Sunteți pe pagina 1din 11

Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

The Baseline Scenario


What happened to the global economy and what we can do about it

Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners


For a complete list of Beginners articles, see Financial Crisis for Beginners.

Arnold Kling helpfully pointed out a 2000 paper on regulatory capital arbitrage by David Jones, an economist at the
Fed. In his post, Kling said, “In retrospect, this is a bit like watching a movie in which a jailer becomes sympathetic
to a prisoner, when we know that the prisoner is eventually going to escape and go on a crime spree.” Having finally
read the paper, I have little to add in the way of analysis. But I thought it provided a useful basis for a discussion of
what regulatory capital arbitrage (RCA) is and why it is a helpful way of thinking about the financial crisis.

Regulatory capital refers to the amount of capital a financial institution must hold because of regulatory
requirements. Capital is the amount of value in a bank that is attributable to the shareholders – that is, the bank’s
assets minus its liabilities. There are different kinds of capital, but we can ignore that here.

One function of capital – the function that regulators care about – is to insulate banks from losses. Assets can
fluctuate in value; a borrower can owe you $100, but if he goes bankrupt and flees the country, that loan is worth
zero. The amount of your liabilities does not fluctuate, however. If you have $100 in assets, $90 in liabilities, and
$10 in capital, then you can withstand a 10% fall in the value of your assets and still pay off your debts; if you have
$98 in liabilities and $2 in capital, then a 3% fall will make you insolvent (unable to pay off your debts).

Regulators impose capital requirements in order to help ensure the safety and soundness of banks. There are various
reasons why safe and sound banks are good, but the most direct – from the regulator’s perspective – is that the
government is insuring the bank’s liabilities; for example, the FDIC now insures deposits up to $250,000 per person.
Since the government is on the hook if the bank becomes insolvent, it wants to reduce the chances of that happening
– hence capital requirements.

The question is how much capital should be required, and the key concept is risk-based capital. The idea is that some
assets are riskier than others. If you hold very safe assets, like cash or short-term U.S. Treasury bills, then the
chances of even a 3% fall in value are miniscule, so you shouldn’t need to hold much capital. However, if you hold
risky assets, like loans to build offshore drilling platforms in the Arctic Ocean, then you should have to hold more
capital.

The theory is simple. Every asset has a certain amount of risk; a firm that holds that asset should also hold, for that
asset, an amount of capital proportional to its risk. Both on the firm level and on the system level, then, capital levels
will adequately insure against the risk of losses. The tricky thing is putting this into practice, for two reasons: first,
it’s impossible a priori to know how risky a given asset is (you can only estimate it); second, the potential
complexity of financial transactions far exceeds the ability of regulators to specify rules for every one.

The 1988 Basel Accord (now known as Basel I) introduced international standards for risk-based capital
requirements. Under Basel I, banks have to hold capital equivalent to 8% of their risk-weighted assets. Each type of
asset has a risk weight that reflects its riskiness. For example, OECD government bonds have a zero risk weight –
theoretically, they have zero risk, and hence require zero capital; home mortgages have a 50% risk weight; and
uncollateralized commercial loans have a 100% risk weight. So if a bank held $100 in Treasuries, $100 in home
mortgages, and $100 in commercial loans, it would have $300 in assets, but only $150 in risk-weighted assets (0% *
$100 + 50% * $100 + 100% * $100); therefore would have to hold $12 in capital (8% * $150). Looked at another
way, the capital requirements are 0% on government bonds, 4% on home mortgages, and 8% on commercial loans.

Regulatory capital arbitrage happens because, all other things being equal, banks would like to hold less rather than
more capital. The reason is that, in general, bank profits are proportional to the amount of assets that they hold. One
main source of banking profits is interest margin: the spread between the interest charged on loans and the interest
paid on deposits and other sources of funding. For any given interest margin, profits will be strictly proportional to
loan volume (assets). The same logic applies to banks’ principal investment and trading businesses; for any given
strategy, doubling the size of the position will double the expected profit. So to increase profits, you have to increase

1 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

assets. If a bank wants to increase its assets, it can do so either by increasing its leverage (lowering its capital as a
percentage of assets) or increasing its capital; the former is preferable, because the latter requires issuing new shares,
which dilutes current shareholders. (Also, issuing new shares results in lower earnings per share, lowering the stock
price.)

How does regulatory capital arbitrage work? There are many strategies, but the most straightforward to describe and
to implement is securitization. Recall our bank earlier that had $100 in mortgages, for which it had to hold $4 in
capital. Let’s say it creates a simple collateralized debt obligation out of these mortgages. It sells them to a special-
purpose vehicle (SPV) that issues bonds to investors; these bonds are backed by the cash flows from the monthly
mortgage payments. The bonds are divided into a set of tranches ordered by seniority (priority), so the incoming
cash flows first pay off the most senior tranche, then the next most senior tranche, and so on. If these are high-quality
mortgages, all the credit risk (at least according to the rating agencies) can be concentrated in the bottom few
tranches (because it’s unlikely that more than a few percent of borrowers will default), so you end up with a few
risky bonds and a lot of “very safe” ones.

The magic is that by getting sufficiently high credit ratings for the senior tranches, the bank can lower the risk
weights on those assets, thereby lowering the amount of capital it has to hold for those tranches. The risky tranches
will require more capital, but it is possible to do the math so that the lower capital requirements on the senior
tranches more than outweigh the higher requirements on the junior tranches. So you end up with lower total capital
requirements – in some cases, 50% lower – simply through securitization. Jones runs through some examples in his
appendix.

An extension of this strategy is to selectively sell some tranches and hold onto others. In this way, a bank can end up
with assets that have a high degree of economic risk but a low risk weight for capital purposes. This is possible
because the rules setting capital requirements are lumpy (e.g., all home mortgages have a 4% capital requirement)
while there is an infinite range of actual financial assets. Structured finance makes it possible to manufacture
securities with various combinations of economic risk and regulatory risk weights, which can then be sold to
investors with different preferences.

Why would you want assets that have a high degree of risk but require little capital? In general, high risk means a
high expected return. So these assets give you a high expected return on a small amount of capital, which is exactly
how you maximize your “shareholder value.” This is also how you maximize your true economic leverage – the ratio
between the risk you are taking on and the capital buffer you hold – beyond the leverage that shows up in your
accounting statements. And, of course, it’s how you maximize the chances that your bank will blow up if something
goes wrong.

The shift from fixed-percentage capital requirements (Basel I) to value-at-risk (VaR) methodologies (Basel II) only
increased the potential for regulatory arbitrage. In VaR, the riskiness of any asset is determined by a model based on
the historical attributes of the asset. In theory, this is an improvement, because it gets around the problem of lumpy
fixed percentages, and tailors the risk weight to the unique characteristics of the asset itself. In practice, however, it
made it possible to assess riskiness based on small amounts of historical data from periods during which, for
example, subprime loans rarely defaulted because rising housing prices always made it possible to refi nance. By
underestimating the risk of certain assets, these models underestimated the capital required to support these assets.

As the business developed earlier this decade, many of the lower-rated tranches ended up going not to regulated
banks, but to unregulated hedge funds that were trying to maximize their yields. Even though these hedge funds did
not have regulatory capital requirements, these custom-manufactured securities had a similar impact there: they
enabled investors to take on a large amount of economic risk using a small amount of capital. As a result, they
increased the chances that hedge funds would go bust when the economy turned.

In general, a hedge fund failing is not such a terrible thing; that’s the price investors pay for seeking out higher
yields. And I don’t buy the argument that hedge funds need to be regulated just because some of their investors
happen to be warm and fuzzy, like teachers’ pension funds. However, individual hedge funds could grow large
enough that their failure could have systemic effects. And in aggregate, the “shadow banking system” – unregulated
institutions that amass capital from investors and direct it to users of capital via various types of investments – is
itself a wholesale form of regulatory capital arbitrage, since this part of the financial system can escape regulatory
capital requirements altogether, undermining the basic principle that the system should have sufficient capital to
support the risks it takes on.

Regulatory capital arbitrage complicates the problem of designing a new regulatory structure for the financial sector.

2 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

First of all, it implies that capital requirements must apply in some form to the shadow banking system as well as the
traditional banking system. Otherwise, as Jones noted back in 2000, certain forms of financial intermediation will
simply shift from the traditional to the shadow system. In addition, if the problem we want to manage is systemic
risk, then focusing solely on institutions with certain types of charters will not be sufficient, especially as the
unregulated ones become bigger and more numerous.

Second, it makes it hard to rely on capital requirements as a safeguard against either individual bank failure or
systemic failure. It is probably a fair assumption that whatever rules are written, smart bankers and their lawyers will
find ways to unbundle economic risk from regulatory risk weights and thereby take on more risk than they are
supposed to. In my opinion, this is another argument for imposing size caps on financial institutions to ensure that
they do not become too big to fail.

Third, however, regulatory capital arbitrage also makes it harder to enforce size caps. Let’s say no institution is
allowed to have more than $300 billion in risk-weighted assets. What’s to stop it from amassing $300 billion of
assets that are disproportionately risky relative to their risk weights? In short, we need a system for risk weighting
that is harder to “game” than the current one – and a set of regulators who will enforce it. Given how long Basel II
has been going on, and what it has come up with, this is asking for a lot.

By James Kwak

Share this: Email 0 Facebook Print Share

Written by James Kwak

May 30, 2009 at 11:15 pm

Posted in Beginners

Tagged with accounting, regulation

« Mr. Geithner Goes to China


When Market Incentives Lead to Bad Outcomes »

Like One blogger likes this post

21 Responses
Subscribe to comments with RSS.

1. “Regulatory capital arbitrage happens because, all other things being equal, banks would like to hold less
rather than more capital.”

That statement sounds too general to me. Suppose that there were no regulation at all. Would banks then like
to hold zero capital? Only if they were con artists, eh?

“How does regulatory capital arbitrage work? There are many strategies, but the most straightforward to
describe and to implement is securitization….

“The magic is that by getting sufficiently high credit ratings for the senior tranches, the bank can lower the
risk weights on those assets, thereby lowering the amount of capital it has to hold for those tranches.”

I take it that you mean magic as in smoke and mirrors.

In all this I kept asking, where is a the reduction of risk? All that I found was where you might get somebody

3 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

else to buy your risk. Finally I went to the site with Jones’s paper. In the abstract Jones says, “In recent years,
securitization and other financial innovations have provided unprecedented opportunities for banks to reduce
substantially their regulatory capital requirements with ***little or no corresponding reduction in their overall
economic risks – a process termed “regulatory capital arbitrage”***.” (Emphasis mine.)

Just as I thought.

“It is probably a fair assumption that whatever rules are written, smart bankers and their lawyers will find
ways to unbundle economic risk from regulatory risk weights and thereby take on more risk than they are
supposed to.”

Clever, perhaps, but smart? Really?

“In short, we need a system for risk weighting that is harder to “game” than the current one – and a set of
regulators who will enforce it.”

I think that new financial instruments should be treated like designer drugs. They should be regulated as soon
as they are created. Furthermore, the burden should be on the creators to show their safety and value. In this
case, it appears that the regulators were aware that securitization was being used to get around capital
requirements. Whether they would have OKed it is another question.

A few weeks ago I saw Obama on TV, talking to a small group of people and a local banker. To my surprise,
he explained securitization, and said that it was a good thing. I assume that that is what his advisors told him.
That gives me a sinking feeling.

Min
May 31, 2009 at 1:21 am

2. It’s simply false to define the “shadow banking system” as “unregulated institutions that amass capital from
investors and direct it to users of capital via various types of investments.” The shadow banking system is
comprised of institutions that engage in financial intermediation, but which are not commercial banks.

To suggest that all institutions in the shadow banking system are “unregulated” is utterly absurd. Money
market mutual funds, for example, are part of the shadow banking system, and they are most certainly NOT
unregulated. Broker-dealers are heavily regulated under the 1934 Act. Insurance companies are also part of
the shadow banking system, but they are regulated heavily at the state level. As dime-store pundits frequently
point out in their attempts to demonize CDS, insurance companies have long been subject to capital
requirements (which, pundits claim, CDS were supposedly designed to circumvent).

Not surprisingly, then, Kwak’s claim that the shadow banking system is “itself a wholesale form of regulatory
capital arbitrage” is equally as ridiculous. (This essentially amounts to saying that any intermediation that
takes place outside the commercial banking system is regulatory capital arbitrage, which, as a securities
lawyer, I find particularly comical.) Of course, many, if not most, of the major players in the shadow banking
system are also subject to regulatory capital requirements, which in some areas are stricter than the regulatory
capital requirements faced by traditional commercial banks, and in other areas are not.

In any event, Kwak does his readers a serious disservice by suggesting that the so-called shadow banking
system — which we used to call “the capital markets” — is (a) unregulated, and (b) a wholesale form of
regulatory capital arbitrage. Both claims are flagrantly untrue, and betray a fundamental misunderstanding of
the U.S. financial system. Perhaps Kwak can get someone to write a “U.S. Financial System for Beginners”
post for him.

Sandy
May 31, 2009 at 2:03 am

The shadow banking system is a term coined by Paul Mcculley here: http://www.pimco.com/LeftNav
/Featured+Market+Commentary/FF/2007/GCBF+August-+September+2007.htm

He states: “the “shadow banking system” – the whole alphabet soup of levered up non-bank

4 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

investment conduits, vehicles, and structures.”

By this definition money market funds, insurance companies and hedge funds interact with the shadow
banking system, but are not in fact part of it. The usage in this post is, I believe, consistent with this
definition.

ccm
May 31, 2009 at 2:13 am

The “shadow banking system” does not refer to any institution that provides intermediation that is not
a commercial bank. By your definition, a lot of ridiculous institutions would be part of the shadow
banking system.

Bond Girl
May 31, 2009 at 2:05 pm

My comment was directed at Sandy, not CCM.

Bond Girl
May 31, 2009 at 2:08 pm

CCM and Bond Girl — My reply showed up down below for some reason.

Sandy
June 2, 2009 at 11:31 pm

Honest, your honor, my clients are honorable people and did nothing wrong in any way. The system is
just fine the way it is.

The mouthpiece speaks.

jrw
May 31, 2009 at 2:19 pm

3. So a securitised pool of loans could be set up so the sum of the VAR’s of all the tranches would be up to 50%
less than the sum of the VAR’s of the individual loans? With a consequentially lower capital requirement and
hence higher available leverage?

And then presumably the lower tranches could be further sliced and diced to give similar, but smaller, second
and higher order effects.

I had not considered this aspect of securitisation before, or even seen it emphasised.

Fascinating.

ozajh
May 31, 2009 at 5:40 am

4. James – a practical example or several would help, such as European institutions gaming their regulator by
booking dubious AIG CDSs as Tier One capital and thereby complying with at least the letter of Basel II, if
not the spirit, intent, numbers, inherent catastrophic risk etc.

As I understand it, ie minimally, Basel II VaR was also methodologically flawed by taking a very short
historical default / risk data series, and naturally extrapolating it foward. Thus is bubbletime, the model, not
only did assume that risk was minimal, and in essence VaR was stable or declining, but that’s the only result

5 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

possible given the model and time series.

Problem two, briefly, is even if risk management moved away from the short(est) run historical series to
assess future VaR, there’s the everso minor matter of CDS pricing itself being used as a transparent and
reliable means to retrofit risk onto the instruments (viz the gaussian cupola formula). That is, because pricing
in the market is perfect, then lower prices for CDS tranches is directly correlated to risk. This of course is a
logical absurdity, and represents an ideologically-driven reverse causality. One analogy would be your
insurance company telling you there will be no hurricanes this year because your premium is low.

Now, the number of hurricanes checking insurance premia before deciding to beef up to force 5 or make
landfall is not well documented but I suspect it is around zero.

Counterpointer
May 31, 2009 at 8:14 am

I’m halfway through Gillian Tett’s new book, _Fool’s Gold_, about the development of the credit
derivatives market. It has a few good anecdotes about how different financial institutions chose to (or,
in the case of pre-Chase merger J.P. Morgan, chose not to) use the new instruments to play shell games
with regulatory capital requirements.

Marcus
May 31, 2009 at 11:58 pm

5. Regarding the problem of a priori risk, a guy named Joel Jameson (who specializes in justifying ESOP and
executive stock compensation programs) has some intriguing (and, in view of recent events, quite accurate)
ideas on the difference between “objective” and “subjective” probability paradigms.

Regarding circumvention of Basel II, a wonderful company named Accenture played a key role in advising
Euro banks on how to redefine their asset portfolio risks. To minimize competition in the evasion of
government regulations, Accenture sought patent protection in many jurisdictions for their business methods
and systems – and in the process, laid a valuable historical paper trail explaining the motivations of our
present financial crises.

Finally, regarding the assertion that (state-regulated) insurance companies do not provide regulatory capital
arbitrage … surely, if this assertion were true, insurers would not invest the time of lawyers and accountants
to assess the business impacts of state insurance commission rulings. However, “arbitrage” is not the same as
“complete evasion”. Rather, arbitrage relates to conscious choice of where and how to operate based on
differing rules in different jurisdictions. For example, when TARP funds became available to bank holding
companies, investment banks changed their business positions – as did some insurers.

patent.drafter
May 31, 2009 at 9:43 am

6. patent drafter – have seen this all too many times, where objective is a noun, not an adjective.

Counterpointer
May 31, 2009 at 11:03 am

7. If the problem is that the supervisory framework relies on a one-size-fits-all approach to risk when some asset
classes require a more sophisticated approach to risk, why not scrap the risk classifications and just have
periodic stress tests for the banks based on economic/market realities?

Bond Girl

6 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

May 31, 2009 at 11:28 am

8. Certainly, regulation probably needs to be overhauled, but the real issue here is (1) personal accountability
and (2) separation between regulators and regulated entities.
(Non-)systemic risk can only be reduced if top managers are certain of having to face dire consequences if
they act irresponsibly:
under no circumstances should the top management hope to be bailed out together with the institution, or
non-eligible institutions hope to be bailed out.
Salaries and bonuses should be repaid if it turns out they were coming out of from fake profits.

Morale: even the most perfectly devised regulatory framework will fail if there is no certainty it will be
upheld during a crisis.

Sadly, the institutional response so far gives no reason to believe this will be happening any time soon, if
ever.

And it was this failure, the belief by top managers of remaining unscathed whatever happened, that really
brought us to the current mess.

Earendil Star
May 31, 2009 at 12:50 pm

9. To amplify Min’s point in the first Comment, it is probably unfair to deem this regulatory arbitrage. Banks
generally hold 50% to 100% MORE in capital than is required by regulation. The reason for this, supposedly,
is to garner high enough ratings from the rating agencies that they can play as derivatives counterparties (less
than an A rating and you get hammered with extra margin). So the binding constraint is usually rating agency
requirements, not regulator requirements.

Of course, it is possible that the rating agencies, despite their supposed fancy modeling, really just require
banks to hold 50% more than what the regulator wants. If that’s true than regulatory capital arbitrage really is
the game that banks need to play. But that’s just abdication on the part of the rating agencies, and they’d
never admit it.

mort_fin
May 31, 2009 at 1:01 pm

What you are saying does not actually contradict Jones’ argument, which is that through regulatory
capital arbitrage banks are able to achieve effective capital requirements that are below the nominal
capital requirements because they model risk differently than the one-size-fits-all approach to risk used
in banking regulations. They can meet or exceed nominal capital requirements while carrying a lot
more risk.

Bond Girl
May 31, 2009 at 2:23 pm

There is no question that the rating agencies should be required to be transparent, and not be paid by
the parties desirous of appropriate ratings. We’re talking serious rating agency regulation. (Obviously
there is a good reason why the rating agencies have the highest profit margins — easy to make money
be having one guy at a desk with a small set of rubber stamps.)

Bayard
June 1, 2009 at 12:07 pm

10. [...] Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners For a complete list of Beginners articles, see Financial Crisis
for Beginners. Arnold Kling helpfully pointed out a [...] [...]

Top Posts « WordPress.com

7 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

May 31, 2009 at 8:33 pm

11. I believe that any practice which leads to unregulated arbitrage is inherently risky. And, when regulation is
achieved, all potential leaks must be plugged, probably by having the regulator (should be an “uber” regulator
which can regulate all affiliated markets where risk shifting can occur) be given the right and responsibility
for approving any and all activities of the potential arbitrageurs, including any new instrument or
methodology. It is hateful to have to do this, but since Greenspan’s surprise that markets ARE NOT
NATURALLY MOTIVATED BY SELF PRESERVATION (except as to their lobbyists), it appears to be
necessary. If this cannot be effectively legislated, the market place will continue to be volatile de facto, and
Congress’s failure to regulate will result in a new group of Congressmen being seated. The present Congress
is not far from being booted out, and the failure of the present “recovery” is likely to ensure lots of future risk
for our legislators. There can be healthy arbitrage, but only at the fringes, not in the core of what should be a
conservatively managed financial banking system.

Bayard
June 1, 2009 at 12:03 pm

12. [...] Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners [...]

Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners | ZachStocks


June 1, 2009 at 9:09 pm

13. Yes, it does. The “shadow banking system” is widely understood to mean nonbank (i.e., nondepository)
financial institutions engaged in financial intermediation.

For example, here’s Paul Krugman’s description of the shadow banking system:

“[T]he old world of banking, in which institutions housed in big marble buildings accepted deposits and lent
the money out to long-term clients, has largely vanished, replaced by what is widely called the ‘shadow
banking system.’ Depository banks, the guys in the marble buildings, now play only a minor role in
channeling funds from savers to borrowers; most of the business of finance is carried out through complex
deals arranged by ‘nondepository’ institutions, institutions like the late lamented Bear Stearns — and
Lehman.” (http://www.nytimes.com/2008/09/15/opinion/15krugman.html)

And here’s Nouriel Roubini’s definition:

“Last week saw the demise of the shadow banking system that has been created over the past 20 years.
Because of a greater regulation of banks, most financial intermediation in the past two decades has grown
within this shadow system whose members are broker-dealers, hedge funds, private equity groups, structured
investment vehicles and conduits, money market funds and non-bank mortgage lenders.” (http://www.ft.com
/cms/s/0/622acc9e-87f1-11dd-b114-0000779fd18c.html)

Before the sexier-sounding “shadow banking system” title came along, we used to talk about the bank-based
financial system versus the capital markets-based financial system. Remember the whole debate about
“disintermediation”?

It’s not that the shadow banking system is “unregulated” — a completely meaningless political term in any
event. It’s that the shadow banking system doesn’t have FDIC deposit insurance (or its equivalent), which
makes it susceptible to classic bank runs. The implosion of the ABCP market, as well as the massive
electronic run on money market mutual funds after the Reserve Primary Fund broke the buck, illustrate the
dichotomy.

Sandy
June 2, 2009 at 10:50 pm

Comments are closed.

8 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

Get Updates!
Daily Email Updates
Updates in a Reader
Raw RSS Feed
Read on Kindle
Follow us on Twitter
Facebook Page
Help with Updates

Navigation
Home
About The Baseline Scenario Financial Crisis for Beginners
Download the Blog in PDF
Simon's papers
Comments
Technical Support

Our Book

Search

Recent Posts
Will Ireland Default? Ask Belgium
How Are the Kids? Unemployed, Underwater, and Sinking
Who Gains From The Eurozone Fiasco? China
“We Have Good Processes and Good Controls”
Fixing The US Budget – Straightforward Or The Hardest Problem On Earth?
The Law of Software Development
The Debt Problems of the European Periphery
Why Our Tax Code?
It’s Not About Ireland Anymore

9 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

Dear Mr. President


G20: Profound And Complete Disappointment For The US Treasury
Vikram Pandit Has No Clothes

Our Other Sites


Economix (New York Times)
Project Syndicate

A Few Commenters
anne
Don the Libertarian Democrat
grahambrokethemold (Ted K.)
Manshu
Nemo and Bond Girl
Paul Handover
Per Kurowski
Pete Muldoon
Russ
Taunter
The Raven
Tippy Golden

Links
Alyssa Katz
Angry Bear
Brad DeLong
Calculated Risk
Crisis Talk (World Bank)
Econbrowser
EconLog
Economic Principals
EconomicsUK
Economist’s View
Economists’ Forum at Financial Times
Ezra Klein
Felix Salmon
Finance: Facts and Follies
iMFdirect
Interfluidity
Macroadvisers
Marginal Revolution
MIT Sloan School of Management
Money Supply (FT)
naked capitalism
New Deal 2.0
Nouriel Roubini
NPR Planet Money
OECD Insights
Paul Krugman
Paul Solman
Peterson Institute: Crisis Watch
Policy Court
Rational Irrationality
Real Time Economics (WSJ)
Rortybomb

10 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM


Regulatory Capital Arbitrage for Beginners « The Baseline Scenario http://baselinescenario.com/2009/05/30/regulatory-capital-arbit...

Sense on Cents
Simon Johnson in the Media
The Fourteenth Banker
The Pareto Commons
The Polifinancial Times
TripleCrisis
Washington Outside
Washington's Blog

Tags

aig auto industry bailout Banking banks Bernanke cds CFPA China citigroup Consumer Protection
deficit derivatives Emerging Markets europe eurozone executive compensation Federal Reserve financial reform
financial regulation g20 Geithner Global Crisis goldman sachs government debt health care
housing imf inflation insurance international Larry Summers macroeconomics mortgages nationalization
politics real economy recapitalization regulation regulatory reform stimulus TARP taxes
technology too big to fail

Categories

Select Category

Archives

Select Month

All contents are copyright of the authors. The Baseline Scenario is a trademark of the authors.

Blog at WordPress.com. Theme: Journalist by Lucian E. Marin.

11 von 11 11/28/10 1:58 PM

S-ar putea să vă placă și