Sunteți pe pagina 1din 30

REPORT | August 2020

OUT TO SEA: THE DISMAL


ECONOMICS OF OFFSHORE WIND
Jonathan A. Lesser
Adjunct Fellow
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

About the Author


Jonathan A. Lesser is an adjunct fellow at the Manhattan Institute. As president of Continental
Economics, Lesser has more than 30 years of experience working for regulated utilities, for
government, and as a consultant in the energy industry. He has addressed economic and regulatory
issues affecting energy in the U.S., Canada, and Latin America. Those issues include gas and
electric utility structure and operations, generating asset valuation under uncertainty, cost-benefit
analysis, mergers and acquisitions, cost allocation and rate design, resource investment-decision
strategies, cost of capital, depreciation, risk management, incentive regulation, economic impact
studies, and energy and environmental policies.

Lesser has prepared expert testimony and reports for utility commissions in numerous states;
for the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission; for international regulators; and for commercial
litigation cases. He has testified before Congress and many state legislative committees on energy
policy and regulatory issues. Lesser is the author of numerous academic and trade-press articles and is a contributing columnist
and editorial board member of Natural Gas & Electricity.

He earned a B.S. in mathematics and economics from the University of New Mexico and an M.A. and a Ph.D. in economics from
the University of Washington.

2
Contents
Executive Summary...................................................................5
I. The Rise of Offshore Wind......................................................7
II. Offshore Wind Contracts........................................................9
III. The Claimed Benefits of Offshore Wind Development..........12
IV. The Reality: Offshore Wind’s Costs Will Far
Exceed Its Benefits..................................................................14
V. Claims of Economic Development Benefits of
Offshore Wind Are Misleading .................................................21
VI. Adverse Environmental Impacts..........................................21
VII. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations.........................23
Appendix. The Mathematics of Calculating Levelized
Cost for a PPA.........................................................................24
Endnotes.................................................................................26

3
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

4
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

Executive Summary
The generation of electricity by onshore wind turbines has benefited from federal subsidies and state renewable
energy mandates for decades. More than 100,000 megawatts (MW) of generating capacity have been construct-
ed in the lower 48 states,1 9,000 MW of which came online in 2019. Onshore wind capacity has now surpassed
installed nuclear capacity (although because of its “always-on” nature, total electricity generated from nuclear
plants far exceeds that of onshore wind) and is exceeded only by natural gas- and coal-fired generating capacity.2

But from an economic perspective, the future of onshore wind is unfavorable. The federal production tax credit
(PTC)—which was created in 1992 and today pays qualifying wind plant owners about $23 per MWh of electricity
generated for 10 years—began to phase out in 2017. The PTC has decreased by 20% per year, and wind projects
whose construction begins after January 1, 2021, will no longer be eligible.3

The demise of the PTC is not, however, the source of onshore wind power’s troubling future. Instead, given the
remote location of many wind farms, expensive transmission lines are necessary to bring the electricity to cities
and towns; perhaps most significant, local opposition has intensified over the past few years and stymied the
development of new projects.4

In response to local pushback, some states are pushing back. In March of this year, for example, New York
enacted legislation to overturn the state’s traditional “home rule” deference, which allows local governments to
have final say over the types of facilities that can be built. Now, under the Accelerated Renewable Energy Growth
and Community Benefit Act, almost all renewable energy development in the Empire State will be approved by a
new Office of Renewable Energy Siting. Locations will be denied only if there are valid and substantive reasons;
local opposition, however, no longer will be considered a valid reason.5

Nevertheless, the opposition to additional onshore wind turbines, as well as the decreasing availability of
high-quality “windy” locations, has led politicians and policymakers to shift their focus to offshore projects. In
January 2019, New York Governor Andrew Cuomo called for developing 9,000 MW of offshore wind capacity by
2035, up from his previous order that 2,400 MW be developed by 2030.6 In January 2018, New Jersey Gover-
nor Phil Murphy signed an executive order requiring 3,500 MW of offshore wind capacity by 2030.7 A 2016 law
in Massachusetts requires that the state’s electric distribution companies procure 1,600 MW of “cost-effective”
offshore wind capacity by June 2027 and 3,200 MW by 2035.8 Similarly, Maryland’s Offshore Wind Energy Act
of 2013 calls for 480 MW of offshore wind capacity to be developed.9

Proponents of offshore wind energy tout its clean energy bona fides and rapidly decreasing costs (as evidenced by
recent competitive solicitations), which will enable states to meet ambitious targets to eliminate greenhouse gas
emissions and reliance on fossil fuel and nuclear power. Advocates also see offshore wind as an avenue to create
a manufacturing and economic renaissance in their respective states, one that will create thousands of construc-
tion jobs and generate billions of dollars of new economic activity.10

As this paper will show, the arguments made on behalf of offshore wind are invalid.

Key Findings
Offshore wind is not cost-effective, and the forecasts of rapidly declining costs through increasing economies of
scale are unrealistic. Absent continued subsidies—such as state mandates for offshore generation and renew-
able energy credits, which force electric utilities to sign long-term agreements with offshore wind developers at
above-market prices—it is unlikely that any offshore wind facilities will be developed. These subsidies, along with
the need for additional transmission infrastructure and backup sources of electricity, will increase the cost of elec-
tricity for consumers and reduce economic growth.

The actual costs of offshore wind projects borne by electric ratepayers and taxpayers are likely to be greater than
advertised. Experience in Europe over the previous decade demonstrates that the performance of offshore wind
turbines degrades rapidly—on average, 4.5% per year. As output declines and maintenance costs increase, proj-
ect developers will have a growing economic incentive to abandon their projects before the end of their contracts
to supply power. In contrast to the strict requirements for nuclear power plants, it is unclear whether offshore

5
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

wind project owners will be required to set aside sufficient funds to decommission their facilities. This will likely
mean that electricity ratepayers and state taxpayers will pay to decommission offshore wind turbines or pay high-
er prices to keep the projects operating.

The cumulative environmental impacts of multiple offshore wind projects along the Atlantic Coast—including on
fisheries and endangered species—may be significant and irreversible. Also, mining the raw materials of offshore
wind turbines, especially rare-earth minerals, has significant environmental impacts because those materials
primarily are mined overseas, where environmental regulations are less stringent than in the United States. Dis-
missing environmental impacts that occur outside the U.S. while championing offshore wind’s alleged worldwide
climate-change benefits is hypocritical.

The justification of subsidies for offshore wind based on increased economic growth, new industries, and state
job creation is an appeal to “free-lunch” economics. The subsidies will benefit the well-connected few while im-
posing economic costs on consumers and businesses at large.
OUT TO SEA: THE DISMAL
ECONOMICS OF OFFSHORE WIND
I. The Rise of Offshore Wind
The first offshore wind facility was constructed in 1991, about one and a half miles off the shore of Denmark, near
the town of Vindeby.11 The facility consisted of 11 450-kilowatt (kW) turbines—a total generating capacity of just
under 5 MW. Another 10 years would pass until the first utility-scale offshore wind facility was built, at Middel-
grunden, off the Danish coast, which consisted of 20 1.5-MW turbines.12 By the end of 2018, the total offshore
wind capacity in Europe was about 18,500 MW. Of that total, Britain and Germany accounted for 14,600 MW.13

Utility-scale offshore wind turbines in Europe and the U.S. today are far larger than the 1.5-MW turbines of two
decades ago. The largest currently operating turbines are 8.5-MW units manufactured by Vestas. Still-larger
turbines are on the horizon: General Electric’s 12-MW turbine, the Haliade-X, is scheduled to begin commercial
operation in 2021.14 (A prototype unit, which was installed onshore, began operation in the Netherlands in late
2019.) Haliade-X stands 853 feet high and has turbine blades that are about 350 feet long. In March 2020, Sie-
mens-Gamesa announced a 15-MW turbine, with 110-meter blades, which the company hopes to have available
by 2024. It will be used by Dominion Energy’s 2,600-MW Coastal Virginia Offshore Wind Project.15 However, it
is unlikely that wind turbines can gain further significant cost reductions by exploiting economies of scale: the
manufacture of wind turbine components and foundations, as well as their installation, is reaching the limits of
current technology.16

The first offshore wind facility in the U.S., Rhode Island’s 30-MW Block Island Wind Farm, was completed in
2016. Located about 4 miles south of Block Island (which is about 9 miles off the coast), the project consists of
five 6-MW turbines. The power purchase agreement (PPA) for the project specified that utilities pay a first-year
price of $245/MWh for the electricity it generates; that price escalates at 3.5% each year. (By comparison, in
2016, the average wholesale price of electricity in New England was less than $30/MWh; in 2019, the average
wholesale price of electricity was $30.67/MWh, reflecting continued low natural gas prices.)17 In 2035, the last
year of the Block Island Wind Farm PPA, the contract price will be more than $470/MWh.

The Rhode Island Public Utilities Commission (RIPUC) initially rejected the Block Island Wind Farm because of
its high cost and the resulting adverse impacts on electric utility ratepayers.18 RIPUC’s findings were consistent
with traditional regulatory principles for electric utilities, which emphasize providing consumers with the low-
est-cost power (see sidebar, How State Regulations Favor Renewable Energy). However, the state legis-
lature changed the applicable regulatory laws, which then required RIPUC to approve the project.19 (Owing to an
exposed underwater transmission cable, the project will be shut down this fall to rebury the cable. It is expected
to reopen sometime in May 2021.)

A much larger project, Cape Wind, first proposed in 2005, was to be built off the coast of Martha’s Vineyard (an
island off the coast of Massachusetts). That project envisioned 130 3.6-MW turbines, totaling 468 MW of capac-
ity. The project attracted bitter opposition, including by many residents of Martha’s Vineyard who complained
that the location would spoil their ocean views. Concerns were also raised about adverse impacts on fisheries
habitat and endangered species.20 Eventually, unable to obtain financing in a timely fashion, the developer aban-
doned the project in 2017.

7
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

How State Regulations Favor Renewable Energy

Beginning in the early 1980s, state utility regulators required the electric utilities they oversee to perform a detailed
economic analysis to determine how best to meet the growing consumer demand for electricity. Although much
of that analysis, called “least-cost planning” (LCP) and then “integrated resource planning” (IRP), was designed
to promote energy conservation as an alternative to building more generating resources, the ultimate goal was to
meet the demand for electricity at the lowest possible cost.
Competitive wholesale electric markets work the same way, but instead of utility regulators determining whether a
generating resource will be built, the lure of profitability drives resource choice: the lowest-cost generating re-
sources, providing the greatest economic value to the bulk power system, will provide their owners with the most
profits.
However, environmental concerns, especially climate change, have changed resource-selection objectives. Rather
than lowest cost, regulators and policymakers have imposed mandates forcing consumers and utilities to use the
“right” types of electricity, with direct costs given secondary consideration.
The surge in offshore wind mandates in East Coast states is the most recent example of this trend. Although
states are adopting competitive solicitations for offshore wind, and although the prices offered in response to
these solicitations have fallen, those prices nevertheless are far higher than average prices in wholesale electricity
markets. Moreover, the prices offered by offshore wind developers encompass only direct costs of the resources
themselves—that is, the costs to build, operate, and maintain the generators. They exclude the costs associated
with providing backup power for times when the wind does not blow.

Nevertheless, the demise of Cape Wind did not stop Project, to be located about 15 miles off Martha’s Vine-
efforts to promote offshore wind. Currently, seven yard; and the 804-MW Mayflower Wind Project, to be
states have laws or executive orders mandating, col- located about 20 miles south of Nantucket Island.25
lectively, about 22,000 MW of offshore wind capacity. (The number of turbines for Mayflower is not known,
An eighth state, Maine, has an Offshore Wind Initiative as it will depend on the size of the turbines that the
but no specific capacity mandate (Figure 1).21 developers install.) Although construction on the first
phase of the Vineyard Wind Project was supposed to
In autumn 2019, the New York State Energy Research begin in autumn 2019 and be completed in 2022, the
and Development Authority (NYSERDA) signed project has been held up because the Bureau of Ocean
20-year PPAs for two offshore wind projects, totaling Energy Management (BOEM) has not yet issued a final
about 1,700 MW of capacity: the 880-MW Sunrise environmental impact statement (EIS).26 Construction
Wind Project, to be located off the eastern shore of on Mayflower Wind is supposed to begin in 2022, with
Long Island; and the 816-MW Empire Wind Project, to the project operational by December 2025.
be located off the southern shore of Long Island.22 Both
projects are slated to be operational by 2024. Sunrise Off the coast of New Jersey, the nation’s single largest
Wind will rely on 110 8.0-MW turbines manufac- offshore wind facility—the 1,100-MW Ocean Wind
tured by Siemens. Empire Wind has not identified any facility—is scheduled to begin construction in 2021 and
specific turbines, except to state that the project will be online in 2024.27 More offshore wind development is
consist of 60–80 turbines having an installed capacity likely as states seek to increase renewable generation.
“of more than 10 MW each.”23 New York also intends to As of December 2019, according to AWEA, solicitations
conduct a solicitation for an additional 2,500 MW of for offshore wind energy in six states totaled almost
offshore wind capacity sometime later this year. More- 6,300 MW of capacity.28 A 2018 report issued by the
over, in June of this year, NYSERDA issued a white National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL), which
paper recommending that it procure the entire 9,000 is part of the U.S. Department of Energy (DOE), cited
MW of offshore wind by 2035, as set forth under the industry forecasts predicting 11,000 MW–16,000 MW
state’s Climate Leadership and Community Protection of U.S. offshore wind-generating capacity by 2030.29
Act.24 The most recent long-term forecast of the U.S. Energy
Information Administration (EIA) is less bullish,
In October 2019, the Massachusetts Department of predicting 10,000 MW of offshore wind capacity by
Public Utilities (DPU) approved long-term agreements 2030, and just over 18,000 MW by 2035.30 That sounds
to purchase power from two proposed offshore wind like a lot; but by comparison, EIA projects that, in
projects: the 84-turbine, 800-MW Vineyard Wind 2050, coal-fired power plants will generate some 700

8
FIGURE 1.

States with Offshore Wind Mandates

WA

ME
MT ND
OR MN VT
NH
ID SD WI NY MA
CT
WY MI RI
IA PA
NE NJ
NV
OH
UT IL IN DE
CA CO WV MD
VA
KS MO DC
KY

NC
TN
OK
AZ NM AR SC

AL GA
MS

TX LA

AK
FL

HI

Source: American Wind Energy Association (AWEA), U.S. Offshore Wind Industry, “Status Update,” June 2020

terawatt-hours (TWh) of electricity and natural gas Offshore Wind, will be built and operated by a regulated
plants will generate over 1,600 TWh, compared with electric utility (Figure 2). Although the utilities must
74 TWh for offshore wind.31 purchase the output from offshore wind generators,
the contract terms are not approved by them. In Mas-
sachusetts, the contracts are approved by that state’s
DPU. In New York, the contract terms with regulated
II. Offshore Wind Contracts utilities have been agreed to by NYSERDA, except for
two contracts signed by the Long Island Power Author-
Most states have adopted a system of competitive so- ity (LIPA), itself a government-run utility.
licitations to secure offshore wind projects. However,
given that there are only a few offshore wind devel- In Figure 2, the column labeled “PPA Type” reflects the
opers, the level of actual competition is unclear. Suc- types of contracts. The simplest PPAs sell the energy
cessful bidders sign contracts called power purchase generated by the offshore wind farm to the buyer at
agreements (PPAs), which include annual pricing, the contract price. This reflects the agreements for the
performance guarantees, and numerous other factors. 30-MW Block Island Wind Farm off the coast of Rhode
Many of the contract terms are kept confidential under Island, which began operating in 2016, as well as the
the rubric of “competitive market information.”32 As proposed Maine Aqua Ventus Project.
such, the actual costs to build and operate these wind
facilities are unknown. This secrecy matters because, The second type of PPA involves the sale of electric-
as discussed below, developers may well abandon facil- ity and offshore renewable energy credits (ORECs).
ities that are no longer profitable to operate or demand ORECs are a specific type of renewable energy credit
changes to their contractual agreements. (REC) that can be used by utilities in lieu of actually
owning renewable energy generating resources or con-
As of this writing, a total of 13 offshore wind projects tracting for their output. For example, suppose that a
have signed PPAs. Only one of them, Coastal Virginia utility expects to sell 100 million MWh of electricity

9
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

FIGURE 2.

U.S. Existing and Announced Offshore Wind Projects


State Project Name Capacity (MW) On-Line Year PPA Type PPA Duration (years)
CT, RI Revolution Wind 300 2023 Energy, ORECs 20
MA Mayflower Wind 804 2025 Energy, ORECs 20
MA Vineyard Wind Phase 1 400 2022 Energy, ORECs 20
MA Vineyard Wind Phase 2 400 2023 Energy, ORECs 20
MD Skipjack Wind 120 2023 Energy, ORECs 20
MD US Wind 248 2023 Energy, ORECs 20
ME Maine Aqua Ventus 12 2022 Energy 20
NJ Ocean Wind 1,100 2024 Energy, ORECs 20
NY Sunrise Wind 880 2025 Energy, ORECs 25
NY Empire Wind 816 2025 Energy, ORECs 25
NY South Fork Wind 130 2023 Energy 20
RI Block Island (Deepwater Wind) 30 2016 Energy 20
RI Revolution Wind 400 2023 Energy, ORECs 20
VA Coastal Virginia Offshore Wind a
12 2020 na na
Total Capacity 6,150

Project to be built and operated by Dominion Energy, placed into ratebase.


a

Source: Individual state utility regulatory commissions and project websites. U.S. wind initially be 248 MW, with a planned build-out to 750 MW.

to its customers next year, of which 20%—20 million supply, the price for ORECs will increase. If the supply
MWh—must come from renewable energy resources. of ORECs increases faster than the offshore wind man-
Of that 20 million MWh, suppose the regulator man- dates, the price of ORECs will decrease.
dates that at least 25% (5 million MWh) be sourced
from offshore wind and another 25% from solar photo- To address the potential volatility of future OREC
voltaics (PV) (Figure 3). prices, long-term PPAs fix their price, regardless of
market conditions. This provides developers with a
If the utility does not own any renewable generating guaranteed income stream that they can use to secure
plants or have existing contracts with renewable gen- financing for their projects.
erators, it can use RECs to meet the renewable energy
mandate. Typically, an offshore (or onshore) wind PPA terms vary significantly. For example, in January
project creates one REC for each MWh of electrici- 2017, LIPA signed a PPA for New York’s first offshore
ty that it generates. As renewable energy mandates wind project, the 90-MW South Fork Wind project.34
become more specific (e.g., X% of solar, Y% of offshore Subsequently, in November 2018, LIPA signed an
wind, etc.), they further restrict the ability of an electric additional PPA for a 40-MW expansion of that project.
utility to reduce the cost of the electricity that it sells to But it was not until October 2019 that LIPA released
consumers.33 the pricing for the project, with the high costs of the
contract surprising some.35 Specifically, the 90-MW
Almost all the East Coast states shown in Figure 1 project’s initial price will be $160 per MWh, escalating
mandate that their electric utilities purchase increas- at 2.0% per year over the 20-year contract life.36 The
ing quantities of offshore wind generation over time. 40-MW expansion project will have a first-year price
Hence, the utilities must purchase offshore electricity of $86 per MWh, also escalating at 2.0% per year.
directly or purchase ORECs in the marketplace that are Both are expected to begin commercial operation in
“produced” by these wind projects. The market value December 2022. The resulting “levelized” costs in real
of ORECs depends on supply-and-demand conditions. 2019$ are $142.48 per MWh for the 90-MW project
If the demand for ORECs increases faster than the and $87.00 per MWh for the expansion project (for

10
FIGURE 3.

Illustration of Renewable Generation Mandate


Fossil, 80% Offshore Wind, 5%

Solar, 5%

Renewables, 20%

Other
Renewables, 10%

an explanation of levelized costs, see pp.11–12 and MWh, which also escalates at 2.5% annually over its
Appendix, pp.24–25). 20-year contract life. New York State’s Empire Wind,
scheduled to begin operation in 2025, has a 25-year
By contrast, New Jersey’s 1,100-MW Ocean Wind PPA. The first-year price will be $99.08 per MWh,
Project will sell ORECs to state electric utilities at an escalating at 2% per year. LIPA’s two Deepwater Wind
initial contract price of $98.10 per OREC. The two projects—a 90-MW project and a 40-MW expansion
other, much larger, New York offshore wind projects— facility—are supposed to be operational sometime in
Empire Wind and Sunrise—are less costly but have 2023. They have first-year costs of $160 per MWh and
very different, and more complex, pricing structures. $86 per MWh, respectively, escalating at 2% per year.
However, unlike Empire Wind, the Deepwater Wind
The Coastal Virginia Offshore Wind Project (Figure Project PPAs have 20-year terms.
2) will be developed by Dominion Energy, a utility. In
contrast to the other projects in Figure 2, Dominion Because these projects have different pricing terms,
will recover the costs of the project from its custom- contract lengths, and start dates, PPA costs cannot be
ers under traditional utility cost-of-service regulation. compared directly. Moreover, comparisons are made
This means that Dominion will earn a regulated return more difficult because the products being sold differ.
on its capital investment and recover all operating ex- Thus, a PPA selling ORECs cannot be compared direct-
penses of its offshore wind farm. ly with one that sells only energy. Nevertheless, one can
compare the costs of the 10 projects selling energy and
ORECs, using their LCOE, or “levelized cost of electric-
Comparing Project Costs ity” (or energy), and LACE “levelized avoided cost of
electricity.” EIA provides a simple explanation of these
Offshore wind projects have different start dates, standard metrics:
different contract lengths, and different price
structures. For example, the Mayflower Wind PPA The levelized cost of electricity (LCOE) rep-
specifies that all the electricity that the project resents the installed capital costs and ongoing op-
generates will be purchased by Massachusetts electric erating costs of a power plant, converted to a level
utilities at a constant $77.76 per MWh over the entire stream of payments over the plant’s assumed fi-
20-year contract term, which is expected to begin nancial lifetime. Installed capital costs include
operations in late 2025. The Bay State’s Vineyard Wind construction costs, financing costs, tax credits, and
has a different deal. Phase 1, scheduled to be operating other plant-related subsidies or taxes. Ongoing costs
sometime in 2022, has a first-year price of $74.00 per include the cost of the generating fuel (for power
MWh, which will escalate 2.5% annually over the entire plants that consume fuel), expected maintenance
20-year contract life. Phase 2, scheduled to be operating costs, and other related taxes or subsidies based on
sometime in 2023, has an initial price of $68.45 per the operation of the plant.

11
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

FIGURE 4.

Levelized Costs of the Vineyard 1 PPA


$/MWh
$140.00

$120.00
Annual PPA Cost ($MWh)
$100.00

Levelized Nominal Cost $89.68/MWh


$80.00

Real Levelized Cost (2019$): $70.14/MWh


$60.00

$40.00

$20.00

$0.00
2022 2025 2028 2031 2034 2037 2040
Year

Source: Author’s calculations

The levelized avoided cost of electricity $55.52/OREC (Mayflower Wind) and $179.27/OREC
(LACE) represents that power plant’s value to the (US Wind).
grid. A generator’s avoided cost reflects the costs
that would be incurred to provide the electricity The three energy-only projects—Maine Aqua Ventus,
displaced by a new generation project as an esti- South Fork Wind, and the Block Island Wind Farm
mate of the revenue available to the plant. As with Project that came online in 2016—have real levelized
LCOE, these revenues are converted to a level costs ranging between $138.68/MWh and $327.70/
stream of payments over the plant’s assumed fi- MWh (2019$).
nancial lifetime.37

Levelized costs can also be adjusted by inflation. As-


suming that the annual generation from the projects III. The Claimed Benefits
remains constant, the “real levelized costs” of elec-
tricity are straightforward to calculate.38 The result- of Offshore Wind
ing cost can be viewed as a fixed mortgage payment in
inflation-adjusted dollars. For example, the Vineyard
Development
Wind 1 Project has a first-year PPA cost of $74.00/
MWh, which escalates each year of the 20-year con- Several drivers are pushing offshore wind development.
tract at a rate of 2.5% (Figure 4). Using EIA assump- Onshore wind development is, for one, becoming more
tions,39 the real levelized cost (2019$) is $70.14/MWh, difficult, as local opposition to siting massive new wind
and the nominal levelized cost is $89.68/MWh. farms has increased, owing to concerns about health
impacts associated with low-frequency noise emitted
Figure 5 compares the real levelized costs in 2019$ by turbines,41 loss of productive farmland,42 and adverse
for all 10 projects whose PPAs will sell ORECs to util- impacts on the scenic landscape.43 Moreover, in several
ities. To be consistent with EIA’s LCOE and LACE es- East Coast states, there is not enough suitable land on
timates, the levelized costs are all adjusted to reflect which to site industrial-scale wind farms.
an online year of 202540 and assume that there will be
no reduction in output from the projects over time. As Another reason: the wind offshore is steadier and more
this figure shows, the levelized costs range between frequent than onshore, which means lower costs. This

12
FIGURE 5.

Levelized Costs for Offshore Wind PPAs Selling ORECs


Levelized 2019$/OREC

$200

$180
$179.27
$160
$155.24
$140
$138.68
$120

$100
$98.36
$80 $85.54
$83.01
$76.07 $71.96 $76.54 $75.25
$60
$55.52
$40

$20

$0
Revolution Mayflower Vineyard Vineyard Skipjack US Wind Ocean Sunrise Empire South Fork Revolution
Wind - CT Wind Wind 1 Wind 2 Wind Wind Wind Wind Wind Wind - RI

Source: Author’s calculations

is why offshore wind facilities are expected to have Wind Project estimated that it would support 974 con-
higher capacity factors (representing the percentage struction job-years in Massachusetts, along with 80
of time the turbines will be generating electricity) than job-years for each year of operation and maintenance
onshore turbines. Between 2015 and 2019, EIA calcu- of the project, totaling 3,180 job-years.47
lated that the average capacity factor for onshore wind
energy in the U.S. was just under 35%.44 For offshore Similarly, a 2017 report commissioned by NYSERDA
wind, EIA assumes capacity factors of 50%–58%.45 estimated that the state’s commitment to installing
2,400 MW of offshore wind would create 5,000 new
Proponents also see the decreasing PPA costs as ev- jobs in manufacturing, installation, and operation.48
idence of rapidly declining costs for offshore wind, Not to be outdone, in approving the 1,100-MW Ocean
which will lead to lower electricity prices. However, as Wind Project in June 2019, the New Jersey Board
discussed below, PPA prices resulting from compet- of Public Utilities (NJBPU) cited estimates that the
itive solicitations likely suffer from what economists project would create $1.17 billion in economic benefits
call the “winner’s curse”; and the actual costs of these and create 15,000 jobs over the project’s 20-year ex-
projects are likely to be higher than predicted. pected life.49 Massachusetts cited claims that the May-
flower Wind Project would create more than 10,000
States also tout the economic development benefits of job-years over its lifetime, creating an additional $690
offshore wind, especially new manufacturing indus- million in gross earnings for the state.50
tries and jobs. For example, a 2018 study prepared
by Bristol Community College, the UMass Dartmouth In September 2019, Virginia Governor Ralph Northam
Public Policy Center, and the Massachusetts Maritime issued an executive order to develop at least 2,600 MW
Academy for the Massachusetts Clean Energy Center of offshore wind by 2026 and to develop an “energy
(MassCEC) estimated that constructing and operating workforce plan.”51 That executive order subsequently
1,600 MW of offshore wind turbines in the Bay State was codified into legislation as the Virginia Clean
could create 2,279–3,171 direct job-years. Taking into Economy Act (VCEA), which calls for the state’s
account the “indirect impacts” of the supply chain, as two largest electric utilities—Dominion Energy and
well as “induced impacts” from employees spending Appalachian Power—to provide power solely from
their earnings could bring the total to 6,878–9,852 in- renewable generating resources by 2045 and 2050,
direct job-years.46 A report for the 800-MW Vineyard respectively. VCEA includes a requirement that no less

13
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

than 5,200 MW of offshore wind power be developed.52 ty costs, less economic growth, and significant adverse
According to its backers, VCEA will create up to 13,000 environmental impacts.
new jobs per year and $69.7 billion in net benefits for
Virginians.53
The High Cost of Offshore Wind
Thus, states promoting offshore wind development
claim that offshore wind development will create thou- Although offshore wind development costs and PPA
sands of new, high-paying jobs and lead to new man- prices have certainly decreased in the last decade, claims
ufacturing industries. All are competing to gain a so- that the costs to construct and operate offshore wind fa-
called first-mover advantage because, as one booster cilities will decrease significantly are likely unrealistic.
claimed, “Whichever states get out ahead and do the For example, a report by DOE projects that the real level-
best job of managing the early growth and development ized costs for offshore wind projects will fall below $50/
of their offshore wind projects are going to garner the MWh (2018$) by 2030.59 That same report projects that
most investment from the industry.”54 (Of course, only the capital cost of the turbines themselves (which con-
one state can gain a first-mover advantage, which may stitute 30%–45% of total capital costs) will decline to
well turn out to be a “first-mover disadvantage,” as dis- about $1,000/kW by 2030.60 These forecasts are almost
cussed below.) surely too optimistic and are inconsistent with EIA’s
forecasts, as discussed below. (EIA falls within DOE.)
Finally, states claim that the environmental benefits Since the 2008 financial crisis, the cost of capital has
of offshore wind will advance them along the path to been at historical lows, with interest rates even declining
a future free of greenhouse gas emissions. NYSERDA to negative values in some countries, such as Germany
says that the first 2,400 MW of offshore wind will and Switzerland. Financing costs cannot go much lower.
reduce greenhouse gas emissions in New York by
more than 5 million short tons per year and provide an As the size of offshore wind projects increases, more
annual benefit of $1.9 billion, based on estimates of the of the costs are devoted to related infrastructure—
social cost of carbon.55 In January 2020, New Jersey foundations, cables, and such. These are mature
Governor Phil Murphy released his Energy Master industries. It is unlikely that increasing the size of
Plan, which calls for 100% clean energy by 2050. His cement manufacturers will result in lower per-unit
November 2019 executive order calls for 7,500 MW of costs; they have likely captured most economies of scale.
offshore wind by 2035 to reduce that state’s approxi- Increasing the demand for offshore wind facilities will
mate 100 million metric tons of greenhouse gas emis- increase the demand for these underlying materials—
sions.56 Maryland’s 248-MW US Wind Project and such as the concrete and steel needed for turbine
the 120-MW Skipjack Project claim to reduce carbon foundations—and is more likely to increase prices than
dioxide (CO2) emissions by about 24 million tons over it is to decrease prices. To the extent that those materials
the entire 20-year project life, or about 1.2 million tons require the use of fossil fuels, efforts to impose carbon
per year.57 A 2016 report by DOE claimed nationwide taxes or other policies to increase the costs of fossil fuels
benefits from reduced greenhouse gas emissions worth will increase the cost of manufacturing and transporting
$50 billion in avoided global damages through 2050 if the materials needed to develop turbine sites.
96,000 MW of offshore wind were installed, along with
$2 billion in avoided costs associated with air pollution Furthermore, as discussed previously,61 the size of wind
emissions and reduced water consumption, among turbines is close to its physical limits. Hence, opportuni-
other benefits.58 ties for continued exploitation of economies of scale in
turbine technology are also limited.

As part of its Annual Energy Outlook, which provides


IV. The Reality: Offshore a long-term forecast of U.S. energy demand, EIA pub-
Wind’s Costs Will Far lishes an accompanying report on the projected costs
of different types of generating resources. In its most
Exceed Its Benefits recent report, EIA estimated the real LCOE for offshore
wind facilities beginning service in 2025 as between
$102.68/MWh and $155.55/MWh, with an average
The combination of lower electricity costs, new man- price of $122.25/MWh (2019$).62 EIA estimates that
ufacturing industries and thousands of new jobs, and the costs for offshore wind installed in 2040 will be
reduced greenhouse gas and air pollution emissions about one-third less, with levelized costs between
makes offshore wind sound like a dream. It is a dream: $74.47/MWh and $105.39/MWh, with an average
in reality, offshore wind will result in higher electrici- price of $85.53/MWh (2019$).63

14
By comparison, the levelized cost of gas-fired com- The upshot: from a strictly economic standpoint, EIA
bined-cycle generating units entering service in estimates that the economic costs of offshore wind
2025 is between $33.35/MWh and $45.31/MWh, resources will be three times larger than the cor-
with an average price of $38.07/MWh (2019$). For responding economic benefits, in terms of avoided
2040, EIA projects levelized costs for combined-cy- costs. As such, the more offshore wind that is added,
cle units to range between $34.27/MWh and $72.32/ the greater will be the net economic cost to society.
MWh, with an average levelized cost of $42.89/MWh
(2019$). (The higher real levelized costs in 2040 are Worse, new research on European offshore wind
the result of higher projected prices for natural gas.) turbine performance over the last decade shows that
performance degrades rapidly over time, especial-
So, even in 2040, EIA projects that the levelized ly for newer and larger wind turbines; that means
costs of gas-fired combined-cycle units will still be higher operating costs and reduced economic life-
half the levelized cost of offshore wind generation. times. As more offshore wind is integrated onto
the bulk power grid, the costs of addressing wind
Because offshore wind is intermittent, its LACE value power’s inherent intermittency will also increase,
is less than that of reliable resources such as natural further increasing the costs borne by electricity con-
gas or coal. EIA estimates the real LACE value for sumers and requiring new gas-fired generating units
a combined-cycle generating unit to be between to operate on standby or highly expensive battery
$29.32/MWh and $45.22/MWh in 2025, with a storage systems.
capacity-weighted average value of $37.15/MWh
(2019$), slightly higher than the capacity-weighted More offshore wind turbines (as well as increased
LCOE. For offshore wind, EIA’s estimate of LACE requirements for batteries for electric vehicles and
is between $25.36/MWh and $42.76/MWh, with a storage of intermittent wind-generated power)
capacity-weighted average value of $37.29/MWh means more rare-earth elements, which historically
(2019$). For a combined-cycle generating unit, have come overwhelmingly from China.64 That in-
LACE exceeds LCOE. Hence, for offshore wind, EIA creased demand will likely bring higher prices and
estimates the average LCOE to be more than three higher turbine manufacturing costs.65
times greater than the average LACE.

15
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

Who Will Pay to Decommission Offshore Wind Turbines?

The Bureau of Ocean Energy Management (BOEM) has have strict decommissioning requirements and regula-
specific requirements for decommissioning offshore tions governing how much money nuclear plant owners
wind turbines.a The bottom line is that all turbine com- must set aside each year for decommissioning.
ponents, from the blades to the foundation, must be BOEM regulations do not specify dollar amounts for
removed to a depth of 15 feet below the mud line (what decommissioning funds. PPAs typically require some
happens to the power cables is unclear). bonding for the projects, especially during the con-
As no offshore wind facilities have been decommis- struction phase, but the details regarding decommis-
sioned in the U.S., the costs to do so are uncertain. sioning funds are sparse and, in some cases,
One recent article estimated the cost of decommis- confidential.
sioning Britain’s offshore wind turbines to be £80,000– Except for the Coastal Virginia Offshore Wind Project to
£300,000 per MW, or about $102,000–$384,000 per be built and operated by Dominion Energy, all the other
MW at current exchange rates.b offshore wind projects will be owned by single-purpose
Several studies have estimated decommissioning costs entities. For example, Mayflower Wind will be devel-
for U.S. offshore projects. A 2010 study estimated the oped by Shell New Energies and EDPR Offshore North
cost of decommissioning the canceled Cape Wind America, two large multinational companies. However,
Project at $63.8 million for the project’s 130 3.6-MW the actual project owner is Mayflower Wind Energy,
turbines, which translates into a cost of $136,000 per LLC, a single-purpose entity. The only assets owned
MW.c A detailed 2014 study for the Cape Wind Project by these companies will be the turbines and undersea
estimated a decommissioning cost of $71 million–$126 cables connecting them to the shore. The same is true
million, with an expected cost of $103 million and a for Vineyard Wind, a joint venture of Avangrid and CIP,
salvage value of $23 million.d The net expected cost, as well as many of the other projects in Figure 2. Once
$80 million, is equivalent to $171,000 per MW. A 2017 the projects are no longer economical to operate, the
study of decommissioning eight offshore wind farms companies can simply walk away, leaving electric
off the British coast estimated an average cost of over ratepayers and U.S. taxpayers to pay the decommis-
£200,000 per MW.e Because the larger turbines to be sioning costs.h
built off the Atlantic Coast will be more difficult and a The requirements can be found at 30 CFR § 585.9–585.913.
costly to remove and dispose of, the per-MW costs b Elaine Maslin, “£10 billion+ Offshore Wind Decommissioning Bill,” Offshore Engineer,
are likely to be higher, perhaps much more so. For Dec. 16, 2019.
example, the 12-MW GE Haliade-X turbine, which will c Mark Kaiser and Brian Snyder, “Offshore Wind Energy Installation and Decommissioning
Cost Estimation in the U.S. Outer Continental Shelf,” BOEM, November 2010, p. 215, table
be used for the Ocean Wind and Skipjack Projects, 12.14. The authors estimated lower costs for an alternative deconstruction alternative,
has 325-foot-long blades, longer than a football field. “felling the turbine like a tree, rather than removing it piece-by-piece.”
d PCCI, “Decommissioning Cost Estimation for the Cape Wind Project,” report prepared for
Disposal of smaller, onshore wind turbine blades, which BOEM, December 2014.
today cannot be recycled, is already a problem.f GE e Eva Topham and David McMillan, “Sustainable Decommissioning of an Offshore Wind Farm,”
admits that the installation of these turbines represents Renewable Energy 102, part B (March 2017): 470–80.
f See, e.g., “Electric Power Research Institute, “Wind Turbine Blade Recycling” 2020 Technical
the limits of existing technology;g removal of the tur- Report,” Apr. 17, 2020. In February 2020, the Wyoming House of Representatives passed
bines likely will pose similar challenges. two bills that would ban the disposal of wind turbine blades in landfills and allow base
materials to be buried in abandoned coal mines. See Brendan LaChance, “Bills Aim to
The approved PPAs for the projects shown in Figure 1 Require Recycling of Wind Turbine Blades, Disposal in Abandoned Coal Mines,” Oil City
News, Feb. 24, 2020.
provide little detail regarding decommissioning costs
g Tomas Kellner, “The X Factor: Here’s What It Takes to Build the Tower for the World’s
and, especially, the funds that the developers are re- Most Powerful Offshore Wind Turbine,” GE Reports, May 25, 2018.
quired to set aside for ultimate decommissioning. This h For a discussion of this issue as it relates to onshore wind farms, see William Stripling,
“Wind Energy’s Dirty Word: Decommissioning,” Texas Law Review 95 (2016): 123–51.
is in marked contrast to nuclear power plants, which

16
FIGURE 6.

AEO 2020 vs. AEO 2019 Average Wholesale Generation Prices and Change in
Renewable Generation
2019 $/MWh GWh
70 1,000

65 900

60 800

55 700

50 600

45 500

40 400

35 300

30 200

25 100

20 0
2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049
Increase in Renewable Generation AEO 2019 Avg. Generation Cost AEO 2020 Avg. Generation Cost

Source: Annual Energy Outlook 2019 and 2020

Nevertheless, some regulators claim that offshore First: in its current Annual Energy Outlook 2020
wind will reduce ratepayers’ electric bills. For (AEO 2020), EIA projects greater quantities of wind
example, in its letter recommending approval of and solar power and lower real (inflation-adjusted)
the Mayflower Wind Project, Mass DOER claimed average wholesale generation prices than its pre-
that the project’s cost would be below the cost of vious forecast (AEO 2019). AEO 2020 projects that
wholesale market power and provide an average of average wholesale market electric generating prices
2.4 cents/kWh (in real 2019 dollars) of direct savings will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an
to ratepayers.66 average $61/MWh to an average $48/MWh in 2050.69
AEO 2020 also shows an increase in renewable gen-
These claims are overblown; they are also an eration, when compared with its 2019 forecast, and
example of “free-lunch” economics. First, Mass lower generation prices (Figure 6).
DOER assumptions about real levelized wholesale
cost of electricity appear to be overstated. Over the Second: as more offshore wind generation is added,
same period as the Mayflower PPA (2026–45), EIA’s the effect will be to lower wholesale prices while
Annual Energy Outlook 2020 forecasts declining tending to drive out unsubsidized generation. Indeed,
inflation-adjusted wholesale electric prices in New analyses of offshore wind PPAs often tout the indirect
England, with a levelized generation cost of 5.6 cents/ price-suppression benefits of offshore wind power to
kWh (2019$), one-third lower than the 8.4 cents/ electric consumers—that is, the benefits to consumers
kWh value in the Mass DOER letter.67 These far from suppressing wholesale generating prices.
lower forecast wholesale energy prices belie the Mass Proponents of such price suppression effects argue
DOER’s claims of cost savings for consumers. that the increase in the supply of offshore wind will
decrease market-clearing prices by more than the cost
Second, it is true that adding more high-cost wind of the plant. Supposedly, everybody wins, except for
and solar resources is likely to drive down wholesale competitive generators that invested their capital.
power prices. That sounds like an unambiguous win This argument is wrong.
for consumers. It is not; those lower prices are the
result of subsidies that will drive out unsubsidized Third: by artificially driving down market prices
generators, which I call “Gresham’s Law of Green through subsidies and mandates, states drive
Energy.”68 Here is how this “law” plays out. out legitimate competitive generators, including

17
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

renewable generators that operate without the benefit will exceed its expected revenues, at which time the
of subsidies and mandates. Thus, any price reductions rational economic response for the project’s owner is
are temporary. The long-term damage to markets is to shut down.
worse. By driving out legitimate competitors, these
policies increase financial risk, as investors don’t The first large-scale study of changes in wind turbine
know if the plant that they finance will be forced out of output over time was in 2012 by Gordon Hughes, an
business in the future by some other state policy action. economics professor at the University of Edinburgh.71
He examined the performance of onshore wind farms
Finally, subsidies reduce the incentive to innovate and in Britain and Denmark, as well as the performance
lower costs. Thus, in the long run, because competitive of offshore wind farms in Denmark. Hughes’s anal-
generators will be more hesitant to invest and because ysis found that the average load factor (i.e., the ratio
investors will demand higher returns to compensate of a generator’s average annual output to its rated ca-
for the additional financial risk, electric prices paid pacity) for offshore wind farms in Denmark fell from
by consumers will end up higher than they otherwise over 40%, when the units were new, to less than 15%
would be. after nine or 10 years.72 The performance degradation
of onshore wind farms in Denmark was much less, but
the performance of onshore wind farms in Britain fell
Hidden Costs rapidly. (Hughes’s onshore turbine findings in Britain
were confirmed in a 2014 study that found that the
The levelized costs estimated by EIA in its Annual average annual output loss from installed facilities was
Energy Outlook, as well as the levelized PPA prices about 1.6%.)73
shown in Figure 5, do not provide a complete account-
ing of offshore wind’s costs. A more accurate picture In 2020, Hughes published an update of his 2012
must account for at least three factors: (i) output deg- study, taking advantage of the much larger quantity of
radation—the tendency for offshore wind turbines to available data.74 This updated analysis found that the
produce less electricity as they age, owing to unexpect- performance of larger offshore wind turbines decreased
ed equipment failures, which may lead to premature an average of 4.5% per year for turbines installed after
abandonment of offshore wind facilities; (ii) the costs 2011. In other words, after 10 years, the average output
of ensuring that the bulk power system can provide of these newer offshore wind turbines was just over
reliable electricity supplies, which becomes more diffi- half the initial output. Hughes’s analysis also showed
cult and costly, the greater the amount of intermittent that the performance of newer, much larger, turbines
generation like wind is integrated onto the system; and was far worse than that of older ones. His findings are
(iii) future decommissioning costs, which are unlikely relevant for the U.S. offshore wind projects because
to be fully accounted for by developers. they will be relying on a newer generation of still-larger
turbines, including GE’s 12-MW Haliade-X turbines.

Output Degradation Hughes’s study also noted another, less well-recog-


nized, problem with offshore turbines: subsea trans-
The levelized costs published by EIA in its Annual mission lines “are notorious for the severity and length
Energy Outlook, as well as the levelized PPA prices of their outages.” (As noted earlier, the Block Island
shown in Figure 5, all assume that there is no reduction Wind Farm’s offshore cable was exposed because of
in the amount of power generated by an offshore wind erosion. Repairs and reburying of the cable are antici-
project as its turbines age. In reality, output tends to pated to take at least six months to complete.)
decrease as generating units age. This can be caused
by the need for additional downtime for maintenance. Finally, Hughes’s study shows that the likelihood of
Or, as in the case of solar photovoltaics, by breakdowns major outages lasting at least one month increases by
in the solar cells themselves. For example, the electric at least 10% per year. In other words, in the first year
conversion efficiency of solar photovoltaics decreases of operation, a turbine has a 10% likelihood of a major
on average 0.8% per year.70 outage. In its second year of operation, that probabil-
ity increases to 20%, then 30% in the third year, and
The output degradation in offshore wind turbines has so forth, increasing to about an 80% probability of a
two key economic impacts. First, the more a project’s major outage by the time a turbine is eight years old.
output declines over time, the higher its levelized
cost. Second, as costs increase as output declines, Not only are major outages costly to repair for the
the relative benefit of continued operation decreases. owners, but the lost output must be replaced. Given
Eventually, the expected costs of maintaining a project the propensity for major outages, this means that there

18
FIGURE 7.

Effect of Output Degradation on Levelized Cost (20-Year PPA)


Relative Increase in Levelized Cost, 20-year PPA (%)
70%

60%

50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%
0.5% 1.0% 1.5% 2.0% 2.5% 3.0% 3.5% 4.0% 4.5%
Average Annual Output Degradation Percentage

Source: Author’s calculation

will be a greater need for the bulk power systems to $122.25/MWh. This would seem to mean that EIA’s
increase the quantity of generating capacity held in levelized cost estimates are too high. In fact, EIA’s lev-
reserve, as well as higher costs paid by consumers. elized cost estimate is likely to be too low.

Output degradation over time will increase the actual As discussed previously, EIA estimated a weighted-
levelized costs of PPAs shown in Figure 5. For example, average LCOE for offshore wind turbines installed in
if output degrades an average of 2.5% per year, the re- 2025 of $115.04/MWh (2019$). That LCOE estimate
sulting increase in a project’s levelized cost is 22% for a is based on an assumed lifetime of 30 years. However,
20-year PPA.75 At the 4.5% average annual degradation offshore wind turbines are designed only to withstand
rate calculated in the Hughes study, the increase in the elements for 20–25 years.
levelized cost is 58%, and, after 10 years, the expected
output will be about half the initial output (Figure 7). Using more favorable financing assumptions,76 NREL
estimates a lower LCOE cost, $89/MWh (2018$),
Output degradation over time is likely to cause another based on projects installed in Europe and a study of
hidden cost for consumers and taxpayers: the cost of a representative 5.5-MW turbine. Contra Hughes,
project abandonment. NREL estimates assume that a wind turbine will never
suffer any extended outages.77 Even so, many of the
levelized PPA costs are below NREL’s LCOE estimate
Project Abandonment and the as well.
“Winner’s Curse” This would seem unlikely, especially as most of the
cost estimates are based on data from Europe, which
The levelized costs of many of the PPAs shown in has an extensive history of offshore wind, while the
Figure 5 are lower than EIA’s levelized cost estimates only functioning offshore wind farm in the U.S. is
for offshore wind turbines—in some cases, much lower. the 30-MW Block Island Wind Farm Project. Yet, as
For example, as shown in Figure 5, the levelized PPA discussed previously, the relatively low-cost PPAs are
price of the Mayflower Wind Project is $55.52/MWh, seen as evidence of rapidly declining costs to construct
versus the EIA’s average forecast for offshore wind of and operate offshore wind projects.

19
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

The apparent contradiction can be resolved by noting Ensuring Bulk Power System
two factors. First, as Hughes (2020) points out, the Reliability
costs of offshore wind projects have declined, owing to
economies of scale and low interest rates, but neither As with all large generators in New England, New York,
trend is likely to continue to any great extent. Second, and the Mid-Atlantic states, the electricity produced by
Hughes (2020) notes that the growing discrepancy offshore wind farms must be integrated onto the bulk
between estimated costs and PPA bids may be ascribed power system that provides electricity to local electric
to what economists call the “winner’s curse,” a familiar utilities and their ultimate customers. To provide safe
concept in auction theory.78 In brief, auction winners and reliable electricity, the supply and demand must be
tend to overpay. In the context of one-off wind power matched continuously by a Regional Transmission Or-
projects, “winners” tend to underestimate costs and ganization (RTO).81 The reason is that electricity-con-
overestimate benefits, a phenomenon known as suming devices—lightbulbs, motors, the computer I
“optimism bias.”79 am using to write this report, etc.—are all designed to
operate within a narrow band of voltage and frequency.
Coupled with the observed annual output degradation If those bands are breached, the effects can range from
rates for offshore wind projects in Denmark, which flickering lights to a large-scale blackout.
have been especially acute for the newer generation of
large turbines, if the lower-cost PPA auction winners in Consequently, power systems have different types
Figure 5 above have underestimated construction and, of reserves that can respond to changes in supply or
especially, ongoing operation costs, they will be more demand. For example, many gas-fired generators
likely to abandon the projects as uneconomic before have the ability to “load-follow”—to have their output
the full terms of their contracts.80 ramped up or down to match instantaneous changes
in electricity demand (called “automatic generation
control”). Other generators are kept on hot standby,
Abandoned Projects equivalent to a car that is running in neutral gear. At
a moment’s notice, the generator can be engaged (put
Most proposed offshore wind projects in the U.S. into gear) to meet demand.
are structured as limited-liability, single-purpose
entities. This means that the only assets of the Unlike fossil-fuel and nuclear plants, wind and solar
company will be the turbines and related equipment. are inherently intermittent, generating electricity only
If a project becomes uneconomic to operate under when the wind blows or the sun shines. Their output
the terms of its PPA, the company can declare cannot be controlled and can change from moment to
bankruptcy. Utility ratepayers and the state’s moment. This inherent intermittency must be compen-
taxpayers will have no recourse to recover the costs sated for by relying more on natural gas-fired generators
to cover decommissioning the turbines and removing that can be brought online quickly, on pumped-storage
them from the ocean. hydroelectric plants, or, thanks to additional mandates
and subsidies,82 on expensive battery storage.83
Thus, if a project with a 20-year PPA is abandoned
after 10 years, the available alternatives will be to Although small quantities of intermittent wind and
renegotiate the PPA and pay more for the project’s solar energy can be accommodated on the bulk power
output; or decommission the project prematurely. If systems at a relatively low cost, these costs increase
the former option is chosen, electric utility ratepayers as greater quantities of these resources are integrated
lose. If the latter option is chosen, moneys set aside onto the bulk power system. A 2012 study prepared for
for decommissioning are unlikely to cover the actual the Organisation of Economic Co-operation and Devel-
decommissioning costs. These costs will have to opment (OECD) examined grid-related costs for differ-
shouldered by electricity consumers and, possibly, ent types of generating resources in different countries.
the state’s taxpayers (see sidebar, Who Will Pay to It estimated that if offshore wind accounted for 10% of
Decommission Offshore Turbines?). the total electricity supply, the resulting grid-support
costs would be $20.51/MWh. At 30%, the costs would
None of the publicly reviewable portions of the be $28.26/MWh. For onshore wind, the study estimat-
approved PPAs provides specific information about ed the costs to be $16.30/MWh and $19.84/MWh for
the moneys that project owners will be required to set the 10% and 30% cases, respectively. By comparison,
aside for eventual decommissioning. Although PPAs the study estimated the grid-support costs of natural
include discussions of performance bonds when the gas-fired generators to be $0.51/MWh.84
projects are under construction, discussions about
decommissioning requirements are absent.

20
Grid-support costs will not be paid by offshore wind It is certainly true that subsidizing offshore wind energy
developers. Instead, they will be socialized across all development will create jobs for energy developers. It
electricity consumers through electric transmission may also lead to new businesses serving the offshore
rates that are charged by grid operators that coordinate wind industry, especially if, as in Maryland, developers
the bulk power system. For the East Coast states with are required to create minimum numbers of jobs and
offshore wind mandates, these grid operators are ISO contribute to the development of new manufacturing
New England, the New York Independent System Op- facilities. When the entire economic ledger is tallied,
erator, and PJM Interconnection. Offshore wind pro- however, the net impact of renewable energy subsidies
ponents (and wind and solar proponents in general) necessarily will be lower economic growth and a citi-
either downplay these costs as de minimus85 or ignore zenry that is worse off.
them altogether.
The fundamental error is to confuse economic benefits
with economic transfers. In effect, claims of enhanced
economic growth assume that the money that pays for
V. Claims of Economic offshore wind development drops out of the sky. In
Development Benefits reality, the money is transferred from ratepayers and
taxpayers to developers—there is no improvement
of Offshore Wind Are in overall well-being. Ignoring or whistling past this
reality leads to a preposterous outcome: if one ignores
Misleading the economic impacts of forcibly transferring dollars
from consumers and taxpayers to developers of renew-
As noted earlier, a 2017 NYSERDA report claimed ables, then the most costly—and least cost-effective—
that developing 2,400 MW of offshore wind in New renewable resources will be seen to create the greatest
York State would create nearly 5,000 new jobs economic “benefits.”90
associated with manufacturing, installation, and
ongoing operations, as well as $6.3 billion of new Given its cost relative to wholesale electric prices, off-
infrastructure spending.86 In March 2020, AWEA shore wind energy will lead to higher electricity prices.
claimed that offshore wind power would create Many public utility commissions that have approved
19,000–45,000 new jobs by 2025, and 45,000– offshore wind PPAs acknowledge the cost increases
83,000 jobs by 2030.87 Offshore wind development, but opine that they will be insignificant. For example,
according to the report, would also increase economic NYSERDA claimed that the average bill impact for res-
output by $12 billion–$25 billion by 2030: “Economic idential customers from the Empire Wind and Sunrise
benefits extend beyond initial project expenditures as Wind Projects would be $0.73/month.91 Similar claims
project spending circulates throughout the economy, by offshore wind proponents based on such cost break-
delivering additional spending and job support. downs (sometimes called the “cup-of-coffee” pricing
Capturing the initial and subsequent impacts fallacy) are disingenuous: they ignore the cumulative
stemming from offshore wind projects provides a full economic impacts of those higher costs. A $3 cup of
picture of the economic contributions the offshore coffee sold by Starbucks may not sound like much, but
wind industry can deliver to the U.S.”88 in 2019, Starbucks’ revenues were $26.5 billion and the
company’s profits exceeded $5.7 billion.92
In approving PPAs for the US Wind and Skipjack
offshore wind projects, Maryland imposed specific
minimum in-state employment requirements.
For US Wind, the state mandated the creation of VI. Adverse
1,298 direct construction-period jobs and 2,282
direct operating-period jobs in the state during the Environmental Impacts
project’s 20-year operational contract life, along with
a $51 million investment in a new steel fabrication Of the 13 projects in Figure 2, only Vineyard Wind has
plant. Skipjack will be required to create a minimum a completed Draft Environmental Impact Statement
of 913 direct construction-period jobs and 484 direct (EIS).93 (A supplement to this EIS was issued on June
operating-period jobs, plus a minimum $25 million 12, 2020.)94 The Draft EIS discusses impacts on a variety
investment in the steel fabrication plant. Skipjack of resources, classifying those impacts as “negligible,”
will be required to create a minimum of 913 direct “minor,” “moderate,” or “major.”95 In some instances,
construction-period jobs and 484 direct operating- the EIS also noted potentially beneficial impacts,
period jobs, plus a minimum $25 million investment such as the creation of artificial reefs for finfish from
in the steel fabrication plant.89 foundations and scour protection,96 although these

21
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

claimed benefits have been challenged by fisheries Unfortunately, as the Supplemental EIS notes, there
representatives.97 (Scour refers to the erosion of the is little research on such long-term impacts.104 For
seabed surrounding a wind turbine foundation, effectively example, it is not known how construction up and
creating a hole around the foundation.) However, for this down the East Coast for many years will affect how
category, the Draft EIS also noted potentially moderate fish migrate. There is no research on how construction
long-term impacts from habitat disruption and moderate will affect the migration of whales, especially the North
to major adverse impacts on commercial fisheries and Atlantic right whale, of which only about 400 remain.105
recreational fishing. One key concern: the proposed Similarly, there is no research on the potential
spacing between the turbines will be too small to allow cumulative impacts on migratory seabirds.
commercial fishing. Another: the underground cable
delivering electricity to the shore may be exposed because
of strong tidal currents, as happened with the Block Island Indirect Environmental Impacts
Wind Farm Project cable in August 2019.
Among other environmental concerns, perhaps the
The Draft EIS ignored the environmental impacts most significant are the rare-earth minerals required to
associated with decommissioning. For example, manufacture turbines. Currently, almost all rare-earth
BOEM stated that undersea cables could be retired minerals are supplied by China, from mines in Mongolia.
in place but did not evaluate the potential long-term China’s environmental laws are far less stringent than
impacts of deactivated cables, or how such impacts those in the West. Hence, by promoting “clean” wind
would be monitored.98 energy, U.S. states are, in effect, outsourcing adverse
environmental impacts, including toxic lakes where
The major adverse cumulative impacts determined by radioactive material—primarily thorium bound up
BOEM help explain the intense opposition to offshore in mineral deposits—is dumped;106 and high levels
wind projects by many commercial fishermen. The of air pollution, “the deadly and sinister side of the
turbines for the proposed South Fork Wind Farm, off massively profitable rare-earths industry that the ‘green’
the eastern tip of Long Island, will not be visible from companies profiting from the demand for wind turbines
the shore, but fishermen are concerned that the under- would prefer you knew nothing about.”107
water cable will permanently disrupt fishing efforts.99
There is no research on cumulative impacts on benthic Moreover, as my Manhattan Institute colleague Mark
(seafloor) species from electromagnetic fields, under- Mills’s most recent report discusses, the raw materi-
water noise, and potential habitat changes that will als needed to manufacture and install wind turbines
encourage the proliferation of nonnative species.100 dwarf those needed to manufacture and install gas-
Nor is there evidence for BOEM’s claim that there will fired combined-cycle turbines.108 Other than fiberglass
be beneficial “reef effects” from turbine foundations. blades, which currently cannot be recycled and are
Perhaps the greatest direct environmental concern, already creating disposal issues for landfills because
however, is the cumulative impacts of all the proposed of their size,109 wind turbines are primarily made from
offshore wind development along the Atlantic Coast. steel (70%–80% of the total mass).110 Steel, of course,
If all these projects are developed, “temporary” dis- is made from coal. The largest monopile foundations,
ruption of marine habitats and fisheries for each proj- upon which about 80% of all offshore wind turbines
ect’s construction will mean long-term disruptions for have been built, weigh over 1,300 tons.111 Each 12-MW
decades.101 This is the primary reason that BOEM has GE Haliade-X turbine weighs 2,800 tons, including
delayed the issuance of a final EIS for the project.102 the 2,000-ton steel monopile foundation.112 To make
one ton of steel solely from raw materials requires
The Vineyard Wind Supplemental EIS issued by about 1.4 tons of iron ore and 0.8 tons of coal,113 so
BOEM in June 2020 examined these cumulative each foundation implies about 2,800 tons of iron ore
impacts of developing 22,000 MW of offshore wind and 1,600 tons of coal. Concrete gravity foundations,
along the Atlantic Coast, which “would result in the the other major alternative to monopile foundations,
construction of about 2,000 wind turbines over a also require large amounts of materials. A gravity base
10-year period.”103 It emphasized the uncertainty of foundation for a single 6-MW turbine in the North Sea
many findings because of lack of data; however, it requires more than 5,000 tons of concrete and more
concluded that there would be “moderate” adverse than 700 tons of steel.114
impacts on bottom fish, finfish, fish habitat, marine
mammals (including whales), and sea turtles. It also The materials requirements for offshore (and onshore)
found that there would be “major” adverse impacts on wind turbines to become a major source of electricity
commercial fisheries, as well as on coastal navigation, in the U.S. will be staggering, especially as states seek
scientific research, and military uses. to electrify their economies toward the stated goals

22
of eliminating all greenhouse gas emissions. Along cepted the estimated annual reduction of 1.2 million
with damage to fisheries, the environmental costs tons of CO2 from the US Wind and Skipjack Projects,
associated with mining and manufacturing rare-earth that represents 0.02% of 2019 U.S. energy-related CO2
elements and the vast quantities of raw materials to emissions.
manufacture and install—compared with other, far
more energy-dense, generating resources such as
gas-fired generators and nuclear units—mean that
states mandating thousands of MW of offshore wind VII. Conclusions and
capacity thus will create their own set of environmental
problems. Yet offshore wind proponents respond to Policy Recommendations
these environmental issues either by dismissing them
as insignificant or ignoring them altogether.115 As in the popular game show Jeopardy!, offshore
wind is an “answer” in search of a policy question. The
Ultimately, the environmental benefits of offshore wind, current projects slated to be built off the Atlantic Coast
in terms of reduced air pollution and greenhouse gas will raise the cost of electricity and reduce the grid’s
emissions, are likely overstated, for two reasons. First, reliability, forcing bulk power systems to invest ad-
to the extent that the intermittent output of offshore ditional resources in backup generation resources or
wind plants is backstopped with gas-fired generators, high-cost battery storage. Claims that offshore wind
the latter will operate less efficiently, producing more costs are declining rapidly, based on PPA prices, fail
emissions and less output, much as a gasoline-powered to consider that the winning bidders may be seriously
car operates less efficiently in stop-and-go traffic than underestimating their costs over time. The experience
on a highway. with offshore wind projects in Europe over the last
decade has demonstrated that newer, larger turbine
Second, offshore wind will tend to displace onshore technologies have been accompanied by significant re-
wind. In a 2017 review, the Maryland Public Service liability and maintenance issues, causing the amount
Commission’s independent evaluator, Levitan and of electricity that these turbines generate each year to
Associates, found that the state’s Skipjack and US decline by almost half over 10 years.
Wind projects would reduce gas-fired generation in
the eastern part of the PJM region (e.g., Delaware, The likely declines in output will reduce the revenues
Maryland, Pennsylvania) but tend to reduce electricity and profitability of these facilities over time. This may
generated from onshore wind in the western portion lead developers to abandon the facilities before the term
(e.g., Illinois, Ohio).116 The reason: offshore wind will of their PPAs, leaving ratepayers and taxpayers to pay
increase the supply of ORECs and offset Maryland util- for decommissioning and dismantling the units. Even
ities’ need for RECs from other resources, primarily if the units do operate for their full claimed economic
onshore wind. Hence, REC prices will tend to fall, re- lifetimes, it is unclear whether they will be required to
ducing the economic value of onshore wind generation. set aside sufficient funds to pay for decommissioning.

This Levitan review also projected that with less Claimed environmental benefits from reduced pollution
onshore wind, more coal-fired generation would take and reduced greenhouse gas emissions fail to account
place in the western PJM, offsetting emissions reduc- for offsetting impacts in wholesale electricity markets
tions. The estimated net emissions reductions would be and fail to account for the increase in pollution from
only about 19,000 tons per year because of these offset- more inefficient use of gas-fired generators that will be
ting impacts on other electric generating plants, versus required to provide backup power to compensate for
the projected 1.2 million tons per year claimed by the the inherent intermittency of wind power. In any event,
projects’ developers.117 The Skipjack Project, accord- offshore wind development will make no meaningful
ing to the review, would result in an average decrease contributions to reductions in U.S. emissions of
in sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions of a mere 1.6 tons/ greenhouse gases, nor will it have any measurable
year and reduce emissions of oxides of nitrogen (NOx) impacts on world climate.
by only 3.4 tons/year over the project’s lifetime.118 By
comparison, U.S. emissions of SO2 and NOx from elec- The claimed economic development benefits of
tric generating plants in 2018 were 1.26 million tons offshore wind are also overstated, as proponents ignore
and 1.02 million tons, respectively. Finally, the Levitan the adverse economic impacts on existing consumers
review estimated that the project would reduce CO2 and businesses from higher electricity costs. Forcing
emissions an average of 6,384 tons/year.119 By compar- offshore wind developers to hire minimum numbers
ison, total U.S. energy-related CO2 emissions in 2019 of workers and contribute to the construction of new
were estimated to be 5.1 billion tons.120 Even if one ac- manufacturing facilities, as Maryland has done, is

23
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

absurd. Ultimately, the economic benefits of subsidized decommissioning funds, as is done for nuclear power
offshore wind development will accrue to the few, at plants and for individual pipelines that are subject to
the expense of the many. asset retirement obligations.

In view of all the shortcomings, this report recommends • Require offshore wind developers to pay for the
that states: additional costs of backup generating resources
needed to compensate for the inherent intermittency
• End subsidized development of offshore wind of their wind facilities. These developers should also
facilities, including the requirement that electric be required to pay for the costs to interconnect their
utilities purchase increasing quantities of offshore projects to the bulk power system, rather than having
wind renewable energy credits. Developers that those costs be paid for by electricity customers.
wish to construct and operate offshore wind
facilities should bear the investment risks, rather • Focus on ensuring that electricity demand is met
than be allowed to transfer those risks to electricity with the most efficient resources possible, rather
consumers. than resources that will create set numbers of jobs.
States that wish to emphasize clean energy resources
• Require offshore wind developers to provide should ensure that reliable nuclear power generat-
full information to the public about anticipated ing units can be constructed, especially new modular
decommissioning costs and post surety bonds that technologies that will reduce financial risks and use
will fully fund those costs. As decommissioning natural forces such as gravity to bring a reactor to a
cost estimates change over time, project developers safe shutdown.121
should be required to adjust their contributions to

Appendix.
The Mathematics of Calculating Levelized
Cost for a PPA
Calculating the levelized cost of a PPA involves three steps:
1. Estimate the overall stream of annual nominal or real costs associated with the PPA.

2. Determine the net present value of that annual stream of costs.

3. Calculate the LCOE as the value that, when multiplied by each year’s output, equals the net present value
of the stream of annual costs.

Assume a PPA that will last T years. The output to be sold in each year t is Qt at a nominal price Pt. The dis-
count rate, i, is just the weighted average cost of capital.

Item (3) implies that:

(A-1)

Solving equation (A-1) for LCOE, we have:

(A-2)

24
There are two cases to consider.
Case 1: The annual output level, Qt, is constant. If so, then equation (A-2)
simplifies as follows:

(A-3)

where CRF is the “capital recovery factor.” Hence, in the case of constant
annual output, the LCOE is just the annualized “mortgage payment”
divided by the annual output.
Case 2: Qt degrades at a constant percentage rate, d, such that:
(A-4)
Hence, we can rewrite the denominator of (A-2) as follows:

(A-5)

where l = (1 - d) / (1 + i). Applying a bit of algebra, it turns out that

(A-6)

Hence, we can rewrite (A-5) as:

(A-7)

Note that, if d = 0, that is, there is no output degradation over time, then
(A-7) simplifies to the denominator in (A-3).

25
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

Endnotes
1 American Wind Energy Association (AWEA), Wind Facts at a Glance, accessed July 27, 2020.
2 U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA), “Electricity Monthly Update,” Apr. 24, 2020. EIA’s electricity data browser shows net generation by source.
3 On Dec. 20, 2019, the president signed the Taxpayer Certainty and Disaster Relief of 2019, which extended PTC eligibility for new wind facilities that
begin construction by Dec. 31, 2020, but need not be operational until Jan. 1, 2023. There have been repeated efforts by some in Congress to extend
this deadline further. Those efforts are sure to continue.
4 See, e.g., Robert Bryce, “Wind Power Is an Attack on Rural America,” Los Angeles Times, Feb. 23, 2017; “Angry U.S. Landowners Are Killing Off
Renewable Energy Projects,” New York Post, Mar. 7, 2020.
5 New York Governor Andrew Cuomo signed emergency budget legislation to create a new Office of Renewable Energy Development within the
Department of Economic Development. Under this legislation, local municipalities will no longer be able to oppose development of industrial-scale wind
and solar projects. See New York State Energy Research and Development Authority (NYSERDA), “New York State Announces Passage of Accelerated
Renewable Energy Growth and Community Benefit Act as Part of 2020–2021 Enacted State Budget,” Apr. 3, 2020; Jonathan Lesser, “Andrew Cuomo’s
Bid to Ram Industrial Wind, Solar Plants Down Locals’ Throats,” New York Post, Mar. 30, 2020.
6 Joshua Hill, “New York Governor Cuomo Announces Mammoth Offshore Wind & Distributed Solar Increases,” Clean Technica, Jan. 16, 2019.
7 Executive Order No. 8, Jan. 31, 2018.
8 The 2016 legislation is called “An Act to Promote Energy Diversity.” It was followed in 2018 by “An Act to Advance Clean Energy.” See Massachusetts
Clean Energy Center, Offshore Wind, undated.
9 “Offshore Wind Energy in Maryland,” Maryland Energy Administration.
10 A 2014 report prepared for the U.S. Department of Energy (DOE), for example, estimated that construction of 16,000 MW of offshore wind capacity
by 2030 would create more than 18,000 full-time-equivalent jobs (FTEs) and that operating and maintaining that capacity would create more than
8,600 FTEs. See DOE, “Economic Impacts of Offshore Wind,” January 2014, table 3; E2, “Offshore Wind: Generating Economic Benefits on the East
Coast,” August 2018. A report prepared by AWEA predicts 45,000–83,000 jobs by 2030. See AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Power Economic Impact
Assessment,” March 2020.
11 European Wind Energy Association (EWEA), “Wind in Our Sails,” 2011, p. 11.
12 The Vindeby facility was decommissioned in 2017.
13 WindEurope, “Offshore Wind in Europe—Key Trends and Statistics 2018,” February 2019.
14 The 138-MW Skipjack Wind Project, to be located off the Delaware coast, will use these turbines.
15 Eizede Vries, “How SGRE Upped the Offshore States with 14MW+ Turbine and 222m Rotor,” Windpower Monthly, May 19, 2020; Adnan Durakovic, “15
MW Siemens Gamesa Turbines for Offshore Wind Farm,” OffshoreWIND.biz, May 26, 2020.
16 Vaclav Smil, “Wind Turbines Just Keep Getting Bigger, but There’s a Limit,” IEEE Spectrum, Oct. 22, 2019.
17 ISO New England (ISO-NE), “New England Power Grid 2019–2020 Profile,” Feb. 27, 2020.
18 Rhode Island Public Utilities Commission, In Re: Review of Proposed Town of New Shoreham Project Pursuant to R.I. Gen. Laws § 39-26.1-7, Docket
No. 4111, Report and Order, Apr. 2, 2010, at 65.
19 State of Rhode Island and Providence Plantations Public Utilities Commission, In Re: Review of Amended Power Purchase Agreement Between
Narragansett Electric Company D/B/A National Grid and Deepwater Wind Block Island, LLC Pursuant to R.I. Gen. Laws § 39-26.1-7, Docket No. 4185,
Report and Order, Aug. 16, 2010.
20 Kathryn Seelye, “After 16 Years, Hopes for Cape Cod Wind Farm Float Away,” New York Times, Dec. 19, 2017. In 2010, I testified on behalf of the
Alliance to Protect Nantucket Sound regarding the economics of the project and the specific costs of the proposed PPAs between Cape Wind and
Massachusetts electric utilities.
21 AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Industry—Status Update,” October 2019. In June 2019, Maine Governor Janet Mills signed legislation requiring the Maine
Public Utilities Commission to approve a power purchase contract for Maine Aqua Ventus, an (up to) 12-MW floating offshore wind farm. The governor
also announced the Offshore Wind Initiative to investigate opportunities for offshore wind development in the Gulf of Maine. See Office of Governor Janet
Mills, “Governor Mills Signs Bill to Advance Offshore Wind Demonstration Project, Announces Maine Offshore Wind Initiative,” June 19, 2019.
22 Maps of the locations for the Sunrise and Empire projects can be downloaded from NYSERDA’s Map Library.
23 Equinor, “Equinor Offshore Wind Bid Wins in New York State,” press release, July 18, 2019. Currently, the only wind turbine with an installed capacity
greater than 10 MW is the GE Haliade X-12, with an installed capacity of 12 MW. That turbine is not yet in service.
24 NYSERDA, “White Paper on Clean Energy Standard Procurements to Implement New York’s Climate Leadership and Community Protection Act,” Case
No. 15-E-0302, June 18, 2020.
25 Colin Young, “Mayflower Wind Picked for 800-Megawatt Project Off of Nantucket Island, Martha’s Vineyard,” WBUR, Oct. 30, 2019.
26 Senator Sheldon Whitehouse (D., RI), who in July 2019 cosponsored legislation for a nationwide carbon tax, is a vocal critic of Vineyard Wind. See
Benjamin Storrow and Heather Richards, “Top Climate Hawk Bashes First Big Offshore Wind Project,” E&E News, Nov. 15, 2019.
27 Inthe Matter of the Board of Public Utilities Offshore Wind Solicitation for 1,100 MW—Evaluation of the Offshore Wind Applications, Docket No.
QO18121289, Order, June 21, 2019.
28 AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Industry—Status Update,” June 2020.
29 DOE, “2018 Offshore Wind Technologies Market Report,” 2018, p. xi.
30 EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020, table 16. Curiously, the EIA forecast shows no additional offshore wind capacity after 2035.
31 Ibid., table 8.
32 E.g., see PPA between NStar Electric Company and Mayflower Wind, Jan. 10, 2020.
33 In states with restructured electric industries, competitive firms are allowed to sell electricity directly to retail consumers. REC mandates also apply to
these firms.
34 LIPA Fact Sheet, “LIPA Procures Energy from New York’s First Offshore Wind Farm,” Oct. 28, 2019.
35 Mark Harrington, “South Fork Wind Farm More Costly than Larger State Projects, LIPA Says,” Newsday, Oct. 28, 2019.

26
36 Ibid.

37 EIA, Today in Energy, “EIA Uses Two Simplified Metrics to Show Future Power Plants’ Relative Economics,” Mar. 29, 2018.
38 The Appendix to this report provides the mathematics for calculating levelized costs.
39 For
its analysis, EIA assumes a real weighted average cost of capital (WACC) of 4.30%. The agency also assumes an average annual inflation rate of
2.3%.
40 The calculation is performed by converting all annual contract prices to 2019$ and then adjusting the present value of those prices to reflect an assumed
start date of 2025. EIA’s offshore wind LCOE estimates are based on the agency’s estimates of project costs, not actual PPA contract prices. As
discussed below, the lower PPA contract prices do not mean that EIA’s cost figures are too high. Rather, they may be evidence of what economists call
the “winner’s curse.”
41 Adiscussion of the health impacts associated with low-frequency sound emitted by wind turbines is beyond the scope of this report. For a discussion,
see Robert McCunney et al., “Wind Turbines and Health: A Critical Review of the Scientific Literature,” Journal of Occupational and Environmental
Medicine 56, no. 11 (November 2014): 108–30; Alice Freiberg et al., “Health Effects of Wind Turbines on Humans in Residential Settings: Results of a
Scoping Review,” Environmental Research 169 (February 2019): 446–63.
42 For
examples of opposition in upstate New York, see Sara Jerving, “Proposed Wind Turbines Generating Conflict,” Investigative Post, Feb. 13, 2019;
Joseph Goldstein, “A Climate Conundrum: The Wind Farm vs. the Eagle’s Nest,” New York Times, June 25, 2019.
43 See,e.g., Jenna Portnoy, “After Coal, Appalachia to Wind Farm Proposal: ‘It Is Insulting, Really,’ ” Washington Post, Aug. 20, 2015; Scott McFetridge,
“New Rebellion Against Wind Energy Stalls or Stops Projects,” Seattle Times, Feb. 21, 2018; Robert Bryce, “Hawaii Protests Show Why Wind Energy
Can’t Save Us from Climate Change,” The Hill, Nov. 13, 2019; Samantha Gross, “Renewables, Land Use, and Local Opposition in the United States,”
Brookings Institution, January 2020.
44 EIA, Electric Power Monthly, May 2020, table 6.07.B.
45 EIA, Assumptions to AEO 2020, Renewable Fuels Module, January 2020, p. 7.
46 PaulVigeant et al., “2018 Massachusetts Offshore Wind Workforce Assessment,” report prepared for MassCEC, May 2018, p. v. One job-year equals
one year of full-time equivalent employment.
47 David
R. Borges et al., “Proposed Vineyard Wind Offshore Wind Energy Project: Estimated Contribution to Employment and Economic Development
(800MW),” UMass Dartmouth, March 2018.
48 NYSERDA, “The Workforce Opportunity of Offshore Wind in New York,” Report No. 17-25t, December 2017.
49 Stateof New Jersey, Governor Phil Murphy, “New Jersey Board of Public Utilities Awards Historic 1,100 MW Offshore Wind Solicitation to Ørsted’s
Ocean Wind Project,” June 21, 2019. The actual award is: In the Matter of the Board of Public Utilities Offshore Wind Solicitation for 1,100 MW-
Evaluations of the Offshore Wind Applications, Docket No. Q018121289, Order, June 21, 2019.
50 “Project Selected to Increase Offshore Wind Energy in the Commonwealth,” Mass.gov, Oct. 10, 2019.
51 Commonwealth of Virginia, Office of the Governor, Executive Order 43, Sept. 17. 2019.
52 Commonwealth of Virginia, HB 1526.
53 Virginia Clean Economy, undated.
54 Frederick Hewett, “Massachusetts Could Win Big in Offshore Wind Energy,” WBUR, Cognoscenti, Mar. 5, 2018.
55 NYSERDA, “Benefits of Offshore Wind,” undated.
56 State of New Jersey, Office of the Governor, Executive Order 92, Nov. 19, 2019.
57 Inthe Matter of the Applications of U.S. Wind, Inc., and Skipjack Offshore Energy, LLC for a Proposed Offshore Wind Project(s) Pursuant to the Maryland
Offshore Wind Energy Act of 2013, Order No. 88192, May 11, 2017, Appendix A (US Wind) and Appendix B (Skipjack). US Wind will eventually build out
to 750 MW.
58 DOE, “National Offshore Wind Strategy,” September 2016, p. viii.
59 DOE, “2018 Offshore Wind Technologies Market Report,” August 2019, p. 57.
60 Ibid.,
p. 60. A proprietary forecast by Bloomberg cited in this report shows far more aggressive cost reductions for turbines, to less than $700/kW by
2025. The Bloomberg forecast is not supported by EIA’s cost forecast.
61 Smil, “Wind Turbines Just Keep Getting Bigger.”
62 EIA, “Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources,” January 2020, p. 8, table 2.
63 Ibid., p. 20.
64 USA Rare Earth is currently developing a project to extract rare earths from Round Top Mountain, located east of El Paso, Texas; see Jim Vinoski, “The
U.S. Needs China for Rare Earth Materials: Not for Long, Thanks to This Mountain,” Forbes, Apr. 7, 2020.
65 Jan Dodd, “Rethinking the Use of Rare-Earth Elements,” Windpower Monthly, Nov. 30, 2018.
66 Re:Petitions for Approval of Proposed Long-Term Contracts for Offshore Wind Energy Pursuant to Section 83C of Chapter 188 of the Acts of 2016,
D.P.U. 20-16, 20-17, 20-18, Letter from Robert Hoagland, Attorney for Massachusetts DOER to Mark Marini, Secretary, Department of Public Utilities,
Feb. 11, 2020, p. 4.
67 The calculation is based on the forecast generation price (energy and capacity) for New England, as shown in table 54.7 of AEO, less EIA’s forecast of
retail level taxes on electricity.
68 Jonathan Lesser, “Gresham’s Law of Green Energy,” Regulation (Winter 2010–11): 12–18.
69 EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020, table 8.
70 Dirk Jordan and Sarah Kurtz, “Photovoltaic Degradation Rates—An Analytical Review,” NREL, June 2012.
71 Gordon Hughes, “The Performance of Wind Farms in the United Kingdom and Denmark,” Renewable Energy Foundation, London, 2012, p. 11.
72 Hughes’s results were challenged in 2013; see David Milborrow, “No Big Drop in Performance as Turbines Get Older,” Windpower Monthly, Mar. 4, 2013.
Milborrow speculated that the decline in observed offshore wind performance was the result of less wind, not more breakdowns of equipment. Another
challenge to Hughes’s findings is Chris Goodsall, “Wind Turbines—Going Strong 20 Years On,” The Ecologist, Jan. 3, 2014. Hughes responded, arguing
that Goodsall did not perform any statistical analysis and considered a narrow subset of wind resources. See Gordon Hughes, “Response from Professor
Gordon Hughes to Previous Posting,” Carbon Commentary, Jan. 5, 2014.

27
Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

73 Iain Staffell and Richard Green, “How Does Wind Farm Performance Decline with Age?” Renewable Energy 66 (2014): 775–86.
74 Gordon Hughes, “The Performance of Wind Generation in Denmark Revisited,” Renewable Energy Foundation, London, forthcoming October 2020.
75 The Appendix to this report provides the underlying mathematics that determine the change in levelized cost relative to a decrease in output.
76 EIA’s real weighted average cost of capital, 4.3%, implies a capital recovery factor of 6.6% for a 25-year life, whereas NREL assumes a slightly lower
6.5% capital recovery factor. NREL also assumes a 5.01% nominal discount rate, equivalent to a 2.65% real discount rate (based on EIA’s average
inflation rate of 2.31%), whereas EIA’s real discount rate is 4.30%. The lower the real discount rate, the lower the levelized cost.
77 Tyler Stehly and Philipp Beiter, “2018 Cost of Wind Energy Review,” NREL, December 2019.
78 For a discussion, see Richard Thayer, “The Winner’s Curse,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, no. 1 (Winter 1988): 191–202.
79 See,e.g., Bent Flyvbjerg, “Survival of the Unfittest: Why the Worst Infrastructure Gets Built and What We Can Do About It,” Oxford Review of Economic
Policy 25, no. 3 (Autumn 2009): 344–67. It may also be the case that PPA developers have assumed that the production tax credit (PTC), which is
scheduled to expire on Dec. 31, 2020, will be renewed ad infinitum by Congress.
80 Hughes (2020) provides a detailed financial analysis of the Kriegers Flak project, which is expected to be operational by the end of 2021. Vattenfall, the
developer, bid a flat nominal price of €49.9/MWh (about US$58/MWh, at the current exchange rate), equivalent to a real levelized cost of $39/MWh.
Hughes concludes that the break-even price for the project is at least one-third too low and, if the project’s output declines at an average rate of 4.5%/
year, two-thirds too low.
81 RTOs coordinate generating facilities and operate the high-voltage transmission grid; together, this is referred to as the “bulk power system.” The PJM
Interconnection (PJM) encompasses 13 Mid-Atlantic states, plus the District of Columbia; ISO-NE, which oversees the bulk power system for the New
England states; and the New York ISO, which does the same for New York State. All have separate markets for energy, capacity, and what are called
“ancillary services.” Capacity can be thought of as a measure of “iron in the ground” that is available to meet electricity demand. Ancillary services
include other components of the bulk power system, such as reserves of generation that can be available on a moment’s notice, ensuring that the
system operates safely, reliably, and within specific voltage and frequency parameters. For simplicity, I refer to the combined products of electric energy
(measured in MWh), capacity (measured in MW), and ancillary services as “energy.” For an additional, nontechnical discussion, see Jonathan Lesser and
Leonardo Giacchino, Fundamentals of Energy Regulation, 3rd ed. (Reston, VA: Public Utilities Reports, 2019), chap. 18.
82 E.g., in 2018, NYSERDA approved a battery storage goal of 1,500 MW by 2025 (NYSERDA, “Governor Cuomo Announces Dramatic Increase in Energy
Efficiency and Energy Storage,” Dec. 13, 2018). That same year, Massachusetts approved legislation mandating 1,000 MWh of battery storage by Dec.
31, 2025 (“Energy Storage Initiative,” Mass.gov). California’s 2013 battery storage mandate calls for 1,325 MW by the end of 2020 (CPUC, Decision
Adopting Energy Storage Procurement Framework and Design Program, Decision 13-10-1040, Oct. 17, 2013). In total, six states have such mandates.
83 Currentestimates of the capital costs for utility-scale battery storage are about $400/MWh for four hours of storage, with forecast costs decreasing to
about $150/MWh (2018$) by 2050. Those costs far exceed current and projected wholesale prices of electricity. See Wesley Cole and A. Will Frazier,
“Cost Projections for Utility-Scale Battery Storage,” NREL, June 2019.
84 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, “Nuclear Energy and Renewables: System Effects in Low-Carbon Electricity Systems,” 2012,
p. 18. See also Lion Hirth, Falko Ueckerdt, and Ottmar Edenhofer, “Why Wind Is Not Coal: On the Economics of Electricity Generation,” Energy Journal
37, no. 3 (July 2016): 1–27, which includes a literature review of grid integration costs.
85 E.g., NYSERDA estimated that the increased cost for the average residential customer would be $0.68/month.
86 NYSERDA, “The Workforce Opportunity of Offshore Wind in New York,” Report 17-25t, December 2017.
87 AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Power Economic Impact Assessment,” March 2020.
88 Ibid., p. 6.
89 In
the Matter of the Applications of U.S. Wind, Inc., and Skipjack Offshore Energy, LLC for a Proposed Offshore Wind Project(s) Pursuant to the Maryland
Offshore Wind Energy Act of 2013, Order No. 88192, May 11, 2017, Appendix A (US Wind) and Appendix B (Skipjack).
90 For
additional discussion, see Jonathan Lesser, “Renewable Energy and the Fallacy of Green Jobs,” Electricity Journal 23, no. 7 (August/September
2010): 45–53.
91 NYSERDA, “Launching New York’s Offshore Wind Industry: Phase 1 Report,” October 2019, p. ii.
92 Starbucks Corporation, FY19 Annual Report, p. 24.
93 BOEM, “Vineyard Wind Offshore Wind Energy Project Draft Environmental Impact Statement,” December 2018.
94 BOEM,“Vineyard Wind 1 Offshore Wind Energy Project: Supplement to the Draft Environmental Impact Statement,” June 2020 (Vineyard Wind
Supplemental EIS). BOEM states that it intends to issue a final decision on project approval by December 2020.
95 Vineyard Wind Draft EIS, pp. ES-6–ES-8.
96 Ibid.

97 Letter
from Annie Hawkins, Responsible Offshore Development Alliance (RODA), to Dr. Walter Cruickshank, BOEM, Feb. 22, 2019 (RODA letter, Feb.
22, 2019), p. 12 (a copy of this letter is available on request from the author). For a discussion of scour, see “Offshore Wind Farm Developments and
Scouring Effects,” Hydro International, Oct. 15, 2008.
98 RODA letter, Feb. 22, 2019, p. 8.
99 ThomasZambito, “Energy Ratepayers Bankrolling Offshore Wind Farm Opposed by the Long Island Fishing Community,” Rockland/Westchester Journal
News, Sept. 12, 2018.
100 RODA letter, Feb. 22, 2019, pp. 4–5.
101 Alex Kuffner, “Troubling Questions, Concerns Raised About Offshore Wind Farms,” Providence Journal, Aug. 21, 2019.
102 As of this writing, there are no published EIS documents for the other offshore wind projects listed in Fig. 2.
103 Vineyard Wind Supplemental EIS, p. ES-2.
104  OEM has published an approach to evaluate cumulative impacts of offshore wind projects. See National Environmental Policy Act Documentation for
B
Impact-Producing Factors in the Offshore Wind Cumulative Impacts Scenario on the North Atlantic Outer Continental Shelf; OCS Study, BOEM 2019-
036, May 2019.
105 Telephone interview with Adam Lipsky, National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, May 19, 2020.
106 Mike Ives, “Boom in Mining Rare Earths Poses Mounting Toxic Risks,” YaleEnvironment360, Jan. 28, 2013.
107 Simon Parry, “In China, the True Cost of Britain’s Clean, Green Wind Power Experiment: Pollution on a Disastrous Scale,” Mail Online, Jan. 26, 2011.

28
108 Mark Mills, “Mines, Minerals, and ‘Green’ Energy: A Reality Check,” Manhattan Institute, July 2020.
109 Christina Stella, “As Wind Energy Thrives, So Does Its Waste Problem,” Harvest Public Media, Sept. 1, 2019.
110 NREL, “2015 Cost of Wind Energy Review,” May 2017, p. 62.
111 A
monopile foundation is a single large-diameter steel or concrete tube driven into the seafloor. The weight figure is for the Veja Mate offshore wind farm,
with 6-MW turbines, located in the North Sea. See Vicente Negro et al., “Monopiles in Offshore Wind: Preliminary Estimate of Main Dimensions,” Ocean
Engineering 133 (March 2017): 253–61.
112  omas Kellner, “The X Factor: Here’s What It Takes to Build the Tower for the World’s Most Powerful Offshore Wind Turbine,” GE Reports, May 25,
T
2018.
113  orld Steel Organization, “Fact Sheet: Steel and Raw materials,” February 2019. In 2017, about 70% of all steel was manufactured this way, while
W
the remaining 30% was made in electric arc furnaces from recycled steel. An electric arc furnace requires about 0.15 tons of coal per ton of steel
manufactured.
114  icente Negro et al., “Gravity-Based Foundations in the Offshore Wind Sector,” Journal of Marine Science and Engineering 7, no. 3 (March 2019):
V
64–77.
115 See Matt Ridley, “More Gas, Less Wind,” The Spectator, May 13, 2017.
116  evitan and Associates, “Evaluation and Comparison of US Wind and Skipjack Proposed Offshore Wind Project Applications,” revised version, Mar. 17,
L
2017.
117 Ibid., p. ES-39, table 6. In its order approving PPAs for the two projects, the Maryland Public Service Commission rejected these estimates. In the
Matter of the Applications of U.S. Wind, Inc. and Skipjack Offshore Energy, LLC for a Proposed Offshore Project(s) Pursuant to the Maryland Offshore
Wind Energy Act of 2013, Case No. 9431, Order No. 88192, May 11, 2017, pp. 63–70.
118  evitan and Associates, “Evaluation and Comparison,” pp. 159–60. As discussed in n. 117, the Maryland Public Service Commission rejected the
L
Levitan analysis because it questioned the market response (i.e., less onshore wind in lieu of more offshore wind).
119 Ibid.
120 U.S. EIA, Monthly Energy Review, May 2020, table 11.1.
121 See Jonathan Lesser, “Is There a Future for Nuclear Power in the United States?” Manhattan Institute, July 2019.

29
August 2020

S-ar putea să vă placă și