Sunteți pe pagina 1din 8

ISSUE 2010/04

JUNE 2010
bruegelpolicybrief

POWER TO THE PEOPLE


OF EUROPE
by Georg Zachmann SUMMARY The European Union has taken steps towards the completion of
Research Fellow at Bruegel
georg.zachmann@bruegel.org
the single electricity market, and thus to reduce costs and boost
competitiveness. But there is still much to do. The growing share of inter-
mittent wind power and the relocation of load and generation centres has
put aging networks under severe pressure. In addition, electricity systems
operate at national level while the physical network is international.
Consequently, at certain borders, almost half of the electricity flows from
high to low price areas, and urgently needed transmission lines are not built
because costs and benefits are asymmetrically distributed across borders.
Current cautious plans for more international network planning and better
coordination of national markets will not tap the full efficiency potential.
POLICY CHALLENGE

The challenge of creating a single electricity market is twofold: available


transmission capacity must be increased and the operation of existing net-
works and power plants must be improved. Only EU-level electricity network
Decreasing transmission capacity design can deliver the required net-
jeopardises the single market work infrastructure. The European
Increase of net Commission should therefore continue
transfer capacity
to push for binding European network
+10%
-50% NL 0% planning, based on both technical and
Decrease of net
transfer capacity
+1% cost-benefit analyses, while member
+2%

states need to move away from the


0%

1%
+5 BE
-16
% GERMANY artificial setting of single national
0%
prices. Electricity prices must be able
+1
FRANCE -46% to take into account the physical con-
straints of meshed international net-
-20%

-
-50%

0% works, resulting in market-led optimi-


%
-50

-34% CH
-7%

sation of the operation of the system


SPAIN and ultimately reducing prices.
Source: ENTSO-E. Figure shows change in net transfer capacities
between winter 2004/05 and winter 2009/10 in direction of arrow.
POWER TO THE PEOPLE OF EUROPE

THE FUNDAMENTAL IMPORTANCE market integration does promise and extension of cross-border net-
02 OF ELECTRICITY to modern
economies is shown by the fact
significant efficiency gains1. As
well as boosting competitiveness,
works. Section 3 sets out the chal-
lenges and presents the changes
bruegelpolicybrief

that final sales of the power sector a SEM would improve supply secu- planned to the organisation of the
represent approximately three per- rity and facilitate the integration of international electricity trade and
cent of European Union GDP. The renewables into the EU energy mix. the planning and financing of net-
price of electricity is not only rele- work connections. The final sec-
vant for direct consumer purchas- Pivotal decisions in this policy tion presents our recommenda-
ing power and welfare. Power is a area will be made this year. Apart tions on the planning and opera-
production factor that is difficult to from the changing of the political tion of the electricity network.
replace and the cost of which thus guard at the Commission, the
determines the competitiveness mandate and powers of newly es- 1 THE SEM VISION AND
of many production processes. tablished institutions (the PROGRESS TO DATE
And – in contrast to other forms of European Network of Transmission
energy – electricity is mainly gen- System Operators for Electricity In broad terms, a fully functioning
erated domestically. Thus, effi- and the Agency for Cooperation of SEM would be a level playing field
ciency gains in the electricity Energy Regulators) will be defined, where, at any given time,
sector could boost Europe’s and decisions will be taken on mid- electricity demand is met by the
competitiveness. term infrastructure plans, which most economic2 power plants irre-
might result in the locking-in of spective of the member state in
There is nothing new in attempting long-term investment paths. which they are located. Taking a
to reap the benefits of completing long-term perspective, the SEM im-
the single electricity market In this policy brief we will analyse plies that investments in networks
(SEM). The European Commission to what extent the SEM has been and generation assets should be
has been striving to do this since completed in terms of market designed to decrease the overall
the beginning of the 1990s. Most design and physical cost of the system. Compared to a
recently, the Commission's infrastructure. Furthermore, we system of national electricity mar-
EU2020 strategy ask if the envisaged kets (with occasional cross-border
paper (European ‘Efficiency gains in reforms will tackle trade of some surplus electricity)
Commission, 2010)
the electricity sector the two major chal- an integrated EU electricity market
1. Partial evidence sug-
gests that the efficien-
cy gains could be huge: explicitly refers to the lenges that lie ahead would have obvious advantages.
deep integration of the need ‘to complete the
could boost in the electricity First, the cost of operation of the
internal energy mar- Europe’s
four German electricity
market zones alone sector, namely in- power-plant fleet would be re-
would reduce the ket’ as a central plank competitiveness. ’ creasing the available duced, because expensive produc-
annual cost of
electricity by an esti- in putting the EU on a transmission capaci- tion in one country – which might
mated €205 million ‘green growth’ track. The ty and improving the use of exist- be optimal in a purely national set-
(Bundesnetzagentur,
2009, p.69) to €400 Commission asserts that further ing networks and power plants. ting – would be replaced by cheap-
million (BMU, 2009). integration of European electricity er generation in another country.
2. In this sentence, markets can boost GDP by 0.5-0.6 The next section considers why Second, the exercise of market
‘economic’ should be
understood as a very percent (European Commission, the SEM is important and the power by national incumbents
comprehensive concept 2007). The somewhat simplistic policy steps towards it that have would become more difficult as
encompassing the min-
imising of short and analysis, based on an assumed been taken so far. The subsequent the market grows and foreign
long-term costs subject
to given technical and
average electricity-price reduction section presents empirical evi- competitors punish the withhold-
legal limitations (net- of 20 percent, seems over opti- dence on the progress towards the ing of capacity by acquiring
work capacity, emis-
sion caps, reliability
mistic. That said, and although it is SEM in terms of price convergence, market shares. Third, the need for
provisions, etc). difficult to quantify, further transmission-capacity utilisation transmission and generation
POWER TO THE PEOPLE OF EUROPE

assets would decline in an inte- national support schemes for and network capacity may be con-
grated market because a larger
market would render some reserve
renewables and possibly the
strategic behaviour of market par-
strained, most EU member states
(Italy being one exception) apply a
03

bruegelpolicybrief
capacity redundant. Finally, it ticipants have prevented the de- single domestic electricity price.
might be cheaper to integrate re- velopment of a fully functioning
newable energy, because national single electricity market. In terms of operation, investment
supply variability is somewhat incentives and the international
offset in an international system. 2 HOW INTEGRATED ARE trade in electricity, this system of
EUROPEAN ELECTRICITY linking countries that have single
However, electricity has some MARKETS? national prices has obvious flaws.
unique characteristics that make As each power plant in a country
designing functioning markets In the member states’ electricity obtains the same price whether it
challenging. Electricity delivery re- markets, domestic incumbents is located close to a major industri-
quires the existence of networks; compete to sell electricity with for- al consumer or in a remote area,
though electricity is a commodity, eign incumbents and some inde- system operators have the costly
it is produced by very different pendent power producers. Apart duty of rebalancing the system in
technologies; it is not possible to from longer-term contracts, case of internal congestion. The
store it cost-effectively; and con- electricity is traded on the day- cheap power plant in the remote
sumers are less willing, in compar- ahead market. This market, with area might be asked to reduce pro-
ison to other commodities, to its hourly prices, serves as a refer- duction while the more expensive
reduce their consumption in peri- ence for scheduling power plants. plant in the industrial area might
ods of high prices. Consequently, In the day-ahead market (typically increase its supply. Although, in
EU countries have been reluctant a power exchange) a seller/buyer theory, this approach might come
to move away from the traditional bids for how much electricity he close to optimal, in practice the
model of vertically integrated wishes to deliver/order at a certain process is often inferior to a
national monopolies and towards price. The market clears at the in- market solution that allows for re-
EU-wide market liberalisation. tersection of the supply and gional price differences4.
demand curve. Markets in different
By and large it has been pressure countries produce different prices. Another flaw in current arrange-
applied by the EU’s single market Thus, taking electricity from a low- ments is the existence of skewed
policy which has moved liberalisa- price country to a high-price coun- investment incentives for con-
tion of national electricity markets try is profitable. If transmission sumers and producers. These lead
forward. The EU’s efforts to develop lines were unlimited, arbitrage to underinvestment by consumers
a SEM have taken the form of three should lead to a single European close to cheap plants and underin-
legislative packages (1998, 2003 market with a single European vestment by generators close to 3. See Pollitt (2009),
and 2009). Many analysts consid- price. However, transmission lines high-demand centres. Finally, ef- Buglione et al (2009)
and Bunn and
er that the first two packages within and between countries are fective international linking of Zachmann (2009).
made only limited progress. not unlimited. Consequently, on such systems is very difficult. 4. One obvious draw-
According to a European most borders, the valuable right to back is that cheap
power plants are com-
Commission sector inquiry, use cross-border transmission Electrons passing through interna- pensated for agreeing
opened in 2005 (European lines is auctioned off. Thus, tional electricity networks follow to reduce their output.
This creates opportuni-
Commission, 2007a), and aca- electricity prices between the complicated physics of ties for gaming and
demic analyses3, an inadequate countries differ. It may be noted meshed alternating-current grids pricing mechanisms
often overcompensate
electricity grid, defective rules for that, despite the fact that, within and do not respect price-zone bor- cheap power plants,
allocation of the right to use cross- countries, transporting electricity ders. Correspondingly, scheduling perversely increasing
the incentive to locate
border electricity lines, differing over long distances incurs losses, power plants on the basis of to remote areas.
POWER TO THE PEOPLE OF EUROPE

national prices without taking into entials were common between cost in both systems. In reality,
04 account the real physical net-
works within and between
2005 and 2009. In the electricity
market as currently structured,
however, electricity often flows
against the price differential. In the
bruegelpolicybrief

countries makes it necessary for decreasing differences between German-Dutch case, electricity
the system operator to take non- national hourly electricity prices flowed from the high price area to
market measures to ensure could be a sign of greater market the low price area for 49 percent of
system stability5. This is illustrated efficiency and/or increasing com- total hours in 2009 (Figure 1). At
by two obvious inefficiencies. mercially available transmission the German-French border this oc-
First, cross-border transmission capacity. However, Nitsche et al curred for 46 percent of total
lines are rarely fully utilised de- (2009) found that German hours. This illustrates the flaws of
spite persisting price differentials. electricity spot prices in 60-90 a system based on coupling large
Second, electricity very often percent of instances differed by national zones that face internal
flows from high- to low-price more than five percent from the congestion.
5. In 2009 the areas6. Overall, the current system price in almost all neighbouring
Commission opened an- is light years away from the theo- countries. In addition, the absolute Third, physical interconnections
titrust proceedings
against Swedish retically optimal use of European annual average price differences have not developed substantially
electricity transmission power plants and transmission in 2009 for almost all of these in recent years. Figure 2 shows
system operator
Svenska Kraftnät (SvK) lines that would characterise a market combinations exceeded the net transfer capacities from
for having limited inter- fully functioning SEM. their corresponding 2004 value9. and to Germany between 2005
connector capacity for
electricity exports. SvK Thus, recent reforms have failed to and 2009. While the import capac-
contended that export Despite institutional progress be- produce a consistent reduction in ity remained constant, the export
curtailments were nec-
essary to alleviate inter- tween 2005 and 20097, we argue, price differentials that would point capacity decreased by more than
nal congestion. using the case of the systemically to increasing market integration. 15 percent. The absence of
6. One country’s
electricity flows might
important German market8, that progress in Germany’s cross-
loop through other progress has been limited in the Second, price differentials are border transmission capacity is
countries, eg electricity
produced in north
last five years. We base our claim almost unrelated to capacity usage. representative of the EU-wide pic-
German wind plants goes on three observations: In an integrated market, as long as ture. Between 2005 and 2009, the
via Poland to southern
Germany, though lines are not fully used, the price average net transfer import capac-
Poland’s electricity price First, prices in the countries that differential should be zero while, as ity of all countries in the European
is lower than Germany’s.
border Germany have not con- soon as congestion occurs (at full transmission system decreased
7. For example the
national implementation verged significantly with German capacity), the price differential de- by more than 15 percent. This is
of the 2003 directive; prices, and high hourly price differ- pends on the difference in marginal mainly due to the need for
the installation of a
national regulatory au-
thority in Germany in
2005; market coupling Figure 1: Hourly price differentials and corresponding electricity flows in 2009
between France,
Belgium and the Price differentials (in €) and flows at the German-French border Price differentials (in €) and flows at the German-Dutch border
Netherlands in 2006; €150 €150
and the 2008 merger of
French and German €100 €100
power exchanges.
8. The German market is Higher French price €50 Higher Dutch price €50
central to European
market integration be- 0 0
cause it is directly con- -4000 -3000 -2000 -1000 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 -4000 -3000 -2000 -1000 0 1000 2000 3000 4000
nected to 10 foreign
Higher German price -€50 Higher German price -€50
electricity zones.
9. We note that -€100 -€100
increased correlation or Electricity flow Electricity flow Electricity flow Electricity flow
cointegration are not a (MWh) FR to DE (MWh) DE to FR (MWh) NL to DE (MWh) DE to NL
-€150 -€150
sign of electricity
market integration
Source: Bruegel based on data from EEX, Powernext, APX and ENTSO-E. MWh = megawatt hours.
POWER TO THE PEOPLE OF EUROPE

increased security margins for


cross-border trade because of
growing shares of intermittent re-
Figure 2: Net transfer capacities from/to Germany in megawatts,

20,000
2004/05-2009/10 05

bruegelpolicybrief
newable production. Thus, de- 19,000
creasing availability of cross- 18,000
border transmission for commer- 17,000
cial operations becomes an in-
16,000
creasingly limiting factor for
15,000
market integration.
14,000
From Germany
In conclusion, the remaining inter- 13,000
To Germany
national price differentials, the in- 12,000
2004/05

2005

2005/06

2006

2006/07

2007

2007/08

2008

2008/09

2009

2009/10
Winter

Summer

Winter

Summer

Winter

Summer

Winter

Summer

Winter

Summer

Winter
sufficient response of electricity
flows to price signals and non-in-
creasing cross-border transmis- Source: BRUEGEL based on data from ENTSO-E.

sion capacity demonstrate that in graphic distribution of generation congestion in Europe. Thus, to
the last five years progress to- in central-western Europe. This de- avoid a deterioration of the current
wards a single market for velopment will challenge the trans- congestion situation, significant
electricity has been limited. mission systems, which saw their investment in European transmis-
last significant construction boom sion networks is needed.
3 CHALLENGES AND PLANNED in the 1960s and 1970s (as
CHANGES shown by Figure 3), when they The extension of electricity grids
carried electricity from the large is, however, still jointly decided by
The SEM faces two challenges: in- thermal and nuclear power plants national transmission system op-
creasing the available transmis- built at that time. As a conse- erators and regulators based on
sion capacity and improving the quence of the longer distances be- mainly technical (ie not econom-
use of existing networks and tween renewable generation sites ic) criteria. In this process the pos-
power plants. and load centres, national and re- itive and negative effects of
gional imbalances will increase. national network investment on
Increasing investment in intercon- Through the peculiarities of other countries’ electricity sys-
nection is needed because the electricity flows this could lead to tems are insufficiently taken into
commercially available transmis- an increase in the general level of account. Electricity lines that
sion capacity will otherwise de-
crease for three reasons. First, the Figure 3: Annual average increase in length of 220-400kV
increasing share of intermittent transmission lines in 16 European countries
7%
wind power will require even
higher safety margins. As these 6%

must be taken into account in the 5%


calculation of commercially avail-
4%
able transmission capacity, the
latter will shrink. Second, national 3%
and cross-border infrastructure is
2%
ageing and thus becoming less re-
liable. Third, the massive shift in 1%

generation mix (the scaling-up of 0%


1975-79 1979-89 1989-99 2000-03
renewables) leads to a new geo-
Source: International Energy Agency (2005).
POWER TO THE PEOPLE OF EUROPE

would increase cross-border trans- bottom-up approach underpin- cross-border interconnectors,


06 fer capacity and thereby global
welfare are not being built because
ning national or regional invest-
ment plans with top-down
they will be unable to incen-
tivise the construction of the
bruegelpolicybrief

the national regulators do not take policy goals (primarily the EU’s domestic transmission lines
into account welfare gains in other so-called ‘20-20-20’ green that are necessary to remove
zones10. Thus, those investments target). However, the absence cross-border bottlenecks.
are typically not optimal with re- of formal obligations on grid
spect to the SEM. users to provide the informa- In order to increase the available
tion necessary to calculate transmission capacities, it will not
To resolve this issue the EU has prospective load- be enough to upgrade
come up with different, not fully patterns, and the ‘Network develop- existing, or construct
coherent, solutions: lack of a European ment and power new, cross-border
network model transmission lines. It
sector operation
1 Definition of priority projects within the will also be neces-
linked to possible access to EU European Network must be optimised sary to use the trans-
funds: in 2010 the old Trans- of Transmission at European level. ’ mission system
European Network guidelines System Operators better. For this, the EU
will be replaced by an ‘EU for Electricity and the Agency has defined in general terms the
Energy Security and for Cooperation of Energy introduction of an improved con-
Infrastructure Instrument’. This Regulators, will make it difficult gestion management method11.
instrument is intended to be to obtain an accurate picture of This approach is derived from the
based less on projects pro- the investment needs. market coupling initiatives in cen-
posed by individual member Furthermore, the means of im- tral-western Europe. The idea of
states (and their national inter- plementation of this non-bind- market coupling is that cross-
ests) but is to be developed ing plan are rather weak. border transmission capacity is
from a European perspective on Consequently, it is unlikely that not auctioned off explicitly but al-
security of supply and efficien- the first Ten-Year Network located by the power exchanges
cy. As EU funding is limited and Development Plan will deliver concerned based on price differen-
discretionary, decisions are an ambitious blueprint for a tials. The trilateral market coupling
subject to intra-EU distribution European electricity network. between Belgium, France and the
10. For instance, a con- considerations. This instrument Netherlands has been highly suc-
nection between north might fix some bottlenecks but 3 Exemptions from regulation for cessful in reducing the number of
and south Germany
that would relieve the is not an integral network devel- interconnectors: national regu- hours in which price differentials
Netherlands and Polish opment solution. latory agencies might, for a lim- between these countries have per-
networks (from inner-
German flows) would ited period, allow transmission sisted (the share of hours with
need to be funded by 2 Presentation of a coordinated system operators to retain rev- equal prices increased from 20
German electricity
consumers. network development plan: in enues from auctioning capacity percent to around 70 percent) and
11. Elaborated at the 2010 the European Network of in new interconnectors be- flows now always follow prices.
17th Florence Transmission System Operators tween countries with different The planned inclusion of Germany
Electricity Regulatory
Forum. Participants in- for Electricity in cooperation prices. As demonstrated by the and Luxembourg into a ‘pentalater-
clude national regulato- with the Agency for Cooperation cable between the Netherlands al’ market coupling in 2010 as well
ry authorities, member
state governments, the of Energy Regulators and the and Norway, this mechanism as the envisaged European market
European Commission,
transmission system
European Commission will pre- can incentivise some highly coupling will lead to the desired de-
operators, electricity pare a Ten-Year Network profitable direct links between crease in the number of hours with
traders, consumers,
network users, and
Development Plan. This non- countries. However, as these low-to-medium price differentials.
power exchanges. binding plan will combine the exemptions only concern direct But market coupling will not deliver
POWER TO THE PEOPLE OF EUROPE

significantly better use of trans- power to produce binding network and consumers, allows almost
mission capacity and not allow
efficient coordination of power
planning at EU level that is based
on international cost-benefit con-
fully market-based optimisation of
power plant scheduling and gives
07

bruegelpolicybrief
plant scheduling internationally. siderations. Money spent on inte- valuable information on transmis-
Both would require a coordinated grated network planning and cost- sion bottlenecks – has been suc-
optimisation of system operations benefit reallocation could in fact cessfully applied in Australia, New
instead of coupling nationally opti- be much more productive in terms Zealand and the US. Various case
mised single-price zones. of achieving the single market studies find that efficiency im-
than multi-billion-euro EU funding provements are possible with this
In summary, the proposed to (politically) selected solution (Eto et al, 2006).
changes are not capable of deliver- infrastructure projects.
ing fully on increasing the avail- European-level implementation of
able transmission capacities and European power sector operation: jointly optimised network develop-
improving the use of existing net- linking nationally optimised sys- ment and power sector operation
works and power plants. tems does not mean that all poten- is a delicate issue. On one hand,
tial efficiency gains from an inte- bottom-up approaches based on
4 RECOMMENDATIONS grated market will be reaped. If unilateral (or only regionally coor-
one accepts coordinated optimisa- dinated) implementation of nodal
To address the outlined chal- tion, there are three alternatives to pricing and network planning
lenges, network development and the current system: a jointly opti- might result in persisting incom-
power sector operation need to be mised European single-price area, patibilities between regions. The
optimised at the European level. a jointly optimised European difficult coexistence of different re-
system of sub-national zones, or gional nodal pricing arrangements
European network development: jointly optimised European nodal in the US provides an illustration of
as implicitly acknowledged by the pricing. In the first case, the draw- this issue that might have even
Ten-Year Network Development backs of national single-price sys- worse effects in the highly meshed
Plan, only EU-level electricity net- tems (difficult market-based oper- continental European electricity
work design would be effective in ation and skewed investment in- network (see Germany with its ten
delivering the required network centives) will be present. In a electricity borders).
infrastructure. The EU should European zonal system, these
therefore continue to push for flaws will vanish with decreasing On the other hand, the technical
jointly optimised and properly im- zone size. The workability and effi- and political complexity of coordi-
plemented network development. ciency of such a sub-national nating some twenty national regu-
This would require defining fair zonal system can be seen in latory systems and thousands of
legal rules for sharing the costs Scandinavia, where Denmark and stakeholders (regulators, trans-
and benefits of investment in Norway are split into different mission system operators, genera-
transmission lines that have ef- zones. But splitting the highly tors, consumers, etc.) seems
fects on more than one country’s meshed European transmission bound to lead to failure.
electricity system. Such a cost- system into hundreds of meaning-
benefit allocation system might ful zones is difficult. Nodal pricing A combination of both approaches
allow a departure from the require- circumvents this problem by is required. The long-term vision of
ment for agreement by unanimity making each injection/withdrawal jointly optimised network develop-
for network planning and thus point of a network (node) into a ment and power plant operation
might allow the European Network price zone of its own. This first-best should be laid out in a binding EU
of Transmission System Operators solution – which provides correct instrument. The technical details
for Electricity to be given the locational incentives to generators should provide enough freedom for
POWER TO THE PEOPLE OF EUROPE

gradual implementation and adap- nificant efficiencies of scale and with the integration of energy mar-
08 tation to different regulatory sys-
tems, while ensuring that the ex-
scope13. So far, however, the neces-
sary institutions to regulate and in-
kets (for example with respect to
market definitions).
bruegelpolicybrief

change of information required to centivise more cooperation be-


optimally coordinate power-plant tween cross-border transmission We should not wait for the results
operation across borders is system operators are not in place. of the European market coupling
standardised. In addition to these If national regulatory agencies find and the first network development
top-down components the trans- ways to incentivise increasing co- plan to appear between 2015 and
mission system operators should operation of network companies to 2020 before bringing forward a
be given stronger incentives for jointly optimise their networks blueprint for a truly European
deep cooperation. Currently, trans- (both in terms of day-to-day opera- electricity network.
mission systems are primarily op- tion and investment) this could
erated within national bound- lead to a ‘bottom-up’ approach to Research assistance by Juan
aries12. This is unnatural, as merg- optimal electricity network plan- Ignacio Aldasoro, Clément Serre
ers of transmission system opera- ning and operation. Competition and Hendrik Worschech is grateful-
tors across borders could reap sig- authorities will need to keep pace ly acknowledged.

REFERENCES:
BMU (2009) ‘Gutachten über die freiwillige Übertragung der Energie-übertragungsnetze, die Errichtung einer bun-
desweiten Netzgesellschaft und die regulatorischen Rahmenbedingungen’, available at
http://bmu.info/energieeffizienz/down loads/doc/44833.php, accessed 28 May 2010
Buglione, Giuseppe, Guido Cervigni, Eileen Fumagalli, Elena Fumagalli and Clara Poletti (2009) ‘Integrating European
Electricity Markets’, IEFE Research Report no.2, October
Bundesnetzagentur (2009) ‘Optimierung der Ausregelung von Leistungsungleichgewichten’, available at
http://www.bundesnetzagentur.de/cae/servlet/contentblob/151484/publicationFile/6058/Gutachten_optimierte_Au
sregelung_ZNR.pdf, accessed 28 May 2010
Bunn, Derek and Georg Zachmann (2009) ‘Inefficient arbitrage in inter-regional electricity transmission’, Journal of
Regulatory Economics 37(3)
Eto, Joseph H., Douglas R. Hale and Bernard C. Lesieutre (2006) ‘Toward More Comprehensive Assessments of FERC
Electricity Restructuring Policies: A Review of Recent Benefit-Cost Studies of RTOs’, The Electricity Journal 19(10)
European Commission (2007) ‘Impact Assessment accompanying the legislative package on the internal market for
electricity and gas’, Commission staff working document SEC(2007) 1179
European Commission (2007a) ‘DG Competition Report on Energy Sector Inquiry’, SEC(2006) 1724, available at
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/sectors/energy/inquiry/index.html, accessed 28 May 2010
12. The exceptions are
two recent acquisitions: European Commission (2010) ‘Communication from the Commission: Europe 2020 a strategy for smart, sustainable
the Dutch transmission and inclusive growth’, COM(2010) 2020
system operator TenneT
acquired the German International Energy Agency (2005) Lessons from Liberalised Electricity Markets, Paris
Transpower and the
Belgian transmission Nitsche, Rainer, Axel Ockenfels, Lars-Hendrik Röller and Lars Wiethaus (2009) ‘The Electricity Wholesale Sector –
system operator Elia Market Integration and Market Power’, ESMT Competition Analysis
bought the German
50Hertz Transmission. Pollitt, Michael G. (2009) ‘Electricity Liberalisation in the European Union: A Progress Report’, EPRG Working Paper
13. Here, a determined
0929
implementation of the
unbundling require- © Bruegel 2010. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted in
ments in the third pack- the original language without explicit permission provided that the source is acknowledged. The Bruegel
age might speed up a Policy Brief Series is published under the editorial responsibility of Jean Pisani-Ferry, Director. Opinions ex-
meaningful pressed in this publication are those of the author(s) alone.
consolidation of
European transmission Visit www.bruegel.org for information on Bruegel's activities and publications.
system operators. Bruegel - Rue de la Charité 33, B-1210 Brussels - phone (+32) 2 227 4210 info@bruegel.org

S-ar putea să vă placă și