
2016. The National IPR Policy unveiled seven objec- vided it is registered as a Start-up with the Ministry
tives which includes: of Commerce.
• “IPR Awareness: Outreach and Promotion” with a While there is no exact information on the total ap-
focus on creating public awareness about the eco- plications filed by SMEs in the Official Patent Office
nomic, social and cultural benefits of IPRs among all Annual Report,4 the RTI Applications filed under the
sections of society and; Right to Information Act 2017 reveal that all in all about
• “Human Capital Development” to strengthen and 33 patent applications and 30 trademark applications
expand human resources, institutions and capaci- have been filed by the Start-ups under the Start-Ups
ties for teaching, training, research and skill build- Intellectual Property Protection Scheme (SIPP). ■
ing in IPR. Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
The IPR Policy also lists “Commercialization of https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009323

3. http://www.ipindia.nic.in/writereaddata/Portal/IPORule/1_ 4. http://www.ipindia.nic.in/writereaddata/Portal/IPOAnnual
42_1_Patent__Amendment_Rules_2016_16May2016.pdf Report/1_71_1_Annual_Report_2015-16_English__2_.pdf

198 les Nouvelles


Patent And SMEs In Brazil

Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Brazil


By Cândida Caffé and Mariana Vicentini

SMEs in Brazil these companies’ administrative, tax, social security

T
he participation of Micro and Small Enterprises and credit obligations should be simplified or sub-
(SMEs) in the Brazilian economy is significant stantially reduced.
and growing: in 1985 SMEs represented 21% of Although various laws ■ Cândida Caffé,
Brazil’s GDP, having increased to 23.2 percent in the were edited to deal with
Dannemann Siemsen,
year of 2001 and to 27 percent in the year of 2011.1 the legal treatment of small
In February 2017, SMEs were responsible for 54 thou- enterprises, they are cur- Partner,
sand new hires, against approximately 26 thousand dis- rently regulated by Com- Rio de Janeiro, Brazil
charges by medium-sized and large companies.2 plementary Law No. 123, E-mail: ccaffe@
In accordance with statistics published in bullet- of 2006, also known as the dannemann.com.br
ins of the Brazilian Micro and Small Business Support “General SMEs Law.”
Service—SEBRAE (a broadly known and respected The General SMEs Law ■ Mariana Vicentini,
non-profit private entity with a mission to promote establishes a series of
simplified and beneficial
Souto, Correa, Cesa, Lummertz
the sustainable and competitive development of small
businesses in Brazil), in 2011,3 SMEs corresponded to treatment for SMEs, in- & Amaral Advogados,
98.2 percent of Brazilian private entities and 59.4 per- cluding a specific tax reg- Senior Associate,
cent of the exporting companies of Brazil, representing imen—with lower taxes Rio de Janeiro, Brazil
52.1 percent of formal jobs in the country. In the same and facilitated procedures E-mail: mariana.vicentini@
year, SMEs were responsible for 4.2 million of rural for tax calculation and col-
lection—the reduction of soutocorrea.com.br
producers and 17 million of formal employees.
bureaucracy for the estab-
SMEs’ participation in the economy increased and in
lishment and maintenance of SMEs; and for labor re-
2015,4 they corresponded to 98.5 percent of Brazilian
lated procedures; the possibility of filing court actions
private entities and 61 percent of the exporting com-
before Small Claim Courts and favorable treatment in
panies of Brazil, representing 54 percent of formal jobs
public bids, such as assurance of preferred rights as a
in the country. Still in 2015, SMEs were responsible
tie-breaking criteria.
for 4.7 million of rural producers and 17.1 million of
formal employees. In general terms, a company will be deemed as a
micro or a small enterprise depending on its gross
The first law regulating the differentiated treatment revenue. Further to the General SMEs Law, duly re-
rendered to small entities in Brazil was Law No. 7.256, gistered limited liability companies or individual entre-
edited in 1984. preneurs may be framed as Micro or Small entities,
Given their importance in Brazilian economy and depending on their annual gross revenue, as follows:
seeking to contribute for the development and com- (a) Individual Entrepreneurs are duly registered
petitiveness of SMEs in the market, they are assured self-employed individuals that do not participate
a differentiated judicial treatment by the Brazilian in any entities neither as partner nor manager who
Federal Constitution of 1988, which determines that have up to one employee and an annual gross rev-
enue of up to R$ 60.000,00 (sixty thousand Bra-
zilian reais) until December 31, 2017 or up to R$
1. Available at https://www.sebrae.com.br/Sebrae/Portal%20 81.000,00 (eighty-one thousand Brazilian reais) as
Sebrae/Estudos%20e%20Pesquisas/Participacao%20das%20 from January 1, 2018;
micro%20e%20pequenas%20empresas.pdf.
(b) Micro Enterprises are those companies with
2. Available at https://www.sebrae.com.br/Sebrae/Portal%20
Sebrae/Anexos/caged-fevereiro-2017.pdf.
an annual gross revenue of up to R$ 360.000,00
(three hundred and sixty Brazilian reais);
3. “Study and Research Bulletin of January 2016,” SEBRAE,
https://www.sebrae.com.br/Sebrae/Portal%20Sebrae/Anexos/ (c) Small Enterprises are those companies with an
boletim%20estudos%20e%20pesquisas%20jan%202016.pdf. annual gross revenue higher than R$ 360.000,00
4. “Study and Research Bulletin of February 2017, SEBRAE, (three hundred and sixty Brazilian reais) and low-
https://www.sebrae.com.br/Sebrae/Portal%20Sebrae/Anexos/ er than or equal to R$ 3.600.000,00 (three million
BEP%20fev%202017.pdf. and six hundred thousand Brazilian reais) until
September 2017 199
Patent And SMEs In Brazil
December 31, 2017 or to R$ 4.800.000,00 (four less, SMEs patent filings have been increasing year
million and eight hundred thousand Brazilian reais) after year, whilst medium and large companies’ filings
as from January 01, 2018. have been decreasing:
Moreover, the General SMEs Law provides that com-
panies with the characteristics listed below cannot be Chart 1: Patent Filing Comparison
framed as SMEs, not being, therefore, qualified to
enjoy the special treatment rendered to such kind of
1523
enterprise: 1600 1442
1400 1322
(a) Companies having legal entities in their 1200
shareholder composition; 1000 800 824
736
(b) Brazilian branches, subsidiaries, agencies or rep- 800
600
resentations of foreign entities; 400
(c) Companies whose individual shareholders are reg- 200
istered as individual entrepreneurs or who are 0
Medium & Large Companies SMEs
shareholders of other SMEs, if their global annual
gross revenue exceeds the limits for being framed 2014 2015 2016

as SMEs; As an incentive for the development of SMEs and for


(d) Companies whose shareholders have equity partic- the due protection of their industrial property rights
ipation exceeding 10 percent in other companies and assets, the official fees of the services offered by
that are not framed as SMEs, if their global annual the National Institute of Industrial Property (INPI) to
gross revenue exceeds the limits for being framed such company category—including patent filing and
as SMEs; recordal of transfer of technology agreements—con-
(e) Companies whose shareholders are managers of template discounts of up to 60 percent of the regular
or hold an equivalent position in other entities, fees. These discounts are also extended to coopera-
provided that their global annual gross revenue tives, educational institutions, non-profit organizations
exceeds the limits for being framed as SMEs; and public entities.
(f) Cooperatives, except if a consumer cooperative; In 2016, an additional initiative was adopted by the
INPI to encourage patent filings and support innova-
(g) Companies holding equity participation in other com- tion of SMEs in Brazil: the launching of Phase I of the
panies; “Patents SMEs,” a new pilot program for fast track
(h) Companies that conduct banking, investment, fi- examination of patent applications filed by Micro and
nancial or insurance related activities; Small Enterprises. With the launching of the Patents
(i) Companies resulting from spin-offs or other split SMEs program, the INPI expected to reduce the nega-
operations in the preceding five years; and tive impacts associated with their delay in the analysis
(j) Joint-stock companies. of patent applications, which is a very sensitive aspect
considered by patent applicants and which, many
Patents and SMEs times, discourages patent filings, especially by SMEs.
Since owners of patents are vested in exclusive rights
of exploitation of their subject matter, the obtainment It is worth mentioning that, in addition to the Pat-
of such protection is an effective measure adopted by ents SMEs, the INPI currently has five fast track ex-
many companies, including SMEs, in the pursuit of a amination programs, which are eligible for patent
stronger position in the market. This is due to the fact applications: (i) filed by the elderly, the physical or
that the obtainment of patent protection may, for ex- mentally disabled, the patients of serious diseases; in
ample, aid SMEs in achieving competitive advantage; cases when the grant of the patent is a condition for
receiving additional income resulting from licensing or obtainment of financial resources from official credit
assignment of rights; entering in new markets upon institutions; in cases when the subject matter of a pat-
licensing; accessing different technologies via cross li- ent application is being reproduced by unauthorized
censing and attracting investments from third parties. third parties; in cases when third parties are accused
Although there is awareness of the importance by a patent applicant of unauthorized reproduction
and value of patents and their potential for business of the application’s subject matter (in this case, the
development of SMEs, the majority of patent filings fast track examination may be requested by the third
are made by medium-sized and large companies, as party); (ii) covering green inventions; (iii) related to
shown in statistics published by the INPI.5 Regard- pharmaceutical products and processes, as well as to
equipment and materials relevant to public health; (iv)
5. Available at http://www.inpi.gov.br/sobre/estatisticas/ filed through the Patent Prosecution Highway—PPH,
estatisticas-preliminares-2013-a-partir-de-2013. according to the collaborative agreement signed be-

200 les Nouvelles


Patent And SMEs In Brazil
tween the Brazilian PTO and United States Patent and of the Pilot Program upon filing an electronic petition
Trademark Office—USPTO and the Japanese Patent before the INPI. Differently from other patent fast
and Trademark Office; and (v) from a family of patents track programs offered by the INPI, no official fees are
initiated at the INPI. charged for a patent application to be examined under
The Patents SMEs Program is currently in its Phase the Patents SMEs.
II. Phase I of the Program was regulated by Resolu- Statistics conducted by the INPI6 demonstrate that
tion No. 160 of the INPI, published in February 2016 the Patents SMEs Program is, so far, successfully
and, after the assessment of its positive results, the achieving its goal: while the INPI currently takes about
INPI issued Resolution No. 181 to regulate Program’s eight years to render decisions on patent applications
Phase II, commencing on March 1, 2017 and valid for not eligible for fast track examination, patent appli-
a period of one year or until 150 fast track requests are cations analyzed under the Pilot Program have been
accepted; whichever occurs first. decided within approximately eight months from the
The main requirements contained in Resolution No. request of their acceptance into the Program.
181 for a patent application to be included in Phase II Transfer of Technology Agreements and SMEs
of the Pilot Patents SMEs are summarized below: Technology transfer agreements comprise patent,
• The application was filed with the INPI at any date; trademark and industrial design licenses, technology
transfer, technical assistance services and franchise
• The application related to an invention or an utility
agreements. Thus, transfer of technology agreements
model;
may be an excellent tool for SMEs to either earn roy-
• The application was filed in the name of an SME, alties or to expand to new markets via licensing or
as defined in Complementary Law 123/2006. In the even franchising.
event of multi applicant applications, all applicants Transfer of technology agreements are valid and
are SMEs; enforceable between contracting parties against one
• The application does not lie within the industrial another regardless recordal at the INPI, which is indis-
fields of “Performing Operations; Transport” (sec- pensable only for the following purposes:
tion B) or “Mechanical Engineering; Lighting; Heat- (a) To make the agreement effective against third par-
ing; Weapons; Blasting” (section F) of the Interna- ties (such as to, if set forth in the agreement, allow
tional Patent Classification; licensee to act in defense of the licensed IP assets
• The application has already been published in the and assure exclusivity of use of the IP assets by
Brazilian Industrial Property Journal or, in the case licensee);
of PCT applications, it has been accepted as eligible (b) To allow remittance of payments to the foreign li-
for examination in the national phase; censor; and
• Examination of the application has been accepted; (c) To qualify local licensee for tax deductions, if the
• Examination of the application has not been sus- local licensee adopts the actual profit tax regime,
pended awaiting compliance with a requirement which is not applicable for SMEs, whose taxes are
previously issued by the INPI; accrued upon the simplified regime established in
the General SMEs Law, and does not provide for
• No annuity fee payment is pending; deductibility.
• The application is not sub judice (under trial or be- Therefore, although SMEs frequently enter into
ing considered by a judge). transfer of technology agreements (especially for IP
SMEs may request the fast track examination of pat- licensing and franchising), practice shows that these
ent applications attending to the above requirements agreements are rarely submitted to the INPI for re-
cordal. This cannot be avoided when it is necessary
to remit royalties abroad though. The fact that such
Chart 2: Tech Transfer Agreements agreements are generally entered in a private fashion,
somewhat hinders the assessment of how frequently
they are in fact adopted by SMEs. Regardless, statis-
10000 1452 1227
tics published by the INPI demonstrate a decrease
1000 803 in the transfer of technology agreements of Medium
and Large Companies in 2016 (as a reflection of the
100 economic situation), against an increase of the same
42 38
25 agreements of SMEs. ■
10 Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
0
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009329
Medium & Large Companies SMEs

2014 2015 2016


6. Available at http://www.inpi.gov.br/menu-servicos/patente/
exame-prioritario-me-epp.

September 2017 201


Patent And SMEs In Chili

Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Chili


By Felipe Claro

The Patent Awareness of SMEs ing of investment,

M
any Chilean SMEs have good ideas that never innovation, entre- ■ Felipe Claro,
see the market, either because they don’t know preneurship and
development of Claro & Cia.,
how to use the patent system in their favor Partner,
companies of dif-
or because they do not have access to good commercial
ferent sizes, deep- Santiago, Chile
partners. Sometimes, prospective partners simply copy ening and develop-
the non-protected solutions and replicate them as their ing more competi- E-mail: felipe@claro.cl
own. There is also a lack of local IPR (Intellectual Property tive markets.
Rights) management organizations that buy up idle pat-
ents and try to commercialize them among SMEs. • It seeks to improve the competitiveness of the
economy by strengthening human capital, in-
In spite of the above, more and more SMEs are realiz- novation and productivity, in order to solve coor-
ing that patents, and more broadly IP, are really important dination failures and remove obstacles in strate-
to their commercial success. It should be considered that gic productive sectors.
less than 4,000 patent applications are filed in the coun- • It promotes collaborative programs that connect
try every year, so the vast majority of worldwide patent companies, universities and technology centers.
filings (millions) directly go into the prior art zone, thus
encouraging Chilean SMEs to take advantage of this valu- How do SMEs use patents?
able public domain subject matter instead of paying high SMEs do not use patents as much as large companies
royalties for few top of the art technologies that are not so do. Normally, they cannot afford costly investigation and
useful to them. In Chile, depending on the field of tech- instead of that they mostly adapt existing technology
nology, even a 25 or 30-year-old technology can be very to meet new market requirements. Their approach to
valuable if correctly implemented. SMEs are reluctant or patents is more informal and have more flexibility to ex-
simply can’t afford to pay high royalties. plore new solutions, which mostly lead to petty patents
and industrial designs, where only novelty is required.
WIPO should make an extra effort to provide complete
SMEs are more on the side of paying royalties than
information about PCT (Patent Cooperation Treaty) ap- collecting them from third parties. When they realize
plications that don’t enter the national phase, to permit about the importance of having their own IPRs and using
SMEs to freely access those not so old non-patented tech- them effectively, they can narrow the distance between
nologies and use them in their favor to make an impact in status quo and commercial success, and also increase
the local market. These databases would give certainty to the company value. Proper legal advice is crucial to de-
SMEs, who don’t want to lose money by infringing IPRs. fine if there is freedom to operate in the local market.
That information is crucial for SMEs in developing coun- SMEs and Patent litigation
tries to discern how to navigate in the vast patent ocean.
The limited resources of SMEs normally leads to af-
The Government Policy to Promote Use of fect their ability to enforce and litigate their rights in
Patent by SMEs front of big entities. Many times they prefer trade se-
The Government is educating SMEs about the con- crets to patenting for this reason. They don’t like being
venience of using IPRs, and especially patents as part dragged by big companies into endless legal battles. In
of their businesses. Generally speaking, the Govern- Chile there is not a patent litigation insurance scheme
ment promotes patents through the following actions: to give a hand to the SMEs as it normally happens in
• It encourages people interested in developing the Northern Hemisphere.
non-conventional businesses. SMEs are mainly involved in patent litigation as de-
• It drives companies to take risks and think of new fendants, trying to get rid of complainants accusing
ways to face challenges. To this end, it helps them to them of using patented material. This is especially com-
finance the creation and protection of new products, mon in the pharmaceutical industry, an area where im-
services or processes, or substantially improve those portant patent litigation takes place in Chile, regardless
already under development. It is also concerned with of the very low magnitude of patent litigation overall.
the development of innovation projects. The patent culture is changing and younger entre-
• It seeks to support companies, so that through preneurs are more inclined to protect their IPRs, thus
co-financing of projects and tax rebates, they increasing the possibility of being involved in patent liti-
can improve their management and innovation gation not only as defendants, but also as patent owners
practices, to improve their productivity and facil- seeking to protect and enforce their own IP assets. ■
itate their internationalization. Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
• It provides solutions to improve the access to financ- https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009330
202 les Nouvelles
Patent And SMEs In Colombia

Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Colombia


By Fernando Triana Soto and Marcela Gómez Rubio

T
he “Promotion of technological development investments in innovation in the future when they
and innovation” is one of the policies set by the must pay income tax. However, this benefit is only
Colombian Government for the growth of the applicable within the following four taxable periods
country’s economy with the objective of strengthening according to Law No. 1819 of 2016.
the national business sector through innovation. In addition, in the National Development Plan3 for
About 10 years ago, a comprehensive overview of 2014 to 2018 approved by Law No. 1753 of June 9,
the status of innovation in Colombia showed low in- 2015, it was established within the Government pol-
vestment in the activities of science, technology and icies: “To promote technological development and in-
innovation (hereinafter STI) in addition to the low novation as an engine of business growth and entre-
participation of Colombian nationals in the Industrial preneurship” with the objective of increasing the use
Property System, namely the protection through pat- of the Industrial Property System for innovation activ-
ents of invention.1 It was found that the tax benefits ities, aiming to increase the number of patent applica-
introduced since the 90’s were not stimulating invest- tions filed by nationals, and leaving the Government
ment in STI, and the main cause was the lack of know- agency Colciencias the task of developing programs
ledge of nationals about how the Intellectual Property to support patentability procedures in companies,
System operates in our country. universities, research and technological development
Thus, in 2008, public policies aimed at strength- centers, as well as citizens. In addition, it was set as a
ening Intellectual Property began to be introduced, goal that investment in STI would reach one percent of
notably Conpes 3533 of 20082 which recommended GDP by 2018, starting from an estimated investment
the implementation of training activities, manuals, in 2014 of 0.5 percent of GDP.
bulletins to disseminate knowledge about the Intellec- Consequently, new changes were introduced to im-
tual Property System between these nationals, it also plement the public policies, among which we consider
recommended the strengthening of the institutions necessary to emphasize the following:
responsible for administrating the system, to make its 1. Regarding the Superintendence of Industry and
work more efficiently. Commerce (hereinafter SIC) which is the entity
Following similar lines, Conpes 3834 of 2015 estab- in charge of administering the Industrial Property
lished the need to introduce tax deductions and im- System:
prove the conditions and alternatives for access to tax 1.1 Reorientation of the entity’s mission; in addition
benefits. In addition, it was recommended to enable to being the authority in charge of granting in-
early stage companies and SMEs to make deductions dustrial property rights, it also has a pedagogical
when they invest in STI. Although presently they do objective of promoting knowledge about the In-
not generate net incomes, they will be able to deduct dustrial Property matters, for which the following
programs have been developed:
1. Report of the “Superintendence of Industry and • Creation of the Intellectual Property Academy
Commerce” published in Industrial Property 2020, according (IPA) in 2011, which organizes training activities
to WIPO, in developed countries more than 50 percent of the for the promotion and generation of a culture of
patent applications are filed by residents of the country. For protection, use and utilization of the Intellectual
instance, in Spain more than 90 percent of patent applications
have been filed by nationals in recent years. On the other hand,
Property system. The micro and small companies
in emerging economies WIPO suggests that this figure is around that attend the courses of IPA have a discount of
20 percent. In Brazil and Argentina, the participation has been 25 percent in the official fees for the industrial
close to 20 percent, while in Chile it has been around 10 property proceedings.
percent in recent years. Unfortunately, in Colombia that figure 3. The National Development Plan is the plan that the
has not reached even eight percent. President of the Republic presents to Congress at the beginning
2. The National Council for Economic and Social Policy, known of his term with the guidelines of the Government. The topics
by its acronym CONPES, is the highest planning authority and should include political, economic, social and security issues of
serves as an advisory body to the Government in all aspects the country. Once Congress approves the Plan, the President
related to the economic and social development of the country and his work team must begin to develop the policies that lead
and it also coordinates the related agencies for decisions on to compliance with it. (For additional reference, please consult
economic and social policy (For additional reference, please http://www.banrepcultural.org/blaavirtual/ayudadetareas/
consult https://www.dnp.gov.co/CONPES/Paginas/conpes.aspx). politica/plan_nacional_de_desarrollo).

September 2017 203


Patent And SMEs In Colombia
• Creation of the SIC Móvil project in 2011, whereby neys specialized in Intellectual Property matters
officials of the entity travel to various cities in the to receive legal advice during the prosecution of
country in order to promote the services provided their patent applications without any charge. The
by the entity in the field of Industrial Property. program in Colombia is coordinated through the
• Granting jurisdictional functions to the SIC through TISC and the Center of Technological Information
Law No. 1564 of 2012, creating a judge special- and Support of the management of the Industrial
ized in Industrial Property issues. These kinds of Property (hereinafter
functions were also granted to the National Direc- CIGEPI), which is a
tion of Copyrights. Thus, these specialized judges unit within the SIC ■ Fernando Triana Soto,
encourage protection, as it strengthens the system in charge of providing Triana, Uribe & Michelsen,
of enforcement in relation to acquired rights. technological infor- Partner and the Head of
1.2 Greater efficiency in the administration of the In- mation services and
specialized guidance the Litigation and Patent
dustrial Property System, for which a new tech-
on Industrial Property Department,
nological platform was implemented and began
operating on July 18, 2016 and allows the online issues and Technology Bogotá, D.C., Colombia
filing of Industrial Property proceedings, including and Innovation Sup-
E-mail: tum@tumnet.com
patent applications, with the purpose of facilitat- port Center Program
ing such procedures for the users. An estimated (TISC).
■ Marcela Gómez Rubio,
discount of 18 percent in official fees is applicable Since the end of 2015,
22 projects have partici- Triana, Uribe & Michelsen,
for the online filings this year.
pated, 11 have been se- Partner,
An online filing platform was also implemented in
the National Direction of Copyrights. lected, seven were already Bogotá, D.C., Colombia
filed as patent applications E-mail: tum@tumnet.com
1.3 Micro, small and medium-sized enterprises have and the other four inven-
an additional 25 percent discount on official fees tions are still in drafting to
for the filings of industrial designs and layout be filed as patents shortly.5
designs for integrated circuit applications and the
petitions of the patentability exam for patents of In fact, TRIANA, URIBE & MICHELSEN’s team,
invention and utility models. through its partner Fernando Triana accepted by WIPO
to be part of the legal advisors offered by the program
It is necessary to note that the fees for the filing of in Colombia, advised a natural person with the drafting
patent applications have been reduced since 2013. In of the patent application, the application was then filed
2012, the filing fee for a patent application was USD and the firm handled the prosecution of the patent ap-
$205.00, and in 2013 the fee was USD $174.00. The plication without any charge for professional fees. The
big decrease was in 2016 when the rate was reduced only expenses taken on by the inventor relates to the
to USD $28.00, and in 2017 the rate is still quite low official fees, which have had significant discounts as
at USD $31.00. previously noted.
1.4 In addition, SIC is part of several programs to en- 2. Strengthening of Colciencias, which through
courage STI such as: Law No. 1286 of 2009 is the National Admin-
• Technology and Innovation Support Center Pro- istrative Department of Science, Technology
gram (hereinafter TISC), which comes from WIPO and Innovation, having its own budget, and ex-
to facilitate access to information and technolo- ecuting public policies for the promotion of sci-
gy services. Currently, these centers are located ence, technology and innovation including the
in Bogotá, Palmira, Barranquilla, Ibagué, Neiva, alliance with diverse sectors to promote areas
Quibdó, Medellín, Pereira, Popayán, Cali, Cartage- of knowledge that are essential to the develop-
na, Bucaramanga, Rionegro and Manizales. During ment of the country. Currently, Colciencias is
2016, 3,909 consultations on Industrial Property leading the following programs:
were handled, 305 projects were identified as eli- • Patents Brigade, began in the third quarter of 2015
gible for protection, and 143 patent applications, with the purpose of finding innovation projects
four industrial design applications and 344 trade- and co-financing the protection of such projects
marks were filed through this program.4 as patent applications, mainly working through
• The Inventor Assistance Program (hereinafter IAP), universities, research centers, technology devel-
which is a project that comes from WIPO and WEF opment centers, companies and independent in-
(the World Economic Forum), has the purpose of ventors. However, it only operates in five cities
putting in contact inventors and small business- (Bogotá, Medellín, Cali, Barranquilla and Bucara-
es with limited financial resources with attor- manga), therefore, it was necessary to carry out

4. Figures taken from the TISC report for the year 2016
which was provided by the CIGEPI. 5. Figures submitted by the CIGEPI.

204 les Nouvelles


Patent And SMEs In Colombia
an operation covering the national territory, which the public sector, 44.53 percent came from the private
is intended to be covered by the Strategy National sector and 1.80 percent came from international re-
Convention for the Protection of Inventions. sources, increasing the investment in the head of the
• National Strategy for Protection of Inventions, be- private sector, since in 2006 the average investment
ing a program led by Colciencias, SIC and INNpul- was 41.93 percent, a figure that has been progressively
sa Colombia (Business Growth Management Unit increasing until 2016 with an investment percentage
of the National Government, created in February of 53.22 percent.
2012 to promote entrepreneurship, innovation In addition, if we focus on R&D activities, while in
and productivity). The purpose is to increase the 2006 the private sector investment was calculated at
number of patent applications in the country, with 41.93 percent, the figures increased to 53.22 percent
the main attraction of financing up to 90 percent in 2016, however, a statistic is not found that allows
of the total costs of the patent application. In the us to determine how much of that private investment
first phase, 29 patent applications will be filed be- corresponds to small, medium or large companies.
fore SIC in the first half of 2017, and in the sec- Speaking to one of the legal advisors of the Colom-
ond phase, they intend to cooperate with at least bian Association of Micro, Small and Medium Enter-
36 additional patent applications.6 prises in Bogotá (ACOPI), Mr. Pedro Alarcón, said that
The public policies will be measured in 2019, to the insight from the association is that the small and
analyze their effectiveness from 2014 to 2018, how- medium enterprises do not know the System of Indus-
ever, please note what the statistics show us up to trial Property yet; the sector just until now is giving
this moment. importance to the trademarks and in general speaking
According to information available in the SIC,7 in to distinctive signs, and concerning innovation, this
2008 the number of patent applications was 2,031 of matter is seen as a something only achievable for large
which 125 were filed by residents, while 1,906 were companies. In fact, according to the experience of this
filed by non-residents, which means that only six per- entity, they do not receive doubts or concerns about
cent of applications were filed by Colombian residents. technology or innovation issues that their partners
In 2016, the number of patent applications was take to the association to receive guidance.
2,2038 of which 545 were filed by residents and 1,658 In addition, small and medium enterprises struggle
were filed by non-residents. In other words, the per- every day to meet with all the regulations imposed to
centage of patents filed by residents was 25 percent, have formalized businesses and to see how their prod-
which shows an increase in the participation of res- ucts and/or services can be sold, therefore, they don’t
idents in the Industrial Property System, concerning have the time to even think about innovation.
patent applications. Such an increase, of course, has The aforementioned allows us to conclude that even
been possible due to the measures taken by the Gov- when there are public policies, and indeed measures,
ernment to promote the knowledge and the use of the that have been taken to create a consciousness about
System of Industrial Property, including the increase of the importance of innovation for entrepreneurs and in
investing in STI. general for the citizens, for now, it seems that small
In 2006, the investment in STI as a percentage of and medium enterprises are still far from receiving the
GDP was 0.401 percent, a figure that timidly grew year message since many of them still ignore the Industrial
after year until it eventually reached 0.711 percent by Property System, and do not even consider what kind
2016. The investment in research and development, as of technology is available in the relevant sector and
a percentage of GDP, was slightly increasing by 0.149 much less are in a position to innovate since they are
percent per year and reached 0.271 percent in 2016. dealing with the urgent things of each day, putting
After reviewing the origin of the investments with- aside important things like innovation as key not just
in the period 2006–2016,9 53.67 percent came from for expanding but even for maintaining the businesses
in the market.
Therefore, the pedagogical activities have not yet
6. Figures included in the statement of the Director of properly reached the SMEs, detecting that there still
Colciencias, Mr. Alejando Olaya, available at https://www. exists a lack of knowledge and dissemination about the
innpulsacolombia.com/es/entrada/en-marcha-segunda-fase-de-la- Industrial Property System, and that entrepreneurs in-
estrategia-nacional-para-proteccion-de-invenciones. deed learn about all the programs developed for STI
7. Statistics from OCyT (Colombian Observatory of Science and and its benefits, without ignoring the efforts that have
Technology,) http://ocyt.org.co/es-es/InformeAnualIndicadores. been made to-date, but unfortunately such programs
8. Statistics from SIC, http://www.sic.gov.co/sites/default/ are not being effectively used, namely by small and me-
files/files/Propiedad%20Industrial/Estadisticas/PATENTES-2016- dium-sized enterprises. ■
Ver-2017-01-14.pdf.
9. Statistics from OCyT (Colombian Observatory of Science and Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
Technology,) http://ocyt.org.co/es-es/InformeAnualIndicadores. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009345

September 2017 205


Patent And SMEs In Mexico

Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Mexico


By Roxana Aispuro and Hector Chagoya

About SMEs in Mexico occupied population and generate incomes equivalent

S
mall and Medium Enterprises (SMEs) have par- to 52 percent of the gross domestic product (GDP).
ticular importance in the Mexican economy. Mexican SMEs, of
This is not only because of their contribution course have available the ■ Karla Roxana Aispuro Castro,
to economic growth, but also their potential for jobs Intellectual Property sys- Becerril, Coca & Becerril, S.C.,
creation and innovation. SMEs generally represent a tem at large in Mexico,
vehicle to boost regional and local economic develop- where the relevant author- IP Value Extraction Engineer,
ment in Mexico. ities such as the Mexican México City, Mexico
The status of SMEs is defined in Mexico by law, par- Institute of Industrial Prop- E-mail: kaispuro@bcb.com.mx
ticularly in the Law for the Development of Competi- erty (IMPI, by its Spanish
acronym), the National ■ Hector Elias Chagoya Cortes,
tiveness of the Micro, Small and Medium Enterprises of
2002. According to this law, a small and medium-sized Institute for Copyrights Becerril, Coca & Becerril, S.C.,
enterprise is defined according to the number of em- (INDAUTOR, by its Span- Partner,
ployees as one that as: ish acronym), the National México City, Mexico
Service for the Inspection
• Up to 250 employees for enterprises focusing on and Certification of Seeds, E-mail: hchagoya@bcb.com.mx
industrial activities, or and even an Intellectual
• Up to 100 employees for enterprises focusing on Property Specialized Bench at the Federal Court for Ad-
commercial or service activities ministrative Justice, together conform a suitable system
In addition, under the rules of the Economy Sec- for intellectual property prosecution and enforcement.
retariat for the recognition of SMEs for government However, the awareness that the use of and respect to
benefits specifically directed to them, enterprises are intellectual property rights will enhance their competi-
classified as follows according to their size in employ- tiveness and business standing still needs to enhance.
ees and amount of sales. See Table 1. Furthermore, even when the SMEs to be enhanced
According to the National Institute of Statistics and are the base of Mexican economy, often they do not
Geography in Mexico (INEGI, by its Spanish acronym) have the management and financial resources neces-
SMEs represent approximately 80 percent of all com- sary for them to develop in a full way, particularly when
panies in Mexico. They employ 75.4 percent of the it comes to their innovation capacity and intellectual

Table 1. Enterprises Classified According To Their Size In Employees


And Amount Of Sales
Micro Enterprise Small Enterprise Medium Enterprise

Sector Empl. Sales1 MCC2 Empl. Sales1 MCC2 Empl. Sales1 MCC2

Industry 0-10 ≤ $4 4.6 11-50 $4-$100 95 51-250 $100-$250 250

Commerce 0-10 ≤ $4 4.6 11-30 $4-$100 93 31-100 $100-$250 235

Services 0-10 ≤ $4 4.6 11-50 $4-$100 95 51-100 $100-$250 235

1. Annual Sales in Millions of Mexican Pesos (MXN)


2. Maximum Combined Cap (MCC)=(Employees)x0.1+(Sales)x0.9

206 les Nouvelles


Patent And SMEs In Mexico
property (IP) protection strategies as the investment developing information for SMEs. The IMPI, togeth-
community in Mexico does not consider intellectual er with the Secretariat of Economy in Mexico, have
property as a key asset when investing in SMEs. developed a database (the Database of Patent Technol-
SMEs innovation in Mexico is not technology driven ogies for SMEs, PYMETEC, by its Spanish acronym)
but driven by marketing strategies. This is why it is not that helps SMEs to identify those technologies that are
surprising that trademarks are the most widely used public domain in Mexico. This is made by identifying
intellectual property right among the SMEs, because if an international patent application under the Patent
of the basic need of identification in the market from Cooperation Treaty (PCT) has been filed in Mexico at
competitors, the franchising model is one of the pre- the national stage, and to determine if said application
ferred mechanisms for growth amongst SMEs, and also can be considered as free to use in the country. This
because the dynamics for domain names leads many information is useful for the SMEs because they can
times to the need of having a trademark in order to define their technology strategy based on what is al-
defend a domain name as webpages are of the essence ready developed by third parties and what is lawfully
for marketing and increasingly for distribution and in- available for use in Mexico.
ternet sales. Trademarks are registered before IMPI and The financial aids for innovation in SMEs are han-
constitute the only industrial property right where the dled by two different entities as explained below:
majority of the rights are owned by Mexican residents. For Scientific and Technology projects, the National
On the technology side, information is scarce and, Council for Science and Technology in Mexico (CONA-
unfortunately, patents are not the best indicator of in- CyT, by its Spanish acronym) is the institution in charge
novation activities because of a lack of patenting cul- of promoting the research and development activities
ture amongst Mexican companies, even for the larger among the enterprises and institutions in Mexico.
corporations. One of the sources of information of Since its creation, CONACyT has been the main in-
innovation activities in Mexico is an informatics plat- stitution in Mexico that provides economic support to
form and database that identifies and contains relevant people both physically and morally, as long as they have
information about entities that, among their activities, the RENIECyT registry, in order to develop innovative
conduct R&D. The National Registry of Technological processes, products or services. Every year CONACyT
and Scientific Institutions and Companies (RENIECyT, publishes several calls for grants, addressed mainly to
by its Spanish acronym) identifies companies, research SMEs, in order to receive projects requesting money
centers, public administration dependencies, natural not only to develop an innovation but also to protect
persons, not-for-profit private institutions and higher the knowledge resulting from the projects submitted.
education institutions. Among the companies with RE- In fact, the projects that consider the protection of IP
NIECyT registry, 48.4 percent are considered SMEs. generated during the activities of the project are now-
Nevertheless, no information about IP protection and adays the most supported by these calls.
innovation activities in these SMEs can be found easily This is possibly one of the main drivers for growth in
but only for those that receive government funding for the number of patents of Mexican residents in recent
R&D projects. years, because before year 2006, intellectual property
Government Policies Promoting Use of Intel- rights were not eligible as expense for use of the funds
lectual Property by SMEs granted by CONACyT.
Even though there is not much available informa- It should be considered that CONACyT is an insti-
tion related to IP protection or innovation activities of tution with national reach and its calls for grants can
SMEs in Mexico, the Government has implemented be exploited by entities all over the country. However,
several programs to promote the creation and use of CONACyT also works closely with the governments of
the IP as an essential tool for SMEs’ growth. the Mexican states to develop programs focused in one
IMPI is the entity in charge of the registration of pat- specific region or State in Mexico, along with a local
ents, utility models, industrial designs and all kinds of authority that mirrors CONACyT functions at a State
trademarks; while INDAUTOR is in charge of the reg- level (State Councils for Science and Technology). One
istration of the copyrights. Both entities are linked and example of these programs is the State Council of Sci-
validated by several governmental institutions which ence and Technology of the State of Jalisco (COECyT-
try to promote the IP protection among the SMEs. As Jal, by its Spanish acronym) that supports only projects
for SNICS, because in addition to the function of pros- from institutions located in the State of Jalisco.
ecuting and granting Breeder’s Rights for plant varie- Regarding commercial innovation and scale-up of
ties this entity has a seed certification function, SNICS projects that have been financed already by CONACyT,
is able to reach agricultural SMEs relatively easy to the National Institute of the Entrepreneur (INADEM,
promote Breeder’s Rights Titles. by its Spanish acronym) is a public organism decentral-
One of the strategies of the Mexican government is ized from the Secretariat of Economy created in 2013

September 2017 207


Patent And SMEs In Mexico
specially to provide economic supports to the entre- implies a long-term planning vision, and the skill to
preneurs and SMEs in Mexico. INADEM develops na- include the investment for obtaining IP in the available
tional programs and publishes calls for grants for pro- government funding programs, for which such invest-
jects mainly focused in further stages of development ments are increasingly eligible for the use of such gov-
of technology projects, with the aim of promoting in- ernment funding.
novative processes or services within SMEs. IP Culture Challenges for Mexican SMEs
In fact, the focus of the Economy Secretariat and IN- Many SMEs are initially founded by young entrepre-
ADEM regarding IP-based models and grants for SMEs neurs coming out of universities and colleges; com-
is franchising, which in fact is a very important and munities where intellectual property has been misun-
dynamic market in Mexico and a driver for both, trade- derstood as a tool designed for “big companies” that
mark registrations and business models. want to keep control over markets and that have much
Intellectual Property as a Tool for Attracting money for controlling innovation and jeopardizing the
Investors and Enhancing Competitiveness creative processes required for innovation. This senti-
in SMEs ment is stronger in communities related to informa-
For Mexican SMEs IP protection should be very im- tion technologies where open-source and freeware are
portant to attract investors. Since they typically do not seen almost as the only viable form of open innovation,
have enough money to increase their productivity and and feel that knowledge should be freely shared with-
installed capacity for expansion, they need to search out constraints and therefore tend not to respect IP
for investors who have the economic capability to sup- rights themselves.
port them. However, the awareness of SME executives This vision is so deeply present among Mexican en-
and Mexican investors about IP protection as a tool trepreneurs that when they face the reality of plagia-
for enhancing competitiveness is scarce but increas- rism, unlawful competition and sense the need to have
ing because of the international awareness and the some protection to their competitive advantages, in-
franchising model popularity, which requires at least a cluding the challenges imposed by fierce competition
trademark register. from companies far larger than theirs, they are still
There are, however, a lot of opportunities for SMEs' hesitant to use in full the intellectual property system,
growth through the use of IP based on the popularity and typically they have limited or wrong information
of the franchising model. about its effects, use and management.
One of them is the understanding of the concept Therefore, the main challenge is to educate young
of IP portfolios. Current franchises can enhance their entrepreneurs on the role of IP as a tool that protects
ability to enforce their rights against underperform- the economically and organizationally weakest, through
ing or non-ethical franchisees by adding to their IP the power that IP represents, in favour of creators and
portfolio trademarks for specific products or services inventors, not only in Mexico but worldwide. The edu-
provided in the franchise, industrial designs and copy- cation must comprise both, the role of IP as a protection
rights for trade-dress elements such as unique designs tool and the importance of the tool for open innovation
of furniture, gadgets or fixtures, architectural works, communities and even open-source business models,
and, of course, patents and utility models for specific where respect for intellectual property, regardless of
operational processes or machinery that is relevant for whether it represents or not a source of revenue, is of
the operation of the franchise. the essence for the growth of the business.
Trade secrets management is also an area of oppor- Conclusion
tunity for Mexican SMEs, considering that the better SMEs are very important for the Mexican economy
managed the information, the better opportunity for and public policy and IP authorities have been focusing
enforcement, and typically the management of confid- efforts towards the promotion of intellectual property
ential information is limited to confidentiality clauses in rights as a tool for enhanced competitiveness, particu-
the franchising contract, but not related to the system- larly for SMEs. The impact of franchising as a business
atic management of the information in order to ensure model is very good for the intellectual property system
that a trade secret remains secret within the franchise. and has promoted awareness of IP rights in general.
SMEs in Mexico are not taking advantage of IP for The main challenge is towards a better understanding
international growth through licensing. Mexican com- of the effects and benefits of the IP system and a more
panies are missing the opportunity that implies obtain- intensive use of other IP tools beyond trademarks. ■
ing intellectual property in other jurisdictions where
there is a market but they do not have enough invest- Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
ment resources to grow. Particularly for patents this https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009397

208 les Nouvelles


Patent And SMEs In Peru

Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Peru


By Renzo Scavia

The Patent Awareness of SMEs in Peru technical advice to

I
n general, Peruvian legal and individual persons are the inventors. ■ Renzo Scavia,
not aware of the importance of patents at the desired Another aspect Scavia & Scavia Abogados,
level. Furthermore, most of the Peruvian companies of the policy in-
which seek protection of their patents before INDECO- volves a legal fo- Principal,
PI,1 the national authority competent for patent matters, cus having Law Lima, Perú
are not SMEs. N° 30309, “Law E-mail: rscavia@scavialaw.com
which promotes
According to a report issued by the Intelligence Unit of scientific research,
The Economist, national patent applications in our coun- technological de-
try show a “weak level of innovation.”2 Furthermore, velopment and innovation” as the main example. Such
such a report concludes that “the number of national pat- a law grants tax incentives to companies which invest in re-
ent applications have increased since 2007, but the vast search, even if the specific corporate purpose of companies
majority of them pertain to non-resident applicants.”3 does not comprise scientific research.
One of the reasons for the low level of innovation in How do SMEs Use Patents?
our country is that scientific research has not had ad- Firstly, it shall be clarified that 72 percent of the na-
equate economical support from the government. In tional patent applications are individual persons, 24 per-
fact, the Ministry of Economy states that our country cent are companies (big and SMES) and four percent are
has “only 0.24 full-time researchers per each 1,000 par- represented by universities and other entities.6
ticipants of the economically active population.”4 Anoth- Additionally, according to a ranking published in 2015,
er reason is the low investment in scientific research the individual and legal persons which have filed most
education making our human capital not even aware of patent applications for inventions in our country be-
the importance of patent protection. Some public insti- tween 1973 and 2004 are Grupo Famesa, an explosives
tutions that received money from the Ministry of Econo- factory (26 applications), Pontificia Universidad Catolica
my returned US $450 million dollars between 2004 and del Perú (PUCP) and Universidad Nacional Mayor de
2012, because they lacked scientists and had no way to San Marcos, two of the most important universities in
invest the money.5 Peru with 25 and 17 applications, respectively, and Al-
The Government Policy to Promote Patent for fredo Valois Chincha Pajuelo, an independent researcher
SMEs with 21 applications.7
The government has a twofold policy to promote in- What this ranking shows is that SMEs do not use their
novation in SMEs. One of them is the creation of edu- own inventions. They may probably obtain inventions
through licenses granted by independent researchers,
cational programs and platforms to foster the culture of but we do not have official data to affirm this.
innovation, such as Patente Rápida, Innovate Perú, Em-
prendedor Peruano: Oportunidades Para El Crecimiento SMEs and Patent Litigation
Empresarial, Start-Up Perú, and Pattem, etc. Statistics of the competent authority indicate that
Patente Rápida is one of the most important education- only 0.56 percent of the proceedings commenced be-
fore the Peruvian Patent Office between May 2014 and
al programs for inventors. This program allows inventors April 2015 corresponds to 14 infringement actions.
to learn the legal framework of patent proceedings, to Moreover, seven nullity actions initiated in the same
know the formal requirements of the proceedings and period represent only 0.28 percent.8 These are global
to adequately prepare the technical document to avoid statistics meaning that said proceedings are commenced
office actions and delays. This program also renders either by national or non-resident companies.
Such previously referred infringement and nullity
1. INDECOPI stands for The National Institute for the Defense actions are brought by pharmaceutical laboratories,
of Free Competition and the Protection of Intellectual Property. i.e., big companies. ■
2. Intelligence Unit of The Economist. “Situación de los
Derechos de Propiedad Intelectual en el Peru.” http://posgrado. Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
pucp.edu.pe/wp-content/uploads/2014/10/EIU-MS-Peru-IP- https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009404
Environment-2014.pdf. 6.. “Historia de las Patentes e Invenciones en el Perú.”
3. Intelligence Unit of The Economist, 12. INDECOPI, (2015) 32. https://www.indecopi.gob.pe/documents/
4. “Ciencia en Perú: ¿Cuáles son las causas de su baja 20791/203175/01.-Historiadelaspatentesweb.pdf/ee9da00e-ae8d-
performance y cómo impulsarla?” Universia News http://noticias. 4fbf-a451-8b103dbc0d01.
universia.edu.pe/ciencia-nn-tt/noticia/2014/07/25/1101155/ciencia- 7. Ibid., 32.
peru-cuales-causas-baja-performance-como-impulsarla.html. 8. INDECOPI’s Monthly Report, (April 2015) 40. https://www.
5. Universia News. indecopi.gob.pe/documents/20182/143803/Abril2015.pdf.

June 2017 209


A South African Perspective

SMEs — A South African Perspective


By Madelein Kleyn

Introduction namely; standard industrial sector and subsector clas-

S
outh Africa does not invest in procuring accurate sification, size of class, equivalent of paid employees,
statistics on small businesses in South Africa, turnover and asset value—excluding fixed property.
making it difficult to find the exact number of Government Support of SME Initiatives
companies that operate in the country. SEDA (Small En- Government raised the status of its small business
terprise Development Agency) issued a broad statistical initiatives with the creation, in 2014, of a department
overview of the SMEs of South Africa1 in January 2016 dedicated to this cause, i.e. the Department of Small
Business Development (DSBD). Public enti-
Table 1: Statistical Overview of SMEs ties that report to the Minister of DSBD are
the Small Enterprise Development Agency
KEY INDICATORS Q2 2015 (SEDA) established in terms of the National
Number of SMEs 2,251,821 Small Enterprise Act, 1996 (No.102 of 1996),
667,433
as amended in 2004 and the Small Enterprise
Number of formal SMEs
Finance Agency (SEFA) established in terms
Number of informal SMEs 1,497,860
of Section 3(d) of the Industrial Development
SME owners as % of total employment 14% Corporation Act, 1940 (No. 22 of 1940) (IDC
% operating in trade & accommodation 43% Act).
% operating in community services 14% SEDA provides non-financial business de-
% operating in construction 13% velopment and support services to small
12%
enterprises in partnership with other role
% operating in financial & business services
players in the small business development
% contribution to GVA* 21%
environment. SEDA’s mission is to develop,
% black owned formal SMEs 34% support and promote small enterprises to
% operated by income group < R30k pa 7% ensure their growth and sustainability. SEFA
Source: BER, StatsSA *GDP before taxes and subsidies
provides access to developmental finance to
survivalist, micro, small and medium busi-
and presented the following indicators. nesses throughout South Africa.
According to the Banking Association of South Af- Further Government initiatives are provided through
rica2 in South Africa, small and medium-sized enter- Act No 102 of 1996 in the establishment of the Na-
prises make up 91 percent of formalised businesses, tional Small Business Council, the Ntsika Enterprise
provide employment to about 60 percent of the labour Promotion Agency (Ntsika), as well as Khula Enterprise
force and total economic output accounts for roughly Finance which is charged with helping small and medi-
34 percent of GDP. um-sized enterprises secure finance. This is primarily
Although there is no exact definition for SMEs, the through the provision of security on behalf of small
National Small Business Act (102 of 1996) defined small businesses to commercial banks, retail financial insti-
business as medium, small, very small and micro enter- tutions, specialist funds and joint ventures, as well as
prises based on certain characteristics. The Act aims to offering loans through partner intermediaries.
provide for the “establishment of the Advisory Body and Main Supporting Entities
the Enterprise Promotion Agency; to provide guidelines There are many agencies and corporate entities that
for organs of State to promote small business in the provide guidance and financial grants to SMEs and en-
Republic; and to provide for matters incidental there- trepreneurs, for the relevance of technology protec-
to.” The National Small Business Amendment Act (26 of tion and commercialisation of intellectual property.
2003) aims to update and further define business ac- Specific mention is to be made of THRIP and TIA.
cording to five categories established by the original act, Technology and Human Resources for Indus-
try Programme (THRIP)
1. http://www.seda.org.za/Publications/Publications/The%20
Small,%20Medium%20and%20Micro%20Enterprise%20 THRIP is a project between DTI3 (Department of
Sector%20of%20South%20Africa%20Commissioned%20by%20
Seda.pdf.
2. http://www.banking.org.za/what-we-do/sme. 3. http://www.thedti.gov.za.

210 les Nouvelles


A South African Perspective
Trade and Industry) and the NRF (National Research business, such as Business Finance, SMME Laws &
Foundation). This scheme was implemented to in- Regulations, Marketing, Technology, Leadership and
crease the high level technical skills for the industry Human Capital. They have an online audience reach in
and improve South Africa’s competitive edge through South Africa, Kenya, United States, India and United
the development of technology. This grant is primarily Kingdom. SME Toolkit7 aids SMEs to start-up business-
aimed at engineering graduates. The THRIP fund ca- es, advise on funding and include information on IP
pacity is R150 million. THRIP aims to develop these protection mechanisms and means for SMEs.8
SMEs into large companies, expanding the networks The National Intellectual Property Manage-
and allowing these SMEs access to scientific expertise, ment Office (NIPMO)
equipment and facilities at partner research entities. NIPMO9 is an initiative
The Technology Innovation Agency (TIA) 4
of the Department of Sci- ■ Dr. Madelein Kleyn,
TIA is a national public entity related to the DTI. It ence and Technology, re- Oro Agri International Ltd;
serves as the key institutional intervention to bridge sponsible for implement- University of Stellenbosch,
the innovation chasm between research and devel- ing the Intellectual Prop-
opment from higher education institutions, science erty Rights from Publicly Director; Legal and Intel-
councils, public entities, and private sector, and com- Financed Research and lectual Property & Research
mercialisation. In terms of the Technology Innovation Development Act (No. 51 Fellow of the Anton Mostert
Act (Act 26 of 2008). The object of TIA is to support of 2008). NIPMO ensures Chair of Intellectual Property,
the State in stimulating and intensifying technological that intellectual property University of Stellenbosch,
innovation to improve economic growth and the qual- emanating from publicly
ity of life of all South Africans by developing and ex- financed research and de- South Africa,
ploiting technological innovations. TIA has available a velopment is identified, Cape Town, South Africa
Patent Support Fund5 which is intended to provide the protected, utilized and E-mail: mkleyn@oroagri.com
support mechanisms to assist entrepreneurs and SMEs commercialized. NIPMO
with the protection of their IP. The Patent Support operates through three
Fund is intended to support the filing, prosecution and directorates: Regulatory and Compliance (registering
maintenance of patents and/or patent applications in IP created from use of public funds, approving certain
respect to technological innovations emanating from IP transactions, and enforcing the Government’s IP
entrepreneurs and SMEs. The support is specifically rights), Advisory and Support (providing legal advice,
intended for funding new or improved technologies and capacity building support in technology transfer),
which TIA can progress from the applied research and Fund Management (providing funds for IP protec-
stage to commercial deployment. tion).
Other industrial and financial sectors that support The IPR Act provided a new basis for the manage-
SMEs through grants, free advice, infrastructure or ment and commercialization of IP created through
networks include the Banking Association of South universities and research institutions. It also allowed
Africa. Apart from financial and financial risk assist- access to SMEs and Black Economic Empowered en-
ance, it also facilitates stakeholder engagement of tities, previously not enabled to exploit IP opportuni-
among others the Gauteng Dept. of Economic Devel- ties. Between 2010 and 2016, over 1,000 invention
opment, Industrial Development Corporation, Khula, disclosures were filed under the new system by South
Small Enterprise Development Agency, South African African institutions, of which seven percent had been
Micro-Finance Apex Fund, Development Finance In- commercialized by the end of this period. Examples
stitutions, Department of Trade and Industry, and include systems to calibrate TB testing equipment, im-
provides Research and Knowledge Management. proving the accuracy of diagnosis to tens of thousands
SME South Africa6 is a daily online news portal that of individuals, and 3D printing/rapid prototyping meth-
provides strategic business content to enable SMMEs ods, for the creation of replacement facial features for
to unlock their growth potential. They offer a one-stop individuals who not have access to medical funds and
shop for SMME-related issues in Africa, providing busi- who are undergoing reconstructive facial surgery.
ness owners with practical insights, advice and tools NIPMO provided support to 30 institutions and
that are essential to running a profitable business. Our regional offices, offering R 106 M of support (which
editorial content focuses on key aspects of running a led to the creation of over 100 specialised technology

4. http://www.tia.org.za. 7. http://southafrica.smetoolkit.org/sa/en.
5. http://www.tia.org.za/Funding-Procedure/intellectual-property- 8. http://southafrica.smetoolkit.org/sa/en/category/2964/
(ip)-fund). Intellectual-Property.
6. http://www.smesouthafrica.co.za. 9. http://nipmo.org.za.

September 2017 211


A South African Perspective
The Innovation Hub’s mission is to promote the socio-economic development
and competitiveness of Gauteng through innovation by:

Creating new business Ensuring human capacity Enhancing the synergy


opportunities and adding value to development of critical skills between industry, government
mature companies in technology matching industry needs in and academic and research
and knowledge-based sectors priority sectors institutions

Fostering entrepreneurship Providing attractive spaces for


and incubating new innovative emerging knowledge companies
companies

Source: http://www.theinnovationhub.com

transfer posts), and provided 24 institutions with R 83 cy. There was no specific mention made of preferent
M of fund management support for IP protection.10 treatment of SMEs, the focus was mainly on the phar-
The Innovation Hub maceutical industry and the introduction of patent
The Innovation Hub was established by the Gauteng examination and pre- and post-grant oppositions. The
Provincial Government in 2001 and creates initiatives public submissions process into the IP Consultative
that support innovation and enterprise development. Framework has created a platform for IP stakeholders
It is in Tshwane, South Africa’s executive capital, and to once again call for IP law reform in South Africa.
has become a regional centre of innovation and knowl- The DTI has not released a list of submitters nor the
edge creation. submissions themselves. After considering substantial
comments received11 from various sectors in industry,
Legislative Framework IP professionals and institutions such as the SAIIPL and
The Patents Act 57 of 1978 as amended, governs LES, the new IP policy based on the IP Consultative
the protection of inventions, the Companies and Intel- Framework has been submitted to Cabinet in the first
lectual Property Commission (CIPC) is the custodian quarter of 2017. No further announcement has been
of all new patent applications that are filed within the made to-date.
Republic of South Africa. Other than that an individ- SME and Patenting
ual can privately file a provisional patent application
(only a patent attorney can file a non-provisional pat- The securing of Intellectual Property (IP) is an im-
ent application and assist in drafting the patent spec- portant aspect in the economic growth strategy for the
ification), no specific mention is made of any form of knowledge economy. According to a study done by SA-
SME and there is no differentiation in filing or filing ICA12, patent propensity is lower in SMEs than in large
fee status that is derived from entity status. For quite organisations (or companies) and patenting as means
some time there has been international criticism on for appropriation is of less importance among SMEs.
the South African patent system and specifically on the There are, however, numerous examples of small busi-
access to medicine protected by patents. In answer to nesses that have sufficient talent to produce significant
this, the South African National Draft IP Policy was and bankable innovations and this is confirmed by the
published in 2013. It included specific reference to patent statistics for South African inventions as shown
BEE and SME enterprises in the context of the trade- below. SAICA’s research shows that a substantial por-
marks system with focus on licensing of franchising tion of technology innovations and inventions emanat-
activities. The Draft Policy was severely and widely ing from the South African public, and in particular,
criticised and in 2016 the DTI issued the National IP entrepreneurs and SMEs have not made their way to
Consultative Framework which replaced the IP Poli- the marketplace because of a lack of support mecha-
nisms, largely financial, for patent protection.

10. Kerry Faul, “Innovation Insights: Entrepreneurial


Ecosystems from Around the World—A South African 11. https://www.ip-watch.org/2016/10/20/south-african-ip-
Perspective,” 6th International Conference on Managing framework-comments-action-seen-early-2017.
Intellectual Property Rights in Universities, (2016) https://view. 12. See SAICA (South African Institute of Chartered
officeapps.live.com/op/view.aspx?src=http%3A%2F%2Fwww. accountants –2014/5/6 SMME INSIGHT REPORTS) and BER
ipconference.boun.edu.tr%2Fipconference-2016%2Fpresentatio “The Small Medium and Micro Enterprise Sector of South
n%2FP6%2Fkerry_faul.pptx; accessed April 2017. Africa,” commissioned by SEDA Note 1 of 2016.

212 les Nouvelles


A South African Perspective
South African research group, World Wide Worx has
released its 2016 State of South African Small Busi- Figure 1. Total Patents Per Entity Type
ness report, showing what small business leaders in
the country are facing in the country. On the question
on whether SMEs embrace technology, two-thirds of 300
small business owners said that technology was very
250
important or essential for their business operations,

Number of Patents
with smart devices and apps making their lives and the 200
running of their businesses easier.
It is evident from the statistics that since the imple- 150
mentation of the IP Rights Act in 2010 the patenting
activity of individuals, research institutions and univer- 100
sities has increased significantly.
50
The data13 presented below covers a period of five
years’ patent application activity of the top 100 appli- 0
cants in South Africa which is determined based on 10 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
or more patent applications per year. There appears to Universities & Research SMEs and Individuals Large Companies
Institutions
be a higher number of patents being filed by SMEs on
total number of patents. On average per year per entity
type, SMEs file less patents than corporations per entity. Figure 2. Average Patent Activity
The data sample in Figure 1 reflects the activity of 17 Re- Per Entity
search institutions, 60 SMEs or individual inventors and
27 large corporations of the top 100 patent applicants in 9
South Africa. This indicates that SMEs are aware of the 8
importance of protecting intellectual property. 7
SME and IP Litigation 6
Legal advice and litigation is expensive. Entrepre- 5
neurs and start-ups are generally unable to afford legal
4
services. Most of the IP litigation of SMEs focus on
3
trademarks rather than patents. Figure 3 is a sum-
2
mary of judgements14 for the period 2010 to 2016.
1
The scope of this article does not allow for further
investigation if the data and the graph below is merely 0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
an indicator that SMEs do participate in litigation but
due to budget constraints the activity is lower than for Universities & Research SMEs and Individuals Large Companies
Institutions
larger corporations.
In Conclusion
SMEs in South Africa play an important role in the Figure 3. IP Litigation
growth of the South African economy. Government Year of Judgement 2010-2016
is supporting SME initiatives and their innovation
through various organisations and agencies that fund 70
start-ups and facilitate filing, prosecuting and commer- 60
cialization of inventions. SMEs are generally informed
about IP and the importance of protecting intellectual 50
property but do not always have the funds to ensure 40
freedom to operate, protect and enforce their IP rights.
30
The enactment of the IPR Act in 2010 brought about
a significant changed in the South African IP landscape 20
and it is foreseen that the newly awaited IP Policy will 10
promote patenting by SMEs and freedom to operate
although the initial focus appears to be on the pharma- 0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
ceutical industry. ■
Total Nr of cases SME
13. Patent statistics provided courtesy of Adams & Adams
Attorneys http://www.adamsadams.com. Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
14. Extracted from BIP and Juta Law reports https://juta.co.za. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009379

September 2017 213


Conclusion—A Different Perspective

Conclusion—A Different Perspective:


Do Not Focus Only On SMEs,
Make The Knowledge Economy Work
By Patrick Terroir

A
ll policies in favor of SMEs have actually lim- Make the Patent a Robust International Title
ited effectiveness and have hardly produced In order to adapt the patent system to the reality
any significant change in the behavior of this of innovation, it is in particular necessary that SMEs
category of enterprises. So, while it may be necessary no longer run up against long and complex proce-
to strengthen and improve them, we may consider dures, which are too different from one country to
whether it is not necessary to transform the “patent another and give no assurance as to the validity of
economy” itself. the issued patents.
As we have seen, the SMEs consider that the cur- The objectives to be attained are therefore to make
rent system is too costly for a limited effectiveness the patent procedures more accessible (less expensive,
and is neither accessible nor useful to them. At a time less complex on the international level) and above all
when innovation is at the heart of our economies, to make the patent a robust title (e.g. non-contestable
where SMEs play an increasing role in this regard and after a certain period of time) at the level of the world
intangible assets represent the core of business value, economy. This, of course, presupposes that patent of-
this defiance toward patenting challenges the entire fices meet equivalent quality standards and that com-
IP system. munication between them improves—which should
Indeed, how can we imagine seriously that the SMEs not be a technical problem in these times of digitaliza-
will invest time and money—which are extremely rare tion, big data and AI (artificial intelligence).
for them—to obtain (after three years at best) a patent Make the Patent a Recognized Industrial and
title that will not be considered as an asset in their Business Asset
balance sheet, which cannot be used to obtain a loan
(except recently in a few countries in Asia) and that SMEs will only be interested in patents if they be-
cannot be simply and securely sold or licensed. come a recognized asset in their balance sheet. It
should not be about “accounting contortions” but
In such a context it seems highly urgent, to safe- putting patents in the same position as other tangible
guard the IP system and truly change the situation of assets and to recognize them as the result of the R&D
the SMEs, to open up an international reflection, as it investment made.
was done in the past for the TRIPS or the PCT agree-
ments. This reflection should focus on the status and The patents have several characteristics that should
the role of the patents as regards the main innovat- contribute to account them as fully-fledged assets: they
ive actors (SMEs and PROs) and take account of the are issued through procedures carried out by inde-
new technologies and the transformation of the global pendent entities, they are standardized (incompletely)
value chain. at the international level, they are accessible in official
databases… The remaining (and essential) question is
In particular, two main objectives should be attained the one about the value of this intangible asset, which
to make the patent system in line with the needs of could not be solved without the setting up of a true
the SMEs: “economy” of knowledge.
• To recognize the patent as a true asset and a pro- Rebalance the Function of Patents and Create
duction input; and a True Economy of Knowledge and Intangible
• To create the full economic mechanisms necessary Assets
to the knowledge economy. The patent can no longer be considered only as a
However, the means of achieving these objectives mean “to prevent a third party”1 and to sue infringers,
are diverse and they often involve some profound even if the defense of property is a necessary condi-
transformations which call for in-depth reflection. To
open them, this conclusion aims to present the most
important ones. 1. TRIPS agreement, article 28.

214 les Nouvelles


Conclusion—A Different Perspective
tion for the working of the IPR system. The process do not accept patents as collateral—which handicaps
of innovation is changing and it rests more and more precisely the SMEs as they rely mostly on their intan-
on cooperation, exchanges and associations between gible assets. As noted in a recent report,2 “Global li-
inventions coming from everywhere. The patents censing activity leaves no doubt that IP is in fact an
are the most suitable vehicle to become the needed immensely valuable, highly tradable and very portable
technology transfer instrument and the valuation and asset class. Current practice simply reflects the fact
transaction asset. that the buyers of IP are
The aim should be to complete the setting up of the immature.”
■ Patrick Terroir,
knowledge economy by giving to every enterprises the When banks will con-
Innovation Legal;
possibility to produce, finance, acquire, exchange, sell sider that patents are ac-
and license intangible assets on the basis of instru- ceptable as collateral, we Sciences Po Paris,
ments and values recognized and accepted. As there may think that it will no Lawyer, Professor,
is no value without a “market” process, the objective longer be necessary to put Paris, France
should be to create the conditions for an easy access, a in place heavy programs E-mail: pterroir@gmail.com
transparent (predictable) and secure frame for patent to convince SMEs of the
exchanges - as such mechanisms exist in all other areas utility of patents. But it
of the economy. The “patent market” fulfills part of is also likely that, without a strong support of public
these functions already between large companies; the money—as is the case in Asia—it will not be possible
goal is to extend it to the SMEs and to get a “regulated to consider the patent as collateral until the previous
market” for intangibles—as it exists (under different objective (create a true patent economy) has not been
forms) in the other domains of the economy. achieved. ■
The conditions and the ways for the implementa- These ending reflections are for the opening of the
tion of such economic market mechanisms are not the debate, and they could be the topic of future issues of
topic of this issue but they can make the subject of a les Nouvelles.
later one.
Make the Patent a Financing Tool Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
The lack of recognition of the value of patents, in the https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009410
absence of an organized IP market, means that banks

2. “Banking on IP? The Role of Intellectual Property and


Intangible Assets in Facilitating Business Finance,” UK IPO,
(2013).

September 2017 215


The Exhaustion Theory

The Exhaustion Theory Is Not Yet Exhausted:


Part 4
By Erik Verbraeken

I
t has been quite some time that I have not updated 2013) regarding the exhaustion of combination claims
the “Exhaustion Theory Is Not Yet Exhausted” through the sale of individual components, (6) FSEL vs.
series. In the latest edition stemming from March Verum (District Court Amsterdam, The Netherlands,
2014, the focus was laid on several U.S. decisions March 10, 2017) regarding the intricacies of the appli-
where the IP right holder contested that he had con- cation of the exhaustion theory in a software context.
sented to a “first sale” of the product as a result of 1. Preliminary Comments
which his IP rights were to be considered as exhausted,
Before examining the four above quoted court deci-
and where as a consequence of such deemed consent
sions, it may be helpful to summarize, in several bul-
the purchaser considered itself free to use or resell
let points, the applicable law on the exhaustion of IP
that product without further restraint from patent law.
rights as the same has been developed by the Europe-
This part 4 of the “Exhaustion Theory Is Not Yet Ex- an Court of Justice since its first milestone decision
hausted” series will have a closer look at some recent of 1974 in the Sterling Drug/Winthrop vs. Centrafarm
national court decisions from within the European Un- parallel trade dispute where it had to reconcile on the
ion where, for several reasons, the IP right holder con- one hand the fundamental principle of the free move-
sidered that he had never authorized the products to ment of goods within the European Union (as laid
be “put into circulation for the first time” (considered down in article 34 of the EU Treaty) and on the other
as the specific subject-matter of an IP rights by the Eu- hand the protection of industrial property rights as a
ropean Court of Justice as defined in Sterling Drugs vs. legitimate exception to such free movement of goods
Centrafarm (C15/74) for patent rights and Winthrop (as laid down in article 36 of the EU Treaty).
vs. Centrafarm (C16/74) for trademark rights). Such
• The specific subject matter of the industrial prop-
authorization or consent is an essential condition for
erty that may be protected under article 36 is the
the application of the exhaustion theory and the ab-
guarantee that the patentee, to reward the crea-
sence of such consent will entitle the IP right holder to
tive effort of the inventor, has the exclusive right
pursue the protection of his rights. Consequently, legal
to use an invention with a view to manufacturing
proceedings were opened against either the trader or
industrial products and putting them into circu-
the purchaser of those goods by the IP right holder
contending that he never authorized the sale. lation for the first time, either directly or by the
grant of licences to third parties, as well as the
Whether or not consent was given by the IP right right to oppose infringements (Sterling Drug/Win-
holder arose in the following cases: (1) Xerox vs. Impro throp vs. Centrafarm, judgment of October 31,
Europe (Court of Appeals Brussels, Belgium, decision 1974 in cases 15 and 16/74).
of October 20, 2015) regarding the consequences of
a contractual reservation of property on the supply of • A derogation from the principle of the free move-
ink cartridges to wholesalers and end-customers, (2) ment of goods is not justified where the product
Living Tower vs. DKW (District Court The Hague, The has been put onto the market in a legal manner,
Netherlands, decision of February 8, 2017) regarding by the patentee himself or with his consent, in the
the consequences of a non-authorized sale by a joint Member State from which it has been imported,
design right owner, (3) Piloxing vs. California Classic in particular in the case of a proprietor of parallel
Cars (District Court The Hague, The Netherlands, de- patents (Sterling Drug / Winthrop vs. Centrafarm,
cision of March 16, 2016) regarding the consequences judgment of October 31, 1974 in cases 15 and
of a letter of intent where goods were made available to 16/74).
the (potential) licensee, (4) Flynn Pharma vs. Drugsrus • The right of first placing a product on the market
(High Court London, England, decision of October 6, enables the patentee, by allowing him a monopoly
2015, confirmed by Court of Appeal, decision of April in exploiting his product, to obtain the reward for
6, 2017) regarding the consequences of the transfer his creative effort without, however, guaranteeing
of a UK marketing authorization coupled with a con- that he will obtain such a reward in all circum-
tract manufacturing arrangement, (5) A vs. B (District stances (Merck vs. Stephar, judgment of July 14,
Court Dusseldorf, Germany, decision of December 12, 1981 in case C-187/80).

216 les Nouvelles


The Exhaustion Theory
• The consent that is implicit in an assignment of occasions by the European Court itself, including, in-
rights is not the consent required for application ter alia, in the above mentioned cases of Peak Holding
of the doctrine of exhaustion of rights. For trade- vs. Axolin-Elinor and Christian Dior vs. COPAD, but
marks, consent implies that the owner of the right also in the cases of Greenstar vs. Hustin and Goossens,
in the importing Member State must, directly or judgment of October 20, 2011 in case C-140/10 and
indirectly, be able to determine the products to Oracle vs. UsedSoft, judgment of July 3, 2012 in case
which the trade mark may be affixed in the ex- C 128/11. In these cases,
porting Member State and to control their qual- the court recognized that ■ Erik Verbraeken,
ity. That power is lost if, by assignment, control contractual reservations IFP Energies, Nouvelles,
over the trade mark is surrendered to a third party to sales transactions do
having no economic link with the assignor (Ideal Associate Director,
not prevent exhaustion
Standard vs. IHT, judgment of June 22, 1994 in from occurring, to the Contracts Division,
case C-9/93). extent that the transac- Rueil-Malmaison, France
• A sale which allows the proprietor to realise the tion allows the proprietor E-mail: erik.verbraeken@
economic value of his IP rights exhausts the exclu- to realise the economic ifpen.org
sive rights thereof, more particularly the right to value of his intellectu-
prohibit the acquiring third party from reselling al property right. Regarding reservations to licensing
the goods (Peak Holding vs. Axolin-Elinor, judg- transactions, although in principle exhaustion of the
ment of November 30, 2004 in case 16/03). intellectual property right occurs when the goods are
• Exhaustion occurs solely by virtue of the putting put on the market by a person with economic links
on the market in the EU by the proprietor. Any to the proprietor (e.g. a licensee), nevertheless the li-
stipulation, in the act of sale effecting the first cense agreement does not constitute the absolute and
putting on the market in the EEA, of territorial re- unconditional consent of the proprietor of the intellec-
strictions on the right to resell the goods concerns tual property right to the licensee putting the goods
only the relations between the parties to that act bearing the trade mark on the market; therefore, there
(Peak Holding vs. Axolin-Elinor, judgment of No- may be situations where the holder of the rights can-
vember 30, 2004 in case 16/03). not be deemed to have consented to the introduction
of the product on the market, e.g. when a directive of
• Where a licensee puts goods bearing the mark on
the European Union explicitly reserves certain rights to
the market he must, as a rule, be considered to be
the intellectual property owner (e.g. the right to pre-
doing so with the consent of the proprietor of the
trade mark; but the license agreement does not vent damage to the reputation of the mark recognized
constitute the absolute and unconditional consent under the Trademark Directive) or where the violation
of the proprietor of the trade mark to the licensee bears on one of the essential features of the intellectu-
putting the goods bearing the trade mark on the al property right (although the Court of Justice did not
market (Christian Dior vs. COPAD, judgment of indicate, in the above mentioned Greenstar vs. Hustin
April 23, 2009 in case C-59/08). and Goossens decision, what should be considered as
essential features of the Community plant variety right).
• Various regulations adopted by the European
Council codify the exhaustion rule in applicable This fourth article in the series of “Exhaustion The-
legislation, especially in the area of trademark ory Is Not Yet Exhausted” chronicle will now focus on
law (both the Community Trademark Regulation some national court decisions that have had to deal
and the Trademarks Directive provide for the ex- with non-consent arguments of the intellectual prop-
haustion of the trademark when the trademarked erty owner regarding the impact of such non-consent
goods have been released within the EU market by on the exhaustion of rights following the introduction
the proprietor or with his consent). of the product on the market.
A key element in the decisions of the European 2. Xerox vs. Impro Europe (Court of Appeal Brus-
Court of Justice for the application of the exhaustion sels, Belgium, Decision of October 20, 2015)
theory is the consent by the proprietor of the intellec- Impro Europe BVBA has set up a trade in unused
tual property right to the introduction of the product printing accessories such as toners, cassettes and cart-
on the marketplace. According to the Court’s ruling ridges. It sources those articles from companies that,
in the Christian Dior vs. COPAD case, consent is tan- following their initial order for such products from the
tamount to the proprietor’s renunciation of his exclu- original manufacturer, find themselves confronted with
sive right and constitutes the decisive factor in the ex- overstock or remainder items. Impro Europe acquires
tinction of that right. The extent to which contractual such unused overstock from such companies and then
reservations of rights can be considered sufficient to resells those products mainly over the internet.
deny consent have already been dealt with at several
Some of those products that are offered for sale by

September 2017 217


The Exhaustion Theory
Impro Europe originate from Xerox Corporation. The cision (where the Court underscored that the license
particular feature at stake in this case was that Xerox agreement does not constitute the absolute and uncon-
supplied the consumables to its customers under two ditional consent of the proprietor of the trade mark to
different formats: (1) supplies made under a mainten- the licensee putting the goods bearing the trade mark
ance agreement, where the client pays for the machine on the market). Unlike the facts in the Peak Holding
under a “price per page” formula, and where consum- decision where the goods were effectively introduced
ables will then be made available by Xerox following to the marketplace through a sales transaction (despite
an order from the customer based on the individual the breach by the intermediate vendor of the resale
machine’s meter configuration, (2) supplies made in restrictions that were agreed with the supplier and
the absence of a maintenance services agreement, trademark owner), in the Christian Dior case as well
where Xerox sells the ink cartridges or cassettes on a as in the present case, the goods were not sold by the
“per unit” basis to the customer. The products ordered proprietor to his own clients but made available to the
under the different formats, although identical in com- other party, either through a license to manufacture
position, can be distinguished by their different pack- and sell the goods under the trademark of the propri-
aging and different purchase channels. Xerox did not etor in the Christian Dior case or through a consign-
contest that its IP rights were effectively exhausted for ment structure where the client orders the cartridges
all products that it had sold to customers under the for future use with his printing machine as part of his
second format; however, Xerox contended that it had maintenance agreement with the vendor (and owner
never “put into circulation” the products supplied un- of the trademark) in the present case.
der the first format because of its reservation of title The Brussels Court of Appeal’s decision can also be
to the goods and the contractual obligation to return distinguished from the Oracle vs. UsedSoft decision of
unused cartridges to Xerox without compensation. the European Court of Justice (decision of July 3, 2012
The Brussels Court of Appeal concurred with Xerox in case C-128/11) where the significant difference was
(and overruled the decision of the lower court who that although the transaction was contractually labeled
had retained that, despite these elements of fact, the as a license, for all economic purposes the transaction
IP rights of Xerox to the trademarked products were qualified as a sale. “The making available by Oracle of
exhausted). The Court considered that the products a copy of its computer program and the conclusion of a
were merely made available to the customer as part of user licence agreement for that copy (were) intended
the maintenance agreement, and were not sold to the to make the copy usable by the customer, permanently,
customer as evidenced by the contractual restrictions in return for payment of a fee designed to enable the
quoted above. Under these circumstances, the goods copyright holder to obtain a remuneration correspond-
cannot be said to have been “put on the market … ing to the economic value of the copy of the work of
by the proprietor or with his consent” which would which it is the proprietor.” In that light, the argument
have been a ground for exhaustion under article 9 of of Impro that the goods were already paid for through
the Community Trademark Regulation for the goods the maintenance fee could have been accepted if the
in question. end-user was indeed authorized to keep the unused
Impro claimed that irrespective of the contrac- cartridges after they were ordered. However, because
tual reservations made in the agreements, the Xerox the cartridges were provided under a pro rata pricing
products were effectively acquired by its clients be- formula based on the annual printing volume with a
cause they were paid for through the maintenance fee, price per page, it can be said that the unused cartridges
but this argument was dismissed by the court. Like- were not paid for—they were left in consignment with
wise, the argument that these contractual reservations the customer for future use and only during such fu-
were merely a “legal loophole” in order to shield the ture use could the consumables be considered to have
market from parallel trade was rejected. been paid for under the maintenance agreement.
This case provides a good illustration of how the 3. Flynn Pharma Ltd. vs. Drugsrus Ltd.
particular details surrounding the various commercial (High Court London, UK, Decision of Octo-
transactions within the supply chain for the products ber 6, 2015, Confirmed by Court of Appeal
will ultimately determine the navigational direction to on April 6, 2017)
either the “absolute” exhaustion rule defined by the This case dealt with the transfer of a marketing au-
European Court of Justice in the Peak Holding decision thorization in the UK for a drug called phenytoin so-
(where the Court concluded that exhaustion takes dium by Pfizer to Flynn Pharma. This transfer came
place irrespective of any contractual reservations that about because the patent rights of Pfizer had expired
“concern only the relations between the parties to that and was no longer considered essential in the product
act”) or the “relative” exhaustion rule defined by the line of that company. In order to avoid the product
European Court of Justice in the Christian Dior de- from disappearing altogether from the UK market,

218 les Nouvelles


The Exhaustion Theory
Flynn Pharma took over the marketing authorization The High Court however declines to follow this log-
rights. Various agreements were concluded between ic; instead of proceeding to a “look alike” exercise in
the parties in this respect, including an outsourcing order to qualify the relationship between the parties,
agreement where Flynn Pharma contracted the man- the court should rather look whether the trademark
ufacture and the supply of the drug out to Pfizer from owner uses its intellectual property right in order to
its German facilities. Pfizer manufactured the products get a second bite of the cherry such that the preven-
ordered by Flynn Pharma in accordance with the speci- tion of imports constitutes a disguised restriction on
fications provided by the latter. Flynn Pharma retained trade. Hence, the question is whether there is any-
the marketing responsibility under the UK regulatory thing arising from the agreements where Flynn Phar-
requirements. ma retains the right to exercise control over the qual-
Under this set-up, Pfizer continued to manufacture ity of Epanutin sold in other Member States and the
and sell the phenytoin sodium in all countries except product sold as Phenytoin Sodium Flynn in the UK.
the UK under its own trade mark Epanutin. Flynn The answer to that question should be negative: the
Pharma sold the same product, as manufactured by fact that Flynn Pharma chooses to acquire its supplies
Pfizer under the outsourcing agreement, as Phenytoin of Phenytoin Sodium Flynn from the same manufactur-
Sodium Flynn in the UK. For all practical purposes, the er as makes Epanutin for other Member States, does
respective capsules were the same: they looked the not mean that the same entity is responsible for the
same, they had the same size and colour, even down to quality of the two products for the purpose of applying
the word “Epanutin” that figured on the capsule itself the free movement provisions. What matters is wheth-
commercialized by Flynn Pharma. er there is anything in the suite of agreements which
At a certain moment, Drugsrus started to import gives Flynn Pharma power to control the quality of the
into the UK the Epanutin drug that it purchased in Epanutin supplied by Pfizer in other Member States or
Germany, and that it rebranded as Phenytoin Sodium anything that entitles Pfizer to control the specification
Flynn; one of the reasons for doing so was directly re- of the Phenytoin Sodium Flynn supplied in the UK.
lated to the specific situation of the UK prescription Such control is not granted to either company over the
pharmaceutical market, where pharmacies are obliged other’s products. Flynn Pharma’s trademark rights in
to supply to the patient the drug that is prescribed by the name Phenytoin Sodium Flynn are therefore not
the doctor in accordance with the prescription form; in exhausted in respect of packages of Epanutin placed
order to access the market for “directed” prescription on the market in other Member States by the very
forms (i.e. where the doctor does not merely provide a same company that manufactures in parallel, on order
generic reference e.g. phenytoin sodium but a specific of Flynn Pharma, a corresponding pharmaceutical drug
reference like, in this case, Phenytoin Sodium Flynn), for the UK market.
Drugsrus therefore decided to proceed to rebranding. The Court of Appeal confirmed the High Court deci-
Against the opposition of Flynn Pharma regarding sion, agreeing that Flynn had no control over the Epa-
these rebranding practices, Drugsrus argued that be- nutin sold by Pfizer which Drugsrus sought to import,
cause of the connection between Flynn Pharma and and that sales of the imported product were likely to
Pfizer, the partnership set up by the parties and struc- affect the guarantee of origin (e.g. because any prod-
tured through several agreements amongst which an uct defect might negatively reflect on the Flynn trade-
asset sale agreement, an exclusive supply agreement, mark for which Flynn could not be held accountable).
a quality agreement and a limited trademark license Therefore, although the products in question were
agreement from Pfizer to Flynn Pharma, the arrange- exactly the same, Flynn Pharma’s consent to the out-
ment resembles an exclusive distributor relationship sourcing of the manufacturing of the Epanutin drugs
between the parties. Since the phenytoin sodium cap- by Pfizer for the purpose of future commercializa-
sules that were sold on the German market by Pfizer tion of the same under the Phenytoin Sodium Flynn
under the Epanutin trademark are strictly identical to trademark in the UK, did not equate to a consent by
the phenytoin sodium capsules supplied by Pfizer to Flynn Pharma to the introduction of the same drug
Flynn Pharma under the same name (figuring as an independently by Pfizer in Germany. In parallel with
identicode on the capsule shell) where only the pack- the Court’s ruling in Ideal Standard: the consent im-
aging material has been branded with the new name plicit in any outsourcing operation is not the consent
“Phenytoin Sodium Flynn,” the rule formulated by the required for the application of the exhaustion theory.
European Court of Justice in the Ideal Standard case A parallel can also be drawn with the Sebago case (Se-
bago vs. GB-UNIC, judgment of July 1, 1999 in case
should apply that exhaustion occurs when control is in
the hands of a single body, e.g. the manufacturer in the C-173/98) where the question was raised whether the
case of products marketed by the distributor. consent of the trademark proprietor to the marketing
in the EU of one batch of goods would exhaust the

September 2017 219


The Exhaustion Theory
rights conferred by the trade mark as regards the mar- tion agreement where Piloxing had agreed to buy back
keting of other batches of these goods coming from the merchandise articles. On this basis, the District
outside the EU if they are identical. The Court an- Court that at the time of sale, Piloxing had acquired
swered in the negative: for there to be consent within the property of these articles, where the Dutch com-
the meaning of the exhaustion theory, such consent pany was merely holding these articles for Piloxing.
must relate to each individual item of the product in Consequently, the sale of these articles to CCC was
respect of which exhaustion is pleaded. In the absence made without the consent of Piloxing, as legal owner
of any control of Flynn Pharma regarding the conditions of these articles, implying that Piloxing had not ex-
of manufacturing and sales of the Epanutin drug by hausted its trademark right.
Pfizer in those countries where Pfizer continues to be It is probably this breach of the transaction agreement
an active player, Flynn Pharma cannot be said to have that triggered the decision of the District Court, since
consented to those drugs being sold on those markets, this transaction agreement ended the license of the
and it therefore stop their imports within the UK, even Dutch company regarding the trademarked products.
if those Epanutin drugs are identical to those sold by The case would probably have been more complex if
Flynn Pharma under the Phenytoin Sodium Flynn label. such transaction agreement had not existed, in which
Drugsrus has submitted a petition for permission to event the Dutch company would have found itself in
appeal to the Supreme Court. the hybrid situation where on the hand, it had received
4. Piloxing vs. California Classic Cars (Dis- the consent from the trademark owner to proceed to
trict Court Rotterdam, The Netherlands, De- the manufacture of the merchandise articles, but on
cision of March 16, 2016) the other hand, the parties were still in negotiation
Piloxing is a leading fitness company and owner of about the set-up of their business relationship. Would
the Piloxing trademark. In the course of negotiations this preliminary consent of the trademark owner re-
with a Dutch company that showed its interest in the garding the manufacture of these products have been
exploitation of the Piloxing fitness concept, Piloxing sufficient to consider that the subsequent sale of these
authorized the company to commence the manufac- products exhausted the trademark right of Piloxing?
ture of merchandise bearing the Piloxing trademark. There are some reasons for doubt, since the European
However, ultimately the negotiations broke down, and Court mentioned in the Christian Dior vs. COPAD case
in order to reduce its losses, the Dutch company sold that “where a licensee puts goods bearing the mark on
the merchandise to a third party, California Classic the market he must, as a rule, be considered to be do-
Cars (CCC), a company that (in spite of its name) is ing so with the consent of the proprietor of the trade
also involved in “fitness experience.” Subsequently, mark” and that “the proprietor of the trade mark can-
Piloxing introduces a cease-and-desist order against not plead that the contract was wrongly implement-
CCC in order to prohibit further use and sales of these ed in order to invoke, in respect of the licensee, the
merchandise articles bearing the Piloxing trademark. rights conferred on him by the trade mark.” Despite
CCC opposes that the products have been legitimately the qualifying comment from the European Court
acquired by it with the consent of Piloxing who had au- that “the licence agreement does not constitute the
thorized the manufacture of the merchandise articles. absolute and unconditional consent of the proprietor
Despite the preliminary consent that Piloxing had of the trade mark to the licensee putting the goods
given to the Dutch company to have those merchan- bearing the trade mark on the market,” the reserved
dise articles manufactured with the purpose for future rights of the trademark owner were considered limit-
introduction on the marketplace as part of a business ed to those that are listed as legitimate restrictions in
relationship that was still in the course of negotiation, the Trademark Directive, all of which are related to a
the District Court considers that this consent on be- contravention by the licensee of “any provision in his
half of Piloxing (that it qualifies as a license) is not suf- licensing contract”—which was non-existent in this
ficient in the sense that Piloxing would have, through case (the license was implied). An implied license may
this consent, exhausted its trademark right. The mere eventually be considered to amount to deemed con-
granting of a license to have the products manufac- sent, where the licensor bears ultimately the business
tured does not (yet) extend to an introduction of those risk that the licensee exceeds the scope of his license.
products on the marketplace under the control of the Cf. the comment of the European Court in the Peak
trademark owner through which the latter has realized Holding case that any contractual limitations in a sales
the economic value of its trademark right, in accord- context concerns only the relations between the par-
ance with the requirements of exhaustion laid down ties to that act; this appears to be the case likewise in a
in the Peak Holding decision of the European Court. licensing context, unless the breach of the contractual
At the time that the sale was made to CCC, Piloxing limitation relates to one of the grounds recognized in
and the Dutch company had entered into a transac- the Trademark Directive.

220 les Nouvelles


The Exhaustion Theory
5. Tower Living vs. De Kleine Winst (District are incorporated in servers. Although the defendant
Court The Hague, The Netherlands, Decision had regularly acquired the two distinctive components
of February 8, 2017) from its suppliers, who were authorized by the paten-
The infringement claim in this procedure was tee to bring these products on the market, respective-
brought at the initiative of the distributor, Tower Liv- ly (in accordance with the terms of the license agree-
ing, with respect to a furniture collection named “the ment) as semiconductors and processors, neither the
Daan collection”; the latter was developed by two indi- suppliers nor the defendant had acquired the right to
viduals, A and B, who held a joint copyright on the col- combine the two components in order to form a sys-
lection. In accordance with the exploitation agreement tem as claimed in the patent.
between A and B, A had granted the right to distribute The court considered that in general, there was no
the copyrighted collection in The Netherlands to Tower reason to hold that the sale of a component protec-
Living. The latter complained to A that a competitor, ted by one patent should lead to the exhaustion of the
De Kleine Winst, commercialized the same collection rights conferred to by a different patent which is dir-
in The Netherlands; it appeared that De Kleine Winst ected to an overall device comprising that component.
had purchased the Daan furniture items from the other Although the data memories and the memory control-
co-owner, B, who (in accordance with the exploitation lers at issue could reasonably only be used for building
agreement) had sold the furniture in the European the patented memory system, the fact that the sup-
Union without having the corresponding contractual pliers’ licenses extended only to the use of the com-
rights to do so, since the commercialization rights for ponents as semiconductors respectively processors
the European Union were vested in A. Therefore, A prevented that an implied consent to use the system
contended that its copyright in the Daan collection in claim of the patent-in-suit could be found. The court
The Netherlands was not exhausted by the prior sale recognized one possible exception though, although it
that was realized by B, to the extent that B had disreg- did not further elaborate on this possibility in the ab-
arded the territorial restrictions to which it had agreed sence of its application to the case at hand: where the
in the exploitation agreement. In addition, even in the inventive concept of the respective patents is the same
absence of this agreement, under Dutch law the ex- and is substantially embodied in the components, the
ploitation of a jointly owned copyright can only occur consent of the patent holder to bring the components
with the consent of the joint owners. In the absence of on the market might lead to the implied consent of the
an authorization by A to the sale of the furniture items patent holder regarding the combination patent.
by B to De Kleine Winst, A could not be said to have 7. FSEL vs. Verum (District Court Amster-
consented to the introduction of those products on the dam, The Netherlands, Decision of March 10,
marketplace by B. 2013)
The District Court ruled (not unsurprisingly) in fa- Although the court only expressed a provisory ruling
vor of De Kleine Winst, on the basis of the case law in this fast-track procedure for a preliminary injunction,
developed by the European Court of Justice in the it demonstrates the difficulties of exercising intellec-
Ideal Standard decision: the exhaustion of rights ap- tual property rights in an IT environment. The dispute
plies where the owner of the IP right in the importing occurred as a result of a sale of assets by the judicial
State and the owner of the IP right in the exporting administrator following the insolvency of the original
State are the same or where, even if they are separate licensee; the assets (including the software licenses)
persons, they are economically linked. Joint owners of are transferred to a new so-called “restart” company.
an IP right are considered to be economically linked
The software in question was an analysis tool named
and to exercise a unitary control over their right; con-
sequently, the introduction of the products on the mar- “FDR” in order to scan computer programs before their
ketplace by one co-owner can be opposed to the other implementation. The original licensee (“Verum 1”) re-
co-owner who has given deemed consent thereto. The ceived the right to distribute, disclose and modify the
limitation of rights agreed in the exploitation agree- FDR software for such purposes from the proprietor,
ment between the co-owners cannot be opposed to a FSEL, through a so-called Server License on the one
third party under the rules of privity of contract. hand (unlimited user right in consideration of a lump
sum payment) and Client Access Licenses (through
6. A vs. B (District Court Dusseldorf, Germany, which customers of Verum 1 could proceed to the
Decision of December 12, 2013) analysis of their computer programs) on the other hand
In a case that resembles the U.S. Quanta vs. LG sit- (1-to-1 licenses entitling FSEL to a “per-user” royalty).
uation, the patent held by the plaintiff held a claim Verum 1 developed its own software code, Dezyne,
directed to a data memory system having two compo- that authorized its customers to make an internet net-
nents, a data memory and a memory controller, that work connection with FDR that was stored on one of

September 2017 221


The Exhaustion Theory
the servers of Verum 1. A total of 129 Client Access ruling of the European Court of Justice in the Peak
Licenses were commercialized by Verum 1. Holding case that any restrictions on the right to re-
Following the bankruptcy of Verum 1, a corporate re- sell the goods concerns only the relations between the
structuring was initiated that resulted in the creation of parties to that act and cannot therefore be opposed
Verum 2, to whom the above license rights were then to third parties has thus found a favorable echo in the
transferred. FSEL subsequently summoned Verum 2 decision of the Dutch District Court regarding the
to cease the use of the software because the license working of the alleged territorial restrictions agreed
rights had been transferred without the authorization between respective co-owners of a copyright—these
of FSEL. Verum 2 considered that FSEL had exhaust- restrictions did not prevent exhaustion to occur as a
ed its copyrights on the software through the grant of result of the first sale made by one of the co-owners
the above (paid-up) licences and that consequently, within the European Union.
Verum 1 had the right to transfer the Server License However, as the list of above national decisions
and the 129 Client Access Licenses to Verum 2. demonstrate, there are still multiple opportunities
The question before the court was the UsedSoft de- available to the IP right holder to circumvent the ap-
cision of the European Court of Justice, where exhaus- plication of the exhaustion theory through “smart
tion was retained in relation with the downloading of contracting,” provided that the IP right holder does
a copy of the software program from the (Oracle) web- not rely on the mere breach of contract terms alone
site server to the individual computer, could be extra- in order to build its argument for a withholding of con-
polated to the present circumstances where the FDR sent in the sense of the exhaustion theory; the IP right
software program was not downloaded but accessed. holder must show an additional objective element that
Because of the fast-track procedure, the court foes not supports his claim that the product was introduced on
provide a straightforward ruling, relying on the com- the market without his consent. Such objective ele-
plexity of the questions before it. The request for a ments can be:
preliminary injunction is refused, however, the court • The nature of the contract as was the case in Xerox
notices that although the intellectual property rights vs. Impro and Flynn Pharma vs. Drugsrus;
of FSEL with respect to the Server License are prob- • The cessation of the commercial relationship as
ably exhausted (which was not contested by FSEL), the was the case in Piloxing vs. CCC;
same is not necessarily true for the 129 Client Access • The limited license rights combined with different
Licences. A procedure on the merits will have to de- patent claims as was the case in A vs. B;
termine if and to what extent the rights of FSEL have
been exhausted or not for this last category. • The limited user access rights with respect to spe-
cific software licenses as was argued in FSEL vs.
8. Conclusion Verum;
Although there still remains some uncertainty where • The existence of legislative grounds for opposition
the red line between exhaustion and non-exhaustion as the European Court of Justice recognized in
of rights resides, the absence of consent in the sense COPAD vs. Christian Dior.
of the absence of authorization as a result of the breach
of the contractual terms of agreement between the IP The next article in this series will address some of
right holder and his counterpart is not, by itself, suffi- the recent national court decisions regarding another
cient to avoid exhaustion. In most cases, the fact that complicated aspect in the relationship between the
the IP right holder has entered into an agreement with free movement of goods and the protection of intellec-
another party that is the contractual foundation for tual property rights within the European Union: who
the introduction of his products on the marketplace has the burden of proof to demonstrate that the goods
will represent as least an implied consent—the terms have been introduced with or without the consent of
of the agreement through which the IP right holder the IP Right holder? ■
has authorized the other party to commercialize the Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
said products do not, in principle, contribute to the https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009415
qualification of the consent provided by the IP right
holder, to the extent that a violation of such terms
would negate the consent of the IP right holder. The

222 les Nouvelles


Licensing Standards Essential Patents

Licensing Standards Essential Patents


By Joseph A. Alfred

Introduction The fourth generation in-


A. Standards and Patents troduced the convergence of

S
wired and wireless. “4G is an ■ Joseph A. Alfred,
teve Jobs and Apple introduced the iPhone, the
first smartphone, in January 2007, and a waiting all IP-based integrated system Alfred Consulting LLC,
world was introduced to incredible volume both will be capable to provide 100 Founder & General Manager,
in standards and in patents. Global data usage now Mbps for high mobility and Fredericksburg, VA, USA
exceeds one billion gigabytes a month and half of all one Gbps for low mobility,
with end-to-end QoS (quality E-mail: joe@
mobile devices are smartphones. The growth in mo-
bile standards from the first generation in the 1980s to of service) and high security. alfred-consulting.com
the development of the fifth generation today has wit- The user services include IP
nessed an amazing array of technology, one release will telephony, ultra-broadband
capture the public interest only to be replaced within Internet access, gaming services and High Definition
a short span of time by a new technology, more useful, Television (HDTV) streamed multimedia.”2
more ubiquitous than the last one. The key question Work on 2G standards involved more than 886,000
for discussion in today’s world of standards and patents person hours from 200 companies from 13 countries
is how to license the standards essential patents for over 15 years. Work on 4G standards “…is ongoing
the smartphone at a fair price. and has already taken more than nine years, and more
Let’s begin this discussion with standards. The first than a million person hours from participants from
generation of standards included devices such as the more than 320 companies.”3
pager, the cordless telephone and private mobile ra- Work on patents kept pace. Baron and Pohlmann
dio and systems such as the Advanced Mobile Phone found 180,215 declarations of standards essential
System (AMPS) and the Total Access Communication patents (SEPs) essential to ETSI mobile standards in
System (TACS.)1 According to Tondare, Panchal and September 2015. Table 1 shows the number of patent
Kushnure “AMPS was introduced in 1982 providing declarations as it grew year by year.4
bandwidth of 40MHz, offering 832 channels for sub-
scribers with data rate of 10Kbps.” This step forward
required better batteries as did all the generations of Table. 1 Patent Declarations
mobile devices.
Number Of ETSI Patent Declarations
The second generation introduced new techniques, Year
Essential To Mobile Standards
Time Division Multiple Access (TDMA), Code Division
1980 20,000
Multiple Access (CDMA) and roaming. The most widely
used protocol was the Global System for Mobile Com- 2002 40,000
munication (GSM.) The United States used TDMA and 2005 60,000
CDMA while most of the world adopted GSM. 2007 80,000
The third generation increased speed and capac- 2009 100,000
ity adding services such as streaming, mobile inter- 2011 120,000
net access, video calling and internet protocol televi-
2012 140,000
sion (IPTV.) The Third Generation Partnership Project
(3GPP), a standards group with representation from 2013 160,000
standards organizations in the United States, Europe, 2014 180,000
China, Japan and Korea developed the International
Mobile Telecommunications-2000 (IMT-2000) with 2. Ibid.
data rates of 200 kbps. CDMA developed an overlay 3. Boston Consulting Group, “The Mobile Revolution, Jan
that allowed data rates over 300 kbps. 2015,” quoted in les Nouvelles, An Experienced-Based Look At
The Licensing Practices That Drive The Cellular Communications
1. Tondare, S.D. Panchal and D.T. Kushnure, “Evolutionary Industry, Blecker, Sanchez & Stasik (Dec 2016).
Steps From 1G to 4.5G, S.M.,” International Journal of Advanced 4. Justin Baron and Tim Pohlmann, Mapping Standards to
Research in Computer and Communication Engineering, Vol. 3, Patents using Databases of Standards-Essential and Systems of
Issue 4, (April 2014). Technological Classification, (September 2015).

September 2017 223


Licensing Standards Essential Patents
The number of standards subject to declared SEPS is Given the volume of smartphone sales, a patent
2,134. The number subject to more than 10 declared owner of a smartphone SEP would certainly find it easy
SEPs is 1,007. The number subject to more than 100 to prove (1) demand for the patented product; because
SEPs is 308. The number subject to more than 1,000 it is covered by standards; (2) absence of acceptable
declared SEPs is 44 and of these 43 are from ETSI. non-infringing substitutes; (3) his manufacturing and
Long Term Evolution (LTE) has the largest number of marketing capability to exploit the demand; (4) the
declarations with 61,831 followed by Universal Mobile amount of profit he would have made. Since sales of
Telecommunication Service (UMTS) with 43,658 and smartphones have been brisk and Apple and Samsung
Universal Terrestrial Radio Access Network UTRAN are the only profitable manufacturers, perhaps unless
with 18,757.5 the complaint was made by Apple or Samsung, this
In 2014, TechIPm found that very few of the patents may be difficult to prove (4). It would be less difficult
claimed as essential to LTE were essential to the Radio to prove (4) for a chip maker.
Access Network (RAN) sections of LTE. There are over Many cases make use of the fifteen Georgia-Pacific
490 sections in the LTE standard. A patent essential Factors to determine reasonable damages.i Fong, Lai
to the LTE standard may or may not be essential to and Liu found, “Using LexisNexus [LexisNexis], we
every device that implements the standard. The RAN have identified cases where judges have referenced
sections of the LTE standard that are included in ev- the Georgia-Pacific case since 1995. There are 96 cases
ery mobile device are less than 70 sections. TechIPm cited this case (Appendix 1). After some manual sort-
found only 447 essential RAN patents compared to ing, we have identified those cases where these factors
the 50,000+ claimed patents essential to the LTE have been discussed (35 cases out of 96, i.e. 36 per-
standard. Assuming this proportion holds there were cent) and included them in our study. This set of cases
roughly 550 patents essential to the RAN sections of was used to determine the inter-relationship between
the LTE standard by September 2015. the various factors and categorise them to have a struc-
B. Back To Case Law tured approach to use the Georgia-Pacific 15 factors.”8
A patent is a negative right to exclude others from Fong et al cite a Durie and Lemley 2010 study that
making, using or selling one’s invention and it includes “…have suggested a structured approach to calculate
the right to license others to make, use or sell it. A pat- reasonable royalties based on the 15 factors cited in
ent is a grant of some privilege, property or authority, Georgia-Pacific case. They suggested that most of the
15 factors essentially answered three questions:
made by the government or sovereign of a country to
one or more individuals.6 In their book, Cases and Ma- 1. What is the marginal contribution of the patented
terials on Patent Law, Martin Adelman and his fellow invention over the prior art?
authors quote White, Patent Litigation: Procedure and 2. How many other inputs were necessary to achieve
Tactics and U.S. statutes. that contribution, and what is their relative value?
To obtain as damages the profits on sales he would have and
made absent the infringement, i.e., the sales made by 3. Is there some concrete evidence suggesting that
the infringer, a patent owner must prove: (1) demand the market has chosen a number different than the
for the patented product, (2) absence of acceptable calculus that results from (1) and (2)?”
non-infringing substitutes, (3) his manufacturing and Fong et al note in their conclusion, “…it has also
marketing capability to exploit the demand, and (4) the been demonstrated the Georgia-Pacific factors can be
amount of profit he would have made. quantified using the Nash bargaining solution. This can
When actual damages, e.g., lost profits, cannot be serve as a guideline for expert witnesses to base their
proved, the patent owner is entitled to a reasonable reasonable royalty calculations on. In addition, the so-
royalty. 35 U.S.C. § 284. A reasonable royalty is an lution can also be used in practical licensing negotia-
amount “which a person, desiring to manufacture tions to guide practitioners.”
and sell a patented article, as a business proposition, C. The Smartphone Royalty Stack
would be willing to pay as a royalty and yet be able to Considering item number two of the Georgia-Pacific
make and sell the patented article, in the market, at factors: “The rates paid by the licensee for the use of
a reasonable profit.” Goodyear Tire and Rubber Co. other patents comparable to the patent-in-suit”, the
v. Overman Cushion Tire Co., 95 F.2d 978 at 984…7 “rates paid” not only vary widely, but use a different
base on which to compare the patents-in-suit. The
question of royalty based on the price of the device in
5. Ibid.
6. Black’s Law Dictionary, sixth edition, (1990) 1,125. 8. Hoi Yan Anna Fong, Yuan Ching Lai, Shang Jyh Liu,
7. Martin J. Adelman, Randall R. Rader, John R. Thomas and Quantified the Georgia-Pacific Factors for Calculating Reasonable
Harold C. Wagner, Cases and Materials on Patent Law, second Rates, Review of Integrative Business & Economics Research, vol.
edition, (2003) 943-944. 2 (2), (2013) 261-275.

224 les Nouvelles


Licensing Standards Essential Patents
which a standard is practiced or royalty based on the patent holders said they would publish their rates and
components that practice the standard is still subject that the combined rate would be a high single digit
to cases in court and license practice in the market. number, that is less than 10 percent. The first seven on
Armstrong, Mueller and Syrett argued that: this list are at 14 percent royalty, so the publication of
The data show that royalty stacking is not merely a rates approach never quite lived up to its billing.
theoretical concern. Indeed, setting aside off-sets I. Standards and GATT—The Global Agreement
such as “payments” made in the form of cross-li- on Tariffs and Trade
censes and patent exhaustion arising from licensed • GATT and WTO—The World Trade Organization
sales by component suppliers, we estimate potential The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
patent royalties in excess of $120 on a hypotheti- is a multilateral agreement regulating international
cal $400 smartphone—which is almost equal to the trade. According to its preamble, its purpose was
cost of device’s components.9 the “substantial reduction of tariffs and other trade
Just using publicly announced royalty rates, Arm- barriers and the elimination of preferences, on a
strong, Mueller and Syrett found: reciprocal and mutually advantageous basis.” It was
negotiated during the United Nations
Table 4. Smartphone Royalty Stacking Conference on Trade and Employment
and was the outcome of the failure of
Company Announced LTE Rate Royalty ($400 Device negotiating governments to create the
Qualcomm 3.25% of device $13.00 International Trade Organization (ITO.)
Motorola 2.25% of device $9.00 GATT was signed by 23 nations in Ge-
Alcatel- Lucent Up to 2% of device $8.00 neva on October 30, 1947 and took
Huawei 1.5% of device $6.00 effect on January 1, 1948. It lasted
Ericsson 1.5% of device $6.00
Nokia 1.5% of device $6.00 until the signature by 123 nations in
Nortel 1% of device $4.00 Marrakesh on April 14, 1994 of the
ZTE 1% of device $4.00 Uruguay Round Agreements, which es-
Siemens 0.8% of device $3.20 tablished the World Trade Organization
Per Unit Sliding-Scale $2.10 per unit (sales
over 10M units) (WTO) on January 1, 1995. The original
Via Licensing Patent Pool Fee Based on Volume
Sisvel Patent Pool 0.99 Euros per device $1.36 GATT text (GATT 1947) is still in effect
Vodafone Free $0.00 under the WTO framework, subject to
TOTAL $54.30
the modifications of GATT 1994.ii
In the table shown above, Armstrong, Mueller and • Purpose of GATT
Syrett identified the companies that have publicly Recognizing that their relations in the field of trade
disclosed royalty rates for their LTE portfolios. For and economic endeavour should be conducted with
each company, they then calculated the royalty that a view to raising standards of living, ensuring full
would be applicable to a $400 device based on the employment and a large and steadily growing vol-
announced rate.10 ume of real income and effective demand, develop-
Nortel filed for bankruptcy and sold their patents to ing the full use of the resources of the world and
the Rockstar Consortium including Apple, Microsoft, expanding the production and exchange of goods…
Ericsson, Sony, and BlackBerry in July 2011. Google • Article VIII—Fees and Formalities Connected with
bought Motorola in May 2012. ZTE joined the Via Li- Importation and Exportation
censing patent pool in October 2012. Rockstar sold
the Nortel patents to RPX in December 2014. Google 1a. All fees and charges of whatever character
joined the Via Licensing patent pool in April 2015. (other than import and export duties and other
Nokia bought Alcatel-Lucent in April 2015. than taxes within the purview of Article III) im-
posed by contracting parties on or in connection
Note that there are two patent pools listed. Usually with importation or exportation shall be limited in
there is only one patent pool per technology so that amount to the approximate cost of services ren-
licensees may gain the benefit of a license from many dered and shall not represent an indirect protec-
companies without stacking the royalty rates—that is tion to domestic products or a taxation of imports
without adding the rates. In the case of LTE, the patent or exports for fiscal purposes.
pools add to the royalty stack. In 2007, the major LTE
4. The provisions of this Article shall extend to fees,
charges, formalities and requirements imposed by
9. Ann Armstrong, Joseph J. Mueller, Timothy D. Syrett,
Wilmer Hale, The Smartphone Royalty Stack: Surveying Royalty
governmental authorities in connection with impor-
Demands for the Components Within Modern Smartphones, tation and exportation, including those relating to:
(2014) 2. (a) consular transactions, such as consular invoices
10. Ibid., (13-14). and certificates; (b) quantitative restrictions; (c) li-

September 2017 225


Licensing Standards Essential Patents
censing; (d) exchange control; (e) statistical services; the Institute of Electrical Electronics Engineers
(f) documents, documentation and certification; (g) (IEEE) and the International Telecommunications
analysis and inspection; and (h) quarantine, sanita- Union (ITU). The standards in this case involve
tion and fumigation.iii wireless communications, commonly known as
• Financial Incentive WiFi—IEEE Wireless Local Area Network (WLAN)
Patents grant exclusive rights that allow owners to called the 802.11 standard and video coding—ITU
benefit from the property they have created, pro- video coding standard called the H.264 standard.
viding a financial incentive for the creation of an Both of these standards incorporate patented tech-
investment in intellectual property, and, in case of nology called standards essential patents—SEPs.
patents, pay associated research and development Thus, in order to practice the standard, it is nec-
costs according to Schroeder and Singer.iv However, essary to obtain a license to these SEPs from the
Levine and Boldrin dispute the research and devel- patent owners.
opment justification. Motorola offered to license its SEPs at what it con-
sidered the RAND rate of 2.25 percent.
Regardless of justification, there is no argument
as to the growing value of intellectual property. In • This letter is to confirm Motorola’s offer to grant
2013, the United States Patent & Trademark Office Microsoft a world-wide non-exclusive license under
approximated that the worth of intellectual prop- Motorola’s portfolio of patents and pending applica-
erty to the U.S. economy is more than US $5 tril- tions having claims that may be or become Essential
lion and creates employment for an estimated 18 Patent Claims subject to a grant back license under
million American people. The value of intellectual 802.11 essential patents of Microsoft…for a com-
property is considered similarly high in other devel- pliant implementation of IEEE 802.11 Standards…
oped nations, such as those in the European Union.v As per Motorola’s standard terms, the royalty is
calculated based on the price of the end product
The question of financial incentive as it applies to (e.g. each Xbox 360 product) and not on component
the licensing rates of standards essential patents is software (e.g. Windows Mobile Software).
therefore a GATT question. Are royalty rates lim-
ited to the approximate cost of services? In particu- • For an Xbox 360 the royalty range is from $3.83
lar, do the services include the practice of product for a $170 Xbox 360 to $7.43 for a $330 Xbox 360.
or service functions not covered by the claims of Since Microsoft sold an average of 11 million Xbox
a patent? Do these services include research and 360s between 2008 and 2014, Motorola was asking
development costs? What base do we use to value for a royalty in the range of $274 million to $572
the royalty rate? Since the international standards million just for the Xbox 360 product.
for smartphones have been adopted and practiced • Motorola offered to license its SEPs at what it
by so many companies and organizations that their considered the RAND rate of 2.25 percent of the
use is considered mandatory, what premium may a price of Microsoft’s Windows 7 and higher H.264
licensing entity reasonably charge? These are key products.
questions in licensing today. The U.S. District Court used six factors in its analy-
• The Case Law Surrounding Device Licensing sis (1.) The court introduced the parties and their rela-
tionship to one another, (2.) The court provided back-
In Microsoft v. Motorola Inc. and Motorola Mobil-
ground on standards, Standards Setting Organizations
ity v. Microsoft: This was a breach of contract case.
(SSOs) and the RAND commitment, (3.) The court
Microsoft claimed that Motorola had an obligation
developed a framework for assessing RAND terms,
to license patents to Microsoft at a reasonable and
specifically a modified version of the Georgia-Pacific
non-discriminatory (“RAND”) rate, and that Mo-
factors:
torola breached its RAND obligations through two
offer letters. Microsoft sued Motorola for breach 1. The court introduced the parties and their rela-
of contract in this court November 2010. The par- tionship to one another;
ties disagreed substantially about the meaning of 2. The court provided background on standards, Stan-
RAND. Thus, to resolve the dispute, the court held dards Setting Organizations (SSOs) and the RAND
a bench trial from November 13–20, 2012. commitment;
To establish a context for these findings and conclu- 3. The court developed a framework for assessing
sions, the court outlined the details of Motorola’s RAND terms, specifically a modified version of the
RAND obligation, the patents at issue in this case,
and the nature of the dispute between Microsoft and
Motorola.11 11. Findings of Fact and Conclusions of Law, Case No. C10-
1823JLR, April 25, 2013, 207 pages, United States District
Motorola’s RAND commitment arises out of its re- Court Western District of Washington at Seattle, James L.
lationship with two standards-setting organizations, Robart, presiding judge.

226 les Nouvelles


Licensing Standards Essential Patents
Georgia-Pacific factors; Section 581: In the past Marvell has charged $3.00
a. See Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. United States Ply- to $4.00 per chip for WiFi chips of the kind its sells
woodCorp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 Southern District to Microsoft. 6. Section 582: Marvell pays a royalty
New York 1970. and licensing fees to ARM Holdings … ARM pro-
vides Marvell with patent licenses and “design and
b. The court determines that the parties in a hypo-
know-how” Marvell needs to make its 802.11 com-
thetical negotiation would set RAND royalty rates
pliant chips … Marvell pays ARM one percent of
by looking at the importance of the SEPs to the
the purchase price of the chip (3-4 cents per chip.)
standard and the importance of the standard and
the SEPs to the products at issue. Section 585: Marvell considers the ARM rate an ap-
propriate benchmark because the rate is based on
4. After establishing a framework, the court intro-
the selling price of the chip, not the sale price of
duced the H.264 standard and Motorola’s H.264
the end-user product into which the chip is embed-
SEPs, analyzing each patent in turn and setting the
ded. Example testimony: A one percent royalty on a
portfolio’s relative importance to the H.264 stan-
chip placed in an $80,000 Audi A8 would be $800,
dard and to Microsoft’s standards-using products;
or about 267 times the retail price of the chip.
5. The court introduced the 802.11 standard and Mo-
Another case citing the smallest saleable unit is Cor-
torola’s 802.11 SEPs and analyzed each 802.11 pat-
nell University v. Hewlett-Packard Co., 609 F. Supp. 2d
ent using the same framework;
279, 283 (2009.)vi
6. The court used all of the foregoing information,
II. The Way Forward
along with comparables suggested by the parties,
to determine an appropriate RAND royalty rate for A. Based on the cases cited above, I disagree with
Motorola’s SEPs. the concept of whole portfolio—whole device li-
censing. Recent case law does not support whole
The US District Court decided that the royalty rate
device licensing and the definition of damages in
and range as follows:
patent law never supported whole portfolio licens-
1. The royalty rate for Motorola’s H.264 SEP portfolio ing. In patent law, a patent owner may not charge
is 0.555 cents per unit. royalty for claims that he or she does not own.
a. The upper bound is 16.389 cents per unit and Even though the license contract may state that
the lower bound is 0.555 cents per unit. the royalty is only for claims that the infringer is
b. This rate and range is applicable to both Micro- actually practicing, the alleged infringing party
soft Windows and Xbox products. is doing themselves a disservice if they pay any
Key factors cited include: amount of royalty for an alleged claim that is not
proved. Similarly, as shown in section 585 of the
Section 540: To this end, in the course of a hypotheti- Microsoft-Motorola case, chips may be placed
cal negotiation with a SEP owner, the implement- in many devices, not just smartphones that cost
er must ask herself as a rational business person, $600. Some large screen TVs cost $9,000. Some
“What is the most I can pay for a license to this automobiles cost $80,000. Boeing lists the price
particular SEP or portfolio of SEPs—knowing that of its 737 as between $51.5 million and $87 mil-
I might have to license all SEPs in the entire stan- lion depending on the model. Once again, the al-
dard—while still maintaining a viable business?” leged infringing party is doing themselves a disser-
The court looked at the Via Licensing 802.11 Li- vice if they pay any amount of royalty for damages
censing Pool and the MPEG LA H.264 Licensing based on using the device price when the entire
Pool as examples to use in setting a royalty rate and device does not infringe the alleged claim.
avoiding royalty stacking. There is a case to be made that the component
Section 578: Microsoft uses as an additional compa- adds value to the whole device, but this case must
rable … the royalty rate that a third- party company, be made in proportion to the device in question –
Marvel Semiconductor … pays for the intellectual Does an airline buy a 737 or does a customer buy
property in its WiFi chips. The court agrees that a seat on a 737 entirely due to Wi-Fi on the flight?
the Marvell rate provides an indicator for 802.11 B. The IEEE has provided a guide, “Understanding Pat-
RAND under Factor 12 of a hypothetical negotia- ent Issues During IEEE Standards Development.”
tion because the experiences of Marvell, a third Section 44 of this guide reads as follows:
party, tend to establish what is customary in the
business of semiconductor licensing. i. In discussing Reasonable Rates, what is an ex-
ample of a “smallest saleable Compliant Imple-
Section 580: …the Marvell WiFi chip…enables the mentation that practices the Essential Patent
device to use the 802.11 Standard to transmit and Claim?”
receive information on radio frequency carriers.
Otherwise stated, the WiFi chip uses the 802.11 ii. Determining the smallest saleable Compliant
Standard to communicate wirelessly. Implementation that practices the Essential
Patent Claim is a function both of the claims in
September 2017 227
Licensing Standards Essential Patents
the patent and of the product or products that 6. The effect of selling the patented specialty in pro-
implement a standard. For example, assume a moting sales of other products of the licensee; the
component is a Compliant Implementation of existing value of the invention to the licensor as a
IEEE 802.11™ and practices the Essential Pat- generator of sales of its non-patented items; and the
ent Claim. That component is then used in an extent of such derivative or convoyed sales;
entertainment system that is then installed into 7. The duration of the patent and the term of the li-
an airplane. In this example, the component is cense;
the smallest saleable Compliant Implementation 8. The established profitability of the product made un-
of IEEE 802.11. der the patent; its commercial success; and its cur-
C. Conclusion rent popularity;
No one denies that a patent owner should be able 9. The utility and advantages of the patent property over
to charge whatever royalty they negotiate for a patent the old modes or devices, if any, that had been used
unrelated to a standard. The key question is whether a for working out similar results;
patent owner of a standards essential patent should be 10. The nature of the patented invention; the character
able to charge a premium when much of the value of of the commercial embodiment of it as owned and
the patent is derived from the international standards produced by the licensor; and the benefits to those
organization adopting the patented technology. who have used the invention;
In the absence of industry coming together in a pat- 11. The extent to which the infringer has made use of the
ent pool with the major players assembled to avoid invention, and any evidence probative of the value
royalty stacking and seek a reasonable royalty based of that use;
on the component practicing the standard, the courts 12. The portion of the profit or of the selling price that
have done the heavy lifting. The results are not all that may be customary in the particular business or in
patent owners may desire, but the results do provide comparable businesses to allow for the use of the
patent owners with reasonable royalty based on patent invention or analogous inventions;
law. This royalty may not pay for all research and devel- 13. The portion of the realizable profit that should be
opment, but it does provide, considering the volume of credited to the invention as distinguished from non-
smartphones in the market and yet to enter the market, patented elements, the manufacturing process, busi-
a considerable sum for those patent owners willing to ness risks, or significant features or improvements
do the serious work of proving their patent claims. added by the infringer;
It is time for industry to reclaim the lead from the 14. The opinion testimony of qualified experts; and
courts. Industry, not the courts should determine 15. The amount that a licensor (such as the patent own-
reasonable royalty for cellular standards essential pat- er) and a licensee (such as the infringer) would have
ents by coming together in a single patent pool and agreed upon (at the time the infringement began) if
developing a royalty that will stand the test of a court both had been reasonably and voluntarily trying to
challenge. ■ reach an agreement; that is, the amount that a prudent
References licensee—who desired, as a business proposition, to
i. Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. United States Plywood Corp., obtain a license to manufacture and sell a particular
318 F. Supp. 1116, 1119-20 (S.D.N.Y. 1970), modified article embodying the patented invention—would
and aff’d, 446 F.2d 295 (2d Cir.); have been willing to pay as a royalty and yet be able
1. The royalties received by the patent owner for the to make a reasonable profit, and which amount would
licensing of the patent-in-suit, proving or tending to have been acceptable by a prudent patent owner who
prove an established royalty; was willing to grant a license.
2. The rates paid by the licensee for the use of other ii. WTO Legal Texts, General Agreement on Tariffs and
patents comparable to the patent-in-suit; Trade, (1994).
3. The nature and scope of the license, as exclusive iii. General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Geneva,
or non-exclusive, or as restricted or non-restricted (July 1986).
in terms of territory or with respect to whom the iv. Doris Schroeder and Peter Singer, “Prudential Rea-
manufactured product may be sold; sons for IPR Reform,” University of Melbourne,
4. The licensor’s established policy and marketing pro- (2009).
gram to maintain its patent monopoly by not licens- v. Thomas Bollyky, “Why Chemotherapy That Costs
ing others to use the invention or by granting licens- $70,000 in the U.S. Costs $2,500 in India,” The At-
es under special conditions designed to preserve lantic, (2013).
that monopoly; vi. Berkley Technology Law Journal, volume 29, issue 4,
5. The commercial relationship between the licensor and annual review, (2014) 657.
the licensee, such as whether they are competitors
in the same territory in the same line of business, or Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
whether they are inventor and promoter; https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009417
228 les Nouvelles
Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb

Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb: Determining


Reasonable Royalties With Corporate Discount
Rates Using The Muthoo Model
By Brian Dies and Joel Wacek

Abstract This article discusses


Damages experts in patent litigation have been apply- the Muthoo Model, its in- ■ Brian Dies, CFA, ASA,
ing an economic model based on the work of Dr. Abhinay puts, and potential applic-
ation to determine reas- Hoffman Alvary &
Muthoo1 to determine reasonable royalty rates through
a profit sharing formula based on relative corporate dis- onable royalties in patent Company LLC,
count rates.2 The work of Dr. Muthoo has been oversim- infringement matters. Principal,
plified and misapplied in this context. Attempts to use Ultimately, we conclude Newton, MA, USA
corporate discount rates as the sole determinative meas- that despite attempts to
consider the facts specific
E-mail: bdies@
ure of bargaining power in a hypothetical negotiation for hoffmanalvary.com
a reasonable royalty are fundamentally flawed. This use to the parties, analyses
of the Muthoo Model is nothing more than another un- that rely on discount rates
alone to measure the rel- ■ Joel Wacek,
supported rule of thumb that is unreliable for determin-
ing reasonable royalties in patent infringement matters. ative bargaining strength Hoffman Alvary &
of the parties and calcu- Company LLC,
I. Introduction

O
late how an economic Principal,
ver the past decade, the courts have paid surplus would be shared
increasingly close attention to the methods are nothing more than Newton, MA, USA
used to determine reasonable royalty rates in another rule of thumb. As E-mail: jwacek@
patent infringement litigation. This scrutiny has resul- such, they provide little hoffmanalvary.com
ted in a fundamental change in the way many experts help to courts and juries
determine royalty rates. “Rules of thumb” or other in providing a reliable
generic formula-based approaches have generally been basis for determining reasonable royalty rates in patent
found to be inadmissible because they are not specific infringement matters.
to the facts of a given case and do not closely reflect II. Reasonable Royalties in Patent Litigation
the value or benefit associated with the use of the pat- and Rules of Thumb
ented technology.
In general, a patent holder is entitled to no less than
Nevertheless, some academics and damages ex- a reasonable royalty from the infringer of a valid pat-
perts continue to introduce royalty opinions based ent.3 A common approach to determining the amount
on broadly applied formulas derived from aspects of of a reasonable royalty is the “hypothetical negoti-
economic bargaining theory. For a brief period, many ation” construct established in Georgia-Pacific v. U.S.
damages experts offered royalty opinions that relied in Plywood.4 However, Georgia-Pacific (and the cases that
part on the Nash Bargaining Solution. More recently, followed) provide no mathematical formula to determ-
some damages experts have used a theory based on ine the final royalty rate.5
the work of Dr. Abhinay Muthoo. Aspects of his work
are similar to the Nash Bargaining Solution, but use In the absence of a clear and accepted formula, ex-
the relative discount rates of the parties to determine perts have applied professional judgment to the facts
how the parties at the hypothetical negotiation would and circumstances of each case to determine the re-
negotiate a split of the profits. sults of the “hypothetical negotiation.” This subjectiv-
ity has led to sometimes conflicting case law on rea-
sonable royalty issues, as well as numerous Daubert
1. Muthoo, Abhinay, “Bargaining Theory with Applications,”
(New York; Cambridge UP, 1999).
2. See for example, “Splitting the Atom: Economic 3. 35 U.S.C. § 284.
Methodologies for Profit Sharing in Reasonable Royalty 4. Georgia-Pacific Corporation v. United States Plywood
Analysis,” les Nouvelles, Volume LI No. 2, (June 2016) 70-73. Corporation, 318 F Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970).

September 2017 229


Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb
challenges on the admissibility of expert opinions on In recent years, some experts have begun using a
reasonable royalties. different mathematical formula for determining the
For many years, certain damages experts and their profit split that would result from the hypothetical ne-
clients looked for simple mathematical formulas to gotiation. This approach determines the portion of the
apply to every hypothetical negotiation. The 25% Rule profit, or economic surplus to award as a royalty based
was such a profit splitting formula, and was widely on the relative bargaining power of the parties. While
used by some experts until the Federal Circuit rejected consideration of the relative bargaining power of the
it as an inappropriately broad rule of thumb in 2011.6 parties has been emphasized by the Federal Circuit in
Other economic and financial models have been de- many decisions, in this model, the parties’ relative bar-
veloped that attempt to allocate incremental profits gaining power is based entirely on differences in their
among parties in licensing negotiations. For example, discount rates, and specifically, each entity’s corporate
Granstrand and Holgersson (2012) describe a model cost of capital.9
for dealing specifically with standard essential patents III. The Muthoo Model
subject to FRAND royalty terms based on each con- The use of discount rates to determine the relat-
tributor’s relative level of investment in the techno- ive bargaining strength, and therefore the profit split
logical standard.7 However, this model has not been between parties to a negotiation is largely based on the
frequently applied in the courts and its applicability work of Dr. Abhinay Muthoo, an economics professor
in a licensing situation that does not include FRAND at the University of Warwick. In his book, Bargaining
obligations is not explored in the article. Theory with Applications (1999), Muthoo theorizes
Following the rejection of the 25% Rule, some ex- that parties to a negotiation would divide an economic
perts began to broadly use a 50/50 profit split formula surplus based on their relative bargaining power. The
based on an economic theory developed by John Nash; relative bargaining power can be measured, accord-
the Nash Bargain Solution (NBS.) However, the gen- ing to Muthoo, by differences in the parties’ discount
eral application of the NBS was similarly rejected as a rates.10 This framework of the Muthoo Model has
rule of thumb in a 2014 ruling by the Federal Circuit.8 been discussed and applied in subsequent academic
Specifically, the Federal Circuit found that absent a de- research.11
tailed showing that the underlying assumptions of the In its base form, the Muthoo Model asserts that the
economic model would apply to the specific facts and economic surplus would be split between the nego-
circumstances of the case, the NBS was an unaccept- tiating parties based only on their relative discount
able rule of thumb. rates. The model was extended and refined in Bargain-
ing Theory with Applications to include other relevant
factors that may change the outcome of the negoti-
ation from what the base form alone would suggest.
5. For example, in Georgia-Pacific, Judge Tenney described
the process of determining a reasonable royalty through the These other factors include the impact of the parties’
hypothetical negotiation as “…There [are] a multiplicity of inter- relative payoffs and aversions to a breakdown of the
penetrating factors bearing upon the amount of a reasonable negotiation, changes in the bargaining procedures, the
royalty. But there is no formula by which these factors can availability to the parties of other options to negoti-
be rated precisely in the order of their relative importance ation, and information asymmetry at the bargaining
or by which their economic significance can be automatically table, among other factors. However, the focus of this
transduced into their pecuniary equivalent. In discharging its
responsibility as fact finder, the Court has attempted to exercise
article is on the model in its base form as that is how
a discriminating judgment reflecting its ultimate appraisal of all it has been applied to determine reasonable royalties
pertinent factors in the context of the credible evidence.” The in patent litigation.
Federal Circuit has also repeatedly “recognized that estimating
a reasonable royalty is not an exact science” and that “all 9. See, for example, Deere & Co. v. Int’l Harvester Co., 710
approximations involve some degree of uncertainty.” See, for F.2d 1551, 1559 (Fed. Cir. 1983), Fujifilm Corp. v. Benun, 605
example, Summit 6, LLC v. Samsung Elecs. Co., 802 F.3d 1283, F.3d 1366, 1372 (Fed. Cir. 2010), VirnetX, Inc. v. Cisco Sys.,
1299 (Fed. Cir. 2015). Inc., 767 F.3d 1308, 1331-33 (Fed. Cir. 2014).
6. USA v. Microsoft Corp., 632 F.3d 1292, 1315 (Fed. Cir. 10. Muthoo, Abhinay, “Bargaining Theory with Applications.”
2011). Chapter 3. (New York; Cambridge UP, 1999).
7. Granstrand, O. and M. Holgersson, “The 25% Rule Revisited 11. See for example, Muthoo, Abhinay, “Bargaining Theory
and a New Investment-Based Method for Determining FRAND and Royalty Contract Negotiations,” Review of Economic
Licensing Royalties.” les Nouvelles (September 2012) 188-195. Research on Copyright Issues, 2006, vol. 3(1), 19-27. For a
8. VirnetX, Inc. v. Cisco Sys., Inc., 767 F.3d 1308, 1337 (Fed. listing of academic papers, see Mcduff, Deforest. “Splitting the
Cir. 2014). The Court did suggest that NBS may be appropriate Atom: Economic Methodologies for Profit Sharing in Reasonable
in circumstances where the expert can show that the specific Royalty Analysis,” les Nouvelles, Volume LI No. 2, (June 2016)
underlying assumptions of the theorem are met in a given case. 70-73.

230 les Nouvelles


Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb
The Muthoo Model has been widely studied, and It is easiest to see how the Muthoo Model has been
many scholars have attempted to verify its predicted applied to determining reasonable royalties with a
outcomes with experiments or by looking at data from simple example. Assume that Company A is the pat-
actual negotiations.12 Muthoo has, however, noted that ent-owner (Plaintiff) and Company B is the accused
“this theory cannot be tested by an appeal to experi- infringer (Defendant). The allegedly infringing product
mental or field data.”13 Muthoo concludes that any ex- is sold by Company B at a price of $1,000 per unit and
perimental data or field data would necessarily involve Company B earns an incremental profit of $200 per
other elements outside the model’s parameters, in- unit on each sale. For simplicity in this example, as-
cluding human irrationality. Muthoo’s comments pro- sume the patent-in-suit is fundamental to the accused
vide instructive context on the admissibility of expert product, and the inclusion of the patented technology
testimony based on the model, as one of the hallmark is the underlying driver of its sales and profits.
requirements of admissibility under Daubert and its An application of the simplified Muthoo Model
progeny is the ability to test and recreate the results would suggest that the parties would have reached an
of an analysis. agreement in the hypothetical negotiation to split the
IV. The Muthoo Model Applied to Patent Dam- $200 of incremental profit per unit based on their re-
ages lative WACCs. If Company A is a small, privately-held
In the past few years, the Muthoo Model has been company with a WACC of 20 percent while Company
receiving increasing attention in the context of de- B is a large, well-financed company with a WACC of
termining reasonable royalty damages in patent litiga- 10 percent, the model suggests the profit split can be
tion. As was the case with the prior mathematical profit determined by the following formulas:17
splitting rules, proponents of the Muthoo Model have WACCB 10%
Profit Split to Company A= = = 33%
written articles in the licensing literature14 and the (WACCA + WACCB ) (10% + 20%)
model has been identified in seminars as a key trend
in patent damages.15 So far, it has met with mixed suc- WACCA 20%
Profit Split to Company B= = = 67%
cess in overcoming Daubert challenges in Court16 and (WACCA + WACCB ) (10% + 20%)
has been used with increasing frequency by damages This analysis suggests that Company A would receive
experts in patent infringement matters. one-third of the incremental profit as a royalty and
It has been argued that the Muthoo Model provides Company B would retain two-thirds of the incremental
academic support for a formula to split the incremental profit from selling the accused product. The result of
profits earned by the Defendant in proportion to the the hypothetical negotiation would be a $67 per unit
parties’ Weighted Average Costs of Capital (“WACC”). royalty (one-third of the $200 incremental profit) paid
Under the Muthoo Model, each company’s cost of cap- by Company B (the infringer) to Company A (the pat-
ital is used as a proxy for its bargaining strength. A ent holder.)18
party with higher capital costs has less bargaining pow- On the surface, this approach to splitting the prof-
er and would consequently receive a smaller share of its in the hypothetical negotiation looks promising.
the incremental profits than a party with lower capital Bargaining models can provide a structured approach
costs. Thus, to the extent the use of patented technol- for evaluating the economic benefits generated by a
ogy results in an economic surplus, that surplus would patented technology that would be at issue in a hypo-
be split at a hypothetical negotiation in accordance thetical negotiation, and properly focus the reasonable
with each company’s relative cost of capital. royalty determination on those benefits. The Muthoo
Model also has several enticing features; (1) it provides
a simple, objective formula; (2) it is based on a well
12. For a list of some of these academic studies, see Deforest
Mcduff, “Splitting the Atom: Economic Methodologies for Profit understood and researched economic theory; and (3)
Sharing in Reasonable Royalty Analysis,” Convert les Nouvelles, it is tied to information specific to the parties in the
Volume LI No. 2 (June 2016) 70-73. case (the infringer’s incremental profit and the parties’
13. Abhinay Muthoo, “Bargaining Theory with Applications,” relative WACCS.) However, reliably determining how
(New York; Cambridge UP, 1999) 341. any economic surplus should be split is a critical aspect
14. Ibid. of any bargaining model. As explained below, the Mut-
15. Williams, Danielle and Chris Marchese, “Patent Damages hoo Model falls short in this key area with respect to
Theories,” Fish & Richardson Webinar, (December 1, 2016). determining a reasonable royalty.
http://www.fr.com/events/webinar-patent-damages-theories.
16. For example; this approach survived a Daubert challenge 17. Abhinay Muthoo, “Bargaining Theory with Applications,”
in ContentGuard Holdings, Inc. v. Amazon.com, 2:13-cv-01112- (New York; Cambridge UP, 1999) 46.
JRG (E.D. Tex. Aug. 6, 2015) (Doc. No. 825) but failed a Daubert 18. The royalty could also be equivalently expressed as a 6.7
challenge in Omega Patents, LLC v. CalAmp Corp., 6:13-cv-1950 percent of revenue ($67 royalty for each unit with a $1,000
(M.D. Fla. Dec. 23, 2015) (Doc. No. 117). price).

September 2017 231


Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb
V. Criticisms of Applying the Muthoo Model Additionally, in many cases where the patent is a
to Reasonable Royalty Determinations small feature of a larger complex product, issues of ap-
Careful consideration of the Muthoo Model and portionment can make it difficult to accurately identify
its application to the analysis of how the incremental the defendant’s incremental profits from using the
profits associated with a patented technology would be specific patented technology. Such patents may still
shared at the hypothetical negotiation identifies many have significant value even if incremental profits can-
issues that suggest that it is nothing more than a more not be cleanly identified.
detailed version of the NBS, and its application to pat- • The Muthoo Model implicitly assumes exclusivity.
ent damages is another rule of thumb. Muthoo himself The bargaining problem is often described as how two
described the base variant of this economic model as parties will split a cake sitting on the table between
“identical to an asymmetric Nash Bargaining Solution them. The same piece of cake cannot be given to mul-
of an appropriately defined bargaining problem.”19 The tiple people—each piece must be exclusively given to
key difference between the previously rejected NBS only one person. However, most reasonable royalty
and the Muthoo Model is its reliance on the parties’ analyses in patent litigation assume the hypothetical
corporate discount rates to measure each party’s bar- license would be non-exclusive. Unlike a cake, one
gaining strength, rather than assuming equal bargain- could grant many parties non-exclusive licenses to the
ing strength. same patent. Granting a non-exclusive license to one
The main issues with applying the Muthoo Model (in player in an industry may impact licensing revenues
its base form) to patent litigation are: (1) the economic the patent holder would receive from prior licensees,
theory does not fit the specific construct of the hypo- and it may even impact profits that the patent holder
thetical negotiation; (2) the sole reliance on corporate would itself earn on products incorporating the pat-
discount rates to measure relative bargaining strength ented technology. The impact of the non-exclusive
is inappropriate; (3) the model ignores many factors nature of certain intellectual property assets is not
long considered relevant to the determination of reas- addressed in the Muthoo Model as it has been applied
onable royalties; and (4) the model implicitly includes in reasonable royalty analyses.
factors long considered irrelevant to the determination • The Muthoo Model accounts for the ability of the
of reasonable royalties in patent litigation. parties not to reach an agreement. Muthoo identifies
A. The Economic Model Does Not Fit the Hypo- that payoffs for the negotiating parties “when (and
thetical Negotiation Construct if) negotiations breakdown and their respective de-
The Muthoo Model is based on many implicit and ex- grees of risk aversion are crucial determinants of the
plicit assumptions. Many of these assumptions are so bargaining outcome.”21 However, in the hypothet-
limiting that they do not broadly apply to the construct ical negotiation construct, the parties must reach an
of a hypothetical negotiation in a patent litigation, and agreement.
are often divergent from real-world licensing negoti- • Muthoo extends the model by altering the equations
ations. For example: to account for inside and outside options.22 In patent
• The Muthoo Model assumes a positive economic sur- litigation, these inside and outside options would be
plus. In other words, the model assumes that there is analogous to the availability of non-infringing altern-
some benefit to both parties from entering the trans- ative technology. The existence of inside and outside
action. This is not always the case in a hypothetical options impacts the negotiation outcome and may
negotiation in a patent litigation. For example, there cause the result to differ from the simple relative
may be no benefit to be had by a highly-profitable pat- weighting of the parties’ relative discount rates. A
ent holder licensing a valid patent to a less-profitable profit split based solely on the relative WACC of the
infringer who is a direct competitor. Also, the profits parties inappropriately ignores these complications.
earned by some infringers may be limited for reas- Applying the base form of the Muthoo Model ignores
ons unrelated to the profit-producing capabilities of the impact of non-infringing alternatives at the hypo-
the patented technology. This may cause the size of thetical negotiation, unless any such alternatives have
the shared economic surplus to be understated. The already been accounted for in the economic surplus
Federal Circuit has warned that the profits of an “in- being considered by the parties.
efficient infringer” need not cap the measure of the • The Muthoo Model is based on a very specific set of
damages caused to the patent holder.20 bargaining procedures. In the alternating-offer bidding

19. Abhinay Muthoo, “Bargaining Theory with Applications,” 21. Abhinay Muthoo, “Bargaining Theory with Applications,”
(New York; Cambridge UP, 1999) 42. (New York; Cambridge UP, 1999) Chapter 4, specifically 73.
20. See Aqua Shield v. Inter Pool Cover Team, et al., 774 F.3d 22. Abhinay Muthoo, “Bargaining Theory with Applications,”
766, 770 (Fed. Cir. 2014). (New York; Cambridge UP, 1999) Chapters 5 and 6.

232 les Nouvelles


Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb
procedure, party A makes an offer, and party B then ac- (or weaken) its bargaining position in the hypothet-
cepts it or issues a counteroffer.23 In the real-world, bar- ical negotiation by issuing debt (or equity). There is
gaining procedures are often ambiguous or ill-defined. no reason to believe that such a corporate financing
Parties can make offers in any order and parties can decision made by a patent holder or alleged infringer
ignore offers without issuing a counter offer. significantly impacts the “the value of the use of the
For example, if party A makes repeated offers and patented technology” that the Federal Circuit and
party B accepts or rejects those offers without coun- Supreme Court have said “measures the reasonable
tering, Muthoo indicates that the discount rates of the royalty.”25
parties have no impact whatsoever on the bargaining 3. Overall Corporate Capital Costs May Not Be
outcome.24 Since there is no reason to assume that the Relevant
hypothetical negotiation would always perfectly follow The WACC of an entire company is not usually the
the alternating-offers bidding procedure required for metric that would be considered to evaluate an in-
the Muthoo Model, it is inappropriate to assume it vestment in an individual product or project. This is
broadly applies. because the risk of a specific corporate project dif-
For these reasons, the economic theory underlying fers from those associated with the operation of an
the Muthoo Model does not map to the specific cir- entire company that may have a diverse product line.
cumstance of a hypothetical negotiation to determine For example, after a corporate acquisition a com-
a reasonable royalty for the use of a patent. pany’s overall WACC may change but the risk profile
B. Corporate WACCs Are Not Relevant Discount associated with individual product lines may be un-
Rates affected. Thus, a company-wide WACC may not be
The portion of the profit received by the patent the appropriate measure to evaluate a single project
holder as a royalty under the applied Muthoo Model or product that may be allegedly infringing and the
is largely dependent on the parties’ weighted average focus of the hypothetical negotiation.
costs of capital. This is a measure of the average cost 4. Product Specific Capital Costs May Not Be
of a company’s equity and debt. As such, it is a com- Appropriate Either
pany-wide statistic. Product specific costs of capital or discount rates
1. WACC as a Concept May Not Be Relevant to may be no more appropriate to the analysis of bar-
All Litigants gaining power than general corporate discount rates.
The concept of WACC is generally applied in finance A company can finance a new product launch from
to operating companies. There are many patent lit- retained earnings (an equity cost of capital), through
igations that involve parties where the concept of the issuance of new debt (a debt cost of capital) or
WACC may not be as applicable. For example, it is some combination of the two (a blended cost of cap-
not clear what discount rate one should use in the ital). If a company makes a significant capital invest-
Muthoo Model if one of the parties is a non-practic- ment to launch an infringing product line, that com-
ing entitiy (NPE), a not-for-profit research institution pany’s bargaining position at the hypothetical nego-
(i.e., a university or a research hospital), or an indi- tiation should not be impacted by how the company
vidual inventor. financed that product launch. Therefore, it would be
inappropriate to use a product level cost of capital in
2. WACC Is Biased by Corporate Financing De- the Muthoo Model (even if one was calculable based
cisions on information in the litigation record).
In operating companies, WACC is influenced by cor- Additionally, when developing new product lines,
porate financing decisions. Generally, the after-tax many companies perform detailed financial analyses
cost of debt is less than the cost of equity. A deci- that may include product specific discount rates ap-
sion by a company to change its relative level of debt plied to expected future cash flows. These manage-
and equity will likely change the company’s WACC. ment determined discount rates can be hurdle rates
Under the Muthoo Model, these corporate financing for the entire business, or they can be subjectively
decisions would have a direct impact on the final roy- determined for the specific project. There are many
alty determination that results from the hypothetical situations where these management determined dis-
negotiation. Specifically, a company could improve count rates may diverge from the corporate costs of
capital. For example, management may set higher
hurdle rates than its cost of capital in situations of
23. A. Rubinstein, “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining
Model,” Econometrica, 50: 97-110 (1982). The alternating-
offer bidding procedure is referred to as the Rubenstein Model. 25. Aqua Shield v. Inter Pool Cover Team, et al., 774 F.3d 766
24. Abhinay Muthoo, “Bargaining Theory with Applications,” (Fed. Cir. 2014), citing Dowagiac Mfg. Co. v. Minn. Moline Plow
(New York; Cambridge UP, 1999) Chapter 7, specifically 190. Co. 235 U.S 641 (1915) at 648.

September 2017 233


Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb
capital scarcity when evaluating competing alternat- a reasonable royalty.28 Accordingly, not only does the
ive projects or to develop more conservative busi- use of relative capital costs likely fail to provide a real-
ness plans. There is no reason to inherently assume istic, reliable measure of the parties’ relative bargain-
that the product specific discount rates that may be ing strength, it results in precisely what the Federal
used by management are related to the company’s Circuit has warned against: it bases royalties on factors
bargaining power in a hypothetical negotiation. unrelated to the patented technology.
5. Conclusion on Capital Costs C. Ignores Relevant Factors
In determining a reasonable royalty, corporate The Muthoo Model ignores other factors that courts
WACCs have been used in the Muthoo Model as a often consider to be important that can influence the
proxy for the relative bargaining strength of the par- final royalty determination. For example:
ties. In fact, the party-specific nature of these dis- • The level of competition between the parties is
count rates is one of the primary reasons proponents ignored in the Muthoo Model as it has been applied.
of the Muthoo Model argue that it succeeds where When the profit split between the parties to the litiga-
the NBS failed in the eyes of the Federal Circuit: tion is based solely on their relative WACCs, whether
that it considers and accounts for the specific facts the parties are direct competitors is an irrelevant fact.
of a case. However, use of an overall company’s cost However, the commercial relationship of the patent
of capital provides little more than a thin veneer holder and alleged infringer is often considered (see
of party-specific facts over the base NBS theorem Georgia-Pacific Factor 5) and it is generally accepted
whose blind application has been rejected by the that, all other things being equal, the presence of dir-
Federal Circuit. ect competition would increase the final royalty rate.
Further, while it is well established that the cost of • The Muthoo Model ignores all licensing indicia,
capital for individual companies is relevant for financial including the prior licenses for the patent-in-suit, and
valuation, there are many reasons why the cost of capi- licenses for similar technology either by the parties
tal of a company may not accurately reflect the bargain- or in the industry. The licensing history of the parties
ing strength of a party in the hypothetical negotiation and the patent holder’s established licensing policy,
construct. For example, corporate level WACCs are if any, have long been considered relevant facts to
biased by corporate financing decisions and not nec- the outcome of a hypothetical negotiation. (see Geor-
essarily related to the bargaining power of a company gia-Pacific Factors 1, 2, 4 and 12.)
at a hypothetical negotiation for rights to a patented • As discussed above, the Muthoo Model does not
technology. More specific product level costs of capital account for the non-exclusive nature of the license as-
or discount rates may also not reflect the bargaining sumed in most hypothetical negotiations in patent in-
power of a party to a hypothetical negotiation. fringement litigations. (see Georgia-Pacific Factor 3.)
The above demonstrates that there are numerous • The time remaining on the patent term is ignored.
external factors which affect a company’s cost of cap- A patent that expires soon is likely to garner lower
ital. Many of these factors are unrelated to how a cor- royalties than a patent with a long remaining life, all
poration uses the patented technology, or the benefits other things being equal. If the patent’s remaining
that are provided by that use. The patent damages term is very short, the accused infringer would be
statute defines a reasonable royalty as reflecting “the expected to consider waiting out the patent term and
use made of the invention by the infringer.”26 Further, launching the accused product after expiration. (see
one of the fundamental requirements that has repeat- Georgia-Pacific Factor 7.)
edly been emphasized by the Federal Circuit in recent
years is that royalties “must reflect the value attrib- • The Muthoo Model ignores the profitability of
utable to the infringing features of the product, and the product as made by the patent owner. The profits
no more.”27 In fact, the Federal Circuit has cautioned the patent owner can make in the absence of grant-
that “any evidence unrelated to the claimed invention” ing a license, and relatedly, what fraction of those
should not be given substantive weight in determining profits are put at risk by granting a license, can be
highly relevant to the royalty the patent owner would
be willing to accept from a potential competitor. The
Muthoo Model looks only at the incremental profit of
26. 35 U.S.C. § 284 states, “Upon finding for the claimant the infringer as the economic surplus to be divided.
the court shall award the claimant damages adequate to This approach completely ignores the profits made by
compensate for the infringement, but in no event less than a
reasonable royalty for the use made of the invention by the the patent owner. (see Georgia-Pacific Factor 8.)
infringer, together with interest and costs as fixed by the court.”
27. Ericsson, Inc. v. D-Link Sys., Inc., 773 F.3d 1201, 1226 28. ResQNet.com, Inc. v. Lansa, Inc., 594 F.3d 860, 869 (Fed.
(Fed. Cir. 2014). Cir. 2010).

234 les Nouvelles


Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb
• Again, as discussed above, the base form of the may or may not be true in a real-world negotiation sce-
Muthoo Model ignores the specific technological im- nario, but its application to the hypothetical negotia-
provements of the patented invention, and the avail- tion construct used to determine damages for infringe-
ability of non-infringing alternatives. The technical ment would appear to be inappropriate. For example,
importance of a patented technology and the avail- if the record company took Paul’s song and used it to
ability of acceptable non-infringing alternatives may make millions of dollars, the amount Paul should re-
have a significant impact on the bargaining strength ceive in damages from that infringement should not
and negotiating position of an alleged infringer. (see at all be related to whether Paul had a side-job wait-
Georgia-Pacific Factors 9 & 10.) ing tables. Rather, the damages should be tied to the
Application of the Muthoo Model to determining a value of the property that was taken, and the use that
reasonable royalty ignores these factors that have long was made of that property. Thus, there appears to be
been held to be relevant to the hypothetical negoti- normative issues involved with the tension between
ation. This calls into serious question the applicability the application of the Muthoo Model and public policy
and reliability of the Muthoo Model to the specific ana- concerns of protecting the property rights of inventors
lysis of determining reasonable royalty damages. regardless of their personal or corporate wealth.
D. Includes Irrelevant Factors Implicitly VI. Just Another Rule of Thumb
The Muthoo Model, either directly or indirectly, in- The Muthoo Model is a complex mathematical theo-
cludes factors that have been appropriately considered ry. That complexity is what some experts may like and,
to be irrelevant in a reasonable royalty analysis. For ex- not coincidentally, is also what makes it difficult for
ample, in the most common application of the Muthoo opposing counsel to challenge effectively. Despite its
Model, the profit split is determined by the parties’ complexity, it appears to allow for a reasonable royalty
relative WACCs. However, a company’s WACC is influ- based on a simple objective calculation based on par-
enced by the risk and profitability of all the company’s ty-specific information, not a subjective opinion. Yet,
products, not just the patented or infringing product. the application of the model to the determination of
It has been long understood that the hypothetical ne- reasonable royalties can result in illogical and unrelia-
gotiation in a patent infringement litigation should ble conclusions.
not be influenced by the fact that either (or both) the Proponents of using the Muthoo Model argue that
Plaintiff or Defendant may (or may not) have profitable by using the relative discount rates from the parties
products that are completely unrelated to the patent- to the litigation, this approach uses enough party-spe-
in-suit.
cific information to succeed where the generalized ap-
In 2006, Muthoo published an article in the Review plication of the NBS failed in the eyes of the Federal
of Economic Research on Copyright Issues specifically Circuit. However, just because the formula uses some
discussing the application of his prior work to the information specific to the case should not be enough
context of royalty negotiations.29 This work has been to clear the hurdle of admissibility and reliability. To
cited to support the acceptance of the applicability of clear that hurdle, an analysis should appropriately use
the Muthoo Model to the determination of reasonable all the relevant case-specific data—not just the parties’
royalties. In this paper, Muthoo uses the example of discount rates.
a musician named Paul negotiating with a record la-
bel over the rights to a specific song Paul has written. Further, there are several problems with the party-
Muthoo concludes that “the larger Paul’s wealth, the specific discount rates typically used in applying the
lower his haggling cost, and thus, the greater his bar- Muthoo Model. Several factors affect a company’s cost
gaining power.” Muthoo further suggests that if Paul, of capital, many of which should not weigh heavily in
the musician, had a second job with a decent source of determining the bargaining strength under the hypo-
income he could improve his relative bargaining power thetical negotiation construct. The Muthoo Model also
in negotiations with the record label.30 ignores many types of case-specific information that,
Applying this analysis to a patent infringement liti- based on long and widely-held belief and case-law
gation would suggest that the wealthier party should precedent, are likely to influence the determination of
always make out better in the hypothetical negotiation, reasonable royalties.
and receive a more favorable damages outcome. This The use of the Muthoo Model to determine reason-
able royalties in patent litigation is nothing more than
a slightly evolved rule of thumb. It should be viewed
29. Abhinay Muthoo, “Bargaining Theory and Royalty
Contract Negotiations,” Review of Economic Research on with the same level of skepticism as the rules of thumb
Copyright Issues, 2006, vol. 3(1), 19-27. that came before it, like the 25% Rule and blind appli-
30. Ibid., 23. cation of the NBS. The Muthoo Model fails to provide

September 2017 235


Magic Bullet Or Rule Of Thumb
a reliable basis for determining a reasonable royalty for The broad application of the Muthoo Model to deter-
the same reasons set forth by the Federal Circuit with mine reasonable royalties is not the magic bullet some
respect to the NBS and the 25% Rule: the general the- have claimed it to be. In the absence of a one size fits
orem can rarely, if ever, be accurately applied to the all approach, professionals must still make determina-
facts of a given case.31 tions based on their experience and the financial and
VII. Going Forward economic models that best fit the specific facts and
circumstance of the situation being analyzed. This can
This application of the Muthoo Model is another at- be a very challenging exercise that necessarily requires
tempt to find the magic bullet of a simple, universal- some level of subjectivity on the part of the expert and
ly applicable mathematical formula for determining a the courts.
reasonable royalty rate. Unfortunately, no such magic
While the Muthoo Model fails to provide a reliable
bullet exists. Where does the rejection of the Muthoo
basis from which to discern how parties to a hypo-
Model for determining reasonable royalties leave us?
thetical negotiation would split an economic surplus,
Economic models based on bargaining theory and it does begin with the proper focus: measuring the
financial models based on other factors are useful incremental profits specifically related to the patent-
and informative to a reasonable royalty analysis, and ed technology at issue. While some subjectivity may
can serve to ground a potentially subjective exercise be unavoidable in determining a reasonable royalty, a
in objective reality.32 We welcome the objective, ana- strong opinion should be grounded in the facts of a giv-
lytical rigor such models provide to the analysis of a en case and well-reasoned, situation specific economic
reasonable royalty. However, no single model has yet and financial analysis that determines the “footprint”
been developed that in all fact patterns, industries and of the patented technology in the marketplace.33 ■
situations appropriately accounts for the complexity of
the issues in determining a reasonable royalty in a re- Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
al-world litigation. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009421

31. Further, the courts have viewed rules of thumb as


inappropriate starting points for any subjective analysis.
Therefore, it is also not reasonable to use the Muthoo Model
as an appropriate starting point for the hypothetical negotiation
and modify the result up or down to account for factors not
considered directly by the model. This approach was found to be
invalid as prior rules of thumb were found to be inappropriate
starting points for a Georgia-Pacific analysis.
32. The Federal Circuit has noted, perhaps fittingly, that “[d]
etermining a fair and reasonable royalty is often…a difficult
judicial chore, seeming often to involve more the talents of a
conjurer than those of a judge.” See Fromson v. Western Litho. 33. ResQNet.com, Inc. v. Lansa, Inc., 594 F.3d 860 (Fed. Cir.
Plate and Supply Co., 853 F.2d 1568, 1574 (Fed. Cir. 1988). 2010).

236 les Nouvelles


Innovation In Artificial Intelligence

A Guide To Commercial Innovation


In Artificial Intelligence
By Deepa Ravindranath

Introduction Section 1: AI Innova-

T
he artificial intelligence (AI) landscape is grow- tion Framework ■ Deepa Ravindranath,
ing quickly. Artificial intelligence start-ups raised AI innovation can be best MaxVal Group,
$5B in 2016, a 10-fold increase since 2012.i characterized along two prin-
Tech giants (Google, Microsoft, IBM) are contribut- ciples:
Associate Director,
ing heavily to this acceleration, both in academic and • Sector specific vs. sector ag-
Los Altos, CA, USA
practical pursuits. Google published 218 papers on ma- nostic. Is AI used as a com- E-mail: dkrishna@
chine learning in 2016, nearly double the number of petitive advantage for a intellectualassetsinc.com
publications in 2014.ii In December 2016, Microsoft single industry (e.g., logis-
launched a new venture fund specifically to evaluate tics)? Or is the innovation
and fund AI start-ups, kicking off the fund with an in- broad-based and generic, cutting across multiple
vestment in Element AI, then acquiring Maluuba just industries and platform types (e.g., improvements
one month later.iii, iv in technology such as natural language processing,
For professional advisors in the technology field image recognition, machine learning).
(attorneys, investors), AI innovation presents unique • Solution type, e.g., “Front-end,”“Back-end,” “End-
challenges. For one, the fast pace of innovation makes to-end.” Does the innovation promote a single AI
it challenging to keep one’s knowledge current. This technology (e.g., natural language processing, deep
will only continue. Due to recent advancements in learning), or a combination involving disparate AI
AI across all dimensions—computational power, al- technologies?
gorithms, and data—innovation cycles have shortened
When mapping these principles using a Gartner
and the cost of innovation is dropping. This is lowering
square, four distinct archetypes become clear. Figure 1.
the barrier to entry, flooding the space with a diverse
group of players. Another unique challenge is that dis- Key takeaways:
cussions about AI are unavoidable in business circles • Tech giants’ activities, i.e., the activities of IBM, Mi-
today. AI is at the peak of the “hype cycle,” and know- crosoft, and Google follow Archetype 2: Land Grab-
ledge in this space is often a way to start conversations bers. These companies are investing across several
and build credibility. AI technologies. Their goal is “standards-setting”
The authors recognize the scarcity of scholarly ma- upon which further AI innovation is built.
terial on the topic of AI targeted to the licensing com- • Archetypes 1, 3, and 4 provide ample opportunity
munity, specifically, thought leadership that facilitates for non-tech giants to compete, either by:
a licensing professional’s ability to track innovation in 1. Creating an AI solution tailored to sector-specific
this space. In this paper, the authors provide a guide customer needs (ideal for large incumbent com-
for a licensing professional to evaluate AI innovation panies, e.g., auto manufacturers)—as Pioneers, or
effectively. 2. Building an improved solution that can either
In Section 1, the authors propose an AI innovation interface with a sector specific or land-grabber
framework. This framework contextualizes AI innov- solution (e.g., an enhanced image recognition
ation into four distinct archetypes. Breaking up the software that can interface with IBM Watson, ap-
landscape into logical parts enables focus, and allows a plied to law enforcement or counterterrorism)—
licensing professional to build expertise in the areas of as Performance Enhancers or Tech Mavens.
greatest interest to their business.
Section 2: Five Identified “Outlier” Companies
In Section 2, the authors illustrate the framework
The authors recently conducted a study to answer
using case studies of five “outlier” companies. Because
the question “What are the innovative AI companies
of the high intensity of innovation, the authors devel-
to watch in 2017-2018?” An outlier company was
oped a series of criteria and techniques to separate the
defined as:
wheat from the chaff. From a list of 20 companies, the
authors showcase five companies to watch in 2017- • Not a household name
2018 that illustrate the archetypes. • Still independent (not recently acquired)

September 2017 237


Innovation In Artificial Intelligence
Here (formerly Navteq and
Figure 1. Four Archetypes Of AI Innovators Nokia maps) provides digital
mapping, location and satellite
End-to-End navigation services. The company
incorporates real-time traffic and
1 2 road condition data from sensors
Pioneers Land Grabbers on-board Mercedes, BMW, and
Applying AI holistically to
enhance the core business and
Locking down applications Audi vehicles to provide a dynam-
and use cases for future
create net new value monetization ic, up-to-date map to the user.
Sector Sector In December 2015, Here was
Specific Agnostic bought by a consortium of Ger-
3 4 man automakers (Volkswagen,
Performance Enhancers Tech Mavens BMW, Daimler) for $2.8B.vi Since
Harnessing AI to solve acute Enhancing the capabilities of December 2016, Here has gar-
challenges in current operations individual AI technologies
nered the attention of several
investors to further the consor-
tium’s development efforts in
Source: Author’s analysis Focused autonomous vehicles (Tencent,
NavInfo, and Singapore GIC in
December 2016 acquiring a 10 percent stake, and In-
• Upward trajectory (measured by successive rounds tel in January 2017 acquiring a 15 percent stake.)vii, viii
of funding, increasing patenting activity in the past
Here is a prominent example of non-tech giants
three years)
standing their ground against tech giants in “land grab-
• Partnership with a large entity or consortium (if ap- ber” mode. Here was acquired by the German auto-
plicable) makers for the purpose of developing an alternative
From a list of over 1,400 initial results, approxi- to Google maps. Despite the ubiquity and zero cost
mately 20 companies met the definition of an “out- nature of Google Mapsix and Google Local services,
lier company.” The authors selected five of these Here has expanded its footprint beyond its German
companies to showcase: automaker owners, providing mapping solutions to
• HERE: Pioneer Amazon, Microsoft, and other corporate entities.
• SECOND SPECTRUM: Performance Enhancer The company owns over 800 active patent families,
• C3IOT: Performance Enhancer with an accelerating patent filing trend in recent years
(173 families in 2014). Recently published patent doc-
• KNUEDGE: Tech Maven uments include innovations across the AI spectrum:
• EDGE3: Tech Maven data management (comprehensive map data), deep
HERE: Archetype 1, Pioneer learning (image recognition, tailored personal experi-
ences), autonomous driving (nav-
Figure 2. Illustrative Placement Of Companies To igation, positioning, error meas-
urement and correction), and IoT
Watch For In 2017-2018 (sensor detection, fleet manage-
End-to-End ment), to name a few. The com-
pany also continues investing in
1 2 adjacencies, such as indoor map-
+ ping and aerial delivery.
HERE Tech Giants
SECOND SPECTRUM:
Archetype 3, Performance
Sector Sector Enhancer
Specific Agnostic Second Spectrum provides a
3 4 machine intelligence-driven solu-
+ +
C3IoT KNUEDGE tion that enables sports teams to
+ enhance player performance and
SECOND + inform game strategy.x Founded in
SPECTRUM EDGE3
2013 by two members of USC’s
Focused Computational Behavior Group,

238 les Nouvelles


Innovation In Artificial Intelligence
the company makes available and analyzes thousands focused on fundamentally altering the way humans
of hours of game footage to extract insights using a interact with machines.xvi The company was founded
unique combination of rules-based approaches and a in 2005 by former NASA chief Daniel Goldin as Intel-
solution that enables easy access to game footage. lisis, and rebranded in 2016 as KnuEdge.xvii In 2015,
Second Spectrum has had a short but productive the company announced that it had raised over $100M
history. The company closed a Series A on August 1, over multiple funding rounds.xviii
2015.xi In 2016, the company signed a multi-year deal KnuEdge markets four products to military and cor-
with the NBA to become the Official Optical Tracking porate customers. The company’s flagship product,
Provider of the NBA starting in the 2017-2018 season, KnuVerse, is a “military grade” voice recognition and
providing advanced statistics (e.g., speed, distance, authentication system that remains effective in noisy
drives, paint touches, defensive impact.)xii The compa- environments. The company continues to develop
ny currently works with two-thirds of NBA teams (in- products based on neural network principles, having
cluding all recent NBA champions) as well as the NFL, already developed a novel chip technology that sur-
NHL, and MLB. passes industry standards of scalability and latency.
Second Spectrum has filed a single patent family KnuEdge has over 40 active patent families, with
(US20150248917) to enable capture and analysis of the first filings in 2009. Since then, the company has
events from video feeds, including metrics related to accelerated its efforts—filing 14 new patent families
sports performance via automated, machine-based al- in 2015, up from single digits in years prior. Recently
gorithms. published patent documents include innovations in
C3IoT: Archetype 3, Performance Enhancer voice enhancement, signal processing for noise reduc-
tion, and latency reduction.
C3IoT is developing a next generation data analytics
platform that customers can use to build predictive an- EDGE3: Archetype 4, Tech Maven
alytics capabilities. The company was founded in 2009 EDGE3 provides an advanced vision analytics en-
by serial entrepreneur Thomas Siebel of Siebel Systems. gine that finds application across several industry ver-
Originally named C3 Energy, the company initially tar- ticals. Founded in 2005 by engineers who built the
geted energy companies to establish proof of concept. Embry Riddle Machine Vision Lab, the company has
The company rebranded in 2016 as C3IoT, embracing developed a vast library of vision stereo algorithms,
the demand for predictive data analytics capabilities including a “depth map” that enables real-time, con-
beyond the energy sector, including healthcare and tinuous measurement. The algorithms enable the use
banking.xiii On March 2, 2017, C3IoT closed a Series E of low-cost, inexpensive cameras typically found in
financing round valuing the company at $1.4B.xiv consumer electronics, thus making the capability af-
C3IoT markets four products that enable it to meet fordable and accessible.
any customer at their level and build an IoT predictive The company has applied the vision analytics engine
suite of capabilities that best fit the company’s vision. to two marketed products, Drive and Gauge.xix Drive
The company markets both off-the-shelf machine learn- is an in-cabin system that monitors drivers for signs
ing-enabled software applications, as well as a plat- of distraction (texting, gaze direction, drowsiness) and
form-as-a-service option for deploying custom industri- can be tailored to the unique traits of each driver via
al-scale IoT applications. To support the PAAS solution Edge3’s machine-trained algorithms. Gauge is a mobile
and enhance the predictive capability, C3IoT leverages calculation algorithm used to measure size and dis-
sensor data from over 20 industrial-scale deployments tance from an image. The company has found applica-
with C3IoT customers (100 million connected IoT tion in transportation and logistics (measuring the size
sensors). C3IoT customers include private and govern- of packages for shipping efficiency) and in healthcare
ment customers—in 2016, C3IoT won a $25 million (tracking the size of wounds and skin abnormalities to
contract to track energy use by the U.S. State Depart- optimize treatment).
ment at more than 22,000 facilities spread globally.xv The company has been awarded over 40 patents
C3IoT has approximately five active patent families, over the past four years (five active patent families).
filed in the past two years. Recently published patent The patents are drawn primarily to human-computer
documents include a development platform for enter- interface algorithms, including context-specific verbal
prise IoT applications and trained algorithms for pre- and gesture-based commands, context identification,
dictive analytics applied to cybersecurity, forecasting and data classification.
energy consumption, and forecasting energy billing. Conclusion
KNUEDGE: Archetype 4, Tech Maven The volume and depth of innovation in AI is much
KnuEdge develops next generation and radical tech- more than can be made sense of in a single paper. The
nologies in voice biometrics and neural computing, authors propose a framework that groups the innovation

September 2017 239


Innovation In Artificial Intelligence
in AI into four discrete archetypes—Pioneer, Land Grab- vii. http://www.reuters.com/article/us-here-equity-idUSK-
ber, Performance Enhancer, and Tech Maven. This men- BN14G0PY.
tal model can be a useful “rule of thumb” as licensing viii. http://www.reuters.com/article/us-intel-here-equity-idUSK-
professionals navigate and track AI developments in pur- BN14N0RN.
suit of solutions that best support their businesses. ■ ix. http://fortune.com/2016/04/06/amazon-microsoft-here-map.
We welcome readers’ participation in this conver- x. https://www.secondspectrum.com/aboutus.html.
sation. How does your organization track AI develop- xi. https://www.crunchbase.com/organization/second-spectrum#/
ments in-house, and what criteria do you use? What entity.
companies should be recognized as the innovative AI xii. http://pr.nba.com/nba-announces-multiyear-partner-
ship-sportradar-second-spectrum.
companies to watch in 2017-2018? Join the conversa-
tion at: http://blog.maxval.com/2017/05/artificial-intelli- xiii. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-09-01/tech-bil-
lionaire-s-data-startup-c3-iot-raises-70-million.
gence-innovation-case-study.
xiv. https://www.crunchbase.com/organization/c3#/entity
References http://c3iot.com/iot-news.
i. https://www.cbinsights.com/blog/artificial-intelligence-start- xv. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-09-01/
up-funding. tech-billionaire-s-data-startup-c3-iot-raises-70-million.
ii. https://www.technologyreview.com/s/603984/googles-ai-ex- xvi. https://www.knuedge.com/innovation.
plosion-in-one-chart. xvii. https://www.crunchbase.com/organization/knuedge#/entity.
iii. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-12-12/ xviii. http://www.sandiegouniontribune.com/business/
microsoft-starts-new-venture-fund-with-investment-in-ben- t e chnology /sdu t -goldin-nasa-k nu e dge -int e llisi s- ca lit-
gio-s-element-ai. tirias-2016jun07-stor y.html.
iv. https://techcrunch.com/2017/01/13/microsoft-acquires xix. http://www.edge3technologies.com/#Products.
-maluuba-a-startup-focused-on-general-artificial-intelligence.
vi. www.engadget.com/2015/07/13/uber-nokia-here. See
also http://www.reuters.com/article/us-nokia-here-idUSKBN0T-
Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
N1J020151204. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009423

240 les Nouvelles


Disruption In The IP Services?

Disruption In The IP Services Industry?


By John Walker

T
he theme of the LES (Australia/New Zealand) IP owners themselves (individuals and corporations)
Annual Conference in May 2016 was “Creation seeking IP rights consistent with their business object-
to Commercial—Disruption and Opportuni- ives, governments through
ties.” In keeping with that theme, a presentation was their agencies providing the
made “Disruption in the IP Services Industry?” The “?” IP infrastructure to obtain IP ■ John Walker,
in this title essentially asks the question “Is There Dis- rights—at the international, Dennemeyer & Associates,
ruption in the IP Services Industry?” This paper, based national and multilateral or Director,
around that presentation, looks at that question from regional levels, and the IP Kew, Australia
the viewpoint of the players or stakeholders in the IP service providers. This latter
industry, the IP lifecycle or ecosystem, and the prod- grouping can be further cat- E-mail: jwalker@
ucts and/or services being supplied in the IP sector. egorized into three: the tra- dennemeyer-law.com
Terminology ditional attorney services; the
As a precursor to answering this key question one commoditized type services
needs to understand what is meant by disruption. (such as renewals); and the management services
One possible definition of disruption is “disturbanc- (such as outsourcing). Looking at each of these stake-
es or problems which intercept an event, activity, or holders helps one understand and address the issue of
process,” with synonyms such as “interference, upset, disruption (or transition?)
confusion” often being used to describe any disrup- IP Owners
tion. These definitions all have negative connotations, IP owners are the cornerstone—or ultimate drivers
and as later described in this paper, the IP services in- —of the sector in that they seek, demand and require
dustry can be considered more in “transition” than as IP rights with certainty, they seek the maximum pro-
a disruption. Transition is more a process or period of tection (both in terms of scope and territory,) and
change from one state to another, and synonyms like with such rights being provided in the minimum time-
transformation, adaptation, gradation and evolution— frame (usually,) at minimum cost, but at the same time
all with a more positive connotation—are better de- without any reduction in quality of service or out-
scriptions, and these certainly more closely reflect the comes. Whilst these objectives might be considered
development—past, current and future—of the IP ser- aspirational, they nonetheless provide the drivers for
vices industry. the other two categories of stakeholders.
In addressing this question, two other terms also Governments
need to be recognized. These are “harmonization” and From the governmental perspective, and looking at
“streamlining.” Harmonization can be considered as an the international level, attempts to simplify IP systems
“adjustment of differences and inconsistencies among have been enacted for over 130 years. Although not an
different measurements, methods, procedures, sched- exhaustive list, notable treaties and conventions in this
ules, specifications or systems to make them uniform evolution include the Paris Convention (1883)—now
or mutually compatible.” This is certainly an underlying 177 member states, Madrid Agreement (1892), Hague
state of affairs within the IP sector over many decades. Agreement (1925)—with over 60 member states now,
Streamlining is the “improvement of the efficiency of the Patent Cooperation Treaty (1978)—with member-
a process, business or organization by nullifying or ship now exceeding 150, Madrid Protocol (1996)—
eliminating unnecessary steps, and using modernizing now comprising almost 100 members, and the Patent
techniques.” Accordingly when we consider the IP eco- Law Treaty. All of these arrangements between nations
system as a whole we can see that harmonization and represent attempts at the international level to harmon-
streamlining by many of its key stakeholders does in ize and streamline the system(s) for IP owners whilst
fact create the environment for the transition or evolu- at the same time indirectly creating challenges and op-
tion of the IP services Industry. portunities for the IP Service Industry to maximize the
The IP Ecosystem—The Stakeholders benefits of such improved systems for IP owners.
Within the IP sector or ecosystem, who are these Similarly at the regional or multilateral level, treat-
key stakeholders? In its simplest form there are the ies, conventions and processes have been developed to

September 2017 241


Disruption In The IP Services?
simplify systems. Examples include the European Pat- ing on IP, helping IP owners register and maintain their
ent Convention (EPC), ARIPO, OAPI, and the Eurasian property, applying for and securing IP nationally and
Patent Convention. The EPC is a classic example where internationally, helping transfer IP, and assisting the IP
its creation led to the IP Service Industry providing a owners with their portfolios. Although it is difficult to
commoditized service for European Patent Validations. put an exact date on changes, it is reasonable to assert
Similarly at a multilateral level, the growth of the num- that all elements of the IP lifecycle just described were
bers, and members, of Patent Prosecution Highways once the sole domain of the traditional attorney ser-
(PPH) represent a further example of governmental co- vice providers. Perhaps one of the pioneering changes
operation aimed at simplifying (streamlining) systems to this framework was in 1962 when John Dennemeyer
for IP owners. In the Asian region, ASPEC (ASEAN Pat- introduced the first computer based patent annuity
ent Examination Co-operation) represents nine mem- payment service. It can certainly be argued this was the
ber states cooperating on patent examination. commencement of a new type of service provider—
The patent lifecycle is introduced later in this paper, the commodity service provider. Part of this review will
but each of the aforementioned international, regional now look at other areas of the IP lifecycle where com-
and multilateral arrangements all aim to harmonize modity service (or product) providers have entered,
or streamline the patent filing and/or examination thereby resulting in increased competition with the
processes. At the Australian national level in 2015, a traditional attorney services and/or various models of
Consultative Report commissioned by IP Australia ex- collaboration between attorney and commodity service
pressly identified objectives for the agency of aligning, providers. In any event, such developments over time
improving, and simplifying its practices and processes. have seen government IP agencies “cheering from the
sidelines” as the end result has been improved efficien-
IP Service Providers cies, particularly in costs, for IP owners.
Before considering the IP service providers in more Commodity Service Providers
detail it is well worth reviewing the IP lifecycle for the
purpose of broadly categorizing the activities (services Reverting to the IP lifecycle, the logical commence-
and/or products) performed (and by whom) in a typical ment point is the searching component. Today, we see
a multitude of searching options provided by the com-
IP lifecycle. The patent lifecycle is used here for illus-
modity services providers to the IP owners (and to the
trative purposes, but other registrable IP rights such
attorney service providers). These searching solutions
as trademarks and industrial designs could equally act
include freely available databases such as PATENT-
as an illustrative example. The patent lifecycle can be
SCOPE and espacenet provided by government agen-
considered to commence with pre-filing considera-
cies—either international (WIPO) or national IP offic-
tions, the most common being the conduct of suitable
es. Commercial databases are also available (e.g. Del-
patent searches. Following the search activity, the pat-
phion, Derwent, Micropatent, and Questel) and these
ent document will be prepared (drafting,) followed by
all tend to provide some functionality benefit over and
filing (either as a priority or convention/international
above the government agency products. It is this dif-
application), next there is the prosecution or examina- ferentiation of functionality that creates the market-
tion stage leading to grant or registration, and finally place for such commodity service providers, such dif-
concluding with maintenance (e.g. annuities or renew- ferentiation being on the basis of interfacing, detailed
als.) It should, however, be recognized that depend- analytics, language translation capability, statistical
ing on the jurisdiction, such maintenance fees may be analysis, graphical and topographic presentation of re-
payable prior to or concurrently with the registration sults, citation analysis, and the like. It is therefore not
stage. Although not strictly a linear process, for the surprising that searching has been a fertile field for en-
purposes of this example, subsequent commercializa- try of commodity service providers as part of their ser-
tion and/or enforcement can be regarded as the final vice is highly dependent upon information searching
stage(s) in this IP lifecycle. and analysis. To put this in perspective, the number of
Traditional IP Attorney Service Providers patents filed worldwide per year increased three-fold
As already identified, there are essentially three from 1980 to 2010, and five-fold in the case of trade-
major groups of players in the IP service providers marks. Hard disk drive capacity increased 100,000-fold
sector: the traditional IP attorney services, the com- in the same period.
modity product/service providers, and IP management Perhaps the two elements in the IP lifecycle that
and related outsourcing service providers. Using the have most rapidly become commonplace in the IP eco-
Australian Institute of Patent & Trade Mark Attorneys system are the maintenance and filing commodity ser-
(IPTA) website as a reference point, and recognizing vices. The nature of each of these elements are read-
there may be slight deviations between jurisdictions, ily transferable as a commodity, and in each case the
the broad traditional services category includes advis- entry of multiple providers including the pioneers and

242 les Nouvelles


Disruption In The IP Services?
subsequent entrants) provided some initial disruption, list demonstrates the computer based “solutions” that
but over time such services have been subsequently are available in the marketplace to assist the IP owner
improved and enhanced and become more efficient— and/or IP attorney in many of the aspects across the
largely due to the aforementioned explosion in inform- entire IP lifecycle. These tools include IP management
ation technology advances. software, discovery and litigation management, law-
The other two pre-registration elements are patent suit databases, attorney-client management, knowl-
drafting and patent examination/prosecution. In the edge management and document management. The
case of drafting, underlying tasks such as identifying development of such broader based software solutions
relevant prior art, interaction with the client, evaluat- across an IP owners business (particularly those with
ing the scope of an invention etc., cannot be readily large portfolios) provides a convenient segway into the
replaced by computers. However, as already identified, third group of IP management and related outsourcing
some searching and analytical software can assist the service providers.
patent attorney particularly in identifying prior art, and IP Management and Related Outsourcing
already there are some purveyors of software tools that Service Providers
electronically enhance the drafting process. Further, it This review has concentrated on the potential
can be argued that with the development and use of “outsourcing” of various elements of the IP lifecycle
more “intelligent” software at the drafting stage where through the utilization and/or acquisition of cer-
relevant prior art is identified, it then becomes a logical tain products or standalone services that are being
extension to transfer these capabilities to government provided by a myriad of product/service providers. In
patent examiners at their examination stage. Although some cases such products cannot be provided without
not necessarily at the “IT level,” government agencies some form of additional or related “service,” and
(international and national) have become drivers for where such “services” can be considered to relate to
the examination/prosecution phase to become more either a specified product or where this can lead to a
of a commodity. Offices sharing examination reports, broader full service arrangement such as outsourced IP
Patent Prosecution Highways, the use of modified ex- management of an IP portfolio (and most likely using
aminations, together with rapidly evolving information one or more commoditized IP services). This is essen-
technology capabilities are pushing this aspect more tially the third component of the IP service provider
towards a commodity. As an example, and building on category—the management services provided through
these developments, the concept of Flat Fee Prosecu- an outsourcing arrangement.
tion services has been introduced whereby IP owners As indicated above, such outsourced services can be
can benefit from many of these developments. as narrow or broad as the client requires, but ultimate-
At the commercialization stage a number of on- ly the client (IP owner) needs to fully understand its
line platforms have, in more recent times, been pro- own workflows so that it can identify what service(s)
moted—both by government agencies and commer- can be best outsourced—that is, they are demand driv-
cial firms—to enhance the likelihood of successful en, not supply driven. Aligned with this consideration
commercialization of IP outcomes. Examples include is the question by the IP owner: “what competencies
SourceIP (an IP Australia initiative that provides an on- and processes do we (or should we) keep in-house?”
line marketplace for public sector technology), PCTxs, Ultimately there must be tangible benefits in outsourc-
IPNexis, IPMarketplace, IPZone, and IPOPHIL. These ing services, and these benefits broadly fit into three
are essentially a random selection of available plat- categories—improved services, cost-effective servic-
forms that assist in the technology transfer process, es, and more efficient services. Further, it should not
but ultimately somewhere in the IP ecosystem the be forgotten that outsourcing is a partnership between
buyer (licensor) and seller (licensee) need to negotiate two or more parties, and ultimately management, com-
and ultimately “do the deal.” Taking the commercial munication and relationship issues (both current and
deal one step further, software tools are available for potential future) need to be openly and transparently
agreement drafting. However, like the stage of pat- identified and addressed at the outset of any outsourc-
ent drafting, such software can assist but due to the ing partnership.
unique situational circumstances—every deal is differ- Disruption?
ent—this cannot replace the need for personal profes- Having identified the landscape of outsourcing in the
sional input and expertise. IP ecosystem we need to return to the fundamental
Although the foregoing has deliberately concen- question of whether there is disruption in the IP ser-
trated on the individual elements of the IP lifecycle, vices industry. As a broad overview, and assuming the
many other related products are available at a broader consideration of outsourcing is more directed at a com-
management level than for a specific aspect of the IP mercial entity with a relatively large portfolio, we need
lifecycle. Again, whilst not exhaustive, the following to make the potential disclaimer that all companies

September 2017 243


Disruption In The IP Services?
are different and use IP services in different ways to bination. The permutations are endless. It is therefore
meet their business objectives. For example, does the not so much the products/services themselves that are
IP owner utilize an in-house corporate department? or disruptive, but rather when such services or solutions
does it rely solely on an external supplier(s)? or some are not provided consistently with the IP owner’s sys-
hybrid? Further, where it outsources, does it outsource tem and its needs, that the potential for disruption is
“products” and/or “services?” or both? present. Therefore, there are two key messages that
With this in mind we can draw a few general con- evolve. First, for the IP owner—understand your IP
clusions. First, as has been observed, most outsourced system and your needs. Secondly, for the IP service
products and/or services are very information technol- provider—understand where your solution fits in the
ogy intensive and therefore, notwithstanding perceived broader IP ecosystem and how it interfaces (if at all)
benefits of the product or service, inappropriate or in- with other elements of the IP lifecycle.
correct consideration of IT implications can create the Further, to eliminate such disruption requires open-
potential for disruption. Secondly, where the IP owner ness and transparency by both the IP owner and the
uses different vendors for products and/or services, and supplier(s) of the product and/or service to ensure the
in association with the “IT issue,” there is again the po- needs and expectations of the IP owner and the func-
tential for disruption. Thirdly, it must be noted that the tionality and capabilities of the supplier’s products
products and/or services themselves are not necessarily and/or services are aligned so there are no misunder-
disruptive, but rather are transitional or evolutionary standings, both in the short and long term, and expec-
being driven by both the consumer (the IP owner) and tations can be seamlessly met. With this understand-
governments (as agents.) However, mismanagement or ing and alignment as the basis of any partnership, the
lack of coordination of these products and/or services IP owner can expect to reap the benefits of products
by the consumer can create or lead to disruption. and/or services relevant to its business, and take ad-
So, the growth in commoditized IP services has been vantage of the ongoing related improvements arising
largely evolutionary or transitionary, and has been mainly through information technology advances and
strongly influenced by developments in information which are provided by the IP services suppliers, with-
technology. The IP lifecycle embraces many interrelat- out any disruption. ■
ed steps, and as identified in this review, IP Service
Providers can supply solutions (and variants thereof) Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
to virtually all of these steps—either alone or in com- https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009432

244 les Nouvelles


Intangible Asset Market

Intangible Asset Market Value Study?


By Cate M. Elsten and Nick Hill

T
he “Intangible Asset Market Value” (IAMV) This year for the first time we compared certain of its
study conducted by the authors examines the IAMV calculations to Interbrand’s calculation of top
components of market value, and specifically the 100 companies worldwide
role intangible assets play in corporate market capital- by brand value.4 For 39 com- ■ Cate M. Elsten,
izations across a range of indexes around the world.1 panies appearing on both the Ocean Tomo,
We believe IAMV is a strong reflection of innovation in S&P 500 and the Interbrand Managing Director,
the greater economy. This is consistent with a Reuters list, this comparison suggests
article on its list of Top 100 Global Innovators which brand value may represent San Francisco, CA, USA
shows organizations that invest in intangible assets roughly one-fourth or more of E-mail: celsten@
such as patents and research & development (R&D) IAMV on average.5 oceantomo.com
continually outperform the S&P 500.2 As seen in Fig-
Also for the first time this ■ Nick Hill,
ure 1, intangible asset value has continued to grow as
year, we have expanded its
the major component of the S&P 500’s market cap over Ocean Tomo,
IAMV Study beyond the S&P
the past decade.3 500 to explore the compo- Analyst,
While emphasis often falls on technology-driven
nents of value in several key Chicago, IL, USA
intangible assets such as patents and trade secrets,
international markets. Stock E-mail: nhill@
brand value is also an important component of IAMV.
market indexes from Europe, oceantomo.com
China, Japan, and
Figure 1. Components of S&P 500 Market Value South Korea were selected and analyzed
to determine the role intangible assets
play in market value. We selected these
100%
83% 68% 32% 20% 16% four geographies as representing the larg-
est non-U.S. markets for intellectual prop-
80%
80%
84%
erty.6 A summary review of results is as
68%
follows:
60%
S&P Europe 350
40% The S&P Europe 350 index comprises
32%
350 leading blue-chip companies from
20% 16 developed European markets. The
17% authors analyzed the index from 2005
0%
1975 1985 2015
to 2015 to determine how IAMV has
1995 2005
changed over time.
Intangible Assets Tangible Assets
As depicted Figure 2, IAMV was com-
parable at the beginning and end of the
1. “The Intangible Asset Market Value” study is released ten-year period, with a dip in between that may have
annually by Ocean Tomo, LLC, the intellectual capital merchant been due to the global financial crisis that began in
bank™ firm.
late 2007. Compared to other developed regions, Eu-
2. “Innovative Organizations With Intangible Assets Are rope’s overall economy has been slower to recover, as
More Successful Than Counterparts,” Reuters, (October 8,
2013) accessed: http://www.reuters.com/article/us-innovative- euro-zone GDP in the final quarter of 2015 was still
organizations-idUSBRE99707E20131008. below pre-2008 levels. The financial crisis appears
3. We calculate IAMV on a company-by-company basis using
data from publicly available financial statements on Bloomberg. 4. Interbrand Best Global Brands, (2016) 13.
IAMV is determined by subtracting a company’s net tangible 5. Ocean Tomo and Interbrand are unrelated entities and there
asset value from its market cap to determine its net intangible is currently no means of comparing data and methodologies for
asset value. Company data is aggregated for the index, and net the two relevant studies in detail. Therefore, this comparison
intangible asset value is then divided by market cap to determine should be considered approximate rather than precise.
the portion of the index’s value that is derived from intangible
6. “World Intellectual Property Indicators 2015,” World
assets. Companies with insufficient data were excluded from
Intellectual Property Organization, 23.
the calculation.

September 2017 245


Intangible Asset Market

Figure 2. Components of S&P Shanghai Shenzhen CSI 300


Europe 350 Market Value China’s Shanghai Shenzhen CSI 300 Index is a free-
100% float weighted index comprising 300 A-share stocks
33% 29%
29%
listed on the Shanghai or Shenzhen Stock Exchanges.
80% IAMV for this index is approximately half of that for
71%
the S&P Europe 350 and analysis shows IAMV fell 14
60%
71% 67% percent from 2014 to 2015. Although care must be
exercised when examining limited data points, this
40% downward movement may be linked to China’s slow-
ing economy. According to an article from the New
20% York Times, China’s economic growth for 2015 was the
slowest in 25 years.8
0%
2005 2010
China’s patent office, the State Intellectual Property
2015
Intangible Assets Tangible Assets
Office (SIPO) is still relatively young, as its prede-
cessor (the Patent Office of the People’s Republic of
China) was founded in 1980. This, along with the role
to have had a specific impact on Europe’s innovation of traditional manufacturing in the Chinese economy,
economy. According to a publication from the Euro- could in part explain why intangible asset value is a
pean Commission, Europe has recently lagged behind much smaller percentage of overall market cap than in
countries like Japan and South Korea in terms of in- more established Western markets. As China begins to
novation, but plans to focus on this more heavily in predictably enforce patent rights and reform infringe-
the future to help boost the overall economy.7 Current ment recoveries, and as Chinese companies begin to
innovation activity levels notwithstanding, Europe re- file more patents and buy patents in foreign markets,
mains second only to the U.S. in the relative contri- Chinese IAMV could change dramatically in the future.
bution of intangible assets to market capitalization as Nikkei 225
measured by this study and is still well ahead of the Japan’s Nikkei 225 Stock Average is a price-weighted
major Asian markets. As Europe begins to invests more average of 225 top-rated Japanese companies listed in
in technology and the European patent marketplace, the First Section of the Tokyo Stock Exchange. IAMV
we may see a rise in intangible asset value in the next grew 14 percent in Japan from 2014 to 2015, indicating
several years. At this time, it is too soon to tell how the Japan’s continued recovery from the global financial cri-
Brexit vote may impact this. sis. However, IAMV seems to be a somewhat surprisingly
Asian Markets small portion of the Japanese economy as measured by
The authors also analyzed IAMV for major Asian eq- this study. We believe this could be in part due to Japan’s
uity markets. Due to unavailability of comparable data, loss of tech share to countries such as China and South
we limited its analysis to 2015. Based on the data, Korea, which have become innovation powerhouses in
the past several years with the rise of companies such
IAMV appears to be a much smaller component of over-
as Huawei, ZTE and Samsung. The BBC reported that
all market cap in Asia than in Western economies. The
several Japanese electronics giants have suffered in re-
pie charts below show a breakdown of the components
cent years due to the global shifting of technology from
of market value for three Asian indexes in 2015. complex electrical machines to software-rich devices
that favor new competitors
Kosdaq Composite Index Shanghai Shenzhen CSI 300 Nikkei 225 from South Korea and China.9
Adapting to this “new tech”
will likely be a priority for Jap-
anese companies in the future
35% 31% and may impact future IAMVs.
46% 54%
65% 69%
8. “As China’s Economy Slows,
a Look at What Could Happen,”
The New York Times, (October
18, 2016). http://www.nytimes.
Intangible Asset Value IAMV 2014-2015 IAMV 2014-2015
Growth Rate: -14% Growth Rate: +14%
com/2016/10/19/business/
Intangible Asset Value
inter national/china-economy-
slows-impact.html?_r=0).
7. “Innovation Union: A Pocket Guide on a Europe 2020 9. “What Happened to Japan’s Electronic Giants?,” BBA News,
Initiative,” European Commission, 3. https://ec.europa.eu/eip/ (April 2, 2013). http://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-21992700.
agriculture/sites/agri-eip/files/innovation-pocket-book_en.pdf.

246 les Nouvelles


Intangible Asset Market
Kosdaq Composite Index pensing development, maintenance, and restoration
Korea’s KOSDAQ Index is a capitalization-weighted costs of internally generated intangible assets as they
index that measures the performance of the KOSDAQ occur16 and limits balance sheet recognition of most
market, a collection of South Korean equities. The intangible assets to those that are acquired as part of
data shows an increase in IAMV over the past two a purchase or other business combination. In theory
years. An article from German broadcaster Deutsche this should have the directional effect of depressing
Welle commented that “Innovation and technology are U.S. IAMV relative to countries allowing more liberal
the key factors that have underpinned South Korean balance sheet recognition of self-created intangibles.
export competitiveness and fueled the country’s re- However, the magnitude of these differences cannot
markable economic rise over the past decades.”10 In be readily calculated with currently available data.
addition, the 2016 Bloomberg Innovation Index, which Beyond these reporting differences, questions re-
ranks countries based on different categories including main as to why various geographic regions display their
R&D, high-tech companies, manufacturing, research relative IAMV positions. For example, a study by the
personnel, patents and education, ranked South Korea Global Intellectual Property Center (GIPC), which is
as having the world’s most innovative economy, ahead similar to the 2016 Bloomberg Innovation Index study
of Germany, Sweden, Japan, and Switzerland.11 This but with some difference in criteria, ranks countries
surge in tech activity appears to be reflected in South based on a variety of categories related to IP to de-
Korea’s relatively high IAMV compared to the other termine each country’s overall IP score.17 Consistent
major Asian economies. with the IAMV calculations prepared by the authors,
Comparing Geographic Regions the GIPC study ranks the U.S., UK and France as the
top three countries with the strongest IP environment.
As an initial matter, when comparing geographic
Japan is ranked sixth by the GIPC, which notes that
regions it is important to bear in mind the impact of
Japan has “significant weaknesses in its participation
differing accounting standards. For example, Interna-
in international IP treaties.”18 However, China ranks
tional Accounting Standard (IAS) 38, effective March
much lower on the GIPC list, nearly 12 points behind
2004, allows for circumstances in which internally
Japan. The GIPC study states that while China has
generated intangible assets can be recognized on the
made some improvements in recent years in patent
balance sheet and capitalized over the life of the as-
rights, enforcement and rapid movement of counter-
set, as opposed to being expensed as development
feiting still remain challenges.19 These results appear
costs.12 Many countries, including South Korea and
at odds with the IAMV analysis. As more comparable
some European countries have adopted this stand-
data points become available, the underlying reasons
ard.13 In Japan, IAS 38 is currently optional, however,
for the relative IAMV positions of different economies
as of January 2015, 62 companies with over $650 bil-
will be studied in more depth.
lion of market cap on the Tokyo Stock Exchange had
adopted IFRS.14 Similar to IAS 38, China’s account- In conclusion, data spanning more than a quar-
ing standards call for recognition of internally gen- ter century for the U.S. make it clear the economy
erated development costs as intangible assets if they is inverting from one where value was measured by
meet certain requirements.15 The U.S., on the other “touch” to one where value is driven by thought. This
hand, follows GAAP which in most cases calls for ex- change has been no less significant than the industrial
revolution more than a century ago. Although a sim-
10. “Why Innovation is King in South Korea,” DW.com, ilar time series of data is not available for European
(February 10, 2016). http://www.dw.com/en/why-innovation-is- and Asian markets, simple observation of the nature
king-in-south-korea/a-19038625.
of companies that increasingly dominate these econ-
11. Ibid. omies suggest something of the same nature has oc-
12. “IAS 38—Intangible Assets,” IASPlus. https://www. curred and is likely continuing to occur there. Further
iasplus.com/en/standards/ias/ias38.
data and analysis will be available as time progresses,
13. “Use of IFRS by Jurisdiction,” IASPlus. https://www. and are required to more fully understand and predict
iasplus.com/en/resources/ifrs-topics/use-of-ifrs#Note12.
innovation trends. ■
14. Japan also permits companies to use Japanese Accounting
Standards or US GAAP, both of which call for expensing internally Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
generated intangible assets as research and development costs https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009783
as they incur. “IFRS as Global Standards: A Pocket Guide,”
IFRS Foundation, (2015) 95. http://www.ifrs.org/Use-around- 16. “Goodwill and Other Intangible Assets—Key Differences
the-world/Documents/IFRS-as-global-standards-Pocket-Guide- Between U.S. GAAP and IFRSs,” USGAAPPlus. https://www.
April-2015.PDF; Ernst & Young, “JGAAP-IFRS Comparison,” iasplus.com/en-us/standards/ifrs-usgaap/goodwill.
https://www.shinnihon.or.jp/services/ifrs/issue/ifrs-others/other/
pdf/ifrs-jgaap-comparison-v30-E.pdf. 17. “Charting the Course,” Global Intellectual Property
Center, Second Edition (January 2014) 29.
15. “Accounting Standard for Business Enterprises No. 6—
Intangible Assets,” Laws of the People’s Republic of China. 18. Ibid.
http://www.asianlii.org/cn/legis/cen/laws/asfben6ia630. 19. Ibid., 30.
September 2017 247
Software IPR Valuation Model

Software IPR Valuation Model


By Dr. Santosh Mohanty and Kaushik Gala

Abstract cell values are, in turn, linked to business outcomes e.g.


The hyper-connected world we live in is fundamental- strategy, defensibility, market coverage, and customer
ly altering our lives. Digital technologies are challenging value. These 16 weighted values, along with simple
long-held norms. Inventions and their related intellec- inputs related to commercial pricing, then result in a
tual property rights (IPR) are crucial for enterprises to systematic valuation of the invention, while accounting
differentiate themselves in a highly competitive global for changes in the estimated valuation over a period of
market. Software enterprises, in particular, are at risk time.
of rapid obsolescence unless they capture, protect and The IVSS model thus provides a systematic, tech-
leverage their innovation ecosystem and IPR portfolio. no-commercial methodology to evaluate a portfolio
Intellectual property (IP) is hotly contested in an of software IPR assets, in the context of enterprise
industry that innovates fast and where technological software IPR management. We illustrate a specific use-
case of IVSS to evaluate software IPR related to a mo-
and design advantages can result in large opportunities.
bile-first agricultural services delivery platform for rural
New companies have emerged whose sole activity is to
farmers in India.
create and lease IP. There are companies that disrupted
the business models and displaced the titans. Whereas Introduction

A
few others have achieved the zenith and then disappea- patented invention requires novel, inventive
red from the scene as a result of market dynamics. steps towards technical and process advance-
Software inventions are inherently different from ments, as well as, utility for commercialization.
those in physical sciences, hardware, and such. Evalua- Such inventions usually constitute the IP assets of soft-
ting them requires a novel approach, given the variety ware enterprises. While mining and protecting such
of ways in which software intellectual property can be inventions, IP managers seek to determine the tangi-
developed, protected, regulated, productized, mone- ble value attached to each intangible asset, so as to en-
tized and infringed. Traditional approaches to IPR valua- able the enterprise’s decision on creating, maintaining
tion such as market-based, cost-based and income-based and monetizing IPR assets. Significant challenges exist
may be irrelevant or cumbersome, given the dynamic for efficient and effective valuation of software inven-
nature of the software industry. Software IPR valuation tions. These include rapid technology change and ob-
is highly contextual and hence, providing relevant input solescence, new go-to-market models, globalization of
software creation and use, dynamic pricing strategies
for traditional valuation models becomes prohibitively
enabled by software, ease of infringement and theft
time-consuming, especially for valuation exercises at a
of software IP, uncertainty in regulatory protection for
portfolio level. Digital transformation of all industries
software IP, etc.
makes software IPR exponentially more valuable.
Software IP can be formally protected via Copy-
To enable global enterprises to quickly and systema-
rights, Trademarks, Patents, Industrial Designs, etc.
tically evaluate their software IP, we introduce a model
From an enterprise perspective, each invention is an
called Invention Valuation and Scoring System (IVSS). IP asset only if the value it delivers exceeds its asso-
The model relies on two primary dimensions: ciated costs. Thus, each invention must be evaluated
1. Sustainability “S” of an invention i.e. how futu- throughout its life cycle viz., from ideation to patent
ristic, agile, resource-efficient and adaptable is the drafting to territorial protections, and finally commer-
software by design; and cialization and patent maintenance. Since IPR such as
2. Commercial Viability “C” of an invention i.e. patents have a defined expiration date, the valuation
how well it can be operationalized, made relevant to model must also account for changes over time. Each
customers, and profitably delivered to a large/fast- invention should ideally be evaluated against others
growing market. within the portfolio, so as to support managerial deci-
Each dimension has four attributes, thus resulting sions on IPR maintenance, go-to-market strategy (e.g.,
in a “4Sx4C” matrix with 16 cells, each cell of which product licensing vs. IP licensing vs. IP sale), etc. Final-
can be assigned a value. Since this model is to be used ly, an ideal IP valuation model should be comprehen-
by a commercial enterprise driven by profit/revenue sive, systematic, quick, and intuitive; it should require
growth targets and shareholder value creation, the 16 minimal, simple human inputs.

248 les Nouvelles


Software IPR Valuation Model
Traditional Models of IP Valuation value creation possibility via network effects, “winner-
Three common approaches to IP valuation have i take-all” effects and the likes. The difficulty in enforce-
traditionally been: cost-based, market-based and in- ment of software IP rights greatly affect its valuation.viii
come-based. Furthermore, the choice of market and path to market
can lead to substantially different “realized” valuesix of
Each approach requires a set of inputs based on
software IP (e.g., Pets.com vs. Amazon.com). It has also
past experience and expert judgment. For example,
been arguedx that software IP can serve as a tax by
the cost-based approach requires the evaluator to as-
larger companies on smaller companies.
sess what a similar IP asset might cost to develop or
acquire. The market-approach requires the value at IVSS Model
■ Dr. Santosh Mohanty,
which similar IP assets have been recently sold in the In a B2B software en-
market. The income-approach requires an estimate of terprise, the IP assets and Tata Consultancy Services
future cash flows from monetization of the asset, and a IPR that are developed are Limited, Vice President
discount rate to compute the net present value. usually consumed by the and Head Component
These approaches are, of course, subject to errors products, platforms and Engineering Group,
due to incorrect inputs, lack of availability of relevant solutions that are offered
Mumbai, India
data, human biases, insufficient expertise on part of to customers. This implies
that the IP valuation mod- E-mail: santosh.mohanty@
the evaluator, incorrect definition of the IP asset, etc. tcs.com
Given the commercial sensitivity of IP assets, public- el used by such enterpris-
ly-available data is often limited or less reliable. More- es accounts for the wide ■ Kaushik Gala,
over, since there are numerous ways to commercialize variety of IP assets (from
Tata Consultancy Services
an IP asset, its value is intricately tied to the context snippets of code to stand-
in which it is marketed. Qualitative methods are also alone products to large Limited, Manager,
sometimes used for patent valuations. These rely on at- software platforms) in the IP Ecosystem Strategy
tributes such as number of independent claims, num- portfolio. Moreover, the Mumbai, India
ber of forward citations, age of the patent, geograph- volume of IP assets and E-mail: k.gala@tcs.com
ic coverage, breadth of portfolio, etc. However, such IPR expected to be cre-
methods remain peripheral in counting business and ated in a large software
market factors, and remain exposed to human biases. business necessitates a systematic approach to IP val-
Despite these limitations, IP managers continue to uation. In fact, an enterprise that offers both software
use, and refine, the above methods to compute IP valu- services and software products requires a sharp dis-
ations, usually by triaging the valuation estimatesii made tinction between its IP assets and those of its custom-
using independent methods, and explicitly noting the ers. This boundary can keep changing over time and
assumptions in the model. The importance of contextiii based on the nature of customer engagements.
has become apparent—the value of a patent may dif- The above requirements, unique to software IP, led
fer by orders of magnitude depending on whether it’s us to refine an earlier, proprietary modelxi for inven-
being sold, licensed, infringed, contributed to a stand- tion valuation and rationalization that accounts for
ards pool, or found to be invalid. Needless to say, there both technical and commercial aspects, their dynamic
are numerous alternative modelsiv being used that ac- nature, and the mapping of IPR to business outcomes.
count for factors such as brand, liquidation value, auc- Sustainability “S” Attributes:
tion value, real options value, etc. In fact, IP valuation Our model seeks to evaluate each software IP on
is further challenged by the fact that it may be done
four dimensions, related to its innovativeness and sus-
as part of in-kind arrangements, fire sales, academic
tenance of the corresponding competitive advantage.
collaborations, etc.v—these in turn require valuation
These are as follows:
inputs and models different from typical licensing/
sales. Given that a majority of patents expire without 1. “Anticipative”—does the invention anticipate
a worth, while a small fraction are worth millions,vi a future needs of market, technology, etc. and create
robust need exists for patent buy/sell transaction data ‘novelty’ at the present time to address it? Will it sus-
as a reliable input to IP valuation models. tain despite the changing nature of market forces?
Software IP Valuation 2. “Agile”—can the “inventive steps” in the inven-
tion sense the current needs and provide a responsive
Valuation of software IP offers an entirely new chal-
lenge, given the variety of ways in which software solution, via a fast track process to transform the IP
inventions can be created, protected, monetized and into products or service offerings?
its enforcement through contracts. Income-based val- 3. “Efficient”—will the invention, when reduced
uation models seem to be more relevantvii given the to practice, allow “doing more with less” in terms
intangible nature of software IP and the non-linear of lower cost, minimum infrastructural modification,

September 2017 249


Software IPR Valuation Model
time reduction, better quality, less effort, etc.? Also, given the incredibly dynamic nature of the soft-
4. “Adaptable”—is the invention flexible and resili- ware industry, and the ease of “bypassing” software
ence to change, i.e., are the inventive steps applicable, IPR, we seek to give greater emphasis on the “anticipa-
with minimal change, to similar scenarios or problems? tive” aspects of invention and the realization of “out-
Does it balance personalization with mechanization? come.” Hence, we choose to weight the 16 cells in the
Commercializability “C” Attributes: above 4x4 matrix as follows:
Our model also seeks to evaluate each software IP • Base weight of “1” for each cell
on four other, orthogonal dimensions, related to its op- • Double the base weight for the cells under “Out-
erational and marketable strength as an asset. These come” column or “Anticipative” row (Hence, the base
are as follows: weight of the cell under “Outcome” column and ‘An-
1. “Technology”—does the invention utilize or cre- ticipative’ row is multiplied by a factor of “4”)
ate state-of-the-art technology, and its associated pro- The Weight Table is presented below as Table 2:
cesses and on-demand, elastic infrastructure, to deliv- Note that the total weight across the 16 cells is 25.
er maximum customer value?
2. “Context”—does the invention
leverage the enterprise’s contextual Table 2
knowledge of customers, industry play- Weight (W) Outcome GTM Context Technology
ers, business domain, white spaces and Table
market dynamics?
3. “GTM”—does the invention ena- Anticipative W:4 W:2 W:2 W:2

ble new, disruptive go-to-market (GTM) Agile W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1
strategies, scaling, distribution channels
or revenue models for the enterprise? Efficient W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1

4. “Outcome”—will the invention Adaptable W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1


have a meaningfully positive outcome for
the business and its stakeholders?
Inventions in a software enterprise are driven by
The first three attributes are “lead” attributes in a current or anticipated business opportunity. Inven-
the sense that these capabilities are pre-requisites for tors are aligned with requirements from development
the IP to be monetized. The fourth attribute is a “lag” teams, inputs from sales and marketing teams, and the
measure of the invention’s impact. Also, the technol- need of the customers. Each patentable/patented in-
ogy and the associated rate of change is becoming key vention is hence expected to have the following char-
for a software enterprise to grow sustainability—much acteristics:
more than process or infrastructure. Being able to de-
a) Align to business strategy, operations and initia-
liver context-specific value to the customer, and take
tives (“Aligned”)—at a granular level, can the patent
inventions to market is the key to success in this digital
be mapped to specific products that the enterprise in-
age of mass customization.
tends to sell, leveraging its market and customer dis-
4Sx4C Matrix: covery efforts?
We capture these 4 “S” and 4 “C” attributes of each b) Be difficult for other industry players to repro-
invention via a 4x4 matrix, as below in Table 1: duce (“Unique”) quickly—is the invention incremen-
Weighted 4Sx4C Matrix: tal (and hence likely to be imitated easily) or disruptive
(and hence, difficult to reproduce)?
Table 1 c) Cover a broad and rapidly growing customer base,
across geographies (“Broad”)—is the total/addressa-
Table Outcome GTM Context Technology ble market and target market share large enough in the
Anticipative context of the enterprise’s revenue and profit goals?
Will the invention enable broad market coverage, de-
Agile spite the varying ability and willingness of different
Efficient
countries to enforce patent protections?
d) Drive value creation, and thus strengthen en-
Adaptable terprise brand, in the mind of the customer (“Valua-
ble”)—does the invention enable a competitive moat,
As a commercial enterprise, the business outcomes as demonstrated in value to the customer, that helps
of an IP asset or IPR are most critical in the valuation. maintain/boost profit margins?

250 les Nouvelles


Software IPR Valuation Model
These four factors can then be added to the 4Sx4C i. Determining the weighted score of each cell by
matrix to evaluate a particular invention. While all the multiplying the respective characteristic’s Boolean
four characteristics are associated with each cell in value with the cell weight; and
the 16-cell matrix, we have identified the most influ- ii. Computing the total score by adding the weighted
encing characteristic associated with each cell in the scores of all 16 cells.
4Sx4C matrix. This is especially true as we focus on Note that the maximum Invention Score (IS) for any
enterprise software inventions, and seek to promote particular invention is 25—while the minimum can
the IVSS model amongst a large number of users/in- be zero.
ventors, each of whom is expected to provide inputs Each invention in an IPR portfolio can thus be in-
to the valuation model. We have mapped the relevant dividually scored by inventors and IP managers. They
characteristic to each cell, as shown in Table 3.
only need to provide a set of 16 Boolean inputs, based
These questions help provide a Boolean (i.e. 0 or 1) on the relevant degree of product, domain and cus-
value for the relevant characteristics (Aligned/Unique/ tomer insights. It can be argued that absent these in-
Broad/Valuable) for a particular cell. sights, it wouldn’t be possible for inventors to develop
Thus, an invention’s score is computed in two a patentable invention anyways! The next step is to
steps as follows: convert the IS into a numerical valuation estimate.

Table 3
IVSS Table Outcome GTM Context Technology

Broad: Will the invention Unique: Will the invention Valuable: Does the Aligned: Does the
enable us to target anchor lead to competitively invention use our customer invention leverage our
Anticipative customers in new, high- advantageous GTM insights to anticipate technology investments
growth markets? strategies? future, unmet needs? and human capital?

Unique: Will the invention Broad: Will the invention


Aligned: Will the invention
Valuable: Does the invention help us gain new customer enable us to compete
allow us to rapidly capture
Agile market share in high-
allow us to quickly scale our insights, not easily despite/because-
marketing and sales? available to other industry of rapidly evolving
growth lines of business?
players? technologies?

Unique: Will the invention Valuable: Does the


Aligned: Does the invention Broad: Can the invention
enable us to improve invention leverage/
introduce operational cater to both price-
Efficient and sustain higher profit
efficiencies in marketing conscious and premium
create technology to
margins, and avoid offer a compelling value
and sales? customers?
commoditization? proposition?

Unique: Will the


Broad: Does the invention
Valuable: Does the Aligned: Will the invention invention allow us to
enable us to market and
Adaptable invention allow us to mass-
sell to a wider variety of
easily evolve with changing serve customers that
customize our offerings? customer requirements? other industry players
customers?
cannot?

Table 4
IVSS Table Outcome GTM Context Technology
Broad (0/1) Unique (0/1) Valuable (0/1) Aligned (0/1)
* * * *
Anticipative
W:4 W:2 W:2 W:2

Aligned (0/1) Valuable (0/1) Unique (0/1) Broad (0/1)


* * * *
Agile
W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1

Unique (0/1) Aligned (0/1) Broad (0/1) Valuable (0/1)


* * * *
Efficient
W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1

Valuable (0/1) Broad (0/1) Aligned (0/1) Unique (0/1)


* * * *
Adaptable W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1

September 2017 251


Software IPR Valuation Model
Initial and Time-dependent Valuation: fering. One proxy for this is the royalty rates that an IP
B2B enterprises, by definition, market their software license can command, if the invention was licensed to
products, platforms and solutions to business users, another enterprise, which then productizes and com-
not (mass market) consumers. Commercial imple- mercializes the invention. Based on our professional
mentation of inventions are thus expected to be con- knowledge, we have estimated royalty rate, if licensed
sumed by users such as corporate employees, middle (RRIL) in the context of a variety of software offer-
management, executives, CXOs, etc. Thus, invention ings that include Components; Frameworks; Proof-of-
creation in an enterprise is usually contextual, driven Concept, Proof-of-Technology, and Demos; Products;
by a business case, with a reasonable idea of the target Platforms; and Solutions. We use this factor (RRIL) to
customer and the corresponding product or platform further modulate the invention valuation. RRIL can
or solution that will consume the invention. As soft- vary from 0.5 percent to 20 percent.
ware gets more consumerized and personalized, B2B We are now able to compute initial (base) valuation
enterprises have to act in B2B2C mode, by anticipating of each invention as a function of the market it targets
and adapting to the needs of the consumers. In fact, (via revenue estimates of the corresponding product),
the border between pure B2B and pure B2C will con- and the degree of its contribution and/or attribution to
tinue to thin out, as digital technologies will transform a commercial outcome.
the consumption pattern. Base Valuation
Thus, a ballpark estimate can be made in many cases The Base Valuation of an Invention (BVI) is defined
by the product management on as its value on the first year and computed as follows:
• Sale price per an unique user, called Value per Unit BVI = NUS * VUS * CAF * RRIL
Sale (VUS).
Alternate Base Valuation
• Number of annual “sales” expected in steady state,
in-line with annual revenue targeted in the business Alternatively, there may be cases where either the
case, called Number of Unit Sales (NUS). inventor has reasonably good benchmark data for
VUS is expected to be in the currency relevant to the value of similar inventions or the invention is of
the target market (US$, by default.) This can be con- “fundamental” nature and not yet mapped to a specif-
verted to another currency using an adjustment factor ic product. In such cases, the IVSS model allows the
such as the Purchasing Power Index (PPI). inventor to directly provide an initial estimate of BVI.
Over time, as the invention is mapped to a commercial
Furthermore, each invention either may be contrib- offering, the BVI will be revised using the formula de-
uted by a team of inventors associated with a software veloped above.
development team or may get attributed to a software
as a part of periodic patent-product mapping exercise Valuation Over Time
to mine enterprise’s invention portfolio. The valuation of software IP assets and IPR will neces-
We thus introduce the Contribution-Attribution sarily change over time, given the inherently dynamic
Factor (CAF) that is simply a function of the total num- nature of technology, industry and market. Rapid com-
ber of inventions associated with the same software moditization of software technology, combined with
as the one targeted by a given invention, computed as exponential pace of innovation, implies that the value
follows: of the majority of software inventions may drastically
reduce in a relatively short time span. Digital trans-
CAF = 1 / Total relevant inventions
formation, of and via software, introduces significant
The CAF calculation thus nudges the product man- variations in how fast, or slow, a given invention will
ager to consciously search the enterprise patent portfo- lose its differentiator to commercial success.
lio for relevant patents, thus broadening the product’s We seek to model this by computing a time-depend-
IP footprint. This is driven systematically by a collab- ent invention valuation (IV) as follows:
orative invention mining (CIM) strategyxii intended to
unearth related inventions from within the existing
portfolio. In fact, the Digital IP Genome setxii allows
rapid portfolio mining, using claim elements as the Wherein, “t” is the year, N is the maximum possi-
core search criteria. This is crucial in a large enterprise ble Invention Score (IS) (i.e. 25) and α is defined as
where inventors across multiple R&D labs, business a “smoothing parameter” ( ≥α≥1). The “smoothing
units, operations and infrastructure groups create IPR parameter” α depends on t and is driven by factors
assets whose claims happen to cover same invention such as changes in technology, target market growth,
subject areas. competitive intensity, life cycle of the invention, crea-
Finally, we account for the fact that IP rights contrib- tion of adjacent inventions, change in business strate-
ute only a certain fraction to the overall commercial of- gy, etc. By default, α =1.

252 les Nouvelles


Software IPR Valuation Model
Note that the valuation of an invention in the first • Number of annual “sales” expected in steady
year equates to BVI itself, i.e. IV(1)=BVI. If the calcu- statexv i.e. Number of Unit Sales (NUS) = 50,000
lated shelf-life for a patent
IS is “t~,” then IV (t~) > 0.1
N
• CAF = 1/11 (there are eleven inventions that con-
percent * IV (0). tribute to this commercial offering)
Lifetime Valuation of an Invention (LVI): • RRIL = 7.5 percent
We compute the Lifetime Valuation of the Invention Thus, BVI = VUS * NUS * CAF * RRIL ~ INR
(LVI) as a sum of its yearly valuations over a specified 340,000.
period “n”: The illustration can also be extended to compute a
lifetime valuation estimate, using:

Wherein n=20 by default, since the lifetime of a


patent is ~20 years, ignoring patent term adjustments For α =1.5, and n=20, the LVI works out to ~ INR
across jurisdictions and starting the time period from 900,000.
the date of filing of the Complete Specification. LVI
estimates the total revenue that an invention might
Summary
generate over its life-cycle. The rise of software-driven enterprises highlights
the increasing importance of software IP and IPR (par-
Example: Patented Agro Service Delivery
ticularly patents) for sustainable growth. As they en-
Platform
gage in continuous software innovation, global tech-
Multiple inventions were developed and protected nology businesses need to systematically evaluate their
as part of the creation of a personalized, mobile-first, software IP. A portfolio-wide estimate of the market
agricultural services delivery platformxiii for rural farm- value of software IP assets is key to strategic R&D in-
ers across India. It is also applicable for fisheries and vestments, IP filings and go-to-market initiatives.
cattle management. Services delivered over the plat-
To support this, we introduce a model called Inven-
form include site-specific agro advisory, pest control,
tion Valuation and Scoring System (IVSS) for compre-
best practices, food grain price alerts, weather fore- hensive valuation of software IPR by business manag-
casts, farm produce procurement, local language train- ers. The model first captures sustainability and com-
ing, information about loans, etc. One such invention mercial viability aspects of an invention in a “4Sx4C”
is Indian Patent No. 271147—“A mobile-based adviso- matrix with 16 cells. Each cell is then assigned a
ry system.”xiv Boolean value, linked to business outcomes e.g. strate-
We illustrate the valuation exercise for this invention gy, defensibility, market coverage, and customer value.
by scoring it as shown in Table 5. These 16 weighted values, along with simple inputs
Thus, the weighted Invention Score (IS) works out related to commercial pricing, enable systematic valu-
to 16. ation of an invention, while accounting for changes in
We then convert the IS to a numerical base valuation the estimated valuation over a period of time. We have
estimate, with these inputs: the illustration of IVSS through a patent in a subject
• Sale price per an unique user i.e. Value per Unit area of “mobile-first agricultural services delivery plat-
Sale (VUS) = INR 1000 subscription per year form for rural farmers.”

Table 5
IVSS Table Outcome GTM Context Technology
Broad (1) Unique (1) Valuable (1) Aligned (1)
* * * *
Anticipative
W:4 W:2 W:2 W:2

Aligned (0) Valuable (0) Unique (0) Broad (1)


* * * *
Agile
W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1

Unique (0) Aligned (0) Broad (1) Valuable (1)


* * * *
Efficient
W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1

Valuable (1) Broad (0) Aligned (1) Unique (0)


* * * *
Adaptable W:2 W:1 W:1 W:1

September 2017 253


Software IPR Valuation Model
We intend to further refine the model over time, viii. Susanna Hult, “Valuation of Intellectual Proper-
with finer estimates of inputs such as royalty rates, his- ties,” KTH, Sweden, (2012).
torical estimates of the smoothing parameter “α”, and • https://www.nada.kth.se/utbildning/grukth/exjobb/
development of similar models for software and other rapportlistor/2012/rapporter12/hult_susanna_12060.pdf.
IP assets. ■ ix. “State of Practice in Software Valuation,” Intel-
©2017, Tata Consultancy Services Limited. All Rights Reserved. lectual Asset Management, 2013.
• http://www.iam-media.com/Magazine/Issue/59/
References Features/State-of-practice-in-software-valuation.
i. “Methods of Intellectual Property Valuation,” x. Colleen Chien, “The Market for Software Innova-
Darden, University of Virginia, (2000). tion Through the Lens of Patent Licenses and Sales,”
• https://faculty.darden.virginia.edu/chaplin- Santa Clara University School of Law, 2017.
skys/PEPortal/Documents/IP%20Valuation%20 • http://digitalcommons.law.scu.edu/facpubs/943.
F-1401%20_watermark_.pdf. xi. Santosh Kumar Mohanty, “Invention Valuation
ii.. “IP Valuation, Exploitation and Finance,” WIPO- and Scoring System,” US20130166459A1, Tata Con-
PwC Workshop, (2011). sultancy Services Limited, (2013).
• http://www.wipo.int/edocs/mdocs/sme/en/wipo_ • https://www.google.com/patents/US20130166459.
smes_tlv_11/wipo_smes_tlv_11_ref_t15.pdf. xii. Santosh Kumar Mohanty, “Managing Sustaina-
iii. “Final Report from the Expert Group on Intel- ble Intellectual Property Portfolio of an Enterprise,”
lectual Property Valuation,” European Commission, US9633403B2, Tata Consultancy Services Limited,
(2013). (2013).
• https://ec.europa.eu/research/innovation-union/ • https://www.google.com/patents/US9633403
pdf/Expert_Group_Report_on_Intellectual_Proper- XIII. “mKRISHI—Connecting India’s Rural Farm-
ty_Valuation_IP_web_2.pdf. ers,” TCS Innovation Labs, (Mumbai, 2017).
iv. Weston Anson, “Alternate Approaches to the Val- • https://www.tcs.com/mkrishi-connecting-india-ru-
uation of Intellectual Property,” IP Watchdog, (2015). ral-farmers.
• http://www.ipwatchdog.com/2015/02/11/alter- XIV. “A Mobile-based Advisory System,” Indian Pat-
nate-approaches-to-the-valuation-of-intellectual-prop- ent No. 271147, Tata Consultancy Services, 2016.
erty/id=54651.
• http://www.allindianpatents.com/pat-
v. “A Practical Guide for Valuing Intangible Assets ents/271147-a-mobile-based-advilsory-system.
in Research and Development Institutions,” WIPO,
(2016). xv. “Evolution of mKRISHI®: A Technology Platform
for Indian Farmers,” Business Innovation Facility,
• http://www.wipo.int/edocs/mdocs/mdocs/en/ 2013.
cdip_17/cdip_17_inf_2.pdf.
• http://www.inclusivebusinesshub.org/wp-content/
vi. Hayes & Soloway, “Patent Valuation,” (2016). uploads/2016/05/Deepdive_mKRISHI_HUB-14.pdf.
• http://www.hayes-soloway.com/patent-valuation.
vii. Gio Wiederhold, “What is Your Software
Worth?,” Stanford University, (2007). Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN):
• http://ilpubs.stanford.edu:8090/862/1/worth43.pdf. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3009919

254 les Nouvelles


Recent U.S. Decisions

Recent U.S. Court Decisions And Developments


Affecting Licensing
By John Paul and D. Brian Kacedon

1. Taxation of Patent Transfer 2. Patent Litigation Settlement Agreements


Obtaining favorable capital gains taxation treat- May Be Used to Support Reasonable Royalty
ment on payments for transferring patent rights. Damages in Later Litigation
2. Reasonable Royalty Litigation settlement
Using patent litigation settlement agreements to sup- agreements can be submit- ■ John C. Paul,
port reasonable royalty damages in later litigation. ted as evidence to establish
Finnegan, Henderson, Farabow,
3. Infringement by Offers for Sale the amount of reasonable
royalty damages and are Garrett & Dunner, LLP,
Avoiding liability for patent infringement when
listing infringing products of third-party sellers on more likely to be admit- Attorney,
a website. ted into evidence when Washington, D.C., USA
4. Litigation Bars by Collateral Estoppel they occur at a later stage E-mail: john.paul@finnegan.com
Using a summary affirmance by the Federal Circuit to of the litigation, if the use
prevent infringement issues from being re-litigated. of the patented technology ■ D. Brian Kacedon,
by the party that settled is Finnegan, Henderson, Farabow,
5. Standing to Sue similar to the use made by
Challenging a litigation agent’s standing to sue for the accused infringer, and Garrett & Dunner, LLP,
infringement and attempting to cure standing by if there are no enhanced Partner,
joining the patent owner. damages at issue in the set- Washington, D.C., USA
6. Patent Marking tled litigation. E-mail: brian.kacedon@
Attempting to avoid patent marking requirements 3. eBay Not Liable
by a retroactive disclaimer. finnegan.com
for Listing Infringing
7. Willful Infringement Products of Third-Par-
Attempting to establish willful infringement based ty Sellers—Not an Offer to Sell by eBay
on activities by an infringer after it is sued for pat- An Alabama court granted eBay’s motion for sum-
ent infringement. mary judgment, finding that eBay’s hosting of a listing
8. Injunctions created by a third party does not constitute an “offer
Losing the opportunity for injunctive relief by li- to sell,” and thus, eBay could not be liable for patent
censing patents to competitors. infringement as a matter of law.
9. Venue for Suit 4. A Summary Affirmance by the Federal Cir-
Dealing with new restrictions on where patent cuit Can Bar Re-Litigation of Infringement
owners may sue for patent infringement. Claims
  The Federal Circuit held that the doctrine of col-
Below are abstracts, for the full articles go to: lateral estoppel could bar a patent owner from re-lit-
LES Global News—September 2017 at LESI.org igating issues even when the prior decision on those
issues was only summarily affirmed by the Federal Cir-
1. Favorable Capital Gains Taxation Rates Ap- cuit without opinion.
ply to Payments for Transfer of All Substantial 5. Litigation Agent’s Lack of Standing to Sue
Rights in Patents for Infringement Cannot be Cured by Joining
A patent holder may treat payments from the sale or Patent Owner
exchange of a patent as long-term capital gain under A California court ruled that an exclusive patent li-
IRC 1235, which taxes such gains at a lower rate than censee acting simply as the licensor’s litigation agent
ordinary income. In January 2017 the IRS considered lacked standing to sue on its own for infringement be-
whether the individual partners in a partnership could cause the licensor had not transferred all substantial
count a portion of a termination payment under an rights in the patents to the licensee, and that adding
agreement between a partnership and a company as the patent owner would not cure the standing defi-
transferring all substantial rights in a patent as long- ciency because the licensee had no proprietary inter-
term capital gain under § 1235. est or exclusive license in the patents and therefore

September 2017 255


Recent U.S. Decisions
did not suffer any injury in fact traceable to infringe-
ment of the patents.
6. Patent Marking Requirements Cannot Be
Avoided by Retroactive Disclaimer
Although a disclaimer of rights to patent claims sur-
renders any rights the patent owner may have, the Fed-
eral Circuit held that disclaimer does not relinquish the
rights of the public. Therefore, using a disclaimer after
the fact will not remedy a failure to mark products and
will not revive pre-notice damages.
7. Activities by an Infringer Occurring After
it is Sued for Patent Infringement May Not
Support a Finding of Willful Infringement
A Georgia court did not allow a patent owner to
amend its complaint to allege willful infringement
based solely on knowledge and conduct of the accused
infringer occurring after the original complaint was
filed.
8. Licensing Patents to Competitors Could
Weigh Against Granting an Injunction
The Federal Circuit refused to grant a permanent
injunction, reasoning that the injunction was not ne-
cessary to protect the patent holder from irreparable
harm, in part because it had previously licensed sev-
eral of its competitors.
9. Supreme Court Restricts Where Patent
Owners May Sue for Patent Infringement
The United States Supreme Court recently restric-
ted where patent owners may file suits for patent in-
fringement against domestic corporations, reversing
the Federal Circuit by finding that domestic corpora-
tions reside only in their State of incorporation. The
Court’s decision, however, leaves open the question
of what constitutes a defendant’s “regular and estab-
lished place of business” for purposes of venue in pat-
ent suits. ■

256 les Nouvelles


LES International
Officers Delegates
President Peter Hess Andean Community Germany Scandinavia
President-Elect François Painchaud Enrique Berckholtz Christian W. Appelt Morten Balle
Renzo Leonello Scavia Ingo Bruckner Martin Draebye Gantzhorn
Past-President Patricia A. O. Bunye
Arab Countries Heinz Goddar Kaisa Fahllund
Vice-President Rob McInnes Nabil Salame Jochen Schäefer
Vice-President Ichiro Nakatomi Singapore
Renad Noubani Guido von Scheffer Yu Sarn Chiew
® Vice-President Jean-Christophe Troussel Argentina Mathias Zintler Sheena Jacob
Vice-President Audrey Yap Gustavo Giay Hungary
Fernando Noetinger South Africa
Secretary Fiona Nicolson Michael Lantos
Australia & New Zealand Katalin Szamosi Johan Du Preez
Treasurer John Paul Pieter Venter
Legal Counsel KJ Kim Albert Ferralore India
Philip Heuzenroeder Santosh Mohanty Spain & Portugal
Russell Levine Jan Tennent José Miguel Lissén
Richa Pandey
Austria Israel Antonio Tavira
les Nouvelles Editorial Review Board Karin Hofmann Tessa Malamud Switzerland
Chair: Rodney DeBoos, Melbourne, Australia Andreas Pföstl Liad Whatstein Markus Ineichen
Lex van Wijk, Amersfoort, Netherlands Benelux Italy Raymond Reuteler
Heinz Goddar, Munich, Germany Laura Macdonald Giovanni Grippiotti
Achim Krebs Martin Schneider
David Drews, San Diego, California U.S.A. Mattia Dalla Costa
Lex van Wijk Mario Traverso Turkey
Sun R. Kim, Seoul, Korea Brazil Murat Idal
Japan
Masato Kobayashi, Tokyo, Japan Cândida Ribeiro Caffé Katsumi Harashima Arda Karaduman
Kenneth D. McKay, Toronto, Canada Marcela Trigo
Britain & Ireland Yorikatsu Hohokabe USA & Canada
Thomas Bereuter, Vienna, Austria Ichiro Nakatomi
Simon Chalkley Ned Barlas
Eduardo C.A. de Mello e Souza, Brazil Hayley French Makoto Ogino
Frank Tietze, Cambridge, United Kingdom Junko Sugimura Allen Baum
Colin Hunsley Pam Cox
Jennifer Pierce Korea
Chile Kwang Jun Kim Ted Cross
Chris J. Katopis, Executive Administrator Fernando Garcia Darby (YuYeon) Park Pam Demain
Gonzalo Sánchez Malaysia Tom Filarski
Larry Plonsker, Editor
China Pauline Khor Bob Gruetzmacher
10580 Northgreen Dr., Wellington, FL 33449 Yibin Feng Brian Law Yoo Foo Ron Grudziecki
Tel: +1-561-432-8814 E-mail: editor@lesi.org Anita Leung Mexico Gary Keller
Carla J. Blackman & Anita Morselli-Zakrajsek Ningling Wang Abraham Alegria Russell Levine
Design Interface Inc. - Design & production Chinese Taipei Jose Luis Solleiro
John R. Alison Keith Lutsch
Philippines
Hong-Dar Lin Stasia Ogden
Leslie Anne Cruz
les Nouvelles Czech Republic & Slovakia Dwight Olson
Vojtech Chloupek Trinidad Villareal
Volume LII Number 3 (ISSN 0270-174X) Poland Brian O‘Shaughnessy
Milos Hraba Janet Pioli
les Nouvelles is published quarterly by the Licensing France Marek Lazewski
Executives Society International (LESI). LESI is an associa- André-Pascal Chauvin Alicja Rogozinska Paul Roberts
tion of 33 National and Regional Societies, each composed Anne-Charlotte Le Bihan Russia Art Rose
of individual members who are engaged in the profession Patrick Pierre Margarita Divina Henry Ward
of licensing and other aspects of transferring or profiting Laurance Le Texier Natalia Karpova Jeff Whittle
from intellectual property. Subscription to the journal is
included in the membership dues paid by all members. Society Officers
Subscription for the print publication is available to non- Chapter President Secretary
members for US$250/year. Please contact the Editor for Andean Community Renzo SCAVIA Enrique BERCKHOLTZ
further details or go to www.lesi.org/les-nouvelles/about- Arab Countries Talal ABU-GHAZALEH Nabil SALAMÉ
les-nouvelles/non-member-subscription Argentina Gustavo P. GIAY Ignacio Maria BERETERBIDE
The articles published in les Nouvelles reflect the views Australia & New Zealand Philip HUEZENROEDER Jan TENNANT
of the authors and not of the Society as an association or Austria Alexander CIZEK Thomas ADOCKER
Benelux Laura MACDONALD Guillemette VITAL DURAND
its officers. Material printed in the journal is covered by Claudio ANTONACCIO
Brazil Cândida Ribeiro CAFFÉ
copyright. No parts of this publication may be reproduced, Britain & Ireland Colin HUNSLEY Simon CHALKLEY
displayed or transmitted in any form, without prior per- Chile Rodrigo PUCHI Hermes TORRES
mission from the Editor or Board of LESI. China-Hong Kong Charmaine KOO Michael LIN
A peer review and evaluation system is used to maintain China Yi LONG Aimin HUO
the scholarly nature of the material published in this Chinese Taipei John R. ALISON Horng-Dar LIN
journal. All articles submitted for publication are reviewed Czech Republic & Slovakia Vojtěch CHLOUPEK Alena KODRASOVA
France Anne-Charlotte LE BIHAN Henri COPPENS
and evaluated by members of the Editorial Review Board Klaus HAFT
Germany Ursula KÖNIGER
(ERB). The ERB members are chosen for their expertise in Hungary Michael LANTOS Katalin DERZSI
the fields of licensing and intellectual property. All evalu- India Raj HIRWANI Sunil KRISHNA
ations are reviewed in a double-blind fashion to remove Israel Hananel KVATINSKY Dalit SAGIV
any bias in the results. The final decision on publication Italy Mattia DALLA COSTA Dario PASCHETTA
rests with the editor. Japan Junko SUGIMURA Masaki HATANO
A guideline for authors can be found on our Web site at Korea Kwang Jun KIM Dookyu KIM
Malaysia Chiew Lan CHEAH Tamara Lee CIAI
the following address: www.lesi.org/lesnouvelles/advertise. Manuel MARQUEZ
Mexico Hector E. CHAGOYA
asp#submission Philippines Maria Trinidad P. VILLAREAL Reefia MITRA-VENTANILLA
Copyright ©2017 Licensing Executives Society International. Poland Alicja ROGOZINSKA Jakub MROZOWSKI
DEADLINES FOR les Nouvelles: Copy for publication Russia Sergey DOROFEEV Velery MEDVEDEV
Scandinavia Per ERICSSON Olli PEKONEN
in les Nouvelles should be received by the Editor-in-Chief George HWANG
Singapore Suresh SACHI
as far as possible in advance of the final deadlines, Janu- South Africa Darren MARGO
ary 1, April 1, July 1 and October 1. Articles for the Alessia DEL BIANCO
Spain & Portugal Susana Bayon PLAZA José Miguel LISSÉN
white pages are reviewed by the LES Editorial Review Switzerland Stefan KOHLER
Raymond REUTELER
Board, and they are published as soon as possible after Thailand Alan ADCOCK Darani VACHANAVUTT IVONG
acceptance. All materials are to be submitted electroni- Turkey Murat IDAL Evren BUKULMEZ
cally in either MS Word or Text Only format. USA & Canada Brian O’SHAUGHNESSY Arthur ROSE
September 2017
LES International
LESI Management Committees
Licensing And Intellectual Chairs & Co-Chairs
Property Organizations Meetings Audit Ted Cross
Awards Kevin Nachtrab
For more information on LESI Meetings, go to www.lesi.org
Communications Omer Hiziroglu
Education Janet Pioli
2017 2018 Martin Schneider
September 11-12 January 19-21 External Relations Audrey Yap
LES Scandinavia Annual LESI Winter
Conference 2017 Planning Meeting Investment Jim Sobieraj
Copenhagen, Denmark Vienna, Austria IP Maintenance Rinaldo Plebani
Michael Lechter
September 15-16 February 15-17
Legal Russell Levine
5th Pan-European The 2018 IP100
Kwang Jun Kim
LESI YMC Event Executive Forum
Budapest, Hungary Arizona Biltmore, Long-Range Planning Sherry Rollo
Phoenix, AZ U.S.A. Meetings Hayley French
October 22–25 Laura MacDonald
LES (USA & Canada) March 21-23
2017 Annual Meeting LES ANZ Annual Membership Heinz Goddar
Chicago, Illinois U.S.A. Conference 2018 Yorikatsu Hohokabe
Adelaide, SA Nominations Patricia A.O. Bunye
October 26
Australia
Certified Licensing Publications Hector Chagoya
Professional (CLP) Exam April 27–May 02 Rodolfo Martinez
Review Course at LESI 2018 Spring
Annual Meeting
Chicago, Illinois U.S.A.
Annual Meeting LESI Industry, Professional &
Grand Hyatt Manchester Regional Committees
November 13-14 San Diego, CA
LES Benelux
Licensing Course October 14-17 Industry
Faculty Club LES (USA & Canada) Consumer Products Junko Sugimura
Leuven, Belgium 2018 Annual Meeting
Boston, Massachusetts U.S.A. EEMC Rush Khan
Tanja Sovic
2019 High Tech Keith Lutsch
October 20–23 Alfred Yip
LES 2019 Annual Meeting Sonja London
Marriott Desert Ridge IUGT Laura MacDonald
Resort & Spa
Phoenix, AZ U.S.A. Life Sciences Gary Keller

Professional
Copyright Licensing Ken McKay
International Past-Presidents Abraham Alegria
1974 J. Gay 1988 D. Ryan 2002 T. Sueur Dispute Resolution Tilman Müller-Stoy
1975 M. Finnegan 1989 K. Payne 2003 M. Jager Patent & Tech Licensing Patrick Terroir
1976 B. Hedberg 1990 J. Portier 2004 J. Gulliksson
Trademarks, Designs
1977 M. Okano 1991 F. Noetinger 2005 W. Manfroy
and Merchandising Stefan Völker
2006 P. Chrocziel
1978 D. Smith 1992 A. Mifune 2007 R. Grudziecki IP Valuation (Vacant)
1979 J. Gaudin 1993 L. Evans 2008 C. Fukuda
1980 J. Stonier 1994 O. Axster 2009 A. Liberman Regional
1981 S. Heijn 1995 N. Jacobs 2010 P. O’Reilley Americas Veronica Canese
1982 W. Poms 1996 J. Brown 2011 A. Lewis Asia-Pacific Yu Sarn Chiew
1983 H. Hodding 1997 S. Layton Jr. 2012 J. Malackowski Ningling Wang
1984 F. Pombo 1998 R. DeBoos 2013 K. Nachtrab
2014 Y. Chua European Jose Miguel Lissen
1985 M. Ariga 1999 P. Mandros Emmanuel Gougé
2015 A. Michel
1986 L. Mackey 2000 H. Goddar 2016 J. Sobieraj
1987 P. Hug 2001 E. Shalloway 2017 P. Bunye Ad Hoc Committees
Global Technology
Impact Forum Mark Wilson
Young Members Congress Natalie Raffoul

les Nouvelles
g
or
8.
01
I2
ES
.L
w
w
!w
W
O
N
Landscape?

R
TE
IS
G
RE
or LESI 2018 ANNUAL CONFERENCE
Strong IP Drives the Bottom Line

Futurescape? April 29 – May 2 l


Manchester Grand Hyatt San Diego,California l

les Nouvelles
JOURNAL OF THE LICENSING EXECUTIVES SOCIETY INTERNATIONAL
JOURNAL OF
les Nouvelles
THE LICENS
ING
Volume L No.
3

Seven Some
Advancing
what Non-
the Busines
Standard Sugg
EXECUTIVE

s of Intellect
estions For
ual Property
S SOCIETY
INTERNATIO

Globally
September
2015
NAL

Nego tiatin
Agreemen g University
MICHAEL ALVAR ts IP Right s

Advertise With LESI’s les Nouvelles


EZ COHEN
Ten Comm — Page 127
on Mistakes
In IP Valua
DAVID DREW
tion/Damages
Downgrad S — Page 129 Reports
e To “Neu tral”:
A Diminishin
In Reasonab Of The Geor g Role
RYAN SULLIV le Royalty gia-Pacific
AN, DEFOR
EST MCDU
Analyses Factors
Standing Of FF AND JUSTIN
Licensees SKINNER —
To Sue For Page 134
PETER HALLE IP Infringeme
Improving TT AND SEAN nt In Austr
The Techn MCGUIRE — alia
ology Trans Page 138
A Comprehen fer Proce ss
sive Asse ssme By Goin
ONG AND nt and Repo g Back To The Basic s:
KUOK TEONG
AISHWARYA rting Syste
Patent Portf
SATHYANAR m
olio Valua AYAN — Page

les Nouvelles is the professional journal of the Licensing Executives Society


Market Dyna tion As Reflected By
141
mics And The Market Trans
Impact Of actions:
JACK LU — AIA And Alice
Computer Page 147
Assis ted Gene
ration Of IP
Transactio

International (LESI), a significant organization encompassing 33 national and


WILLIAM BIRD n Document
— Page 152 s
Asse ssing
The Value
TERRY LUDLO Of Your Paten
W AND MICH ts
Use Of Clust AEL SPENC
E — Page 154
er Searc hing
To Find Paten
ts With Licen

regional societies and reaching more than 10,000 members worldwide. This
MIKE LLOYD sing Poten
— Page 162 tial
Valuing Trade
Secre ts
Trade Mark DAVID WANE
Filing Strat TICK — Page
egies In Europ 167
e, Selec ted

journal is mailed quarterly to members in 90 countries, with more than half go-
DR. FRANK Aspects Of
REMMERTZ The EC Trade
Recent U.S. — Page 172 Mark Refor
Cour t Decis m
ions And Deve
JOHN C. PAUL lopments Affec
AND D. BRIAN ting Licensing
KACEDON
— Page 183
The Scoop

ing to North American membership. When polled, LESI members consistently


From Europ
PATRIC IA CAPPU e
YNS — Page
187 $62.50/Issu
e

agree that les Nouvelles is one of the top three benefits of their membership in LESI.

LESI will accept Recent Advertisers Include:


CENTER FOR THE PROTECTION OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY

advertising in les
20% OFF
LESI Member Benefit: LESI
Member
20% Off Bloomberg BNA Treatises, Including These Publications Discount
:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::

DRAFTING DRAFTING PATENTS

Nouvelles. Adver-
“A penny for their thoughts!” PATENT LICENSE FOR LITIGATION AND
Maybe that’s crossed your own mind once or twice AGREEMENTS, LICENSING,
when dealing with EPO examiners and their search reports
AUCTIONS SEVENTH EDITION SECOND EDITION
With more than $100 million dollars in completed transactions, Ocean Tomo Auctions have helped sellers
and communications? realize instant liquidity of their IP assets, while buyers have benefitted from a highly efficient transfer of
By Brian G. Brunsvold, D. Patrick
O’Reilley, and D. Brian Kacedon
Bradley C. Wright, Editor-in-Chief; ABA
Section of Intellectual Property Law
technology. In conjunction with Ocean Tomo Market 2009 conferences thousands have gained unique insight
Join us for the EPO’s outstanding training opportunity Please Join us for a Conference on Intellectual Property Law: into the Marketplace for IP. This volume tracks and discusses—clause This book helps practitioners draft the
by clause—all the critical components broadest possible patent by synthesizing
for patent search professionals:

tising will be limited


Announcing the re-scheduled Summer Auction Event, now being held in Chicago, July 23, 2009. To submit IP of a licensing agreement. The Seventh and applying lessons from the case law
Affiliated Offices: for catalog consideration or to register for this event visit: www.OceanTomo.com/SubmitIP. Edition presents a current overview of all legal issues surrounding to sustain a validity challenge. The Second Edition has been
PETOŠEVIĆ Offices:
licensing and of every typical provision used in patent and know- extensively revised to address passage of the Leahy-Smith America
ALBANIA ARMENIA how licenses. Sample provisions include references to applicable

Common Ground:
Invents Act (AIA), including supplemental examination of patents
legal and practical consequences. Major cases covered include

Search Matters 2016


BOSNIA AZERBAIJAN under AIA. The treatise examines patenting strategies in view of the
WiAV Solutions LLC v. Motorola, Inc.; Stanford v. Roche; Preston v. Biologics Price Competition and Innovation Act of 2009, looking at
BULGARIA BELARUS Marathon Oil Co.; Tessera, Inc. v. International Trade Commission;

How Intellectual Property


effective reexamination strategies in view of concurrent litigation. It
Sunbeam Products, Inc. v. Chicago American Manufacturing also features a new chapter on Validity Trials at the Patent Trial and
CROATIA CZECH REPUBLIC LLC; Rates Tech., Inc. v. Speakeasy, Inc.; and In re K-Dur Antitrust Appeal Board, including trial procedures, inter partes review, post-
Litigation.

Unites Creators and Innovators


HUNGARY ESTONIA grant review, and transitional program for covered business method

to products and
8-10 June KOSOVO (UNSCR 1244) GEORGIA
2012/746 pp. Hardcover with forms on CD-ROM patents (part of the AIA).
ISBN 978-1-61746-121-7
The Hague, Netherlands MACEDONIA (FYROM) KAZAKHSTAN Order #2121/List Price: $255.00 2013/1,000 Harcover/ISBN 978-1-61746-28-6
Special LESI Member Discount Price: $204.00 Order #2285/List Price: $445.00
MONTENEGRO KYRGYZSTAN Special LESI Member Discount Price: $356.00
www.epo.org/search-matters PRIVATE IP BROKERAGE :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::
Keynote Speaker: Professor Richard A. Epstein 2014 Supplement Due Fall 2014.

 Patent Search Services  Technology/Innovation Research


ROMANIA LATVIA
RUSSIAN FEDERATION LITHUANIA Typically undertaken for larger and more complex IP portfolio transactions, Ocean Tomo Private IP Brokerage :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::
efforts are managed by the most experienced IP professionals and deliver the highest level of transaction INTELLECTUAL
SERBIA MOLDOVA advisory services. This specialized sale process is tailored to the specific needs of the seller. PROPERTY, SOFTWARE, PATENT, TRADEMARK,

Reach us services that relate


SLOVENIA POLAND AND INFORMATION AND COPYRIGHT
UKRAINE SLOVAK REPUBLIC LICENSING: LAWS, JUNE 2014 EDITION,
LAW AND PRACTICE,
TAJIKISTAN 9 Hours Virginia CLE (Credit Pending) AND 2013 CUMULATIVE
WITH FULL TEXT & SPECIAL
petosevic.com TURKMENISTAN FEATURES ON CD-ROM
SUPPLEMENT
October 9-10, 2014

 White Space Analysis  Claim Charting/Infringement Analysis


instructions@petosevic.com UZBEKISTAN By Xuan-Thao N. Nguyen,
Edited by Jeffrey M. Samuels
Robert W. Gomulkiewicz, and This volume fully integrates the provisions
Danielle M. Conway of the Leahy-Smith America Invents Act
George Mason University School of Law

to the profession-
As licensing law is created and revised to keep pace with developer into the U.S. Code sections of this book
and user needs, this volume provides the information and tools and provides helpful visual guides that will
practitioners need to develop comprehensive licensing agreements, aid practitioners in understanding the law and when provisions will go
PATENT/BID-ASK into effect. This is a must-have resource for patent law practitioners, as

USA: 1-888-247-1618
rectify existing problems, maximize returns within the legal
boundaries, anticipate new concerns, and avoid potential pitfalls. The it contains all the changes enacted into law through April 2014. The
The first and only online public forum that allows buyers and sellers to make and receive offers for their IP in 2013 Cumulative Supplement offers updates on licensing cases, June 2014 Edition includes the 2014 appropriations for the Patent
a completely transparent fashion, Patent Bid-Ask supports unsolicited and confidential offers or bids for any and Trademark Office; the 2014 appropriations for the Copyright
REGISTER NOW at cpip.gmu.edu/conferences patent and facilitates securing related assets by integrating IP from 81 different issuing jurisdictions.
including decisions from the Supreme Court regarding the body
of licensing law; court decisions clarifying when a transaction is a Office; NASA’s statutory authority regarding government interest in

 Portfolio Analysis
Has you covered throughout Eastern Europe and CIS patents; and the statutory changes enacted into law by the “Patent

 Patent Licensing Support Services


copyright or patent first sale and when it is a license; and rulings on
Law Treaties Implementation Act of 2012.”

al interests of our
the enforceability of open source software licenses and the antitrust

MEET OTI
With 120 people in 15 jurisdictions, PETOŠEVIĆ PETOŠEVIĆ Governing Entity PETOŠEVIĆ Brussels Office implications of licenses used in standards organizations. 2014/990 pp. Softcover with CD-ROM
The new member of the expansively intelligent, robust and
specializes in intellectual property services in 30 countries 57, Route de Longwy R. Hyelaan 6 2007/1,584 pp. Hardcover/ISBN 978-1-61746-528-1 ISBN 978-1-61746-500-0
uniquely insightful Ocean Tomo team @ www.OTI.com/NewGuy. Order #2500/List Price: $185.00
of Eastern Europe and the CIS. We have been living by L-8080 Bertrange 3090 Overijse/Brussels Order #1528/List Price: $365.00
the EMBRACING CHANGE motto for over 20 years, Luxembourg Belgium Special LESI Member Discount Price: $292.00 Special LESI Member Discount Price: $148.00

India: +91-44-2231 0321


tirelessly bridging the gap between Eastern and Western Phone: +352 26 9237 45 Phone: + 32 2 688 33 15
European IP practices. We strive to bring together the Fax: +352 26 9237 46 Fax: + 32 2 688 33 16
2013 Cumulative Supplement alone
ISBN 978-1-61746-307-5
best of both worlds and save time and money for our
Order #2307/List Price: $225.00
clients through tailor-made solutions. Expert Testimony • Valuation • Investments • Risk Management • Transactions Special LESI Member Discount Price: $180.00

 Portfolio Management  Patent Due Diligence members.


Chicago • Greenwich • DC Metro • Orange County • Palm Beach • San Francisco www.oceantomo.com • 312.327.4400 To order these and other treatises available from Bloomberg BNA at your
special 20% LESI member discount, go to www.bna.com/bnabooks/lesi
or call 1.800.960.1220.
Ocean Tomo Auctions, LLC 200 W. Madison 37th Floor Chicago, IL 60606 312.327.4400 IL Auction Firm Lic. No. 444.000350 Nicole D’Hondt IL Auctioneer Lic. No. 441.001366

2009_LES_MAY_4.15.indd 1 4/15/09 4:43:21 PM

contact@e-mergeglobal.com European Patent Office PETOŠEVIĆ George Mason University Ocean Tomo Bloomberg BNA
 Landscaping Studies  Patent Drafting
les Nouvelles

September 2017
XCELL
IP E E JOURNAL OF THE LICENSING EXECUTIVES SOCIETY INTERNATIONAL

N
Yea

55

CE
rs
Volume LII No. 3 September 2017

Denn
em
ey

up
er o

LES NOUVELLES
• The IP Gr Advancing the Business of Intellectual Property Globally
Patent Challenge Around The World For Small And Medium Entities (SMEs)
Introduction—SMEs And The Patent Challenge Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Chili
PATRICK TERROIR — Page 139 FELIPE CLARO — Page 202

SMEs And Patent Valorization Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Colombia
JOSEP MARIA PUJALS — Page149 FERNANDO TRIANA SOTO & MARCELA GÓMEZ RUBIO — Page 204

JOURNAL OF THE LICENSING EXECUTIVES SOCIETY INTERNATIONAL


Subject 2.2 SMEs And Open Innovation (OI)
Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Mexico
PAUL GERMERAAD — Page 156
ROXANA AISPURO & HECTOR CHAGOYA — Page 207
SMEs & Patent Litigation: European Perspective
Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Peru

55 years of Dennemeyer
EMMANUEL GOUGÉ & VALICHA TORRECILLA — Page 162
RENZO SCAVIA — Page 210
Creating SEPs­— A Risky Business For SMEs
MENNO TREFFERS, MATTEO SABATTINI & SMEs—A South African Perspective
ALESSANDRA MOSCA — Page 167 MADELEIN KLEYN — Page 211

SMEs & SEPS: Licensing Efficiently In IoT Conclusion—A Different Perspective: Not Only

Thanks for 55 years


HARRIS TSILIKAS & CLAUDIA TAPIA — Page 170 SMEs, Make The Knowledge Economy Work
SMEs In France PATRICK TERROIR — Page 216
EMMANUELLE FORTUNE — Page 177
The Exhaustion Theory Is Not Yet Exhausted: Part 4
SMEs And The Patent Challenge

of entrusting your IP
ERIK VERBRAEKEN — Page 218
TOBIAS WUTTKE — Page 179
Licensing Standards Essential Patents
SMEs In Italy JOSEPH A. ALFRED — Page 225
MATTIA DALLA COSTA & BARBARA SARTORI — Page 181
Magic Bullet: Determining Royalties With Corporate

to Dennemeyer.
IP Manager For SMEs? An Italian Contribution
Discounts Rates Using Muthoo Model
ERCOLE BONINI — Page 184
BRIAN DIES & JOEL WACEK — Page 230
Intellectual Property Services For SMEs In The UK
CHRISTI MITCHELL & ROBERT LOOKER — Page 186 A Guide To Commercial Innovation
In Artificial Intelligence
SMEs And Patents In The United States DEEPA RAVINDRANATH — Page 239
JOHN CABECA & IVAN CHAPEROT — Page 189
Disruption In The IP Services Industry?
SMEs: Patent Challenges And Policies in China JOHN WALKER — Page 243
QINGHONG XU — Page 192
• Client-oriented • Self-funded • Owner-managed • Global SMEs In ASEAN & Singapore—IP Perspectives Intangible Asset Market Value Study?
CATE M. ELSTEN & NICK HILL — Page 245
AUDREY YAP — Page 195
Patent And SMEs In India Software IPR Valuation Model
SUNITA K. SREEDHARAN — Page 197 SANTOSH MOHANTY & KAUSHIK GALA — Page 248

Patent And SMEs In Latin America: Brazil Recent U.S. Decisions Affecting Licensing
CÂNDIDA CAFFÉ & MARIANA VICENTINI — Page199 JOHN PAUL & BRIAN KACEDON — Page 255
$62.50/Issue

S-ar putea să vă placă și