Sunteți pe pagina 1din 23

Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants

By GEORGEJ. BORJAS*

Thispaper analyzesthe way in whichthe earningsof the immigrantpopulation


may be expectedto differfrom the earningsof the nativepopulationbecauseof
the endogeneityof the decisionto migrate. The empiricalstudy shows that
differencesin the U.S. earningsof immigrantswiththesamemeasuredskills,but
from differenthome countries,are attributableto variationsin political and
economicconditionsin the countriesof originat the timeof migration.

Immigrantsin the United States do not unobservedcharacteristicsof the migrants:


make up a randomsampleof the population Immigrantsare a self-selectedgroupand, as
from the countriesof origin.This is perhaps a result,immigrantsmay be "moreable and
the most convincingfindingin the literature more highly motivated"(Chiswick,p. 900)
that analyzeshow immigrantsperformin the than the nativeborn.
U.S. labor market.In the "first-generation" Recently, the focus has shifted from
studies of this literature(Barry Chiswick, analyses of single cross-sectiondata sets to
1978; GeoffreyCarliner,1980; GregoryDe- studies of cohort or longitudinaldata (see
Freitas, 1980), cross-sectionearnings func- my 1985 and 1987 papers;and Guillermina
tions were estimated and two conclusions Jasso and Mark Rosenzweig,1985, 1986).
were reached: 1) the age-earningsprofileof The departurepoint for these studiesis the
immigrantsis steeperthan the age-earnings well-knownfact that the analysisof a single
profile of the native population with the cross section of data cannotseparatelyiden-
same measuredskills; and 2) the age-earn- tify aging and cohorteffects.'The cross-sec-
ings profile of immigrantscrosses the age- tion finding that immigrantearnings and
earnings profile of natives about ten to fif- years since migration are positively corre-
teen years after immigration.Thus, after a lated can be explainedeitherin termsof an
relativelyshort adaptationperiod,immigrant aging effect (i.e., assimilation)or it may be
earnings "overtake"the earnings of com- due to cohort differencesin quality(caused
parable native workers.The first of these by nonrandomreturnmigrationpropensities
findingswas often explainedin termsof the and/or secular shifts in the skill mix of
human capital framework:Immigrantspre- immigrantsadmittedto the United States).
sumablyhave strongerinvestmentincentives These recent studies, in effect, bring to the
than native workers,and hence immigrant forefrontthe questionof how cohortquality
earnings grow at a faster rate than native and immigrantself-selectionare related.For
earnings. The existence of the overtaking example, are immigrantsselected from the
age, however,was explainedin termsof the upper or lower tail of the ability(or income)
distributionin the sendingcountries?Evenif
immigrantsare drawnfromthe uppertail of
the income distributionin the home country,
*Departmentof Economics,Universityof California, does that ensure that they end up in the
Santa Barbara,CA 93106, and National Bureauof upper tail of the U.S. income distribution?
Economic Research. I am grateful to Gary Becker, Finally, if cohort qualityhas experienceda
Stephen Bronars, Richard Freeman, Daniel Hamer-
mesh, James Heckman, Larry Kenny, and Sherwin seculardecline in the postwarperiod(as my
Rosen for commentson earlierdraftsof this paper.The
researchwas fundedby a grantfromthe FordFounda-
tion to the NBER, and by the NationalScienceFoun-
dation (GrantNo. SES-8604973). The data sets used in 'For a recent discussionof this identificationprob-
this paperare availableon requestfromthe author. lem, see JamesHeckmanand RichardRobb (1983).
531

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
532 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

1985 analysis suggests),what factorsare re- origin, while country 1 denotes the United
sponsible for this change in the selection States or the countryof destination.3Resi-
mechanismdeterminingimmigration? dents of the home country have earnings
This paper presentsa theoreticaland em- which are distributedas
pirical study of these questions. It is as-
sumed that individualscomparethe poten- (1) wo= o+Eo,
tial incomes in the United States with the
incomes in the home countries,and make where 6 N(O,aj). The earningsfacingthis
the migration decision based on these in- population if they were to migrate to the
come differentials(net of mobility costs). UrtitedStates are givenby
The use of this standardmodel allows a
systematicanalysis of the types of selection (2) Inw = y1 + El
biases that are createdby this behavior.2It
will be seen that the common assumption where e -N(O, a 2), and Eo and ?i have
that immigrantsare drawn from the upper correlationcoefficientp.
tail of the "home" income distributionre- Equations (1) and (2) describethe earn-
quires a set of conditions that will not be ings distributionsfacing a given individual
generally satisfied. More importantly,this that is contemplating emigration to the
type of model suggestsa few key variables United States.This framework,due to A. D.
(namely, the characteristicsof the relevant Roy, can be interpretedas decomposingin-
income distributions) that "predict" the dividual earningsinto a part due to observ-
types of selection biases createdby income- able socioeconomicvariables(,LOand It ),
maximizingbehavioron the partof potential and a part due to unobservedcharacteristics
migrants. (6o and el). The Roy model focuses on the
The empiricalworkpresentedin this paper impact of selection biases on the dis-
analyzes the U.S. earnings of immigrants turbancesE0 and e1.Initially,therefore,vari-
from forty-onecountriesusing the 1970 and ations in socioeconomic variables (which
1980 censuses. Not surprisingly,it is found shift ,u and ,il) are ignored,but their role
that the variance in (relative) immigrant will be discussedbelow.4
earningsacrossthesecountriesis substantial. The parameter,ul is the meanincomethat
Using the theoreticalinsights,however,the residentsfrom the home countrywouldearn
analysis shows that the variancein various in the United States if all home country
measuresof the "quality"of immigrantscan citizenswere to migrateto the United States.
be explained to a large extent by a few key In general,this level of income need not be
variables describingeconomic and political the same as that of the U.S. native popula-
conditionsin the countriesof origin. tion since the averageskillsof the two popu-
lations-even in the absence of selection
I. TheoreticalFramework

Suppose there are two countries:country


0 and country1. For concreteness,country0 3Two importantproblemsare ignoredby the two-
denotes the home countryor the countryof country setup. First, it is likely that potentialmovers
from any countryj will have more than one possible
country of destination, Second, the probabilitythat
U.S. native-bornpersons emigrateto other countries
may not be negligible.Thesepossibilitiesare ignoredin
2The model is formallyidenticalto thatpresentedin order to focus on the essentialaspectsof the selection
A. D. Roy's (1951) studyof the impactof self-selection problem.
in occupationalchoice on the incomedistribution.The 4The Roy model has been recentlyused by Robert
wealth-maximization hypothesisis also the cornerstone Willisand SherwinRosen(1979)to analyzethe typesof
of the humancapital model by LarrySjaastad(1962). selectionbiases createdby the collegeattendancedeci-
However, both Sjaastad'swork and the literatureit sion. Heckmanand GuilhermeSedlacek(1985)present
engenderedpay little attentionto the selectionbiases a generalizationof the Roy model and applyit to the
that are at the core of the Roy model. problemof estimatingmarketwagefunctions.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO.4 BORJAS:EARNINGSOFIMMIGRANTS 533

biases-may differ. For simplicity, in the tion decision.In particular,considerthe con-


remainder of the discussionit is assumed ditional means E(ln woII> 0) and E(ln wI
that these intercountrydifferencesin skill > 0). The first of these means gives the
(such as educationand age) have been stan- averageearningsof emigrantsin the country
dardized,and hence 1,, also gives the earn- of origin, while the latter term gives the
ings of the average native worker in the average earnings of these migrantsin the
United States.5 United States. Under the normalityassump-
The migration decision for persons in tions these conditionalmeansare givenby
country 0 is determinedby the sign of the
index function:
(5) E(In wolI> O)= l+- p-- A,
(3) I ln(wl/(wO + C)) lv

(A
(y UO ') + (el Eo), (6) E(lnwjI>O)=I1 +-(---p l A,
av aO
where C gives the level of mobility costs,
and r gives a "time-equivalent" measureof where X = O(z)/P; and 4 is the density of
the costs of emigratingto the United States the standardnormal.The variable A is in-
(i.e., w = C/wo). Assumethat azis constant versely related to the emigrationrate, and
acrossall individualsin the countryof origin. takes on a value of zero when P = 1 (James
Since migrationto the United States occurs Heckman,1979).Assumeinitiallythat P < 1
when I> 0, the emigrationrate from the so that at least part of the home country's
countryof origin is givenby population is better off by not emigrating.
Then the second termsin (5) and (6) define
(4) P =Pr[ v > - GLl- [o - r)] the kinds of selection biases generatedby
income-maximizingbehavior. Equation (5)
=1- ?D(Z), shows that the average emigrant may be
"better"or "worse"off thanthe averageper-
where v, = -o; = -(Al - Ao - )IU; son in the country of origin dependingon
and 4> is the standardnormal distribution p < ao/a,. Similarly,equation(6) showsthat
function. the averageimmigrantin the United States
Equation (4) neatly summarizesthe eco- may have higheror lower earningsthan the
nomic content of the theory of migration averagenativepersondependingon a,/oO <
proposedby LarrySjaastad.If follows from p. Let QObe the incomedifferentialbetween
(4) that the emigrationrate is: (a) a negative the averageemigrantand the averageperson
function of mean incomein the home coun- in country 0, Q, be the income differential
try; (b) a positive functionof mean income betweenthe averageimmigrantand the aver-
in the United States; and (c) a negative age native person in the United States, and
function of the costs of emigratingto the k = a,/oo. There are threecases that are of
United States.Thereare,however,a number interest.6
of other implicationsin the theorythat yield
importantinsightsinto the kindsof selection Case 1: Positive Selection: QO> 0 and
biases generatedby the endogenousmigra- Q1> 0. In this situationthe "best" persons
leave the country of origin and when they
get to the United States,they outperformthe
nativepopulation.A readingof the literature
5It is possible,of course,that the averagepersonin on the earningsof immigrantssuggeststhat
country0 has ethnic or racialcharacteristics which are
favoredor penalizedby the U.S. labor market.Hence
the mean income of (equallyskilled)nativesmay not
equal tL. This possibilityis ignoredin the discussion
that follows, but it can be easily incorporatedinto the 6A fourthcase where QO> 0 and Q1< 0 is theoreti-
model. cally impossiblesince it requiresp > 1.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
534 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW SEPTEMBER1987

this positive selectionis most often assumed These three cases summarizethe quality
in the interpretationof those empiricalre- differentialsbetweenmigrantsand the native
sults. Inspection of equations (5) and (6), base in each of the two countries.It seems
however,shows that the necessary(and suffi- plausible to argue that for non-Communist
cient) conditions for positive selection to countries,p is likely to be positiveand large.
occur are After all, profit-maximizingemployers are
likely to value the samefactorsin any market
(7) p > min(1/k, k) and k > 1. economy. The quality of immigrantsin the
United States then depends entirely on the
Thus if p is sufficientlyhigh and, if income ratio of variancesin the incomedistributions
is more dispersedin the United States than of the United States and the country of
in the country of origin, the immigrants origin. Suppose, for example,that a0 > a2.
arriving in the United States are indeed The United States, in a sense, "insures"
selected from the upper tail of the home low-incomeworkersagainstpoor labormar-
country's income distributionand will out- ket outcomes while "taxing" high-income
performthe nativeborn. workers (relative to the country of origin).
This opportunity set implies that low-
Case 2: Negative Selection: QO< 0 and income workers have much greater incen-
Q1< 0. In this type of selectionthe United tives to migrate than high-incomeworkers,
States draws persons from the lower tail of and thus leads to immigrantsbeing nega-
the home country'sincome distributionand tively selected from the population. Con-
these immigrantsdo not performwell in the versely, if a2 > a2, the home country now
U.S. labor market.The necessary(and suffi- protectslow-incomeworkersfrompoorlabor
cient) conditions for negative selection to marketoutcomes and taxes the high-income
occur are worker. This opportunity set generates a
"brain drain"into the United States.Avail-
(8) p>min(1/k,k) and k<1. able data on the distributionof income
(World Bank, 1986, pp. 226-27) suggests
Negative selection again requiresthat p be that income is more unequallydistributedin
"sufficiently"positive but that the income the large number of ThirdWorld countries
distribution be more unequal in the home (for example,Mexico,India,etc.)whichform
countrythat in the United States.7 the bulk of currentimmigrationto the United
States.8 Income-maximizing behavior is
Case 3: RefugeeSorting:QO< 0 and Q1> 0. inconsistentwith the traditionalassumption
The United States drawsbelow-averageim- that the United States draws the "best"
migrants(in termsof the countryof origin), workersfrom a givencountryand that those
but they outperformthe U.S. native born workerswill (eventually)outperformthe U.S.
upon arrival.The necessary(and sufficient) native born.
condition for this to occuris On the other hand, p need not alwaysbe
positive and strong.It is likely, in fact, that
(9) p<min(l/k,k). p is negativefor countriesthat have recently
experienced a Communist takeover. The
change from a marketeconomy to a Com-
munist system is often accompanied by
7The generalizationof the model to allow for vari-
able mobilitycosts (q,) showsthat the necessarycondi-
tions for negative(positive)selectionremainunchanged
as long as mobilitycosts and earningsdo not have an 8It must be noted, however, that these data on
"excessive"negative(positive)correlation.In addition, income inequality do not correspondexactly to the
the impact of variablemobilitycosts on the resultsof variancesthat are the primitiveparametersof the Roy
the analysisis negligibleif thevariancein mobilitycosts model. In particular,q,2 and a2 describethe dispersion
is small relativeto the variancein the incomedistribu- in "opportunities"(for a given socioeconomicchar-
tions. acteristics).

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS:EARNINGSOFIMMIGRANTS 535

structuralshifts in the income distribution of-immigrantsequationgivenby


and, in particular,the confiscationof the
financial holdings of entrepreneurs.Im- (10) Q1=Q1(ji1- i0- x,a1,P)
migrants from such systems will be in the
lower tail of the "revolutionary"incomedis- To determinethe restrictionsimpliedby the
tribution but will outperformthe average behavioral assumption of income maximi-
U.S. native worker.This result signals the zation it is instructiveto recallthat Q1= yX,
movementof personswho cannotmatchwith where y = (Oaj1q,)(k - p). The parameter
the new political structure,but who "seek y does not depend on the size of the flow,
refuge" and match quite well in a market while X does. The impactof any variablea
economy. on the quality of immigrantsin the United
These insights are developed under the States is given by
assumption that selection biases do exist
(i.e., P< 1 and X>O).Sincefor mostcountries _Q_ ay ax
in Latin Americaand Asia the meanlevel of (11) dQ A +y_
da da da
the U.S. income distributiongreatlyexceeds
the mean level of the homecountry'sincome The first term in (11) holds the size of the
distribution,it is unclearwhy-in the con- flow constant and will be called the "com-
text of an income-maximizingmodel-the position"effect.It measureshow a changein
entire population of country 0 does not the abilitymix of a constant-sizedimmigrant
emigrateto the United States. pool affectstheirquality(relativeto the U.S.
There are two reasons why we do not native population).The second term in (11)
observewholesalemigrationsof entirepopu- will be called the "scale"effectand captures
lations to the United States. First, it is not what happens to the quality of U.S. im-
the differencesin mean income levels that migrants as the size of the flow is changed
determine the extent of migration,but the for any given "mix"(i.e., for constant y).
differences in mean income levels net of Consider what happens to immigrant
migration costs. These migrationcosts will quality as the mean of the home country's
be both monetaryand psychic,and arelikely income distribution increases. It can be
to be large in countriesthat have different shown that
cultural and social backgroundsthan the
United States. Second, there are statutory
restrictions on the number of legal im- (12) da021= 0 (k -p) dy
migrantsthe United Stateswill accept from
any given country. These quotas play the Shifts in po lead only to a scaleeffecton Q1.
importantrole of increasingmigrationcosts In addition,it is easy to show that aX/az>
of emigrants(if the numericalconstraintsare 0.9 As discussed earlier, the sign of k - p
binding), since these individualswill pre- determines whether immigrantsfall in the
sumably have to compete (and invest time upperor lower tail of the U.S. incomedistri-
and effort) to obtain the relatively scarce bution. Equation(12) shows that k - p also
visas. Hence mobilitycosts ensurethat only determineswhat happensto the (U.S.) earn-
some personsin country0 findit worthwhile ings of immigrantsas mean income in the
to emigrateand therebycreatethe selection home countryincreases.If k - p is negative
biases that are apparentin immigrationdata. (immigrantsare comingfromcountrieswith
The model outlinedabove can be used to significantlymore unequalincome distribu-
infer how the quality of immigrantsin the tions and p is "sufficiently" positive),
United States will differin the cross section aQ1/dMO < 0. The intuition for this result
(across differentcountriesof origin)or over
time (as economicconditionsin the country
of origin and in the United States change). 9This followstriviallyfromthe fact that X is defined
The income-maximizationhypothesis im- as E(xlx > z), where x is a standardnormalrandom
plies the existenceof a reduced-formquality- variable.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
536 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW SEPTEMBER1987

follows from the fact that as Itoincreasesthe The change in the quality of immigrants
emigration rate falls. The increase in A0 due to a mean-preservingincrease in the
improvesthe position of the "marginal"im- income inequality of the home country is
migrant so that he no longer migrates.But given by
this marginalimmigrantwas more produc-
tive than the average immigrant.The in- dQ1 a2a
crease in ,u , therefore, leads to a reduction (13) 2 3 2-)X
in theaveragequalityof theimmigrantpopula-
tion. Since the mean of the home coun- a2 ax
try's income distributionand mobilitycosts (k - p)(1 - pk) -z,
31?0
play identical roles in the model, equation
(12) also predicts that increasesin mobil-
ity costs will decrease immigrant quality where the first term gives the composition
if k-p<O. effect and the second term gives the scale
It is importantto note that this resultonly effect. Since I?<1, the compositioneffect
captures the impact of changes in ,uo (or will alwaysbe nonpositive.An increasein a0
migration costs) on the extent of selection reduces the income of the poorest while it
bias (Q1). The increasein ,.o, however,can improvesthe position of the richest.Hence
be induced by either a shift in the skill the mix of immigrantswill include more
distributionof the countryof origin'spopu- persons from the lower tail of the distribu-
lation, or by an increase in the country's tion.
wealth that is unrelatedto skills (for exam- In addition, a change in a0 changes the
ple, the discovery of a large inventory of rate of emigration.Equation(13) showsthat
naturalresources).If p0 shiftsbecauseof the the sign of the scale effect depends on the
latter factor, equation(12) correctlypredicts sign of three terms: (k - p), (1 - pk), and z.
the change in observedimmigrantearnings The first two of these termsare nothingbut
(which are given by j,u + Q1). However, the restrictionsin equations(7) and (8). Sup-
if tLo shifts due to an increasein the skill pose, for concreteness,that thereis negative
level of the population,the changein immi- selection: the least-able persons leave the
grant earningswill also dependon the term home country and they performbelow the
d,il/d1io. This derivativewill be positive if U.S. native average.This implies k - p < 0
skills are transferableacross countries,and and 1- pk> 0. Inspection of (13) reveals
this skill shift may dominate any changes that the directionof the scale effectdepends
that occur in Q1as ,u increases.Hence the on the sign of z=-(p1- u0-7T)/av. If
(relative) earnings of immigrants in the y > /o + 'r, so that mean U.S. incomes are
United States may well be a positive func- higher than foreign incomes even after ad-
tion of 40 regardlessof the sign of equation justing for mobilitycosts, z is negative,the
(12).10 scale effect is negative,and thus immigrants
from countrieswith more incomeinequality
will performworsein the United States.
10This discussionillustrateshow differencesin skill The intuitionfor the workingsof the scale
characteristicscan enter the Roy model. More gener-
ally, the earningsdistributionsin the two countriescan effect can be graspedby consideringFigure
be writtenas 1, whichis drawnwith z < 0 and a1< ao. As
lnw1=X81+El,
a0 increases,the worst-offpersonsin coun-
lnwo=X80+eo,
try 0 will still want to migrate,while the
X) is
and the emigrationrate (for givencharacteristics better-off persons become relativelybetter
givenby
p = Pr( (F - Eo) > - s) ]
[ X(81

Selectionwill occurnot only on the basisof unobserved


characteristics(?), but also in terms of the socioeco- below (by holding X constant)focuseson the selections
nomic variables X as long as the two countriesvalue in e, it wouldbe veryinterestingto also investigatethe
these skills differently.Althoughthe empiricalanalysis types of selectionsgeneratedin X.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS: EARNINGS OF IMMIGRANTS 537

correlationcoefficienton the quality of im-


migrantsis seen to be positive.
A summaryof the comparativestatics re-
sults under the variousregimesis provided
in Table 1. One implicationis immediately
clear: generalizationsabout the quality of
immigrantsin the United Statesare hard to
come by. The model does, however,isolate
the key factors that determinethe types of
selections in the immigrantpopulationand
these factors shed some light on my 1985
finding that the quality of immigrantsde-
clined in the postwar period. Prior to the
1965 Amendmentsto the Immigrationand
FIGURE 1
Nationality Act, immigrationto the United
States from Eastern Hemispherecountries
off and their migrationincentives decline. was regulated by numericalquotas. These
The emigration rate drops due to the quotas were based on the ethnic population
withdrawalof the "best"potentialmigrants of the United States in 1919 and thus en-
from the market,and thus the qualityof the couragedimmigrationfrom (some) Western
pool that does reach the United States de- European countries and discouraged im-
clines. migration from all other countries. The
The last characteristicof the home coun- favored countrieshave one importantchar-
try's income distributionwhich determines acteristic: their income distributions are
the quality of immigrantsis p. It can be probablymuch less dispersedthan those of
shown that countries in Latin America or Asia. The
1965 Amendmentsrevampedthe quota sys-
3Q1 31 tem, establisheda 20,000numericallimit for
(14) - (1- pk)X immigrationfrom any single country (sub-
dp UV ject to both hemispheric and worldwide
numerical limits), and led to a substantial
increase in the numberof immigrantsfrom
+ 3 (k-p)_ Z. Asia and Latin America.The new flow of
migrantsoriginatein countriesthat aremuch
more likely to have greater income in-
Changesin the correlationcoefficientalso in- equalitythan the United States.It wouldnot
duce two effects. Considerfirstthe composi- be surprising, therefore,if the quality of
tion effect. Its sign depends on -(1 - pk), immigrantsdeclined as a result of the 1965
which is negative if there is negative selec- Amendments."1
tion. An increasein p implies that a better
match exists between performancein the II. Empirical
Framework
United Statesand in the homecountry.Since
a0 > al this decreases the profitabilityof The quality measure Q1 derived in the
migrationfor the best personsin country0 previous section is the standardizedwage
and increasesit for the worstpersons. differentialbetween immigrantsand natives
In addition, changesin p have an impact
on the emigrationrate,and the scaleeffectis
given by the last term in (14). If the condi-
tions for negative selection hold, k - p < 0 "1Inaddition,the 1965Act changedthe emphasisin
the allocationof visas towardfamilyreunificationand
and the sign of the scale effect will depend awayfromoccupationalpreferences. Thisshiftmaywell
on the sign of - z. If, as before,we assume lead to an even steeperdecline in the qualityof im-
z < 0, the scale effect of an increasein the migrantsadmittedto the United States.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
538 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

STATICSRESULTS
TABLE 1-SUMMARY OF COMPARATIVE

Positive Negative Refugee


Selection Selection Sorting
Qo>?,Q1>O Q<O,Q1 <O Q<O,Q1 >O
Q,l/d,o: Composition Effect none none none
Scale Effect + - +
aQ, /a a0: Composition Effect - -
Scale Effect, z<O - - +
z>O + +
dQl/dp: Composition Effect +
Scale Effect, z<O - +
z>O + - +

in the United States. In any given cross Of course,in a singlecrosssectionof data,


section, this wage differentialis affectedby equation (15) cannot be estimatedsince the
two factors: 1) differencesin the skill com- variablesCi and yi are relatedby the iden-
position of the various immigrantcohorts; tity T Ci+ yi. Substitutingthis identityin
and 2) the rate of convergencebetweenfor- (15) yields
eign- and native-bornearnings(i.e., the rate
of assimilationof immigrants).An empirical (16) lnwi(T) = XOT?+ (a + #hT+f32T )Ii
frameworkfor measuringthese effects thus
begins with the specification of the re-
gressionmodel: + (a1 -2 -2f2T)Iiyi

(15) ln wi(T) = XiOT+ SIi + ajIjyj + a2IiY7 + Vi.


+ ((X2 + #2),iYi2

+ flIiCi +
42P C7 + Vi,
Equation (16) shows that the typical cross-
where wi(T) is the wage rate of individuali section earnings function estimatedin the
in cross-sectionyear T; Xi is a vector of immigrationliteraturedoes not identify a
socioeconomiccharacteristics;Ii is a dummy single parameterof interest."3It is easy to
variableset to unity if the individualis for- show, however,that if anothercross section
eign born; yi representsthe numberof years is available in calendar year T' all the
the immigrant has resided in the United parametersin (15) can be identified.14More-
States; and C, is the calendaryear of the over, the comparisonof the two cross-sec-
immigrant'sarrival.The parametersa, and tion regressionsprovidesinterestinginsights
a2 capturethe impactof assimilationon the about the extent and direction of cohort-
(relative) earnings of immigrants,while , quality differentials. Let Y1= 8 + P1T +
and 2 capturethe cohortdifferentials.12 /32T2, Y2=al-1, - 2f2T, and Y3= a2 + 2
be the coefficientsof the immigrationvari-
ables in the cross sectionat calendaryear T.
12The parameters fIBand /2 capture two kinds of
cohort effects: 1) differences in the skill composition of
cohorts due to a secular trend in the quality of im-
migrants; and 2) differences due to selective emigration 13Except perhaps for the coefficient of the immigrant
of foreign-born persons in the United States. Little is dummy. This coefficient gives the wage differential be-
known, however, about the selection biases associated tween the most recent cohort of immigrants and the
with return migration even though the Roy model can native-born population.
14 Provided that period effects on the immigrant-
be generalized to account for the possibility that indi-
viduals make "mistakes." Unfortunately, U.S. data on native wage differential are negligible. This assumption
the return migration of foreign-born persons is basically is far from innocuous. Unfortunately, since only two
nonexistent, and hence this problem is ignored in what cross sections are available, little can be done to test its
follows. validity.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS:EARNINGSOFIMMIGRANTS 539

This vectorwill shift overtime since 1) The predicted wage differentialin


1979 between the most recentlyarrivedim-
(17) dyl/d T =
f1 + 22T migrant cohort and the native base. This
measureof the qualityof a single cohort of
(18) ay2/aT= -232 immigrants-prior to assimilation taking
place-is given by the coefficientof the im-
(19) ay3/dT= O migrant dummy variablein the 1980 cross
section.
The immigration vector in cross-section 2) The rate of wage growth(relativeto
earningsfunctions(exceptfor the coefficient natives) for an immigrantcohort that has
of I_y2) is inherentlyunstable,though the resided in the United States for ten years.
direction of the instabilityprovidesinsights This is the assimilationeffect evaluatedat
into the underlyingstructuralchanges.For y = 10, and is givenbya ln w/dyjY=IO = a1+
instance, Y1(the coefficientof the immigrant 20a2.
dummy) will be shiftingdown over time if 3) The predictedwage differentialim-
the qualityof immigrantsis decreasingat the mediately after immigrationbetween the
"margin"(i.e., in the cross-sectionyear T). 1979 cohort and the 1955 cohort.This mea-
In addition, the age-earningsprofile of im- sure of the extent of cohort-qualitychangeis
migrants(relativeto natives)becomessteeper designed to comparethe typical immigrant
over time (i.e., Y2increases)if the declinein that migratedpriorto the 1965 Immigration
the quality of immigrantcohorts has accel- and Nationality Act with the typical im-
erated over the sampleperiod. migrant from the most recent wave. Using
The empiricalanalysesbelowuses the 1970 equation (15) it is easy to show that this
and 1980 census cross sections to identify changein cohortqualityis givenby 24 (PI1+
the parametersof interest(3, a,, a2, 1, and 2/32T- 2432 ), where T indexes the 1980 cross
12). From these estimatesit is possible to section.
calculate measures of three alternativedi-
mensions of cohort qualitythat underliethe III. RegressionResultsfrom
discussion. The first of these dimensionsis the 1970-1980Censuses
simply the wage of an immigrantcohort
relativeto the nativebase priorto any assim- The data are drawn from the 1970 2/100
ilation takingplace; that is, a measureof the U.S. Census (obtained by pooling the 5%
"raw"skills a givenimmigrantcohortbrings SMSA and County Group Sampleand the
to the United States.A seconddimensionis 5% State Sample) and the 1980 5/100 A
given by the extent to which the qualityof Sample.15The completesamplesare used in
successive immigrant cohorts is changing the creation of the immigrantextracts,but
over time, while a third dimensionis given random samples are drawn for the native
by the extent to which the earnings of a "baseline"population.'6The analysisis re-
specific immigrantcohort grow-above and stricted to men aged 25-64 who satisfied
beyond pure agingeffects-in the U.S. labor four sample-selectionrules:1) the individual
market. Clearly, there are many ways of was employed in the calendaryear prior to
defining variables that capture these three
facets of the "quality"of immigrants.How-
ever, since all possible definitionsof a par-
15The two 1970 samplesthat are pooled are essen-
ticulardimensionof qualityarebasedon the tially independentof each other.The only substantive
same underlyingparameters,there is a high differencebetween them-in the contextof this study
degree of correlationamong the alternative -is that the set of personsfor whomSMSAresidence
measures.Thus, to some extent, the choice is defined differs in the two samples. However,the
of the empirical representationof a given coefficientsof the SMSAdummyin earningsfunctions
estimatedseparatelyin the two samplesarenot statisti-
facet of quality is arbitrary.In the empirical cally differentfrom eachother.
analysisbelow, the threedimensionsof qual- 16The native-bornextractis a .001 sample in the
ity are definedby 1970 censusand a .00042samplein the 1980census.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
540 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW SEPTEMBER1987

the census; 2) the individualwas not self- it is more instructiveif it is convertedinto a


employed or working without pay; 3) the percentageof the country of origin's 1980
individualwas not in the ArmedForces (as population.This statisticis presentedin the
of the survey week); and 4) the individual second column and gives the percentageby
did not residein groupquarters.'7 which the country of origin's population
Since labor market conditions changed would increase (in 1980) if all the persons
substantially between 1970 and 1980, the who emigratedto the United States in the
empiricalframeworkderivedin the previous past three decades returnedto their birth-
section focused on the behavior of im- place. This percentrangesfrom the trivially
migrantearningsrelativeto the earningsof small (.04 percent of Braziland the USSR)
natives. In this paper all immigrantgroups to the amazinglylarge (over 10 percentfor
will be compared to a single native base: Jamaica).Of the 41 countriesin Table 2, 17
the groupof white,non-Hispanic,non-Asian of themexperiencedemigrationto the United
men. States which exceeded 1 percent of that
Forty-onecountrieswerechosen for anal- country'spopulation.
ysis. The countrieswereselectedon the basis The national compositionof the flows re-
that both the 1970 and 1980 censusescon- ceived by the United Statesoverthe 1951-80
tained a substantialnumberof immigrants period did not remain constant over the
from the country. In particular,it is neces- three decades. The third column gives the
sary to have at least 80 observationsof per- flow of immigrantsin the 1951-60 decadeas
sons born in a particularforeigncountryin a percent of the country's1950 population;
the pooled 2/100 1970 Census to enter the while the fourthcolumnpresentsthe flow of
sample of the 41 countries.'8The 41 coun- immigrantsin 1971-80 as a percentof the
tries under analysisaccountfor 90.4 percent country's 1970 population.These statistics
of all immigrationto the United States be- documentthe decliningimportanceof West-
tween 1951 and 1980. ern Europeancountriesas a source of im-
Summarystatisticson the immigrantflow migrants and the increasingimportanceof
in the 1951-80 periodarepresentedin Table Asia and Latin America.The fact that the
2. The firstcolumnof Table2 gives the total characteristics of the sending countries
number of immigrantsfrom each country changed drastically during the postwar
that arrived in the United States in that period implies that the types of selections
period. Although this numberis interesting, that distinguish the immigrantpopulation
from the native born also changed.
The 1970 and 1980 cross-sectionregres-
sions werejointly estimatedin each of the 41
samples(i.e., the groupof immigrantsfroma
"7Theanalysis is restrictedto men aged 25-64 in specific country of origin pooled with the
either censusyear. This differsfromthe morecommon
methodologyof trackingthe "same"men over time. It "white" native base), using the (In) wage
can be shown(HeckmanandRobb)thatif the underly- rate in the year preceding the census as
ing parametersare constantovertime,it is unnecessary the dependent variable.The socioeconomic
to track specific cohorts across censusesin order to vector of characteristicsX included:years
identify the structure.In addition,the samplesexclude
men who are self-employed.This restrictioncreatesits of completed schooling, age, age squared,
own set of selectionbiases.However,an equallyserious whether healthlimitswork,whethermarried,
problem would arise if self-employedmen were in- spouse present, and whetherresidentof an
cluded in the study and their incomeswere analyzed SMSA. The regressionframeworkderived
jointly with the wagesof salariedmen.Finally,the data in Section II implies that the coefficientof
exclude men who had annualearningsunder$1,000in
eitherof the censusyears. the quadraticyears-since-migration variable
18Only two of the countriesin the analysis have should be constant acrosscensuses.This re-
between 80 to 100 observationsin the 1970 census,an strictionwas satisfied(at the 5 percentlevel
additional11 countrieshave between101 and 200 ob- of significance)by 32 of the 41 countriesin
servations,8 have between201 and 300 observations,
and 20 have more than300 observations.Of course,the the data, and hence was imposed on the
sample sizes in the 1980 censusare significantlylarger. analysis.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS:EARNINGSOFIMMIGRANTS 541

IN THE1951-80 PERIOD
FLOWSTOTHEUNITEDSTATES
TABLE2-IMMIGRATION

1951-60 1971-80
1951-80 Immigration Immigrants Immigrants
Total Number As Percent of as Percent of as Percent of
Country of Birth (in 1000s) 1980 Populationa 1950 Populationa 1970 Populationa

Europe:
Austria 48.1 .6 .4 .1
Czechoslovakia 60.4 .4 .2 .1
Denmark 30.0 .6 .3 .1
France 90.1 .2 .1 .04
Germany 611.5 1.0 .7 .1
Greece 232.3 2.4 .6 1.1
Hungary 93.4 .9 .7 .1
Ireland 120.9 3.5 2.2 .5
Italy 524.8 .9 .4 .2
Netherlands 85.7 .6 .5 .1
Norway 45.1 1.1 .8 .1
Poland 244.9 .7 .5 .1
Portugal 204.2 2.1 .2 1.2
Romania 49.8 .2 .1 .1
Spain 71.2 .2 .04 .1
Sweden 41.9 .5 .3 .1
Switzerland 40.1 .6 .4 .1
United Kingdom 562.9 1.0 .4 .2
USSR 105.4 .04 .02 .02
Yugoslavia 147.0 .7 .4 .2
Asia and Africa:
China(Taiwan) 331.9 1.9 .4 1.4
Egypt 46.4 .1 .02 .1
India 211.1 .03 .001 .03
Iran 59.1 .2 .01 .2
Israel 48.1 1.3 .7 .9
Japan 131.1 .1 .05 .05
Korea 314.8 .8 .02 .8
Philippines 478.9 .9 .1 1.0
Americas:
Argentina 81.5 .3 .1 .3
Brazil 43.1 .04 .02 .01
Canada 676.4 2.8 2.0 .5
Colombia 165.5 .6 .4 .6
Cuba 611.9 6.3 1.5 3.2
DominicanRepublic 251.9 4.3 .5 3.4
Ecuador 96.7 1.2 .3 .8
Guatemala 45.1 .7 .1 .5
Haiti 100.2 1.8 .1 1.3
Jamaica 221.7 10.3 .6 7.3
Mexico 1399.8 2.0 1.2 1.3
Panama 50.8 2.6 1.2 1.5
Trinidad&Tobago 88.0 8.0 .2 6.0
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census (various issues).
aThe populationbase refersto the countryof origin.

The restrictedcoefficientsof the inmmigra- variables in 1980. This differenceimplies


tion vectorin both the 1970 and 1980census that cross-sectionregressionsdo not capture
cross sections are presentedin the first five the "true" assimilationimpact since cohort
columns of Table 3. The coefficientsof the effects are confounding the analysis. Con-
immigrationvariablesin 1970 differ drasti- sider, for example, Colombia:In 1970, the
cally from the coefficientsof the immigration most recentimmigrantsearnedabout22 per-

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
542 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW SEPTEMBER1987

TABLE3-ESTIMATESOFMODELPARAMETERSa

1970 1980 Rate of 1955-79


______________
______________________2
Assimilation Change in
Countryof Birth I I Y I I-Y I-Y2 at y=10 CohortQuality

Europe:
Austria .0189 .0036 .0321 .0034 - .00003 .0040 .0287
(.26) (.75) (.52) (.82) (-.45) (.66) (.20)
Czechoslovakia - .1525 .0147 - .1441 .0127 - .00019 .0088 - .0143
(-2.48) (3.34) (-2.79) (3.23) (-2.74) (1.64) (- .10)
Denmark .0838 - .0033 .2018 - .0056 .00009 .0068 .2441
(.82) (-.44) (2.14) (-.81) (.72) (.78) (1.21)
France - .0785 .0020 .0999 - .0046 .00005 .0111 .3183
(-1.28) (.47) (2.48) (-1.33) (.79) (2.05) (2.74)
Germany .0999 - .0025 .1409 - .0047 .00007 - .0002 .0618
(3.82) (-1.37) (5.40) (-2.62) (2.38) (- .10) (1.17)
Greece -.2400 .0115 - .3092 .0141 - .00018 .0049 - .1231
(-6.70) (3.73) (-11.28) (5.42) (-3.33) (1.56) (-1.75)
Hungary - .1555 .0173 - .2082 .0145 - .00021 .0036 -.1744
(- 2.98) (4.12) (-4.30) (4.23) (- 3.31) (.86) (-1.85)
Ireland - .0732 .0019 - .0514 .0027 - .00002 .0050 .0666
(-1.54) (.53) (- 1.09) (.78) (-.28) (1.26) (.72)
Italy .0133 .0060 - .0673 .0065 - .00009 - .0031 - .1855
(.60) (3.72) (-3.45) (4.58) (-3.49) (-1.55) (-4.07)
Netherlands .0127 - .0061 .1252 - .0074 .00015 .0062 .2487
(.23) (-1.45) (2.71) (-2.15) (2.35) (1.35) (2.41)
Norway .2245 - .0093 .2785 -.0096 .00015 - .0013 .1241
(2.54) (-1.55) (3.77) (-1.76) (1.58) (- .17) (.71)
Poland - .1936 .0181 - .2734 .0184 - .00024 .0058 - .1865
(-5.70) (7.62) (-11.08) (9.61) (-6.86) (1.98) (- 3.08)
Portugal .0797 .0032 - .0913 .0073 - .00012 - .0102 - .3418
(1.95) (.86) (- 3.25) (2.47) (-1.95) (-2.77) (-4.02)
Romania -.3015 .0263 - .3161 .0229 - .00030 .0136 -.0929
(-4.23) (4.97) (- 7.02) (5.47) (- 3.65) (2.17) (- .72)
Spain - .3547 .0233 - .1920 .0134 - .00022 .0203 .2245
(-6.15) (4.32) (-4.10) (2.88) (-2.39) (3.98) (1.92)
Sweden .0128 .0119 .0465 .0099 -.00021 .0080 .0465
(.13) (1.90) (.69) (1.88) (- 2.14) (.88) (.24)
Switzerland - .0201 .0132 .1467 .0067 - .00015 .0171 .2912
(-.27) (2.18) (2.48) (1.33) (-1.56) (2.56) (1.97)
United Kingdom .0607 -.0006 .1271 -.0023 .00002 .0038 .1303
(2.70) (- .34) (7.38) (-1.61) (.67) (1.84) (2.81)
USSR - .3509 .0277 -42.99 .0262 - .00035 .0105 - .2144
(- 6.70) (8.34) (-18.75) (11.70) (-7.67) (2.22) (-2.31)
Yugoslavia - .0659 .0096 - .0920 .0097 - .00009 .0054 - .0608
(-1.51) (2.72) (-2.82) (3.52) (-1.61) (1.49) (-.79)

cent less than the native base, and their Colombian immigrantwaves is lower than
(relative) earnings increased by about 1.7 that of the earlier waves. Conversely,con-
percent in the first year after immigration. sider the immigrantsfrom France:In 1970,
By 1980, the most recentwave of Colombi- the typicalFrenchimmigrantearnedabout8
ans earned 40 percent less than the same percent less than a comparablenative per-
native base, and theirearningsincreasedby son, and had earningsgrowth of about .2
about 2.2 percent in the first year after im- percent duringthat firstyear after immigra-
migration. The tilting of the cross-section tion. By 1980, the most recent immigrant
profile so that latercrosssectionsare steeper earned about 10 percent more than the na-
and have a more negative constant term tive base, and had earningsgrowthof minus
implies that the quality of the more recent .5 percentduringthat firstyear.The flatten-

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS: EARNINGS OF IMMIGRANTS 543

TABLE3 -CONTINUED

Rate of 1955-79
1970 1980 Assimilation Change in
Countryof Birth I I-y I Iy Iy2 at y=10 Cohort Quality
Asia andAfrica:
China (Taiwan) -.4525 .0227 -.5327 .0254 -.00037 .0114 -.1481
(-14.34) (9.43) (-26.43) (11.66) (- 8.22) (4.01) (- 2.44)
Egypt - .4466 .0421 - .4586 .0396 - .00056 .0260 - .0706
(-7.00) (5.67) (-10.84) (7.57) (-4.34) (4.76) (- .57)
India - .2847 .0453 - .4340 .0497 - .00096 .0179 - .2845
(- 7.09) (9.71) (-21.41) (16.75) (-11.03) (5.33) (-3.84)
Iran - .4078 .0229 - .3101 .0249 - .00031 .0294 .2690
(-4.71) (3.03) (-10.19) (5.45) (- 2.47) (4.13) (1.88)
Israel - .2998 .0282 - .3397 .0260 - .00041 .0128 - .1314
(-4.19) (4.54) (-8.44) (5.74) (-3.84) (2.11) (-1.00)
Japan - .1314 .0010 .1016 - .0049 .00002 .0159 .4616
(-2.65) (.19) (4.31) (-1.46) (.18) (3.60) (4.78)
Korea - .5450 .0439 - .4481 .0393 - .00071 .0323 .1544
(- 8.69) (5.72) (-19.44) (9.68) (- 5.40) (6.31) (1.37)
Philippines - .4360 .0265 - .3881 .0266 - .00041 .0233 .1158
(-13.31) (11.30) (-23.14) (13.33) (- 9.34) (7.84) (1.80)
Americas:
Argentina - .2099 .0210 - .2427 .0186 - .00032 .0077 - .1191
(- 3.81) (3.58) (- 5.80) (4.13) (- 3.11) (1.65) (-1.12)
Brazil - .1430 .0114 - .0257 .0062 - .00015 .0123 .1941
(-1.70) (1.44) (-.45) (1.00) (- 1.11) (1.66) (1.19)
Canada .0645 .0003 .1165 - .0013 - .00000 .0030 .0988
(2.86) (.17) (6.06) (-.91) (-.21) (1.50) (2.17)
Colombia - .2247 .0169 - .4030 .0219 - .00036 - .0007 - .3444
(-4.33) (2.74) (-12.67) (5.78) (- 3.71) (-.17) (-3.82)
Cuba - .4612 .0214 - .4517 .0208 - .00025 .0164 .0129
(D- 22.20) (8.89) (-18.26) (9.24) (- 5.20) (9.74) (.28)
Dominican
Republic - .3293 .0141 - .4556 .0142 - .00018 - .0019 - .3020
(- 5.81) (2.45) (-13.91) (3.62) (-1.74) (-.44) (- 3.01)
Ecuador - .4041 .0242 - .4195 .0210 - .00026 .0127 - .0906
(- 6.06) (3.28) (- 9.77) (4.13) (-1.98) (2.58) (- .82)
Guatemala - .5127 .0408 - .4013 .0298 - .00066 .0222 .0828
(- 5.76) (5.03) (- 8.97) (5.09) (- 4.40) (2.96) (.51)
Haiti - .3356 - .0027 - .5234 .0175 - .00011 .0064 - .1130
(-4.99) (- .34) (-13.95) (3.39) (- .77) (1.20) (- .94)
Jamaica - .3322 .0165 - .2594 .0097 - .00020 .0095 .0600
(- 6.75) (4.06) (- 9.33) (2.92) (- 2.77) (2.24) (.64)
Mexico - .3307 .0191 - .4037 .0206 - .00031 .0078 - .1497
(-16.57) (14.80) (-34.72) (22.25) (-15.94) (4.16) (-3.61)
Panama - .3438 .0159 - .2516 .0115 - .00010 .0165 .1476
(- 3.52) (2.31) (- 4.35) (2.07) (- .88) (2.04) (.84)
Trinidad&
Tobago - .3091 .0187 - .3257 .0211 - .00024 .0158 .0013
(-4.02) (2.59) (-6.94) (3.70) (-1.95) (2.35) (.03)

aThe t-ratios are presented in parentheses. The cross-section regressions hold constant the individual's completed
schooling, age, marital status, health, and SMSA residence.

ing of the cross-sectionprofileimplies that entry wage differentialbetweenthe 1979 im-


the quality of Frenchimmigrantsincreased migrantcohort and the native base is given
over the sampleperiod. by the coefficientof the immigrantdummy
Three dimensions of cohort quality are in the 1980 census cross section. Table 3
implicit in these regressioncoefficients.The clearly shows that this coefficienthas a large

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
544 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

varianceacross countries.The last two col- origin.These politicalmeasuresare obtained


umns of Table 3 present estimates of the from the Cross-NationalTime-SeriesAr-
other two dimensionsof cohort quality:the chive (CNTSA),a historicaldata set contain-
assimilation rate defined by the slope of ing both politicaland economicvariablesfor
the earnings-assimilation path at y = 10; and all sovereign countries since 1815 (up to
the rate of change in cohortquality,defined 1973).'9The CNTSA set containsa variable
by the earningsdifferentialbetweenthe 1979 describingthe extent of "party legitimacy,"
cohort and the 1955 cohort at the time of that is, whetheror not there is competition
arrival in the United States. Since these among political partiesin the electoralsys-
estimated parametersare functions of the tem. The measureof party legitimacyis in-
cross-sectioncoefficientsof Table 3, it is not terpretedas an index of political freedom,
surprisingto find that thereis a lot of vari- and is used to constructtwo variables:1) a
ance in both of these variablesacrosscoun- dummy variable set equal to unity if the
tries. Immigrantsfrom some countrieshave immigrant's birthplace had a competitive
high assimilation rates, while immigrants political system during the entire 1950-73
from other countries experienceno assim- period;and 2) a dummyvariableset equalto
ilation at all. Similarly,the rate of cohort- unity if the. immigrant'sbirthplacehad a
quality change is sometimespositive (thus competitivepoliticalsystemat the beginning
indicatingqualityincreasedbetweenthe 1955 of the period, but lost its political freedom
and 1979 cohorts) and sometimesnegative by the end of the period.Theomitteddummy
(thus indicating a quality decrease across variableindicates whetherthe birthplaceof
cohorts). For example,the most recent im- the immigranthad a noncompetitivepoliti-
migrantwave from the United Kingdomhas cal system both at the beginningand at the
an earnings potential that is about 13 per- end of the 1950-73 period.20The last index
cent higher that the wave that arrivedin of political stabilityused is a variablemea-
1955, while the most recentimmigrantsfrom suringthe numberof politicalassassinations
India have 28 percent lower earningsthan (definedas a politicallymotivatedmurderor
the earliercohort. attemptedmurderof a high governmentoffi-
The Roy model suggests that country- cial or politician) that took place in the
specific characteristicsof the income distri- specificcountryduringthe 1950-73 period.
bution (and mobility costs) determinethe The country-specificvector also includes
quality of immigrantsin the United States. variablesthat describeeconomicconditions
The importanttask, therefore,becomes the in the variouscountriesof origin:
identificationof observablevariableswhich 1) The logarithmof per capita Gross
can proxy for these theoreticalparameters, National Product in 1980 (in U.S. dollars).
and the determination of whether these In addition, the analysisalso uses the aver-
country-specificvariables"explain"the vari- age annual percentagechange in that vari-
ance in the qualityproxiespresentedin Ta- able over the 1963-80 period. These vari-
ble 3. ables, of course, are designedto control for
the mean level of the incomedistribution(as
IV. Determinantsof Immigrant
Quality well as changes in that level) in the various
countriesof origin.
Table 4 describes the constructionand
source of country-specificaggregate vari-
ables which portray the political and eco-
nomic conditions (as well as some charac- 19The CNTSA was created by Arthur Banks and is
teristics of the immigrantpopulations)of available through the Inter-University Consortium for
the 41 countries under analysis during the Political and Social Research, Ann Arbor, MI 48106.
1950-79 period. Table 4 also presents the 20There is also the possibility that a country gained
mean and range of these variablesand com- its freedom during the 1950-73 period. Only one coun-
try, however, falls in this category (the Dominican
parablestatisticsfor the United States. Republic). To reduce the number of exogenous vari-
Three of these variablesare designed to ables, this country was pooled with the countries that
capturepoliticalconditionsin the countryof were "free" throughout the entire period.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS: EARNINGS OF IMMIGRANTS 545

TABLE4-DEFINITION OF COUNTRY-SPECIFICVARIABLES

Mini- Maxi-
Variable Definition and Source Mean mum mum U.S. Value

Politically Competitive = 1 if the country had a competitive party system .41 - - 1


System during the entire 1950-73 period; 0 otherwise.
Source: Cross-National Time-Series
Archive (CNTSA)
Recent Loss of Freedom = 1 if the country had a competitive party system .20 - - 0
at the beginning of the period but had a non-
competitive party system at the end of the period;
0 otherwise. Source: CNTSA.
Number of Number of politically motivated.murders or 3.27 0 22 12
Assassinations attempted murders of high government officials
or politicians in 1950-73. Source: CNTSA.
Income Inequality Ratio of household income of the top 10 percent 7.50 1.42 30.0 5.91
of the households to the income of the bottom
20 percent of the households. Source: World Bank
(various issues) and United Nations (1977).
Distance from U.S. Number of air miles (in thousands) between the 3.37 .18 7.49
country's capital and the nearest U.S. gateway
(Los Angeles, Miami, or New York).
Source: Airline offices contacted by author.
English Proficiency Fraction of 1975-80 cohort of immigrants who .74 .24 1.00
speak English well or very well. Source:
5/100 A Sample of the 1980 U.S. Census.
Age at Migration Mean age at migration. Source: 5/100 A Sample 24.56 12.40 32.40 -
of the 1980 U.S. Census.
In (per capital GNP) (In) 1980 per capita GNP in dollars. 8.17 5.42 9.62 9.39
Source:U.S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency
(1984).
Rate of Change in Annual rate of change in per capita GNP between .03 .004 .07 .02
Per Capita GNP 1963 and 1980, defined by:
ln(GNP1980/GNP1963)/17. Source: U.S. Arms
Control and Disarmament Agency
(1975, 1984).
Rate of Change in Annual Change in the Percentage of GNP that is .41 -1.69 2.08 .26
Central Government accounted for by central government expenditures,
Expenditures defined by (GOVT1980- GOVT7950)/30,where
GOVT, is the percent of GNP attributable to
central government expenditures in year t.
Source: CNTSA and U.S. Arms Control and
Disarmament Agency (1984).
Change in Quota Change in fraction of population eligible for 38.90 .28 149.67
migration to the U.S., defined by (20000/1979
population) . (QUOTA/1950 population),
where 20,000 is the maximum number of visas
allocated to the country after 1965, and QUOTA is the
number of visas allocated prior to 1965.
Source: U.S. Immigration and Naturalization
Service (1965).

2) The ratio of householdincomeaccru- hence the change in the extent of income


ing to the top 10 percentof the households inequalityduringthe last threedecadescan-
to the income accruing to the bottom 20 not be documented.The empiricalanalysis
percent of the households(circa 1970). Un- below will proxy for the change in income
fortunately, this measure of income in- inequality by using the change in the frac-
equalitydoes not exist priorto the 1970'sfor tion of GNP that can be attributedto central
most of the countries under analysis, and governmentexpendituresover that period.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
546 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

Presumably, the greater the role of the The simplest specificationin column 1
governmentthe more taxation and income shows that the variablemeasuringwhether
redistributionthat occurs,and hence the less or not the country was politicallycompeti-
unequalthe income distributionwill be. tive in the postwarperiodhas a strongposi-
3) The level of mobilitycosts is proxied tive impact on the immigrant'sentry wage.
by the number of air miles between the Immigrants from these countries have 27
country'scapital and the nearestU.S. gate- percenthigherrelativeearnings(at the time
way. of entry into the United States) than im-
Finally, the regressionsalso include vari- migrants from politically repressivecoun-
ables that describerelevantcharacteristics of tries. This basic regressionalso shows that
the immigrant population itself. The two the extent of income inequalityhas a weak
variablesin this categoryare the fractionof negative impact on the relative quality of
the most recently arrivedimmigrantswho immigrants.Immigrantsfromcountrieswith
speakEnglishwell or verywell, and the aver- more income inequalityare of lowerquality.
age age at migration.These variables are This result is consistentwith the theoretical
likely to affect the earningsof immigrantsas implications of the Roy model. As income
well as their incentivesto invest in human inequalityincreases,the migrationincentives
capital,and hencewill be importantdetermi- for personsin the uppertail of the distribu-
nants of immigrantquality. tion decline, thus loweringthe averagequal-
ity of the immigrantpopulation.
A. Determinantsof the In column 2 of Table 5, the variables
Entry Wage Differential measuringmobility costs and the age and
Englishproficiencyof immigrantsare added
In the last section a variablemeasuring to the regression.The results suggest that
the entry wage differentialbetweenthe for- persons migratingfrom countriesthat have
eign born and the native born for the im- 100 percent English proficiencyrates have
migrant cohort arrivingin 1979 was calcu- about 26 percenthigherrelativeearningsat
lated for each of the 41 countries under the time of entry than immigrantsfrom
analysis. Table 5 presents the generalized countrieswith 0 percentEnglishproficiency
least squaresregressionsof this measureof rates.22 Table 5 also shows that age at
immigrant quality on the country-specific migrationhas a significantnegativeimpact
aggregatevariables.2" on the initial relativeearningsof immigrants
in the United States. Hence persons who
migrateas youths have an easiertime in the
21The dependent variables in the "second-stage" re-
U.S. labormarketthanolderimmigrants.
gressions presented in this section are themselves esti-
mated regression coefficients (or linear combinations The third regressionin Table 5 adds the
thereof). Hence the disturbances in these regressions are level of GNP per capitato the list of exoge-
heteroscedastic. Let Yi be the true value of the depen- nous variables.Its impact is stronglyposi-
dent variable (for country i) in the second-stage regres- tive, and its inclusion increasesthe expla-
sions. The " true" model is given by y, = Z,/3 + ei, where
natory power of the regressionto over 80
E(Ei) = 0 and E(-2) a2. The variable yi is unob-
served, but 9 is estimated from the regressions in percent! A 10 percent increasein a coun-
Section III, where Yi=Y+ vi, E(v) =-, E(v?) =-a2, try's GNP increasesthe relativeearningsof
and ri and vi are assumed to be independent. The
heteroscedasticity arises because the estimated regres-
sions are given by

Yi= Zip, + (Ej - vi) = Zip ?i


+ where SSE is the error sum of squares from the OLS
where E(tti)=O and E(2)=aU,2?+2. The OLS re- second-stage regression and N - K is the number of
gression of the second stage provides an estimate of Ai, degrees of freedom. The calculated 62 is then used to
and combined with the estimates of 62 available from reestimate the second-stage regression using generalized
the first-stage regressions, the parameter a,2 can be least squares.
22 These results are consistent with the estimated
estimated by
gains to English language proficiency reported in Walter
62 = (SSE- 62)/(N- K), McManus et al. (1983).

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS: EARNINGS OF IMMIGRANTS 547

TABLE5-DETERMINANTS BETWEEN
OFTHEENTRYWAGEDIFFERENTIAL
ANDNATIVESa
COHORT
THE1979 IMMIGRANT

Country of Origin Regression


Characteristics 1 2 3 4

Intercept - .2214 .1838 - .9934 - .9469


(-3.88) (1.06) (-3.41) (-3.30)
Politically Competitive System .2743 .1306 .1101 .1264
(4.49) (2.01) (2.16) (2.39)
Recent Loss of Freedom -.0010 -.0511 -.0062 .0136
(-.01) (-.75) (-.12) (.25)
Number of Assassinations - .0072 -.0028 .0021 .0044
(-1.20) (-.54) (.51) (.92)
Income Inequality -.0084 -.0038 .0039 .0046
(-1.78) (- .89) (1.02) (1.13)
Distance from U.S. - -.0114 -.0031 .0018
(-.89) (-.31) (.09)
English Proficiency - .2596 .1980 .2030
(2.20) (2.12) (2.21)
Mean Age at Migration - -.0217 -.0149 -.0119
(-3.55) (-2.99) (2.28)
ln (per capita GNP) - - .1164 .1015
(4.57) (3.77)
Country in Asia or Africa - - - - .1145
(-1.58)
Country in North or
South America - - - -.0640
(-.73)
R2 .504 .681 .808 .826

aThe t-ratios are presented in parentheses.

immigrantsby about 1.2 percent. This ef- Table 5 shows that controllingfor varia-
fect is likely to be causedby the fact that the tions in per capita GNP acrosscountriesof
higherthe GNP in the countryof origin,the origin has a majorimpacton the coefficient
greaterthe resemblancebetween that coun- of the inequality variable:the latter turns
try's economic structureand that of the positive (and insignificant).The reason for
United States,as well as the greaterthe skills this shift lies in the veryhigh negativecorre-
of the immigrant flow. Hence immigrants lation between the two variables (r = -.6).
from those countriesperformquite well in Since high-income countries (mostly in
the U.S. labor market.The last regressionin WesternEurope)also tend to have the least
Table 6 addscontinentdummies(the omitted amount of income inequality,the impactof
continent is Europe) to control for conti- per capita GNP on initialimmigrantquality
nent-specificfixed effects. These additional is likely capturingshifts in both the mean
controlsdo not havea majorimpacton theco- and the varianceof the countryof origin's
efficientof the othervariables.23 income distribution.
The results in Table 5, therefore,are not
entirely consistent with the theoreticalpre-
23To further test the sensitivity of the results, two dictions. Note, however,that these regres-
additional variables were introduced into the regression: sions do not truly constitutea "test" of the
the percent of the country's labor force that is in theory.The Roy model shows that selection
agriculture, and the per capita school enrollment rate. biases will depend on a numberof parame-
Both of these variables were highly correlated with GNP
per capita, and in fact became insignificant once GNP
ters which are not directlymeasurable.Table
was controlled for. Their impact on the other variables 5 attempts to explain intercountry dif-
in the regression was negligible. ferences in terms of variableswhich sup-

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
548 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

TABLE6-DETERMINANTS OF THERATE OF ASSIMILATION


a

Country of Origin Regression


Characteristics 1 2 3 4

Intercept .0076 - .0240 - .0237 - .0280


(2.96) (-3.88) (-1.50) (-2.32)
Politically Competitive System -.0029 -.0068 -.0068 -.0091
(-1.06) (-2.66) (-2.60) (-4.28)
Recent Loss of Freedom .0063 .0029 .0030 .0021
(1.81) (1.21) (1.15) (1.06)
Number of Assassinations .0008 .0006 .0006 .0008
(2.68) (2.36) (2.14) (3.07)
Income Inequality -.0001 -.00002 -.00002 .0002
(- .50) (-.11) (-.10) (.90)
Distance from U.S. - .0003 .0003 -.0027
(.74) (.70) (-2.89)
English Proficiency - .0138 .0138 .0122
(3.27) (3.20) (3.70)
Mean Age at Migration - .0009 .0009 .0009
(4.28) (3.95) (4.72)
In (per capita GNP) - - -.00002 .0021
(-.01) (1.83)
Country in Asia or Africa - - - .0151
(5.11)
Country in North or
South America - - - - .0080
(-2.08)
R2 .302 .704 .704 .842

aThe t-ratios are presented in parentheses.

posedly proxy for these primitiveconcepts. their political freedomhave the highest as-
Clearlythe errorsintroducedin the creation similationrates. These resultsare consistent
of these variablesweaken the link between with the hypothesisthat the costs of return
the theoryand the empiricalwork.Neverthe- migrationfor immigrantsfrompoliticallyre-
less, it is importantto note that these few pressive countries are high, and therefore
country-specificvariables"explain"a large they have the most incentivesto adaptto the
fraction of the intercountrydifferencesevi- U.S. labor market.The same reasoningcan
dent in census data. also explainthe strongpositiveimpactof the
numberof assassinationson the rate of im-
B. Determinants of the Rate of Assimilation migrantassimilation:immigrantsfrompolit-
ically unstablecountrieshave greaterincen-
The assimilationrateis definedby the rate tives to assimilatein the U.S. labor market
of earningsgrowth of an immigrantcohort since theirreturnmigrationmay be costly.
(relative to natives) evaluatedat ten years The regressionin column 2 shows that
after immigration.Table 6 presentsthe re- althoughdistancebetweenthe United States
gressions of this variable on the various and the country of birth has a positive im-
country-specificproxies. pact on the assimilationrate,the effectis not
Assimilationratesaredeterminedby polit- significant.However,immigrantsfromcoun-
ical factors. In particular,immigrantsfrom tries with higherlevelsof Englishproficiency
free countries have lower assimilationrates have much higherassimilationrates.In fact,
than immigrantsfrom countrieswith a long the rate of earningsgrowth of immigrants
history of political repression, while im- from English-speakingcountriesis 1.4 per-
migrants from countries that recently lost centage points higher than that of im-

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS:EARNINGSOF IMMIGRANTS 549

OFTHERATEOFCHANGE
TABLE7-DETERMINANTS IN COHORT
QUALITY

Country of Origin Regression


Characteristics 1 2 3 4

Intercept -.3194 -.9951 -1.1779 - 2.2202


(-3.19) (-3.97) (-4.08) (-4.69)
Politically
Competitive
System .1760 .1075 .0712 .0630
(2.54) (1.60) (.97) (.70)
Recent Loss of
Freedom .1256 .1468 .1272 .1310
(1.67) (2.16) (1.81) (1.33)
Number of
Assassinations .0077 .0156 .0122 .0256
(1.19) (2.32) (1.69) (2.00)
Rate of Change in
Central Government
Expenditures .0698 .0699 .0641 - .0099
(1.60) (1.75) (1.60) (-.21)
Rate of Change in Per
Capita GNP 4.7010 3.0956 1.1567 -1.5321
(2.27) (1.60) (.46) (-.50)
In (per capita GNP) - .0889 .1186 .2443
(1.93) (3.22) (4.15)
Country in Asia or
Africa -- .1374
(1.42)
Country in North or
South America - .0274
(.41)
Change in Quota - - - .0034
(2.26)
R2 .284 .418 .453 .581

aThe t-ratios are presented in parentheses.

migrantsfrom countrieswith 0 percentEn- similationratesthaninumigrants bornin Asia


glish proficiencyrates. Similarly,the age at or Africa. Despite the strongly significant
immigrationhas a strongpositiveimpacton impact of the continentdummies,the quali-
assimilation rates. This result is consistent tative effect of most of the othervariablesin
with the hypothesis that immigrantswho the regressionis unaffected.
migrate as youths have little to gain from
assimilationper se. On the other hand, the C. Determinantsof the Change
adaptation period is likely to be important in CohortQuality
for personswho migrateat older ages.
The last two regressionsin Table6 include Section III calculateda variablemeasur-
per capita GNP variableand the continent ing the wage differentialbetween the 1979
dummiesin the list of regressors.Thesevari- immigrantcohort and the 1955 immigrant
ables have a significantimpacton the assimi- cohort as of the date of immigration.The
lation rate (in column 4). Immigrantsfrom regressions analyzing the determinantsof
wealthiercountrieshave higherassimilation cohort qualitychangeare presentedin Table
rates, and Europeans(the omittedcontinent) 7. It shouldbe noted that the specificationof
have higher assimilation rates than im- these regressionsdiffersslightly from those
migrants from the Americas,but lower as- presented in Tables 5 and 6 since cohort

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
550 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 1987

quality change is likely to be determinedby TABLE 8-PROBIT REGRESSIONON


THE EMIGRATIONRATEa
changesin the explanatoryvariablesoverthe
1954-79 period.
Countryof Origin Regression
The simple specificationin column 1 re- Characteristics 1 2
veals that cohort quality change is strongly
influencedby practicallyall the variablesin Intercept - .6060 -1.1614
the regressions.For example,the qualityof (-1.30) (-2.46)
PoliticallyCompetitive
cohorts from countries that experienceda System .1206 .0801
shift frompoliticalcompetitionto repression (1.13) (.81)
increased by about 13 percent (relative to RecentLossof Freedom .1096 -.0365
the quality of cohorts from countries that (.95) (-.32)
Number of Assassinations -.0245 -.0337
were politically repressive throughout the (- 3.65)
(- 2.65)
period). This effect is consistent with the Income Inequality -.0113 -.0145
implicationsof the theorydevelopedin Sec- (-1.51) (- 2.00)
tion I. The change in politicalstructurecan Distance from U.S. -.1332 -.1271
be viewed as a change in the correlation (- 6.11) (-2.68)
EnglishProficiency .1661 .0488
coefficient of the earnings of individuals
(.94) (.30)
between the home country and the United In (percapita GNP) -.1130 - .0441
States. The change toward a repressive (-2.14) (-.83)
governmentmay makethe correlationcoeffi- Countryin Asia
cient in earnings across the two countries or Africa - .3386
(2.19)
negative. Thus persons in the "revolution- Countryin North
ary"lower tail of the homecountry'sincome or South America - .2923
distributionmigrateto the United Statesand (1.52)
performquite well in the U.S. labor market. X2 98.45 108.82
Table 7 also shows that cohort quality aThe dependentvariableis the probabilitythat an
change is strongly affectedby the average individualmigratedto the United States in 1951-80,
annualchangein the percentof GNP that is and is given by the second column of Table 2. The
attributableto expendituresby the central t-ratiosare presentedin parentheses.
government.Presumablythe greaterthe role
of the government,the moreincomeredistri-
bution that takes place and the greaterthe
decreasein income inequalityover the post- One factor causing systematic quality
war period.The coefficientof this variablein shifts across immigrantcohorts may have
Table 8 is consistent with the theoretical been the change in the quota system man-
implication. dated by the 1965 Amendmentsto the Im-
The next two regressionsin Table 8 add migrationand NationalityAct. Table 4 de-
the level of per capita GNP to control for fined a variablethat measuresthe changein
country-specificdifferencesin wealth, and the fraction of the home country'spopula-
the continent dummiesto controlfor conti- tion "eligible"for emigrationto the United
nent-specific fixed effects. The continent States before and after the 1965 Amend-
dummies are not very significant,but per ments. Higherlevels of this variableimply a
capita GNP variable does have a strong reduction in the levels of "mobility costs"
positive impacton cohort-qualitychange.Its faced by potentialemigrants.The Roy model
positive coefficientconfirmsthe findingsug- suggests that its impact on the rate of
gested by the descriptiveanalysisin Section cohort-qualitychangeis positiveif the corre-
III: the quality of immigrantsadmittedto lation coefficientbetweenearningscapacities
the United States has been increasingover in the two countriesis positiveand if income
time when the immigrantsoriginatein West- is more unequally distributedin the coun-
ern Europeand has been decliningover time tries of origin than in the United States.The
when the immigrantsoriginatein the less last column of Table 7 adds the quota vari-
developedcountries. able to the regression and shows that it

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS: EARNINGS OFIMMIGRANTS 551

indeed has a positive and significantimpact framework.More interestingly,the second


on the rate of changein cohortquality.It is moment of the income distribution(as pre-
important to note that this regressionis dicted by the Roy model)playsan important
estimatedon only 28 observationssince the role in the determinationof the emigration
quota systempriorto the 1965Amendments rate. In particular,countrieswith more in-
was applicableonly to countriesthatwerein come inequalityhaveloweremigrationrates.
the EasternHemisphere. This negative coefficientis implied by the
wealth-maximizationframeworkif there is
D. Determinants of the EmigrationRate negative selection in the immigrantpool.
Negative selection requiresthat the correla-
The empiricalanalysisin thispaperfocuses tion between earningsin the United States
on the determinantsof the (relative)earnings and in the sending countriesbe sufficiently
of immigrants.It is worth noting, however, positive and that the United Stateshas less
that the Roy model also implies that the income inequality than the sending coun-
emigration rate will be a function of the tries. If, in addition, mean income in the
same characteristicsof the income distribu- United States exceedsmeanincomein send-
tion, politicalconditions,andmigrationcosts ing countries(adjustedfor mobilitycosts),as
that determine the relativeearningsof im- income inequality in the home country in-
migrants. Therefore,it is importantto ex- creases,the migrationincentivesof the most
plore if the emigrationrate from the various able decreases while the poorest will still
countriesof origin is responsiveto shifts in migrate.Hence the emigrationrate declines
the country-specificvariablesthat have been due to the withdrawalof high-incomeper-
used throughoutthis section. sons from the pool of emigrants.The analy-
Table 8 presentstwo probitregressionson sis of the emigrationrate, therefore,leads
the emigrationrate.24The dependentvari- to results that are generallyconsistentwith
able is obtained from the second columnof the types of selectionbiases that have been
the summarystatisticspresentedin Table 2, documentedin this paper.
and is the fractionof the countryof origin's
population that emigrated to the United V. Summary
States in the 1951-80 period.The firstof the
two regressionsincludes the political varia- What determinesthe (labormarket)qual-
bles, the distance variable (to measure ity of foreign-bornpersons in the United
migrationcosts), and the inequalityvariable, States?Most of the literatureaddressesthis
while the second regressionadds the conti- question simply by assuming that immi-
nent dummies.25 grants are a "select" group, and that the
As expected, the distance between the selection mechanism somehow sends the
country of origin and the United Stateshas most able and the most ambitiouspersonsin
a negative impact on the emigrationrate. any country of origin to the United States.
The emigrationrate is also lower for coun- This paperis an attemptto analyzeboth the
tries that have high levelsof GNP percapita. conceptualand empiricalfoundationsfor this
These results, of course,are consistentwith type of assertion.Among the majorfindings
the predictions of the wealth-maximization of the study are:
1) If potential emigrants are income
maximizers, foreign-born persons in the
United States need not be drawn from the
24The probitswere estimatedusinggeneralizedleast most able and most ambitiousin the country
squares. The estimator, therefore,is minimum chi- of origin. Two conditionsmust be satisfied
squaredand efficient. in order for positive selectionto take place:
25 The regressionsin Table 8 exclude the age at
a) there is a strong positive correlationbe-
migrationfrom the list of regressorssince this variable
was calculatedin the subsampleof immigrantsand may tween the earningsa workermay expect in
have little relationshipto the age distributionof the the home countryand the earningsthe same
populationin the countryof origin. workermay expectin the United States;and

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
552 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW SEPTEMBER1987

b) the United States has a more unequal BarryR., "The Effectof Americani-
Chiswick,
income distributionthan the home country. zation on the Earningsof Foreign-Born
If the income distributionin the sending Men," Journal of Political Economy, Oc-
country is more unequal than that of the tober 1978, 86, 897-921.
United States (and the correlationin earn- DeFreitas, Gregory, "The Earnings of Im-
ings is positiveand strong),emigrantswill be migrantsin the AmericanLaborMarket,"
chosen from the lower tail of the income unpublished doctoral dissertation, Co-
distributionin the countryof origin. lumbia University,1980.
2) The empiricalanalysis of the earn- Heckman,James J., "Sample Selection Bias as
ings of immigrantsfrom 41 differentcoun- Jan-
a SpecificationError,"Econometrica,
tries using the 1970 and 1980censusesshows uary 1979, 47, 153-61.
that there are strong country-specificfixed and Robb, Richard,"Using Longitu-
effects in the (labor market)quality of for- dinal Data to EstimateAge, Period,and
eign-born persons. In particular,persons Cohort Effectsin EarningsEquations,"in
from Western Europeancountriesdo quite H. Winsboroughand 0. Duncan, eds.,
well in the United States, and their cohorts Analyzing LongitudinalData for Age, Per-
have exhibiteda generalincreasein earnings iod, and Cohort Effects, New York:
(relative to their measuredskills) over the AcademicPress,1983.
postwarperiod. On the other hand, persons and Sedlacek,Guilherne,"Heterogene-
from less developed countriesdo not per- ity, Aggregation,and MarketWageFunc-
form well in the U.S. labormarketand their tions: An EmpiricalModel of Self-Selec-
cohorts have exhibiteda generaldecreasein tion in the Labor Market,"Journal of
earnings (relative to their measuredskills) Political Economy, December 1985, 93,
over the postwarperiod. 1077-125.
3) The empiricalanalysis of the vari- Jasso, Guillennina and Rosenzweig,Mark R.,
ance in various dimensions of immigrant "How Well Do U.S. ImmigrantsDo? Vin-
incomes shows that a few variablesdescrib- tage Effects, EmigrationSelectivity,and
ing political and economicconditionsin the the Occupational Mobility of Immi-
variouscountriesof originexplainover two- grants,"mimeo.,Universityof Minnesota,
thirds of the intercountryvariance in the June 1985.
mean U.S. incomes of immigrantswith the and ,"Family Reunification
same measuredskills. Immigrantswith high and the ImmigrationMultiplier:U.S. Im-
incomesin the United Statesrelativeto their migration Law, Origin-CountryCondi-
measured skills come from countries that tions, and the Reproductionof Immi-
have high levels of GNP, low levels of in- grants," Demography, August 1986, 23,
come inequality,and politicallycompetitive 291-311.
systems. McManus, Walter, Gould, William,and Welch,
Finis, "Earnings of Hispanic Men: The
REFERENCES Role of English LanguageProficiency,"
Journal of Labor Economics,April 1983, 1,
Borjas,GeorgeJ., "Assimilation,Changesin 101-30.
Cohort Quality, and the Earningsof Im- Roy,A. D., "SomeThoughtson the Distribu-
migrants," Journal of Labor Economics, tion of Earnings," Oxford Economic Pa-
October1985, 3, 463-89. pers, June 1951, 3, 135-46.
____, "A Longitudinal Analysis of Im- Sjaastad,LarryA., "The Costs and Returns of
migrantsEarnings:The Case of Scientists Human Migration," Journal of Political
and Engineers," mimeo., University of Economy,October1962,Suppl.,70, 80-93.
California-SantaBarbara,1987. Willis, Robert J. and Rosen, Sherwin,"Educa-
Carliner,Geoffrey,"'Wages, Earnings, and tion and Self-Selection," Journal of Politi-
Hours of First, Secondand ThirdGenera- cal Economy, October 1979, Suppl., 87,
tion American Males," Economic Inquiry, S7-S36.
January1980, 18, 87-102. United Nations, Compendiumof Social Statis-

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 77 NO. 4 BORJAS: EARNINGS OF IMMIGRANTS 553

tics, New York: UN, 1977. of the United States, Washington: USGPO,
U.S. Arms Control and DisarmamentAgency, various issues.
World Military Expenditures and Arms U.S. ImmigrationandNaturalizationService,An-
Transfers, 1972- 1982, Washington: nual Report of the Immigration and Natu-
USGPO, 1984. ralization Service, Washington: USGPO,
, World Military Expenditures and 1965.
Arms Trade, 1963-1973, Washington: WorldBank, WorldDevelopmentReport, New
USGPO, 1975. York: Oxford University Press, various
U.S. Bureauof the Census,Statistical Abstract issues.

This content downloaded from 128.103.149.52 on Fri, 2 May 2014 10:03:13 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

S-ar putea să vă placă și