Sunteți pe pagina 1din 15

40 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 40 10/8/06 6:40:17 PM


warning: Negotiating
with trial lawyers and
cigarette companies
can be dangerous to
your fiscal health.

By
Jeremy
Bulow
It’s too bad that just 98 percent of all the
trial lawyers, politicians and tobacco executives give such a
bad name to all the rest. But if you look at the tobacco
Master Settlement Agreement – the deal that purportedly
punished Big Tobacco for its sins and compensated state
governments for the burden of tobacco-related health care
costs – you can see how stuff happens.
In November 1998, the executives of four major tobacco
companies and the attorneys general of eight states formally
settled their liability disputes. The settlement required the
companies to pay fees to the states on future sales of ciga-
rettes, in return for an end to all state claims against the
companies for fraud and violations of antitrust laws as well
as for smoking-related Medicaid expenses. The remaining
©gary roebuck/alamy

states (other than the four that had previously made similar
deals with the big cigarette makers) were given a week to
decide whether to sign, and all of them did.

Fourth Quarter 2006 41

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 41 10/8/06 6:40:23 PM


tobacco settlement
worse for the overall financial health of the
Economists estimate that about one-fifth trial lawyers and the tobacco companies, as
of the 20 percent decline in smoking since well as for a handful of the states that were at
1998 is attributable to the increase in cigarette the center of the negotiations on the master
prices because the tobacco companies passed agreement.
the fees on to smokers. So, as a result of the
agreement, fewer people are smoking fewer the (uneasy) justification for
cigarettes. And the states have a new multibil- high cigarette taxes
lion-dollar source of revenue, whose burden Most people agree that the days when “sin”
falls only on those who choose the self-de- taxes can be justified on moral grounds are
structive behavior of smoking. As my grand- over. One way or another, then, high cigarette
mother never said, “What’s not to like?” taxes must be linked to the costs that smoking
Well, actually, plenty. The structure of the imposes on others. The federal government’s
agreement effectively forced individual states Centers for Disease Control’s estimates for
to sign on in spite of the inherently unfair medical care costs and lost productivity linked
formula for distributing revenues, lest their to smoking from 1995 to 1999 were a whop-
own residents bear the costs of higher ciga- ping $157 billion per year, or $6 to $7 a pack.
rette prices with no offsetting revenue for the However, smokers and their families bear the
state. Under the agreement, smokers in some brunt of these costs, just as the consumers
states (including Georgia, Kentucky, North of Krispy Kremes and supersized Cokes bear
Carolina and Virginia) are paying over $100 most of the costs of the empty calories. And
million per year more for tobacco than the to the extent that consumers already pay,
settlement returns to their states’ coffers. there is no cost spillover that needs to be off-
Sometimes the companies and state attorneys set by taxing cigarettes more heavily.
general who negotiated the settlement say the This leaves three possible ways to justify
division of revenues was based on estimate of higher cigarette taxes: Claims that smoking
individual state’s Medicaid costs; other times generates a different cost spillover through
they argue it was unrelated to Medicaid. environmental or secondhand smoke; claims
Opinions seem to vary according to the con- that the government bears a significant por-
text in which they are voiced. The data show tion of the costs of smoking-related illness
no link between payments and Medicaid costs. through Medicaid or Medicare programs;
Straightforward taxes on cigarettes would and claims that, because smokers are addicted
be fairer and have a more neutral impact on and would in many cases be happier if they
competing manufacturers. But as we shall see, quit or smoked less, the current price of
more conventional taxes would be much cigarettes is lower than the economically effi-
cient price.
J ER E MY B U LOW is the Richard Stepp professor of The evidence on secondhand smoke is
economics at Stanford University’s Graduate School mixed. The surgeon general recently conclud-
of Business and is currently co-editor of the American
Economic Review. He was the director of the Federal Trade
ed that “the scientific evidence indicates there
Commission’s Bureau of Economics from 1998 to 2001. It is no risk-free level of exposure to second-
should be noted that he has worked as a paid consultant hand smoke.” On the other hand, a study by
to a small cigarette manufacturer (Xcaliber) that did not
participate in the tobacco settlement in legal challenges to
two academics, James Enstrom and Geoffrey
the settlement in Oklahoma and Kansas. Kabat, of 118,000 people in California over a

42 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 42 10/8/06 6:40:23 PM


Under the agreement,
smokers in some states
(including Georgia, Kentucky, North Carolina
and Virginia) are paying over $100 million
per year more for tobacco than the settlement
returns to their states’ coffers.

40-year period, published in the British Medi- health, public and private enterprises seem
cal Journal in 2003, found no measurable ef- within their rights to bar smoking on their
fect from passive smoking. A problem in such property, if only because of the distasteful
studies, which tend to focus on the health of smell. But today, with such bans so prevalent,
nonsmokers who live with smokers, is that it the remaining costs of secondhand smoke are
is hard to correct for other differences in be- overwhelmingly borne by spouses and other
havior that may affect health. To illustrate the family members. Applying compensatory
pitfall of not making such corrections, con- taxes to correct for cost spillovers within
sider the fact that people in Greece smoke households is difficult at best, as those who
©fogstock llc/age fotostock

much more and spend much less on health impose the cost and those who should be
care than Americans do – yet still live longer. compensated share family incomes.
That hardly means the Greeks benefit from While smokers do incur higher average
smoking. annual health care expenditures, and some of
Regardless of how one interprets the evi- these expenditures are borne by state and fed-
dence on the effects of secondhand smoke on eral governments, there is more to this part of

Fourth Quarter 2006 43

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 43 10/8/06 6:40:23 PM


tobacco settlement
the participating manufacturer operated in
the story, too. Smokers also have a shorter life the state. Kentucky collected a national tax of
expectancy, which reduces their likelihood of 6 cents per carton sold anywhere in the coun-
collecting both Medicare benefits and Social try, and so on. Those 55 taxes totaled about
Security payments in old age. A Harvard Law $4.30 per carton for the original participating
professor, W. Kip Viscusi, has estimated that manufacturers (Philip Morris, Reynolds, Lo-
smokers were already more than paying their rillard and Brown & Williamson) in 2004.
way through taxes at both the state and feder- Smaller companies that joined the agreement
al levels before they were subjected to the set- after it was signed by the four majors – known
tlement fees. Note, moreover, as “subsequent participating
that, since the time Viscusi made manufacturers” – were ex-
those estimates, state and feder- empted from making any pay-
al cigarette taxes have more than ments unless their future mar-
doubled. ket shares rose to a specified
It is surely true that many level over their 1997 shares.
people who smoke would be Only one of these smaller
happier if they quit, and that firms, Commonwealth Brands
higher cigarette prices do in- (the maker of USA Golds),
spire efforts to reduce consump- pays significant amounts into
tion. By the same token, teenag- the settlement pool.
ers may be less likely to make Also, in addition to the
the mistake of starting to smoke separate taxes for each state
if they face higher prices. These and territory under the agree-
“behavioral” arguments, while outside the ment, there is a supplemental fee on sales by
mainstream of economic analysis, should be the original participating manufacturers that
taken seriously. It is hard to argue, though, generates $500 million annually. All of this
that the settlement’s fee structure is the best revenue goes to the trial lawyers involved in
possible way (or even a good way) to attack the 1998 deal. Indeed, one of the many ironies
nicotine addiction. flowing from the tobacco agreement is that
some of this mega-bonanza goes to lawyers
the byzantine structure of the who were purportedly representing smokers
tobacco settlement – the folks who pay the costs of the settlement
The settlement and earlier similar deals with but receive none of the proceeds.
four other states (Florida, Minnesota, Missis- While the settlement was the deal of a life-
sippi and Texas) created 55 national taxes on time for the small tobacco companies (which
cigarettes – one for the benefit of each partic- collect fees under it but don’t have to pass on
ipating jurisdiction. For the master settle- the money to the states as long as their mar-
ment, a negotiating committee that included ket shares remain minimal) and for the trial
©najlah feanny/corbis

eight state attorneys general determined the lawyers (who receive what is effectively a tort
fees (tax rates) and exemptions. In 2004, for settlement contingency fee on what by any
example, New York collected a tax of about 45 other name is a tax increase), the results are
cents for every carton of cigarettes sold any- more mixed for the states and for smokers.
where in the country, regardless of whether On the one hand, New York and California

44 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 44 10/8/06 6:40:25 PM


make out like bandits on the distribution of tionally. That meant the state would receive
settlements. But it is a financial millstone for less than 50 cents in settlement money for
states like Kentucky and Oklahoma, which every dollar paid by its smokers, leaving Okla-
would be far better off if the formula were re- homa short by some $90 million a year by
placed with plain-vanilla state excise taxes 2004 compared to the potential revenues
they could keep in entirety. from an equal-sized state excise tax on ciga-
How did the settlement designers per- rettes. But that, of course, was still better than
suade the “losing” states to sign the agree- not signing, and falling short by over $150
ment? One view is that the states were simply million a year.
bamboozled: Given only a week from the time Big Tobacco was willing to agree to the set-
the settlement agreement became public to tlement’s fee system in return for five key pro-
join in, many state attorneys general may sim- visos. First, the companies wanted not just re-
ply not have had enough time to figure out lief from lawsuits by the states for any past ac-
what a bad deal they were accepting. The other tions, but relief from possible future actions
(nonexclusive) possibility is that the states as well. Second, they wanted their wholesalers
were coerced into signing. When a state (say, and retailers to be exempt from future suits,
Oklahoma) was called upon to sign the agree- ensuring that their products would continue
ment, it was given the following options: to be ubiquitously available. Wal-Mart, super-
1. Don’t sign. In this case, the agreement markets and other chain stores might decide
would have meant that Oklaho-
mans buying cigarettes would still
have paid fees (taxes) to every ju-
risdiction that did sign (over $4
S mokers were already
per carton in total), but the Okla- more than paying their way
homa state treasury wouldn’t get
a penny.
through taxes at both the
2. Sign, but do not pass the ac- state and federal levels
companying statutes designed to
deter new entry to the cigarette before they were subjected
industry. Again, this would mean
to the settlement fees.
that the state’s citizens would pay
all the agreement’s fees, but the
state would probably not get any money. not to sell cigarettes if they were concerned
3. Sign, and pass the enabling statutes as about being sued by the states. Third, the
written in the original agreement. This is the companies wanted the fees to be specific (vol-
option that all signers followed – though at ume-based) rather than ad valorem (a per-
least one had to rewrite its statute because its centage of value, like a sales tax). This gave an
legislature initially used a wording that the advantage to the more expensive, more heav-
big tobacco companies found unacceptable. ily marketed cigarette brands like Marlboro,
By signing the agreement and passing the Camel and Virginia Slims sold by the big
required legislation, Oklahoma, for example, companies.
was entitled to collect about 4 cents for every Fourth, Big Tobacco wanted provisions
carton the participating companies sell na- to ensure that small cigarette companies

Fourth Quarter 2006 45

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 45 10/8/06 6:40:26 PM


tobacco settlement
for 25 years against the possibility that the
remained small. (More about this later.) Fifth, states would win legal judgments against the
Big Tobacco wanted to deter entry by new company.
manufacturers that chose not to join the set- But the treatment of participating and
tlement – the so-called “nonparticipating nonparticipating companies was not entirely
manufacturers” – imposing additional costs parallel. While a nonparticipating manufac-
on these firms by requiring them to make turer’s costs within the states that it operated
hefty deposits to escrow accounts that would in were similar to what they would have been
cover the potential costs of future liability as members of the settlement agreement, its
suits. The escrow-enabling statutes and the national costs would be lower. That’s because
potential litigation exposure to wholesalers the settlement had to be constructed around
and retailers who sold cigarettes from the a set of individual state statutes, after Con-
nonparticipating manufacturers also provid- gress refused to pass enabling legislation.
ed a stick for getting existing small cigarette (The Congressional deal collapsed in part be-
manufacturers to join, complementing the cause some Republicans tried to limit the
carrot of the settlement exemptions they were contingency fees paid to the trial lawyers.)
offered. And the nonparticipating manufacturers
While the nonparticipating manufacturers could therefore not be forced to open escrow
are often portrayed by cartel members as out- accounts and make payments in states where
laws unwilling to do their civic duty, their real they did not do business. By contrast, compa-
crime is that they did not sell cigarettes prior nies that joined the agreement were legally
to the settlement. These companies are not el- bound to pay all the states.
igible for the generous subsidies provided to Thus, if a nonparticipating manufacturer
incumbent small companies in the form of only sold cigarettes in 25 percent of the coun-
partial exemption from the obligation to pass try, it would have to pay those states roughly
on the settlement fees they collect. Thus, the the same $1 per carton as would Big Tobacco
only way these entrants could compete effec- – but nothing at all to the states in which it
tively was to stay out of the agreement. Not did not operate. This, in addition to the fact
surprisingly, then, in the first five years of the that the major cigarette companies chose to
deal, few new firms decided to join. And those raise prices by much more than their costs
that did typically went bankrupt. under the settlement, made it possible for the
Here is roughly how the state escrow stat- nonparticipating manufacturers to grab
utes worked originally: a company just begin- about 8 percent of the cigarette market in
ning to sell cigarettes that chose to sign the terms of unit volume.
agreement would have to pay 4 cents a carton To understand how significant this 8 per-
for every carton sold anywhere in the United cent market share was (and how sensitive to
States to the State of Oklahoma. If the com- price some smokers had become in choosing
pany chose not to sign the agreement, it brands), remember that the major retailing
would be classified as a non-participating chains were unwilling to stock nonparticipat-
manufacturer, and therefore, under the model ing manufacturers’ brands because it would
statute passed by the Oklahoma legislature, have made them vulnerable to liability suits
would instead have to pay approximately the by the states. As a result, the only places bar-
same amount into escrow – there to be held gain-minded smokers could find nonpartici-

46 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 46 10/8/06 6:40:26 PM


WINNERS AND LOSERS
MSA REVENUES FOR 2004, $MILLION CONSUMER MSA PAYMENTS FOR 2004, $MILLION

0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800

Alabama 101 Montana 26


171 27
Alaska 21 Nebraska 37
18 47
Arizona 92 Nevada 38
103 68
Arkansas 51 New Hampshire 41
95 83
California 793 New Jersey 240
509 161
Colorado 85 New Mexico 37
120 29
Connecticut 115 New York 793
80 281
Delaware 25 North Carolina 145
62 348
D.C. 38 North Dakota 23
9 18
Florida 380 Ohio 313
547 426
Georgia 152 Oklahoma 64
256 155
Hawaii 37 Oregon 71
26 85
Idaho 23 Pennsylvania 357
36 369
Illinois 289 Rhode Island 45
329 28
Indiana 127 South Carolina 73
262 166
Iowa 54 South Dakota 22
107 23
Kansas 52 Tennessee 152
67 244
Kentucky 109 Texas 501
311 535
Louisiana 140 Utah 28
167 35
Maine 48 Vermont 26
41 19
Maryland 140 Virginia 127
117 312
Massachusetts 251 Washington 128
122 100
Michigan 270 West Virginia 55
299 82
Minnesota 176 Wisconsin 129
160 167
Mississippi 117 Wyoming 15
110 10
Missouri 141 US Territories 74
259 5

sources: PriceWaterhouse MSA Documents, State Sales Data

pating manufacturers’ cigarettes were in The ability of nonparticipating manufac-


mom-and-pop stores, smoke shops and other turers to keep their costs low (along with the
small, less-convenient outlets that don’t have inclination of a surprisingly large number of
the deep pockets tort plaintiffs covet. smokers to abandon brand-name cigarettes

Fourth Quarter 2006 47

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 47 10/8/06 6:40:27 PM


tobacco settlement
That puts the nonparticipating manufac-
in favor of cheap, unadvertised generics) ex- turers in a financially untenable position:
plains why the big exemptions granted to their settlement-related costs are now as high
small participating companies by the agree- as those of participating manufacturers, but
ment were needed to keep them within the the large retailers are not willing to stock their
cartel. Without the exemptions these compa- products because of ongoing liability con-
nies might well have been better off not join- cerns. Indeed, it seems unlikely that the non-

By framing the deal as the grand settlement of a legal


claim, the lawyers got contingency fees totaling bil-
lions in the first five years of the agreement and con-
tinuing indefinitely at a rate of $500 million annually.

ing, even though joining enabled them to participating manufacturers will be able to
market their cigarettes much more widely. remain in business – a reality that hardly up-
Consider Liggett, which, thanks to small- sets Big Tobacco.
manufacturer exemptions, had an average Wait; it gets worse. If a nonparticipating
settlement cost of 37 cents per carton in 2005, manufacturer cries uncle and applies for
saving the company over $160 million com- membership in the settlement agreement, it
pared to what it would have had to pay with- must sign a pledge to pay back any money it
out exemptions. But that still suited the big- saved by not being a participant in the past.
four tobacco companies, which no longer had But that just isn’t going to happen; the com-
to worry that Liggett would chip away at their panies don’t have this money because they
market share. After all, under the agreement, passed along the savings to cigarette buyers
Liggett would have had to pay the full settle- before the escrow rules were changed in 2003.
ment fee – over $4 a carton – on incremental
sales that came at the expense of the market the rationale
share of the major manufacturers. for the msa structure
Under pressure from the participating To understand why the states chose to make a
manufacturers, who feared the rise of the non- deal with the cigarette companies rather than
participating manufacturers and their no- just raise cigarette taxes to cover alleged ciga-
name brands, the state escrow statutes were rette-related medical costs, do as good report-
modified in 2003. The sums that nonpartici- ers do: follow the money. Had the lawsuits
pating manufacturers must leave in escrow that the states brought against tobacco mak-
no longer depends on the number of states in ers been dropped and the state legislatures
which they sell cigarettes. Hence there is no simply passed tax increases on cigarettes to
longer much cost advantage to a strategy of cover their smoking-related medical costs, the
staying out of the settlement agreement and lawyers working for the states would have
operating in only a handful of states. gotten, at most, hourly fees for their services.

48 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 48 10/8/06 6:40:27 PM


By framing the deal as the grand settlement of DOING EXCEPTIONALLY WELL
a legal claim, the lawyers got contingency fees BY DOING GOOD(?)
totaling billions in the first five years of the Since 1998, an arbitration panel has awarded some $12
billion in fees to lawyers who represented states in the
agreement and continuing indefinitely at a litigation against Big Tobacco.
rate of $500 million annually.
AWARDS
Others benefited as well from this framing. STATE TO LAWYERS LAW FIRMS

First, Big Tobacco wanted a national deal that Mississippi $1.4 billion Scruggs; Ness Motley
would spare it from being nickeled-and- Florida $3.4 billion Scruggs; Ness Motley;
9 other firms
dimed in lawsuits by individual states. The Texas $3.3 billion Scruggs; Ness Motley;
only way to force all the states to join was by 5 other firms
taxing consumers in all states and then giving Massachusetts $775 million Ness Motley; Lieff
Cabraser; 4 other firms
money back to individual states only on the Hawaii $90 million Scruggs; Ness Motley;
condition that they sign on the dotted line. 4 other firms
Illinois $121 million Lieff Cabraser;Hagens
But since one state cannot impose taxes on Berman; 2 other firms
business transactions in other states – New Iowa $85 million Ness Motley; 6 other firms
York sales and excise taxes must be based on Louisiana $575 million Scruggs; Lieff Cabraser;
15 other firms
New York (not national) sales – it was in the Kansas $54 million Scruggs; Ness Motley;
companies’ interests to structure the pay- 2 other firms
Ohio $265 million Scruggs; Ness Motley;
ments as the costs of settling a lawsuit rather 5 other firms
than as taxes. Second, the structure of the set- Oklahoma $250 million Scruggs; Ness Motley;
4 other firms
tlement allowed states with proactive attor- Puerto Rico $75 million Scruggs; Ness Motley;
neys general to set up a financial distribution 2 other firms
schedule that reserved disproportionate New Mexico $25 million 2 local firms
South Carolina $83 million Ness Motley
shares for their own states. Utah $65 million Ness Motley;
The politicians involved had two extra in- Giaque Crockett
California $638 million Lieff Cabraser; Millberg
centives to go the settlement route. It sounds Weiss; 2 others
better to say you negotiated a large settlement Michigan $450 million Scruggs; Ness Motley
from the death-dealers of tobacco than to say
you imposed an equally large tax increase on source: The American Lawyer, Dec. 2002
long-suffering smokers. What’s more, by notes: Lieff Cabraser = Lieff, Cabraser, Heimann & Bernstein of San Francisco, CA;
Scruggs = Scruggs, Millette, Lawson, Bozeman & Dent of Pascagoula, MS; Ness
claiming that the revenues were attributable Motley = Ness, Motley, Loadholt, Richardson & Poole of Charleston, SC
to a one-time settlement paid out over de- The head of the Scruggs firm is Richard Scruggs, who first hit big money in mass
torts litigation against asbestos makers. He is the brother-in-law of Sen. Trent
cades rather than to a tax increase, states were Lott of Mississippi.
able to borrow against future revenues and
spend the cash immediately without violating as well as hourly rates, were heavily padded by
constitutional requirements to balance their reading into the record of the cases in differ-
budgets each year. ent states the same testimony over and over
again. But the subsidies that the settlement
the msa’s “success stories” created for the small participating tobacco
The egregious sums paid to the trial lawyers companies (Liggett, in particular) are equally
as part of the settlement – up to $92,000 an unconscionable. After all, at its peak, Liggett
hour in some cases – have been well publi- sold more cigarettes than Phillip Morris. If
cized. Perhaps less well known is that hours, the responsibility for smoking deaths lies

Fourth Quarter 2006 49

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 49 10/8/06 6:40:28 PM


tobacco settlement
sider that before the agreement was negotiat-
with the companies that addicted the smokers ed, the entire market value of Liggett stock
when they were youths, then arguably Liggett had fallen to just $37 million.
should be responsible for a significant part of Some of the other “success stories” spawned
the damages – certainly more than its current by the settlement are equally remarkable.
share of total sales. With exemptions under the settlement based
on the maximum of 125 percent of 1997 sales
or 100 percent of 1998 sales, the little dis-
count-cigarette maker Medallion did what
was necessary to quadruple its volume from
1997 to 1998. The owner, Gary Hall, thus ac-
quired exemptions worth over $20 million
per year. He later sold his company to Liggett
for $110 million. Liggett described the trans-
action price in its SEC filings as $107 million
for the exemptions and less than $3 million
for the actual business.
Premier International Holdings more than
doubled its cigarette sales in 1998, thereby ac-
quiring exemptions worth $19 million per
year. Premier then proceeded to sell more cig-
arettes than were covered by its exemption.
But the company sharply underreported sales,
claiming it owed $287,000 for 1999 to 2002
but ultimately admitting that it owed $46.5
million. While Premier was unable to pay off
all this debt at once, it was able to provide
what the state attorneys general regarded as
sufficiently good collateral to allow it to repay
over time and thereby avoid being shut down.
Just what was that collateral? The company’s
One would expect companies that admit- ongoing settlement subsidy.
ted to committing major torts that killed Commonwealth Tobacco, at the time con-
hundreds of thousands of people would be trolled by Brian M. Kelly, received the second
ecstatic about getting off without any sacrifice largest bundle of MSA fee exemptions. Its
on the part of their executives or their stock- market share was largely based on lesser
holders. But Liggett wanted – and got – much brands that it had acquired from Brown &
more as an inducement to sign. Philip Morris Williamson in 1995. Kelly went on to sell the
was muscled into agreeing to buy four dying company, and last year was the only Kentuck-
Liggett brands for $300 million. In addition, ian to make the Forbes 400. He may also have
©ed kashi/corbis

Liggett was given exemptions from the Master been the only person on the list to create a
Settlement Agreement fees that save it over fortune by starting a company in a low-tech,
$125 million per year. Not bad when you con- declining manufacturing industry in the

50 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 50 10/8/06 6:40:29 PM


1990s and building a modest market share in ries: irrational impulse purchases, and more
the commodity end of his business. rational purchases where the consumer
Finally, since 1997, the big tobacco compa- weighs the costs and benefits of his decisions.
nies have been able to raise prices by about $2 There is a consensus on banning cigarette
per carton above and beyond all cost increas- purchases by minors because everyone agrees
es linked to tax increases and settlement pay- they lack the maturity to make good decisions
ments. For perspective, that increase was about about risking addiction. We also ban certain
equal to the entire cost of producing the ciga- kinds of cigarette marketing, both to reduce
rettes. While it is impossible to say whether the appeal of cigarettes to young people and
these startling increases in profit margins in a to reduce the likelihood of triggering impulse
business with significant overcapacity were consumption in already-addicted adults.
solely attributable to market power created by
the settlement, it is certainly the case that the
big companies would have done much worse
had the states imposed conventional ad valor- By helping ensure that
em tax increases on cigarettes. cigarettes continue to
public health consequences of be sold ubiquitously,
msa taxation
The core provision of the settlement agree-
the agreement makes
ment gives participating cigarette makers and it that much harder for
their distributors broad protection from legal
liability linked to smoking in exchange for col- addicts to avoid
lecting huge sums of money from smokers impulse purchases.
and passing it on to the states. Was this deal
with the devil a good one in terms of public
policy? On the other hand, there is no political
The legal protection ensured that cigarettes pressure for banning smoking by adults in
would continue to be widely available. With- private. All told, these policies are consistent
out freedom from lawsuits, it is at least possi- with the principle that deterrence should
ble that the big retailers like Wal-Mart, which focus on impulse purchases rather than on
do not touch nonparticipating manufactur- calculated purchases by adults.
ers’ cigarettes today because of the potential The easy availability of cigarettes (or lack
liability, would have decided that selling thereof) is an important factor in controlling
brand-name cigarettes was not worth the risk, impulse purchases. This rings true, for exam-
either. Consumers would then find cigarettes ple, to people who do not buy ice cream be-
much less convenient to buy. cause they will inevitably eat it in one sitting.
Hence it is possible that the agreement Without the settlement’s legal protections,
took us in exactly the wrong direction. As the smokers might no longer be able to find ciga-
economists Douglas Bernheim of Stanford rettes at the major stores where they do most of
and Antonio Rangel of Cal Tech have argued, their shopping. Thus, by helping ensure that
we can think of the purchase of addictive cigarettes continue to be sold ubiquitously,
products as falling broadly into two catego- the agreement makes it that much harder for

Fourth Quarter 2006 51

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 51 10/8/06 6:40:29 PM


tobacco settlement The settlement
addicts to avoid impulse purchases. while it gave the
Price, on the other hand, is probably a sig-
nificant factor in reducing calculated pur- source of income
chases, but probably has less impact on im-
pulse purchases. Indeed, much of economics
is based on the notion that higher prices tend
to curb purchases by rational consumers. So
higher prices should lead to a decline in smok-
ing by those making considered calculations.
By contrast, a smoker carrying a nicotine
jones is unlikely to be sensitive to price. In-
deed, the fact that smoking is fairly insensitive
to price – a 10 percent price increase typically
causes only a 3 to 4 percent reduction in con-
sumption – is consistent with the idea that we
might do better to attack smoking by making
it inconvenient to buy cigarettes or by re-
stricting marketing activities, than by raising
prices with taxes or fees.
Attempting to price smokers out of the
market has another drawback: taxes on ciga-
rettes are highly regressive, because smokers
disproportionately have lower incomes. Ciga-
rette taxes could be made a bit less regressive
by making taxes proportional to the price of
the cigarettes, rather than the volume of to-
bacco sales since the poor disproportionately
smoke deep-discount cigarettes. But Big To-
bacco would bitterly oppose such changes be- rettes and the expensive, heavily marketed
cause most of the cigarettes it sells are higher cigarettes is like exempting the marketing
priced branded products. component of the cigarette price from tax,
Finally, if the focus of cigarette taxes is to and may explain why a Justice Department
deter young smokers, taxes in proportion to report concluded that the agreement has
value make much more sense. The public failed to reduce the big companies’ marketing
health community long ago concluded that expenditures.
young smokers overwhelmingly bought pre- Ideally, then, cigarette sales should be re-
mium brands because kids are particularly stricted to outlets that are experts in making
susceptible to image marketing. So for any their services inaccessible and unappealing.
given tax rate on cigarettes, a tax in propor- My own Swiftian fix would be to turn over
tion to value will tax the cigarettes that kids sales to the nice folks who run the Immigra-
smoke more heavily. Imposing the same per- tion and Naturalization Service. A more prac-
carton tax on both the cheap, generic ciga- tical alternative, perhaps, would be to restrict

52 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 52 10/8/06 6:40:29 PM


preserved tobacco companies’ profits,
trial lawyers an incredibly large ongoing
gouged from the hides of smokers.

retail transactions to state-owned stores that In reality, the settlement preserved tobacco
have little incentive to generate volume, as a companies’ profits, while it gave the trial law-
number of states (among them Idaho, Mon- yers an incredibly large ongoing source of in-
tana, North Carolina, Ohio, Pennsylvania, come gouged from the hides of smokers and
Utah and Washington) do with liquor. handed state politicians bragging rights as
Davids to Big Tobacco’s Goliath.
will we ever be rid of the msa? While some states came out ahead finan-
jessica persson/afp/getty images

Few people trust tobacco companies, trial cially compared to the sums they would have
lawyers or politicians. But somehow when the garnered from equivalent state excise taxes,
three groups got together and spoke with one the states lost as a group because they were
voice they were able to convince most people forced to share the windfall with the trial law-
– particularly nonsmokers who benefit from yers and a handful of smaller settlement-
higher cigarette tax revenue – that the settle- favored companies like Liggett.
ment had achieved a noble public health goal. The confluence of such muscular special

Fourth Quarter 2006 53

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 53 10/8/06 6:40:31 PM


tobacco settlement
claims, the states may finally come to realize
interests that benefit from the agreement has that Big Tobacco is not a docile ally and de-
made it difficult to challenge the agreement in cide they would be better off with legally bul-
court or in legislatures. Smokers don’t have letproof excise taxes than with the settlement.
the financial resources or the organization. Before it comes to that, however, the manu-
And while the nonparticipating manufactur- facturers will likely offer a deal foregoing all
ers are challenging the settlement agreement or part of these rebates in return for even
because the new structure of the escrow stat- tougher measures to keep newcomers out of
utes is putting them out of business, the fi- the cigarette business.
nancial squeeze makes it tough for them to The third and best hope is that legislators
spend seriously on court fights. in the states whose smokers pay more in fees
than the states get back from the settlement
will come to realize how badly they were
The states may finally taken in 1998 and devise ways to undermine
the agreement. For example, Oklahoma could
decide they would be pass a tax equal to the minimum of the na-
tional settlement payment per carton for sales
better off with legally
in the state and the state payment under the
bulletproof excise taxes settlement for every carton sold anywhere in
the country.
than with the settlement. Since the state’s settlement payment is so
low, the effective tax would be the state pay-
So is there any hope that the master settle- ment times national sales for virtually every
ment agreement can be undone? I see three company, and would effectively double Okla-
possible avenues to this end. homa’s share.
First, the structure of the settlement, which Alternatively, Oklahoma could sue to pre-
creates what must be considered either a set of vent the companies that signed the agreement
national taxes implemented by states or a set from basing payments to other states on sales
of collusive cost-sharing agreements that raise within Oklahoma, arguing that each
prices for consumers, would almost certainly state should get back all the fees
fall afoul of the courts if the product in ques- paid by its own smokers. The
tion was anything other than tobacco. And it is state would have a very strong
possible that court challenges by the nonpartic- economic case and, with the
ipating manufacturers will prove successful. home court advantage, an excel-
Second, the big tobacco companies are lent chance of winning before
now suing to have $1.3 billion returned to state-elected judges. Indeed,
them by the states. They are invoking a provi- once losing states realize that
©nation wong/zefa/corbis

sion of the agreement that requires states to they have a significant finan-
compensate them if they lose market share as cial interest in dumping the
a result of ineffective enforcement of the es- agreement or changing the
crow provisions designed to undermine the distribution formula, they
competitive edge of the nonparticipating should be able to rid
manufacturers. If the companies win these themselves of it. M

54 The Milken Institute Review

79925_MR_40_54.r1.indd 54 10/8/06 6:40:31 PM

S-ar putea să vă placă și