Sunteți pe pagina 1din 47

Self-Selection of Auditors and Size Nonlinearities in Audit Pricing

Paul Chaney 401 21st Avenue South Owen Graduate School of Management Vanderbilt University Nashville, TN 37203 Paul.Chaney@owen.vanderbilt.edu Ph: (615) 322 2685 Debra Jeter Owen Graduate School of Management Vanderbilt University Debra.Jeter@owen.vanderbilt.edu Ph: (615) 322 3638 Lakshmanan Shivakumar London Business School Lshivakumar@london.edu Ph: (44) 20 7262 5050 February 4, 2005

Self-Selection of Auditors and Size Nonlinearities in Audit Pricing

Abstract Prior research has examined audit pricing for publicly held firms and provided some evidence of a Big 8 premium in pricing. More recent research provides evidence that private firms do not pay such a premium on average; i.e. a premium is observed using standard OLS regressions, but it vanishes once self-selection bias is controlled for. This paper returns to the setting of listed U.S. firms and provides evidence that, on average, the firms in the sample examined also do not pay a Big 5 premium (once self-selection bias and nonlinearities in client size are taken into account). Consistent with the findings of Chaney, Jeter, and Shivakumar (2004), we find that publicly traded client firms choosing Big 5 auditors generally would have faced higher fees had they chosen non-Big 5 auditors, given their firm-specific characteristics. Our results are consistent with audit markets for listed firms, as well as for private firms, being segmented along cost-effective lines. Our findings emphasize the importance of controlling for self selection and size nonlinearities in any audit fee study using standard OLS regressions to control for client size or auditor size (or quality).

1. Introduction
Prior audit fee research has demonstrated that model specification is sensitive to firm size (Francis and Stokes, 1986; Palmrose, 1986; Simunic, 1980; Craswell, Francis, and Taylor, 1995; among others1), to self-selection bias (Chaney, Jeter and Shivakumar, 2004; Copley, Gaver and Gaver, 1995; Ireland and Lennox, 2001) and to product and cost differentiation (Chaney, Jeter and Shivakumar, 2004; Deltas and Doogar, 2003). In this paper, we examine the importance of these criticisms in the context of audit fee models for publicly traded U.S. firms. Prior studies have provided mixed evidence with regard to a Big 8(5) fee premium, with Simunic (1980) suggesting that neither small nor large U.S. clients pay such a premium while Francis (1984) argues that both small and large Australian firms in their sample paid such a premium. Francis and Stokes (1986) attempted to reconcile the results by noting that all firms in the former study were relatively large, while all in the latter were relatively small. One explanation for the absence of fee premiums in larger clients is that the premiums are offset by economies of scale in larger clients. This explanation, however, is more of an ex-post rationalization than a testable hypothesis. The sensitivity of results related to fee premiums with respect to client size extend to tests of specialist fees and premiums (Craswell et al., 1995) as well as to Big 5/non-Big 5 fee comparisons. These issuesthe evidence that fee premiums are only observed in a relatively small subset of clients; and the sensitivity of results to client sizeraise the concern that test specification in these studies suffers from methodological problems with respect to client size. This paper revisits the issue of Big 5 fee premiums after considering econometric issues in the model specification for audit fees. We provide empirical support that these concerns are valid, and we find that when self-selection and nonlinearities in client size, as well as product

differentiation, are considered, the Big 5 auditor fee premium, which emerges under standard OLS regressions, disappears. In fact, we show that most firms choosing Big 5 auditors would in fact pay higher fees if they make the alternate (non-Big 5) choice. Although we focus on the existence (absence) of a large fee premium as the setting for our examination, the econometric problems documented extend to a wide range of accounting research applications where standard OLS regressions have been the traditional norm for testing or controlling for client size and auditor size (quality).2 This is most notably the case when the model specifies audit fees as the dependent variable. Our results indicate that reliance on these models may lead to erroneous or misleading conclusions and that, at a minimum, studies should check their results for robustness to the issues of self-selection bias and nonlinearities in client size. Craswell, et al. (1995) present evidence that the parameters of their model are inconsistent between the upper and lower halves of firms in their sample. They conclude that the general brand-name Big 8 premium observed for the Australian firms examined is significant only for the bottom half (smaller firms) while the specialist fee premium is significant only for the upper half. Also using Australian data, Ferguson and Stokes (2002) look at the post-1990 period. They find evidence of a generalist Big 6(5) fee premium for firms in the smaller half of their sample by comparing nonspecialist Big 6(5) auditors and nonspecialist non-Big 6(5) auditors; however, they find little evidence of a specialist premium during this period. These studies have focused almost exclusively on the differences in the Big 8(6 or 5) or specialist premium across size-sorted

1 Note that whereas these studies focus on the coefficient on the variable of interest, we extend the size sensitivity

arguments to all coefficients in the audit fee regression.


2 See, for example, Ferguson, Francis, and Stokes (2003), who examine the effects of firm-wide and office-level

industry experience in audit pricing. Other studies that analyze the effect of auditor quality on dimensions other than fees include Teoh and Wong (1993, the effect on earnings response coefficients); Petroni and Beasley (1996, the effect on errors in accounting estimates; Basu, Hwang and Jan (2001, the effect on conservative reporting); Pittman and Fortin (2004) and Mansi, Maxwell and Miller (2004, the effect on the cost of debt).

subsamples. We argue that differences in client size will impact almost all the coefficients in audit-fee regressions, not just the variables of primary interest. Further, when such nonlinearities are not taken into account, spurious correlations between audit fees and variables of interest may lead to erroneous conclusions. Although a few prior studies have examined the effects of nonlinearity by estimating regressions within client groups determined using arbitrary size cutoffs, such an approach is unlikely to be sufficient as the effects of client sizes on regression coefficients are continuous and not discrete. So, we do not rely on such cutoffs in our analyses. Client size has the potential to affect audit fees in a variety of ways. Auditors pricing their services differentially for clients of varying size must consider such issues as risk, reputation, and economies of scale (Simunic, 1980, for one). For example, because of greater exposure to media damage and subsequent litigation, an audit failure in a large client firm tends to be disproportionately more costly for the auditor than an audit failure of a smaller client. While larger companies generally have more sophisticated internal control systems and more competent or extensive staff of internal auditors than smaller companies, they may also face greater pressure to meet or beat analysts expectations (Barton and Simko, 2002). Larger firms may be argued to have greater bargaining power with auditors (Kim, Liu, and Rhee, 2003), and auditors may covet the status of auditing the very largest clients in a particular geographic area or in a particular industry. Moreover, if the audit market is segmented along client size, then some auditors may be able to offer more efficient or higher quality audits for a particular client group than another auditor can. Hence nonlinearities in the relation between client size and various determinants of audit fees are likely. Using a sample of private U.K. client firms, Chaney, Jeter, and Shivakumar (2004) present evidence that the Big 5 premium documented with standard OLS regressions disappears when self-selection bias is controlled for. However, as pointed out by Chaney, et al. (2004), this

result may not extend to a sample of listed U.S. firms due either to differences in the setting or in the clientele. Using the two-stage Heckman approach to test for self-selection in a sample of listed U.S. firms, we reject a null hypothesis that clients are randomly allocated across Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors. After controlling for self-selection and size nonlinearities, we find no evidence of a Big 5 auditor fee premium. While by no means constituting a direct test of audit quality, an examination of fees paid to Big 5 versus non-Big 5 auditors does shed some insight into how the respective groups of auditors are valued by their clientele. Our findings suggest: (a) choice of a Big 5 auditor need not necessarily signal auditor superiority as the auditor selection may instead be dictated by cost considerations; and (b) in contrast to the argument that large auditors charge a premium relative to smaller auditors to cover additional litigation costs (Dye, 1993), audit markets appear to be segmented along cost-efficient dimensions. In general, the auditor type (Big 5 or non-Big 5) best equipped to audit a particular client efficiently is usually selected, and audit fee premiums are most likely to result for those clients that depart from that choice. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses our theoretical concerns, including the background for our paper, the arguments in the literature for differentiated pricing across auditor types (Big 5 and non-Big 5) and methodological issues. Section 3 describes our model, and Section 4 presents the data and results. Section 5 concludes.

2. Background and Theory


2.1 BACKGROUND Corporate scandals and alleged audit failures since the turn of the millennium have brought the accounting and audit professions into the limelight to an extent rarely, if ever, seen since the stock market crash of 1929. In the wake of Enron, WorldCom, and Tyco, among others, the investing public has become leery of the value of audits in general and of the

independence and competence of Big 5 audit firms in particular. Whereas a number of accounting and auditing studies in the past have assumed Big 5 (or 8 or 6) to be synonymous with high quality, academics and practitioners alike are now questioning the validity of that assumption. Recent events have heightened our awareness of a need to understand the working of audit markets in general and of the value added by Big 5 as well as by non-Big 5 auditors. Copley, Gaver and Gaver (1995) suggest that prior studies of audit fees and premiums suffer from potential endogeneity biases as client characteristics (such as size, risk, and leverage) play important roles in determining both the demand for a particular auditor and the marginal fees paid. Employing a simultaneous equations approach and using a sample of 162 municipal audits, they provide mixed support for a Big 5 reputation effect in audit fees. In this study we compare audit fees across the two auditor groups with the aim of gleaning some new insights into how audit markets work and along what dimensions the clientele are segmented into Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditees. We do this largely by pursuing the approach of prior studies, but in addition, relaxing the following assumptions made in prior studies fee regressions: (i) slope coefficients are the same across Big 5 and non-Big 5 clients; (ii) the effect of client size on audit fees is additive and not interactive; and (iii) self-selection of auditors does not lead to any bias. We discuss below the rationale and the importance of considering these econometric issues in audit free regressions. 2.2 EXPLANATIONS FOR DIFFERENTIAL PRICING ACROSS AUDITOR TYPES Several arguments have been presented in the literature to explain observed fee differentials across Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors. Although it is difficult to discuss these arguments independently of client size issues, our emphasis in this section is on the basic premises for a Big 5 auditor fee premium (or discount). Then, in the following section (2.3), we elaborate on the effects of client size on the various arguments advanced for fee differentials.

Various researchers (e.g., Watts and Zimmerman, 1983) argue that the demand for auditing services arises from conflicts of interest among managers, creditors and outside shareholders. Given the existence of such agency issues, managers and entrepreneurs have incentives to reduce agency costs through high quality monitoring. Titman and Trueman (1986) present a model wherein firms with favorable information signal their quality by selecting auditors that are costly, but that provide relatively more precise information about the firms final cash flows. Also, DeAngelo (1981) argues that larger and more prestigious auditors stand to lose more from other clients in the event of an audit failure and thus are less likely to perform low-quality audits. In the context of these theories, the Big 5 auditor fee premium could be interpreted as the price paid, by clients signaling their quality, for an auditor of superior reputation. Dye (1993) suggests that audit fees may reflect the option value that investors place on a claim against an auditors wealth in the event of audit failure. Under this argument, financial statement users perceive auditors as providing insurance in the event of securities litigation; consequently, an auditors wealth is viewed as a bond posted to ensure the delivery of an audit of appropriate quality. The higher the bond (or the wealthier the auditor), the higher quality the audit should be. In this context, the Big 5-auditor fee premium is viewed by client firms as the value of the increased insurance coverage; alternatively, from the auditor's perspective, it may be viewed as the expected cost of higher potential litigation losses. Prior studies have suggested that economies of scale could result in lower audit fees for large clients of Big 5 auditors (relative to non-Big 5 auditees) (Simunic, 1980; Francis and Stokes, 1986). In addition, Simunic (1980) suggests that Big 5 auditors may be able to audit virtually all firms with greater efficiency and at lower cost (though diseconomies are more likely to small auditors auditing large clients). To the extent that efficiencies and/or economies of scale are passed on to client firms, Big 5 auditor fees would be expected to be lower than non-Big 5 fees.

Based on the above arguments, most prior studies restrict the slope coefficients in audit fee regressions to be the same across Big 5 and non-Big 5 clients, allowing only the intercept to vary between the two groups.3 However, Chaney, Jeter and Shivakumar (2004) show that such restrictions are neither theoretically nor empirically justifiable and consequently introduce significant bias in the analyses. They suggest that auditors structure their businesses in a manner appropriate for targeted client segments, with Big 5 auditors investing more in technology, training and facilities and, as a result, carrying out audits more efficiently for large, relatively complex clients. The costs of these investments result in a relatively high fixed component of audit fees, which may be unattractive (and costly) for small and less complex clients. Consequently, the slope coefficients as well as the intercepts are likely to differ across auditor groups. Although the empirical evidence in Chaney, Jeter and Shivakumar (2004) is for private companies, their arguments for differences in slope coefficients across auditor types fully carry forward to the case of listed companies. 2.3 IMPACT OF CLIENT SIZE ON AUDIT FEES Several studies have investigated the effect of client size and also of auditor size on companies audit fees (e.g., Simunic, 1980; Palmrose, 1986). Initial studies on audit pricing tested this issue by estimating a cross-sectional regression of audit fees on a set of explanatory variables, which included both client size and an indicator variable for auditor size (Big 8 or non-Big 8) as separate additive variables. The studies found strong evidence for the role of client size in determining audit fees, but mixed evidence for the role of auditor size. However, the framework presented in Simunic (1980) provides several reasons to suggest that client size and auditor size are unlikely to be merely additive, but instead are likely to have interactive effects on audit fees. First, large audit firms enjoy economies of scale in auditing larger clients; or, viewed differently, small auditors suffer diseconomies of scale when auditing larger clients. Second, due to the small number
3 Although the economies of scale argument discussed in the previous paragraph implies differences in slope

of audit suppliers in the audit market for larger clients, the assumption of perfect competition for audit pricing may not apply to audits of larger clients. Thus, if larger auditors charge a premium for their monopolistic power, such a premium is more likely to be observed among larger clients than among smaller clients. Yet the opposite has been shown. Francis and Simon (1987), for example, document that client size and auditor size have an interactive effect on audit fees and that a fee premium for Big 8 auditors is observed only among small clients. Based on this finding, Francis and Simon (1987) conclude that Big 8 auditors provide a differentiated audit product relative to smaller (non-Big 8) auditors. Although Simunic (1980) and others address the interaction between client size and an auditor indicator variable, the arguments regarding economies of scale and market competition suggest that client size will have interactive effects with all explanatory variables that capture either audit effort or monopolistic power rather than merely with a categorical variable for Big 8 vs. non-Big 8 auditor. Moreover, these arguments suggest that such interactive effects will vary across large and small auditors due to their potential for product differentiation and for taking advantage of monopolistic opportunities. We extend the arguments from prior literature and suggest that the interactive effect of size is not limited to differences in the fixed component of fees for Big 5(8) and non-Big 5(8) auditors but is important for other determinants of audit fees as well. There are at least four mutually non-exclusive reasons for this: monopolistic competition, economies of scale, product differentiation and audit risk. We discuss each of these in turn below. Monopolistic Competition Although in the economics of auditing literature it is generally assumed that the audit market is competitive, regulatory agencies in several countries have questioned the extent to

coefficients across Big5 and non-Big5 auditors, this implication has been largely ignored in prior studies.

which large and small auditors compete realistically. It has been documented that large auditor dominance increases significantly with the size of audited clientele (see for e.g., Simunic, 1980), leading to a conjecture that audit markets are not competitive for larger clients. Consequently, audit pricing for larger clients is likely to be more discretionary relative to audit pricing for smaller clients, where the assumption of perfect competition more aptly applies. This suggests that the relation between audit fees and its determinants is likely to vary as one moves from the smallest clients to the largest clients (see Shailer, Cummings, Vatuloka and Welch, 2004). In particular, the coefficients on variables reflecting potential discretionary pricing (e.g., audit risk and effort, as well as the Big 5 indicator variable) will increase in magnitude with client size if the large client segment of the audit market is vulnerable to monopolistic pricing. On the other hand, the possibility cannot be ignored that very large clients exercise power over competing auditors, even among the Big 5, thus offsetting or even dominating the effects of monopolistic pricing. Economies of Scale Simunic (1980) and Francis and Stokes (1986) suggest that auditors of larger clients may benefit from economies of scale, in which case audit costs would increase non-linearly with size. One argument put forth for scale economies is that both internal and external auditing are sampling-based processes. To the extent that an increase in the measured total assets of an audit client reflects an increase in the number of individual elements of which those assets are composed, the sample size necessary to obtain a given level of confidence increases at a declining rate (Simunic, 1980). In the audit fee model, variables included to capture the costs

associated with audit effort should thus exhibit coefficients that monotonically decrease with size.4 Product Differentiation Although most studies of audit pricing recognize that large auditors and small auditors provide differentiated products, the implications of such product differentiation on model specifications have been largely ignored. This sub-section develops the link between product differentiation and models for audit fees. The key to a product differentiation strategy is to develop and supply a differentiated service that clients demand and that competitors find difficult to duplicate. Prior research generally assumes that large auditors make costly investments both to safeguard their reputation for superiority and to provide higher quality audits. Implicit in this assumption is the notion that these costs prevent competitors from easily achieving comparable degrees of perceived quality or reputation. Researchers argue that these costly investments require a correspondingly higher return, with the result that Big 8(5) auditors justifiably earn fee premiums over their non-Big 8(5) counterparts. In contrast, we contend that while such differentiation may indeed require specific investments by larger auditors, they do not necessarily imply higher fees (see Mayhew and Wilkins (2003)). Chaney, Jeter and Shivakumar (2004) provide evidence that large and small auditors of private clients in the U.K. provide differentiated audit services, each of which appeals to specific segments of privately held audit clients. Auditors are able to structure their business in a manner targeted to be optimal for specific client segments. For instance, as argued in Chaney, et al. (2004), Big 5 auditors invest more in technology, training and facilities and are, consequently, able to carry out audits more efficiently
4 In acknowledgement of this potentially monotonically decreasing relation with size, most prior studies consider a

logarithmic transformations of audit fees and client size in the regressions. However, several studies have pointed

10

for large, relatively complex clients. The higher fixed costs of these investments are not attractive to smaller and less complex clients in general.5 Furthermore, such product differentiation leads to specialization as the audit personnel deal almost exclusively with a specific client segment. The audit personnel become very adept at identifying and addressing issues that are unique to their clientele. For instance, auditors that focus on larger clients would be better able to deal with issues related to public borrowings, since public issues of debt are predominantly done by larger clients. Such product differentiation and specialization leads to increases in audit efficiency, as well as to lower audit costs for all auditors involved. Deltas and Doogar (2003) provide evidence consistent with such product and cost differentiation in the audit market. Since an important dimension along which Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors are segmented is clearly client size,6 the above arguments imply that client size is likely to affect the relation of audit fees with either audit effort or audit risk; further, this impact (differential client size) will vary across Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors. Because the two basic benefits of product differentiation and specializationlower costs and higher service quality or efficiencytend to pull audit fees in opposite directions, the effect of client-size segmentation on audit fees is not immediately clear. If increased quality is reflected in higher audit fees, then Big 5 auditors will charge more for larger clients, and the coefficients reflecting the pricing of effort and risk are likely to increase in magnitude with client size. However, such increases could be offset by cost efficiencies that arise from specialization.
out that even after logarithmic transformations, there is a non-linear relationship between fees and size (e.g., Carson, Fargher, Simon and Taylor (2004)). 5 These arguments differ from arguments based on economies of scale. Under straight-forward economies of scale arguments, there is no reason to expect Big 5 auditors to have a cost disadvantage for less complicated audit clients. Furthermore, economies of scale arguments define clientele groups based only on the size dimension, whereas this need not be the case for arguments regarding product differentiation. Under product differentiation arguments, even a small firm, say with significant exports, could find a Big 5 auditor more cost-efficient than a non-Big auditor.

11

Audit Risks Audit risks are unlikely to increase linearly with client size. Since larger clients face greater media coverage and political attention, and have larger numbers of investors and heavier analyst coverage, the audit failure of a larger client firm will have a disproportionately more negative impact on the auditors reputation than the audit failure of a smaller client firm. Even scaled (e.g., as a percentage of clients total assets), we would not expect the costs of an audit failure, particularly auditors non-monetary costs, to be the same involving a client firm with $10 million of total assets and one with $10 billion of total assets. Casual empiricism suggests that the reputation loss suffered by Arthur Anderson from the failure of the Enron audit was much greater than that incurred from previous failures of smaller client firms, both in terms of media attention and ultimate consequences. Thus, we hypothesize that the variables in the audit fee model that are intended to capture audit risks should have coefficients that increase in magnitude with client size. The preceding arguments suggest that one could expect almost all determinants of audit pricing, irrespective of whether the variable captures audit effort, audit risk or monopolistic rents, to vary non-linearly in size. Consequently, existing models of audit pricing, which ignore the interactive effect of client size or limit its interactive effect to fee premiums, may be misspecified. In particular, the omission of size-related interactive variables from an audit pricing model could cause variables that are correlated with size, such as the Big 5 dummy, to have biased coefficients. Thus, at the very least, the above arguments suggest that studies of audit pricing should check the robustness of the results after considering non-linearities in size.

6 Almost all very large clients are audited by Big 5 auditors; further, this proportion decreases monotonically with

client size.

12

The precise interactive effect of client size on the relation between audit fees and its determinants may vary depending on whether client size is interacted with a variable that proxies for audit risk, audit effort, or monopolistic rents. However, unambiguous separation of audit fee variables into these categories is not feasible. Moreover, the precise client attributes along which Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors differentiate their services is unobservable. Therefore, we do not hypothesize the direction of the relations between the size-interacted variables and audit fees. 2.4 SELF-SELECTION IN AUDITOR CHOICE As pointed out in Chaney, et al. (2004),7 companies are not randomly assigned to audit firms, but rather self select their auditors. Theoretical studies, such as Titman and Trueman (1986) and Datar et al. (1991) present signaling models to explore the self-selection of auditors by clients. In these models, clients with favorable private information choose higher quality auditors despite higher costs. However, from an econometric perspective, self-selection introduces a bias in the standard OLS regressions. The self-selection problem arises because fees are observable only after a firm has chosen its auditor, while the fees under an alternative auditor choice remain unobserved. This causes the expected error in the standard OLS specification of audit fees to be non-zero and the auditor choice (Big 5 vs. non-Big 5) variable to be endogenous. To see this, consider the following self-selection model for audit fees:8 Auditor choice function: Big 5i* = / Zi + ui Big 5i = 1 if Big 5i* > 0 Big 5i = 0 if Big 5i* 0 Audit-fee function: F0i = 0/ Xi + 0i if Big 5i=0 (2) (1)

7 Much of this section is adapted from Chaney, et al. (2004).

13

F1i = 1/ Xi + 1i

if Big 5i=1

(3)

where Xi and Zi are vectors of exogenous variables and the error terms, ui, 0i and 1i, are assumed to be normally distributed with mean zero and variance-covariance matrix given by:
00 01 0u Covariance(0i, 1i, ui) = 01 11 1u 0u 1u uu

Since F0i is observed only when Big 5i = 0, the expected value of the residuals from estimating regression (2) on observed data is given by: E(0i | Big 5i=0) = E(0i | ui - / Zi)
( Z i ) = 0u ( Z i ) ( Z i ) = 0u ( Z i ) 1

0u 0i , where the functions and are the standard normal probability density function and the cumulative distribution function, respectively. Similarly, the expected value of the residuals in regression (3) is given by E(1i | Big 5i=1) = E(0i | ui > -/ Zi)
( Z i ) = 1u 1 ( Z i ) ( Z i ) = 1u ( Z i )

1u 1i If either 0u 0 or 1u 0, then OLS specifications of audit fees are biased as the expected error in these regressions is non-zero.9 Moreover, the primary parameter of interest in

8 The self-selection model, which is based on Lee (1979), is quite general in that, it allows for simultaneity in the

auditor choice and audit-fee equations, as well as for self-selection. The model also allows slope coefficients and the error terms in the fee equations to vary across auditor types. 9 Testing whether 0u=0 and 1u=0 is, in fact, the test for self-selection (see Maddala (1983) pg. 259).

14

such analyses, namely the average benefit or cost of auditor choice, will also be biased. To see this, note that the average benefit or cost of auditor choice is essentially measured as average fees observed for a firm minus the average potential fees that would have been charged if the alternative auditor choice were made. Formally, this is given by:
For non-Big 5 clients: F0 E (F1 | Big 5 = 0 ) = F0 1 X 1u 0

(4) (5)

For Big 5 clients:

F1 E (F0 | Big 5 = 1) = F1 0 X 0u 1

where a bar over a variable denotes its cross-sectional average.10 If either 0u 0 or 1u 0, then the estimated difference in fees between Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors from standard OLS regressions is biased. In particular, if 0u is positive, then the fee differential estimated from OLS regressions will be biased upward for Big 5 clients as 1 > 0 . Similarly, if 1u is positive, then the fee differential estimated from OLS regressions will be biased downward for non-Big 5 clients, as 0 < 0 . It is also worth noting from equations (1) to (3) that, if either 0u 0 or 1u 0, then the dummy variable Big 5i is correlated with the error term in audit fee equation. In such a case, Big 5i is endogenous in the standard OLS regression of audit fees. Thus, self-selection of auditors potentially introduces biases in standard OLS regressions both due to non-zero expectations for the error term as well as due to endogeneity of the Big 5i dummy variable.

3. MODEL ESTIMATION
Initially a traditional audit fee regression is estimated using an OLS regression including a Big 5 indicator variable (without controlling for self-selection or considering size non-

10 In equations (4) and (5), all variables and firm-characteristics that determine fees, including j (j=0,1), are obtained from a particular auditor type. However, the parameters (j and ju, j=0 or 1) are obtained from the alternative auditor type.

15

linearities). Next, size interactive variables are included to assess the impact due to nonlinearities in size. These models are as follows: Traditional fee regression: Lfeei = 1 + 2Sizei + 3Levi + 4 Sqrtsubti + 5ROAi + 6Sqrtempli + 7Yrendi + 8Replagi + 9 Big 5i + i Traditional fee regression with size interactive variables: Lfeei = 1 + 2Sizei + 3Levi + 4Sqrtsubi + 5ROAi + 6Sqrtempli + 7Yrendi + B8Replagi + B9Sizei* Sizei + 10Sizei*Levi + 11Sizei*Sqrtsubi +12Sizei*ROAi + 13Sizei*Sqrtempli + 14Sizei*Yrendi + 15Sizei*Replagi + 16Big 5i + 17Sizei*Big 5i + i where: Lfeei Big 5i Sizei Levi Sqrtsubit ROAi Sqrtempli Yrendi Replagi = Logarithm of audit fees; = 1 if firm i chose a Big 5 auditor in year t; 0 otherwise; = Logarithm of end of year total client assets; = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; = square root of the number of subsidiaries; = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; = Square root of the number of employees; = 1 if the firms year-end occurs in December, 0 otherwise; = Number of days between the firms year-end and the earnings announcement date. (7) (6)

Next, we estimate the self-selection model using the two-stage procedure of Heckman (1979) and Lee (1979). In the first stage, a probit regression is estimated to obtain consistent estimates for of the indicator variable, Big 5i, on Zi. Using these estimates, the inverse Mills ratios (IMR), 0i and 1i are computed. Then, in the second stage, the audit fee equation is estimated by OLS with the inverse Mills ratio included as an additional explanatory variable. Our self-selection model is given as:

16

Probit Regression:

Big 5it = 1 + 2Sizeit + 3Levit + 4Sqrtsubit + 5ROAit + 6Sqrtemplit + 7Sizeit* Sizeit + 8Sizeit*Levit + 9Sizeit*Sqrtsubit +10Sizeit*ROAit + 11Sizeit*Sqrtemplit + it (8) Lfeei = j1 + j2Sizei + j3Levi + j4Sqrtsubi + j5ROAi + j6Sqrtempli + j7Yrendi + Bj8Replagi + Bj9Sizei* Sizei + j10Sizei*Levi + j11Sizei*Sqrtsubi +j12Sizei*ROAi + j13Sizei*Sqrtempli + j14Sizei*Yrendi + j15Sizei*Replagi + j ji + ji (9)

OLS regression:

where ji is the inverse Mills ratio for firm i, a client of auditor type j; where j is equal to 0 for non-Big 5 client firms and equal to 1 for Big 5 client firms; and where size is defined as a continuous variable in all interactive specifications (log of client assets). The coefficients, 0 and 1, which are the estimates for 0u and 1u , are the covariances of the residuals from the non-Big 5 or Big 5 audit-fee equation (9) and the residuals from the auditor-choice equation (8). The variables have been chosen based largely on previous studies of audit fee regressions; the rationale for their inclusion is discussed briefly below. For the auditor fee equation, we expect audit fees to increase with audit effort, risk and complexity. We use the logarithm of total assets to control for client size, which captures the amount of audit effort needed to a large degree. To control for audit risk, we include variables for financial structure (Lev) and profitability (ROA) of the client firm. We include the square root of the number of subsidiaries and the square root of the number of employees to control for audit complexity. Other variables likely to affect the audit fee include a year-end indicator variable to control for peak versus off-peak pricing, and the reporting lag between the end of the year and the firms earnings announcement date (to capture cross-sectional differences in the timeliness of the audit or in the time taken to complete the audit). The self-selection model allows the slope

17

coefficients and the intercept in the audit fee regression to vary across Big 5 and non-Big 5 clients. This is important since our arguments regarding market segmentation predict differences in cost functions across these client firms. Specifically, if Big 5 auditors invest more in technology, training, etc., then the intercept in the fee regression of Big 5 clients will be larger, reflecting the Big 5 auditors compensation for their increased investments. However, this larger investment will allow Big 5 auditors to conduct audits more efficiently, particularly for large, risky and relatively complex clients. In such a case, the slope coefficients on variables associated with audit effort or risk would be smaller for these clients if pricing is based on audit costs and efficiencies rather than monopolistic or reputation advantages. While the year-end dummy variable is included to control for peak vs. off-peak pricing, the effect of this variable interacted with client size is somewhat ambiguous. Large clients are often continuously audited throughout the year, which should reduce the incremental workload at year-end somewhat; however, even with continuous auditing, the heaviest burden occurs during the auditors busy season for large clients whose year ends in December. For the auditor choice equation in the self-selection model, we expect larger companies to be more likely to hire Big 5 audit firms for various reasons, including the perception that larger auditors are better equipped to handle the audit efficiently. Also, to the extent that Big 5 auditors have generally wider experience and arguably better-trained personnel, they may be able to audit riskier clients more efficiently, especially as size increases. Agency costs tend to be higher in highly leveraged clients, and such firms may prefer to hire auditors of superior reputation to reduce agency costs. However, while leverage is a risk variable, as the client firms size increases, more proactive measures may be taken on the part of lenders and other groups to guard against firm failure. Large firms with higher ROA are desirable clients and lower fees are likely, as these firms may be viewed as relatively low-risk and high-profit auditees. In addition, we

18

interact all the above variables with client size, as was done for the audit fee regression. The main motivation behind this is that Big 5 auditors will almost certainly audit very large clients, due to resource constraints faced by non-Big 5 auditors. Thus, as client size increases, we expect all variables other than size to decline in importance in determining auditor choice.

4. Data and Results 4.1 DATA


The data source for this study begins with all U.S. listed firms with audit pricing data on S&P audit pricing database for 2001 (n=5,786). Observations eliminated included 688 observations with missing data, 1,606 regulated firms, and the top and bottom half percent of continuous variables (n=151). This resulted in a final sample of 3,341 firms. Table 1 reports descriptive information for our sample of firms. We present the mean and medians for each variable used in our regressions, first for all audit clients and then separately for clients of Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors. The audit fee for the average Big 5 client is $458.7 thousand, while the audit fee for the average non-Big 5 client is $122.6 thousand. We test for differences in means and medians between Big 5 and non-Big 5 clients and present these results in the last two columns of Table 1. As shown in these columns, virtually all means and medians are significantly different for Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditees. The mean of total assets for firms in our sample is $1,013 million. For Big 5 auditees, the mean is $1,159 million, while for non-Big 5 auditees it is $93.12 million. The mean (median) number of employees is 6,107 (886) for Big 5 clients and 806 (111) for non-Big 5 clients. The average leverage, defined as the ratio of current and long-term debt to market value of equity plus total liabilities, is about 15.7% for Big 5 auditees and 20.3% for non-Big 5 clientele. The mean return on assets is -9.1% for Big 5 and -13.7% non-Big 5 auditees in our sample. Somewhat surprisingly, the

19

number of subsidiaries (reportable segments) is larger for non-Big 5 clients with a mean of 1.6 versus a mean of 1.5 for Big 5 clients. This differential reflects differences in how companies define a reportable segment as well as the actual number of segments; thus, it may not be a good proxy for client complexity. Sixty-five percent of the Big 5 clients reported year-ends in December versus 58 percent for the non-Big 5 clients. Finally, the reporting lag between the year-end and the firms earnings announcement is significantly longer for non-Big 5 clients versus the Big 5 clients (75 days versus 48 days), consistent with an argument that Big 5 auditors may be more efficient, on average, for auditing clients in our sample in a timely fashion. Correlation coefficients are reported in Table 2. As expected, size is highly correlated with audit fees. The Big 5 indicator variable is also highly correlated with size. This is expected since most large firms tend to select Big 5 auditors. ROA and Lev are positively related to audit fees, and reporting lag is negatively related to both the Big 5 indicator variable and audit fees. ROA is included as a measure of profitability and is generally expected to be negatively related to fees after controlling for client size. The positive correlation between ROA and audit fees in this table may be spuriously induced by the positive correlation between ROA and client size coupled with that between client size (0.42) and audit fees (0.83). 4.2 RESULTS OLS Regression Results For comparison with prior studies, we present the estimates from traditional OLS regressions of audit fees on the explanatory variables in Table 3. While the results presented in the first two columns of Table 3 are consistent with prior studies results on fee premiums from an OLS regression

20

(with size as an additive explanatory variable), the last two columns include size-interactive variables for each explanatory variable in the regression.11 Initially, consider the first two columns of Table 3. We see that fees are positively related to client size (log of assets), the square of the number of employees, a busy-season year-end, the reporting lag, and the choice of a Big 5 auditor. They are negatively related to the return on assets and are not significantly associated with the number of subsidiaries or the market to book ratio. The adjusted R-square value for this specification is 72.1%, which is comparable to those in prior studies. In the last two columns of Table 3, we present an OLS regression with the addition of interactive variables between client size and each explanatory variable. An F test indicates that the inclusion of the interactive terms adds significantly to the model. We find that the coefficient on the square of the number of subsidiaries is now marginally significant and negative, while the coefficient on replag, leverage, and year-end are no longer statistically significant. In addition, the interactive variables for size*log assets, size*year-end, and size*Big 5 are now significant. In particular the coefficient on size*Big 5 is significantly negative, suggesting that as client size increases, the Big 5 fee premium decreases. This is consistent with prior studies (e.g., Francis and Simon, 1987). The adjusted R-Square value is 72.9%. Although the increase in the adjusted R-square value is marginal, the significance of the size-interacted variables indicates that regressions excluding these terms would be biased. However, this specification fails to control for the endogeneity of auditor choice and audit fees, nor does it allow for the interaction between client size and risk or complexity variables in the auditor choice decision. Thus we next proceed to our two-stage specification. Regression Results for Auditor Choice
11 The t-statistics reported throughout the paper are based on heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors. Further

for the self-selection model, the standard errors are corrected to account for the fact that an explanatory variable is

21

Table 4 presents the results of our estimation of the probit regression described in equation (8). In predicting auditor choice, we find that firms choosing Big 5 auditors tend to be larger and less leveraged, but not significantly different from those choosing non-Big 5 auditors in terms of the square root of the number of subsidiaries or the square of the number of employees. When we consider the interaction of these attributes with client size, we find, consistent with our expectations, that as size increases, almost all factors other than size become less important in the choice of auditors. However, return on assets becomes more important with larger, profitable clients less likely to choose Big 5 auditors. As client size increases, the negative relation between leverage and Big 5 choice is lessened; i.e., small, highly levered clients are more likely to choose non-Big 5 auditors than larger, highly levered firms. To assess the accuracy of our stage one classification, we chose a cut-off level of 50%; i.e., if the probability of choosing a Big 5 auditor is greater than 50%, we assume the firm would make that choice. Based on this cut-off, our classification is accurate, on average, 88.5% of the time. Also note that approximately 86.8% of the firms in our sample chose Big 5 auditors. A Hosmer-Lemeshow chisquare statistic was computed. This test divides the sample into groups and compares the predicted values against a perfect model. An insignificant Hosmer-Lemeshow index implies a good model fit. Thus since the index is insignificant, the model is considered a good fit.12 In addition, a likelihood ratio test was performed to test the significance of the model (with interactive size variables) to a model without interactive size variables. The test results indicate that size interactive variables are significant in predicting auditor type. To assist in interpreting the coefficients from the probit estimation, we graph the marginal effects for each independent variable in Figure 1. In the Appendix to the paper, we provide a brief
an estimate from another statistical model. The t-values are based on the method proposed by Greene (1981) to estimate consistent standard errors.

22

discussion of the computation of marginal effects for the probit model. At least two significant issues emerge from an examination of the figure. First, unit changes in the independent variables have a decreasing effect in predicting audit fees as firm size increases. This is less surprising in view of the realization that the probability of auditor choice (being Big 5) cannot exceed one and that very large firms almost always employ Big 5 auditors. However, it is not suggestive of monopolistic pricing for large clientele, as the power to affect audit pricing may rest in the hands of very large audit clients in negotiating within the set of Big 5 auditors. Second, unit changes in leverage, ROA, and size have the greatest impact on auditor choice prediction. Regression Results for Audit Fees Table 5 presents the estimates from our regression of audit fees on the explanatory variables (the second stage of our estimation). Regression equation (9) is estimated separately for Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditees. This specification includes the variable lambda (inverse Mills ratio) from stage one, which controls for potential self-selection bias in the second stage. The significance of the coefficient on the IMR for the Big 5 sample suggests the importance of controlling for self-selection bias. Further, by estimating the regressions separately for Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors, our approach allows the slope coefficients to vary across the two groups. For illustrative purposes, Figures 2 through 4 present the pricing effects for the variables estimated in the fee regression for various size cut-offs of the data. For instance in Figure 2, we formed ten portfolios of Big 5 clients based on size.13 Second, we computed the mean values for all independent variables used in the fee regression. Then we multiplied the regression coefficients by these mean values to obtain the impact on the predicted audit fee. Although we recognize that the separation of our sample into size groups is arbitrary, these figures are presented to aid in the interpretation of the impact of size on audit pricing.

12 A Hosmer-Lemeshow index was computed for the model that did not include interactive size variables. The index

indicated that the model without interactive size variables was a poor model fit.
13 Because of the smaller sample size, we form five portfolios for the non-Big 5 sampple.

23

The intercept for the Big 5 regression is larger than the intercept for the non-Big 5 regression, suggesting that Big 5 auditors include a higher fixed component in audit fees. Control variables exhibiting significance include leverage, ROA, the number of employees, and whether the firms year-end occurred during December. Reporting lag and the number of subsidiaries were not significant in either the Big 5 or Non-Big 5 regressions. Because of the importance of size effects, we discuss the results for our individual variables along with the interaction of each with client size. In fact, because all firms have a non-zero measure for size, the coefficients on the variables without size serve merely as intercept effects. The coefficient on leverage is statistically insignificant for the non-Big 5 subsample but positive and significant for Big 5 auditees. The interactive term for size and leverage is negative and significant for Big 5 auditees. In Figure 2, the impact of leverage on audit pricing decreases as firm size increases (even though the average leverage increases). One possible reason for the insignificance for non-Big 5 clients is that leverage for these clients, given their size and auditor choice, is likely to be private debt and for such debt, increased monitoring by lenders of smaller clientele could mitigate any increased risk due to higher leverage in this subsample. The number of employees picks up another dimension of complexity beyond that of either size or number of subsidiaries. For both the Big 5 and non-Big 5 samples, the coefficient on Sqempl is positive and significant and the interactive term is negative and significant. In Figures 2 and 3, the slope of the predicted fee line for Sqempl is positive for the Big 5 sample and relatively flat for the non-Big 5 sample. For portfolios of smaller non-Big 5 clients, a larger coefficient reflects a greater impact on fees. Neither the Yrend variable nor the interactive term (with client size) is statistically significant for the non-Big 5 sample, while only the interactive term is significant for the Big 5 sample. This implies that year-end does not affect pricing except for the very largest clients that have December year-ends (also see Figure 2). Fees are higher for these clients, consistent with an

24

argument that Big 5 auditors pass the burden of overtime work, etc. during the peak period to some extent to their large clients with calendar year-ends. ROA is not significant in the Big 5 regression and is only significant in the non-Big 5 sample when interacted with size. As size increases (in both samples), average ROA increases (see Figures 2 and 3, and also Table 2). For the non-Big 5 sample, as the firms performance (ROA) increases with firm size, auditors modify their fees downward. This finding is consistent with an argument that nonBig 5 auditors offer discounts to attract these large, profitable (low risk) clientele. As seen throughout the results (tables and figures), the greatest effects on audit fees arise from client size and the fixed component (intercept). The intercept is larger for the Big 5 than the non-Big 5 sample, consistent with an argument that Big 5 auditors pass along the costs of greater training, etc. in the fixed component of fees. In contrast, the coefficient on size is greater for the non-Big 5 sample. As seen in Figure 4, non-Big 5 auditors charge fees that increase at a faster rate than Big 5 auditors. This may occur because of economies of scale for the Big 5 auditors or diseconomies to non-Big 5 auditors auditing very large clients. A large firm would incur a very large audit fee if it hired a nonBig 5 auditor. The results presented thus far are consistent with audit markets being differentiated along auditor and client factors. They are inconsistent with monopolistic pricing by Big 5 auditors among large clients; if anything, the results suggest that very large clientele, who virtually always hire Big 5 auditors, may hold increasing levels of power for negotiating audit fees as client size increases. Given that we allow the slope coefficients to vary across Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors (and the evidence of self-selection bias), we next evaluate the existence (absence) of a Big 5 auditor fee premium in our sample by computing the difference between the actual audit fee paid and the fee that the firm would have paid, on average, had the alternative choice on auditor-type been made, [E(Alternate fee)]. We follow Chapter 9 of Maddala (1983) and Section 3.3 of Heckman, Lalonde

25

and Smith (1999), both of which provide detailed discussions of self-selection bias and evaluation problems that require estimation of counterfactuals. We report the mean and median in the last row of Panel A. We present the comparative data first for firms actually choosing Big 5 auditors, and then for firms choosing non-Big 5 auditors. The differences are negative in every case, suggesting that if Big 5 auditees had chosen non-Big 5 auditors, their audit fees would have been higher. Similarly, we find that if non-Big 5 auditees had chosen to hire Big 5 auditors, their fees [E(Alternate fee)] would also have been significantly higher on average than the actual fees paid. These results suggest that firms, on average, self select an auditor type that minimizes their audit fees. Explanations for a Big 5 auditor fee premium that are based on superior reputation or deeper pockets of Big 5 auditors imply that firms choosing Big 5 auditors pay higher fees than the amount they would have paid had they chosen a non-Big 5 auditor. However, our results indicate just the opposite and do not support the view that Big 5 auditors charge more than that which would have been charged by non-Big 5 auditors, given the firms' characteristics. However, our findings are consistent with audit markets being differentiated along dimensions other than just reputation and deep-pockets. Extending the arguments from Simunic (1980) that Big 5 auditors enjoy economies of scale, we suggest efficiency and differences in audit costs as one likely dimension. Auditors may structure their businesses in a manner that appeals to specific client segments. For instance, Big 5 auditors invest more in technology, training and facilities, enabling them to carry out audits more efficiently for large, relatively complex clients. However, the fixed costs of these investments may not be attractive to small clients in general. In general, firms selfselect the most cost-effective auditor given their firm-specific characteristics. Further, our results are inconsistent with monopolistic pricing among large clientele. Also, in comparing coefficients across Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors in the audit fee regressions, we observe Big 5 auditors fee specifications to reveal larger intercepts but smaller slope

26

coefficients on most variables associated with client and audit complexity. These findings are consistent with the above argument, which suggests that Big 5 auditors charge a greater fixed fee component for audit services, but lower increments for heightened levels of complexity and client size. Robustness Tests We next repeated the auditor choice and audit fee regressions with additional variables or other modifications to consider the robustness of our results to model specification. First, we recognize that above a certain size threshold, virtually all listed firms select Big 5 auditors. Thus, we repeat our tests with extremely large firms eliminated from the sample. We tried various cutoffs, and our results were remarkably robust. For example, we eliminated all Big 5 firms larger than the largest non-Big 5 client, thus eliminating 195 Big 5 firms.14 Our coefficients and their statistical significance are qualitatively similar to those reported in Table 5. When we evaluate the existence (absence) of a Big 5 auditor fee premium in this sample by computing the difference between the actual audit fee paid and the fee that the firm would have paid, on average, had the alternative choice on auditor-type been made, [E(Alternate fee)], we find a significant difference for both the Big 5 and non-Big 5 samples. For the Big 5 sample, for example, the difference is -2.3, consistent in direction with the results presented in Table 5. See Table 6 for the differences between actual and alternative fees for the various robustness tests described in this section. Next, we introduced additional variables used in some prior studies of audit fees to see if their inclusion made any difference in our results. For example, we introduced the quick ratio (as a measure of audit risk) and the ratio of current to total assets (as a measure of audit or effort intensiveness), as well as the interaction between each of these new variables and firm size, to
14 We also used a size cut-off that eliminated the top 5% of non-Big 5 firms with similar results.

27

both stage one and stage two of our model. This specification of our model had slightly better predictive power than the one presented (over 89% of the firms were correctly classified), but all of our main conclusions were unaltered. We chose to present the more streamlined model (excluding these variables) since our results are already somewhat cumbersome due to the inclusion of so many size-interactive variables. Once more, the test to evaluate the existence (absence) of a Big 5 auditor fee premium in our sample by computing the difference between the actual audit fee paid and the fee that the firm would have paid, on average, had the alternative choice on auditor-type been made, [E(Alternate fee)] is statistically significant for both Big 5 and non-Big 5 samples. The mean difference for the Big 5 sample is -0.96, and that for the non-Big 5 sample is -0.94. In view of the importance of the size effect to our research question, we next wish to consider the possibility that using a different measure of client firm size might lead to different conclusions. Thus, we replace client size with the square root of the number of employees in both stage one and stage two for all interactive variables. Once again, our results remain qualitatively unchanged. The difference between the actual audit fee paid and the fee that the firm would have paid under the alternative choice is -0.61 (p<0.0001) for the Big 5 sample, and -0.26 (p<0.0001) for the non-Big 5 sample. Thus, throughout our robustness procedures, our basic conclusion remains unchanged: no Big 5 auditor fee premium is observed in our sample once we control for self-selection and size nonlinearities. To the contrary, most firms appear to be hiring the type of auditor which results in the most economical and efficient audit based on their size and other specific firm characteristics. 5. Conclusion Prior research has examined audit pricing for publicly held firms and provided some evidence of a Big 8 premium in pricing. More recent research provides evidence that private

28

firms do not pay such a premium on average; i.e. a premium is observed using standard OLS regressions, but it vanishes once self-selection bias is controlled for. This paper returns to the setting of listed U.S. firms and provides evidence that, on average, the firms in the sample examined also do not pay a Big 5 premium (once self-selection bias and nonlinearities in client size are taken into account). Consistent with the findings of Chaney, Jeter, and Shivakumar (2004), we find that publicly traded client firms choosing Big 5 auditors generally would have faced higher fees had they chosen non-Big 5 auditors, given their firm-specific characteristics. Our results are consistent with audit markets for listed firms, as well as for private firms, being segmented along cost-effective lines. In addition, we extend the research investigating the effect of client size on components of audit pricing and auditor choice. Auditors pricing their services differentially for clients of varying size must consider such issues as risk, reputation, and economies of scale. For example, because of greater exposure, an audit failure in a large client firm tends to be more costly for the auditor than an audit failure of a smaller client. While larger companies generally have more sophisticated internal control systems and more extensive staffs of internal auditors than smaller companies, they may also face greater pressure to meet or beat analysts expectations (Barton and Simko, 2002). Larger firms may be argued to have greater bargaining power with auditors (Kim, Liu, and Rhee, 2003), and auditors may covet the status of auditing the very largest clients in a particular geographic area or in a particular industry. Hence nonlinearities in the relation between client size and various determinants of audit fees are likely. Using the two-stage Heckman approach to test for self-selection in a sample of listed U.S. firms, we reject a null hypothesis that clients are randomly allocated across Big 5 and non-Big 5 auditors. After controlling for self-selection and size nonlinearities, we find no evidence of a Big 5 auditor fee premium. While by no means constituting a direct test of audit quality, an

29

examination of fees paid to Big 5 versus non-Big 5 auditors does shed some insight into how the respective groups of auditors are valued by their clientele. Our findings suggest: (a) choice of a Big 5 auditor need not necessarily signal auditor superiority as the auditor selection may instead be dictated by cost considerations; and (b) in contrast to the argument that large auditors charge a premium relative to smaller auditors to cover additional litigation costs (Dye, 1993), audit markets appear to be segmented along cost-efficient dimensions. This cost-segmentation argument may also explain why Big 5 auditors almost exclusively audit larger clients. Further, our results are inconsistent with monopolistic pricing among large clients; to the contrary, some evidence suggests that the power to affect pricing may, to some extent, lie in the hands of very large clientele. In general, the auditor type (Big 5 or non-Big 5) best equipped to audit a particular client efficiently is usually selected, and audit fee premiums are most likely to result for those clients that depart from that choice. Finally, our findings emphasize the importance of controlling for self-selection and size nonlinearities in any study using standard OLS regressions to control for client size or auditor size (or quality).

30

Appendix Marginal Effects for Variables estimated using a Probit Model Define a linear function that determines the probability of an event: Z = 0 + 1X1 + +kXk. F(Z), the standardized cumulative normal distribution, gives the probability of the event occurring for any value of Z: pi = F(Zi). Using maximum likelihood, estimates of the parameters (i) are computed. The marginal effect of Xi is p/Xi. This is computed as

p dp Z = = f (Z ) i X i dZ X i Where f (Z) is the derivative of F(Z), the cumulative standard normal distribution, or simply the standardized normal distribution: f (Z ) = 1 2 e ..5 z
2

31

References

Barton, J. and P. Simko, 2002, The balance sheet as an earnings management constraint, The Accounting Review 77 (Supplement): 1-27. Basu, S., L. Hwang, and C. Jan, 2001, Differences in conservatism between Big 8 and non-Big 8 auditors, Working Paper, Emory University. Beatty, R., 1989, Auditor reputation and the pricing of initial public offerings, The Accounting Review 64, 693-709. Carson, Elizabeth, Neil Fargher, Daniel Simon and Mark Taylor, 2004, Audit fees and market segmentation further evidence on how client size matters within the context of audit fee models. Journal of International Auditing. Chaney, P., D. Jeter, and L. Shivakumar, 2004, Self-selection of auditors and audit pricing in private firms, The Accounting Review 79: 51-72. Copley, P., J.J. Gaver and K.M. Gaver, 1995, Simultaneous estimation of the supply and demand of differentiated audits: Evidence from municipal audit market, Journal of Accounting Research 33, 137-155. Craswell, A., J. Francis, and S. Taylor, 1995, Auditor brand name reputations and industry specializations, Journal of Accounting and Economics 20:3, 297-322. Datar , S.M., G.A. Feltham and J.S. Hughes, 1991, The role of audits and audit quality in valuing new issues, Journal of Accounting and Economics 14,3-49. DeAngelo, L., 1981, Auditor size and audit quality, Journal of Accounting and Economics 3, 183-199. Deltas, George and Rajib Doogar, 2003, Product differentiation and cost differentiation by large audit firms, Working paper, University of Illinois, Urbana Champagne. Dye, R.A., 1993, Auditing standards, legal liability and auditor wealth, Journal of Political Economy 101, 887-914. Ferguson, A., J. Francis, and D. Stokes, 2003, The effects of firm-wide and office-level industry experience on audit pricing, Working Paper. Francis, J., 1984, The effect of audit firm size on audit prices: A study of the Australian market, Journal of Accounting and Economics 6, 133-151. Francis, J. and D. Simon, 1987, A test of audit pricing in the small-client segment of the U.S. audit market, The Accounting Review 62, 145-157.

32

Francis, J. and D. Stokes, 1986, Audit prices, product differentiation, and scale economies: Further evidence from the Australian audit market, Journal of Accounting Research 24, 383393. Greene, William, 1981, Sample selection bias as a specification error: comment, Econometrica 49, 795-798. Heckman, J. James, 1979, "Sample selection bias as a specification error", Econometrica 47, 153-162. Heckman, J. James, Robert J. Lalonde and Jeffrey A. Smith, 1999, "The economics and econometrics of active labor market programs," Chapter 31, in Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 3A, Eds. O. Ashenfelter and D. Card. Ireland, Jan C. and Clive Lennox, 2002, The large audit firm fee premium: A case of selectivity bias? forthcoming, Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance. Kim, Yangseon, Caixing Liu, and S. Ghon Rhee, 2003, The effect of firm size on earnings management, Working Paper, the University of Hawaii. Lee, Lung-Fei, 1979, Identification and estimation in binary choice models with limited (censored) dependent variables, Econometrica 47, 977-996. Maddala, G.S., 1983, Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics (Cambridge University Press). Mansi, S., W. Maxwell, and D. Miller, 2004, Does audit quality and tenure matter to investors? Evidence from the bond market, Journal of Accounting Research 42(4), pp. 755-793. Mayhew, B. and M. Wilkins, 2003, The Impact of Audit Firm Industry Specialization on Fees Charged to Firms Going Public. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory 22, pp. 33-52. Palmrose, Z., 1986, Audit fees and auditor size: Further evidence, Journal of Accounting Research 24: 97-110. Petroni, K. and M. Beasley, 1996, Errors in accounting estimates and their relation to audit firm type, Journal of Accounting Research 34(1), pp. 151-171. Pittman, J. and S. Fortin, 2004, Auditor choice and the cost of debt capital for newly public firms, Journal of Accounting & Economics 27, pp. 113-136. Shailer, G., L. Cummings, E. Vatuloka and S. Welch, 2004, Discretionary Pricing in a Monopolistic Audit Market, International Journal of Auditing 8(3) 2004 pp.263-277 Simunic, D., 1980, The pricing of audit services: theory and evidence, Journal of Accounting Research 18, 161-190.

33

Teoh, S. and T.J. Wong, 1993, Perceived audit quality and the earnings response coefficient, The Accounting Review 68(2), pp. 346-366. Titman, S. and B. Trueman, 1986, Information quality and the valuation of new issues, Journal of Accounting & Economics 8, 159-172. Watts, R., and J. Zimmerman, 1983, Agency problems, auditing and the theory of the firm: Some evidence, Journal of Law & Economics 26, 613-633.

34

Table 1 Descriptive Statistics

Variables Audit Fees Lfee $ Thous. Log(size ) $ Mill. Lev

Total (n=3,341) Mean Median 5.347 412.6 5.011 1,013 0.163 -0.097 Sq. root in Thous. Sq. root Number Yrend Replag 1.482 5.381 1.008 1.513 0.639 51.67 5.208 182.69 4.912 135.91 0.086 0.025 0.782 0.612 1.000 1.000 1.000 45.00

Big 5 (n=2,883) Mean Median 5.495 458.7 5.316 1,159 0.157 -0.091 1.627 6.107 0.995 1.497 0.649 47.96 5.323 205 5.214 183.86 0.080 0.029 0.941 0.886 1.000 1.000 1.000 43.00

Non-Big 5 (n=458) Mean Median 4.417 122.6 3.091 93.12 0.203 -0.137 0.569 0.806 1.086 1.609 0.576 75.03 4.360 78.25 2.859 17.447 0.133 -0.002 0.333 0.111 1.000 1.000 1.000 84.00

Differences Mean Median t-test z-test -26.720 ** -16.89 **

Size Leverage ROA Employees Subsidiarie s Year-end Reporting Lag

-29.59 ** 4.36 ** -2.29 * 2.71 *

-18.30 ** 3.83 ** -3.31** 1.63

-22.27 ** -2.93 ** 24.52 **

-14.65 ** -3.02 ** 17.21 **

** Significant at the .01 level, * significant at the .05 level. Lfeei= Logarithm of audit fees; Sizei = Logarithm of end of year total assets; Levi = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; Sqrtsubi = square root of the number of subsidiaries; ROAi = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; Sqrtempli = Square root of the number of employees; Yrendi = 1 if the firms year-end occurs in December, 0 otherwise; Replagi = Number of days between the firms year-end and the earnings announcement date.

35

Table 2 Spearman Cross-Correlations (significance level)

Lfee Lfee Size Lev ROA Sqempl Sqrtsub Yrend Replag Big 5
n= 3,341

Size

Lev

ROA

Sqempl

Sqrtsub Yrend

Replag

Big 5

1.000 0.828 (0.00) 0.123 (0.00) 0.231 (0.00) 0.700 (0.00) 0.060 (0.00) 0.066 (0.00) -0.386 (0.00) 0.357 (0.00) 1.000 0.132 (0.00) 0.415 (0.00) 0.752 (0.00) 0.079 (0.00) 0.033 (0.05) -0.537 (0.00) 0.396 (0.00) 1.000 0.170 (0.00) 0.112 (0.00) 0.093 (0.00) 0.007 (0.69) 0.268 (0.00) -0.082 (0.00) 1.000 0.309 (0.00) 0.104 (0.00) -0.104 (0.00) -0.185 (0.00) 0.045 (0.01) 1.000 0.122 (0.00) -0.016 (0.37) -0.333 (0.00) 0.204 (0.00) 1.000 -0.076 (0.00) 0.047 (0.01) -0.044 (0.01) 1.000 -0.059 (0.00) 0.052 (0.00) 1.000 -0.389 (0.00) 1.000

Lfeei= Logarithm of audit fees; Sizei = Logarithm of end of year total assets; Levi = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; Sqrtsubi = square root of the number of subsidiaries; ROAi = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; Sqrtempli = Square root of the number of employees; Yrendi = 1 if the firms year-end occurs in December, 0 otherwise; Replagi = Number of days between the firms year-end and the earnings announcement date; Big 5= 1 if firm i chose a Big 5 auditor in year t; 0 otherwise.

36

Table 3 Fee Regressions with Big 5 Indicator Variable With/without Interactive Size Variables (OLS)

Big 5 Dummy OLS Variable


Intercept Size Lev Sqrtsub ROA Sqrtempl Yrend Replag Big 5 Size*Big 5 Size*Size Size*Lev Size*Sqrtsub Size*ROA Size*Sqrtempl Size*Yrend Size*Replag F test significance of interactive terms

Coeff. 2.72 0.41 0.02 -0.01 -0.37 0.10 0.07 0.00 0.16

t-stat 44.15 43.98 0.45 -1.01 -12.25 12.58 3.41 6.95 5.07

Big 5 Dummy OLS With Size interactive variables Coeff. t-stat 3.37 20.97 0.12 2.41 0.25 1.57 -0.07 -1.81 -0.28 -4.12 0.10 2.80 -0.05 -0.89 0.00 1.12 0.46 5.73 -0.07 0.03 -0.04 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.02 0.00 -3.17 7.49 -1.45 1.26 -0.34 -1.58 2.27 1.28 13.30 72.9 3,341

Adj R Sq. (%) No. of obs.


Where:

72.1 3,341

Lfeei Big 5i Sizei Levi Sqrtsubi ROAi Sqrtempli Yrendi Replagi

= Logarithm of audit fees; = 1 if firm i chose a Big 5 auditor in year t; 0 otherwise; = Logarithm of end of year total assets; = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; = square root of the number of subsidiaries; = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; = Square root of the number of employees; = 1 if the firms year-end occurs in December, 0 otherwise; = Number of days between the firms year-end and the earnings announcement date.

37

Table 4 Auditor Demand Equation

Intercept Size Lev Sqrtsub ROA Sqrtempl Size*Size Size*Lev Size*Sqrtsub Size*ROA Size*Sqrtempl Model likelihood Hosmer/Lemeshow LR test of specification N= % Correctly Classified % Using Big 5 Pseudo R-square

Coefficient Chi-sq value -1.534 31.09 0.806 38.01 -2.069 17.40 0.078 0.38 -0.079 0.12 0.136 0.77 -0.031 0.252 -0.037 -0.287 -0.018 3.66 4.97 1.53 10.78 0.68 791.49 8.77 38.54 3,341 88.5 86.3 0.383

Pr > t 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.54 0.73 0.38 0.06 0.03 0.22 0.00 0.41 0.00 0.36 0.00

The demand equation estimated is: Big 5i = 1 + 2Sizei + 3Levi + 4Sqrtsubi + 5ROAi + 6Sqrtempli + 7Sizei* Sizei + 8Sizei*Levi + 9Sizei*Sqrtsubi +10Sizei*ROAi +11Sizei*Sqrtempli + i where Big 5= 1 if firm i chose a Big 5 auditor in year t; 0 otherwise, Sizei = Logarithm of end of year total assets; Levi = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; Sqrtsubi = square root of the number of subsidiaries; ROAi = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; Sqrtempli = Square root of the number of employees.

38

Table 5 Fee Regressions by Auditor Type Panel A: Big Five Coeff. t-stat

Non-Big Five Coeff. t-stat 2.99 0.62 -1.05 0.10 0.03 0.49 0.03 0.00 0.05 -0.01 -0.05 -0.49 -0.07 0.01 0.00 1.19 56.1 458 -1.04 -214.20 -1.02 7.91 2.00 -1.35 0.97 0.17 2.48 0.28 0.85 2.65 -0.05 -1.60 -2.53 -1.95 0.19 0.63 1.76

Intercept Size Lev Sqrtsub ROA Sqrtempl Yrend Replag Size*Size Size*Lev Size*Sqrtsub Size*ROA Size*Sqrtempl Size*Yrend Size*Replag Lambda () Adj R Sq. (%) No. of obs. Mean (ActualExpected fee) t-value Median (Actual Expected fee)
Where:

4.66 -0.19 0.87 -0.07 -0.11 0.14 -0.08 0.00 0.05 -0.13 0.01 -0.02 -0.01 0.03 0.00 -0.45 70.2 2,883 -2.58 -194.62 -2.53

13.56 -1.78 3.18 -1.46 -0.99 3.23 -1.22 0.46 5.98 -2.93 1.23 -0.88 -2.34 2.41 1.35 -2.30

Lfeei Big 5i Sizei Levi

= Logarithm of audit fees (dependent variable); = 1 if firm i chose a Big 5 auditor in year t; 0 otherwise; = Logarithm of end of year total assets; = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; = square root of the number of subsidiaries; Sqrtsubi = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; ROAi Sqrtempli = Square root of the number of employees; = 1 if the firms year-end occurs in December, 0 otherwise; Yrendi = Number of days between the firms year-end and the earnings announcement date; Replagi Lambdai () = Inverse Mills Ratio.

39

Table 5 (continued) Panel B:

Mean (Actual-Expected fee) t-value Median (Actual Expected fee)

Quartile 1 (Small) Big 5 Non-Big 5 Clients Clients -1.87 -1.03 -124.18 -165.10 -1.77 -1.01

Quartile 2 Big 5 Non-Big 5 Clients Clients -2.32 -1.04 -115.74 -162.06 -2.20 -1.04

Quartile 3 Big 5 Non-Big 5 Clients Clients -2.66 -1.09 -147.32 -78.34 -2.58 -1.09

Quartile 4 (Large) Big 5 Non-Big 5 Clients Clients -3.19 -1.14 -140.32 -31.34 -3.08 -1.15

40

Table 6 Robustness Tests Counterfactuals: Actual Fees less Expected Fees for Alternative Auditor

Big 5 Clients
Test 1: Truncated firms larger than the largest firm in the non-Big 5 sample Mean (Actual-Expected fee) t-value Median (Actual Expected fee)

Non-Big 5 Clients

-2.30 -189.31 -2.27 2,688 58.3 87.9%

-1.22 -237.90 -1.21 458 56.1

No. of obs. Adj R Sq. (%) Fee regression Percent correctly classified Demand equation
Test 2: Added quick ratio and ratio of current to total assets to both the demand and fee regressions Mean (Actual-Expected fee) t-value Median (Actual Expected fee)

-0.96 -128.99 -0.92 2,784 74.2 89.1%

-0.94 -240.81 -0.94 439 58.3

No. of obs. Adj R Sq. (%) Fee regression Percent correctly classified Demand equation
Test 3: Alternative size variable (replaced asset size with square root of employees) Mean (Actual-Expected fee) t-value Median (Actual Expected fee)

-0.61 -66.09 -0.54 2,883 71.4 88.8%

-0.26 -40.26 -0.29 458 57.5

No. of obs. Adj R Sq. (%) Fee regression Percent correctly classified Demand equation

41

Figure 1 Marginal Effects for the Independent Variables on Auditor Choice


0.3 Size 0.2

0.1

Marginal Effects On Auditor Choice

-0.1 ROA -0.2

-0.3

-0.4 Leverage -0.5

-0.6

-0.7

Small

Large

Rank of Size (10 groups)


Size Lev ROA Employ Sub

See appendix for a discussion of the method of computation. For each observation, the marginal effect for each variable was estimated. Then, ten portfolios were created based on firm size. The plot includes the average of the marginal effect for each portfolio. Sizei Levi Sqrtsubi ROAi Sqrtempli = Logarithm of end of year total assets; = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; = square root of the number of subsidiaries; = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; = Square root of the number of employees.

42

Figure 2 Effects of Independent Variables On the Prediction of Big 5 Audit Fees (Lfee) (Including Size Interactive Terms)
Predicted Fee Effects Big Five
0.2

0.15

0.1 Leverage ROA Employee Sub Replag Yrend

0.05

-0.05

-0.1 rank of size

Variable Size Lev ROA Yrend Replag Sqrtsub Sqempl n=

1 2.330 0.104 -0.484 0.646 66.823 1.014 0.308 288

2 3.408 0.112 -0.247 0.677 60.868 0.963 0.442 288

3 4.033 0.130 -0.181 0.644 53.429 0.839 0.578 289

4 4.509 0.129 -0.128 0.667 50.278 0.845 0.787 288

Rank of Size Portfolios 5 6 7 4.976 5.457 5.966 0.140 0.145 0.165 -0.065 0.010 0.018 0.653 0.640 0.649 48.764 44.785 43.059 0.880 0.920 1.072 0.960 1.233 1.528 288 289 288

8 6.502 0.226 0.051 0.612 42.509 1.072 2.141 289

9 7.267 0.214 0.049 0.594 37.017 1.144 2.893 288

10 8.708 0.202 0.072 0.708 32.097 1.205 5.403 288

Sizei Levi Sqrtsubi ROAi Yrendi Replagi Sqrtempli

= Logarithm of end of year total assets; = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; = square root of the number of subsidiaries; = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; = 1 if the firms year-end occurs in December, 0 otherwise; = Number of days between the firms year-end and the earnings announcement date; = Square root of the number of employees.

43

Figure 3 Effects of Independent Variables On the Prediction of Non-Big 5 Audit Fees (Lfee) (Including Size Interactive Terms)
Non-big 5 Predicted Fees
0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2 Leverage ROA Employee Sub Replag Yrend

0.1

0 1 -0.1 2 3 4 5

-0.2

-0.3

-0.4 Rank of Size (5 groups)

Rank of Size Portfolios Variabl e Size Lev ROA Yrend Replag Sqrtsub Sqempl n= Sizei Levi Sqrtsubi ROAi Yrendi Replagi 1 1.347 0.152 -0.428 0.516 85.967 1.177 0.208 91 2 2.236 0.189 -0.221 0.533 80.728 1.047 0.287 92 3 2.874 0.200 -0.084 0.598 78.500 1.016 0.417 92 4 3.706 0.225 0.006 0.576 71.413 1.024 0.583 92 5 5.296 0.249 0.042 0.659 58.462 1.168 1.355 91

= Logarithm of end of year total assets; = long-term debt plus debt in current liabilities divided by market value of equity plus total liabilities; = square root of the number of subsidiaries; = Earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets; = 1 if the firms year-end occurs in December, 0 otherwise; = Number of days between the firms year-end and the earnings announcement date;

44

= Square root of the number of employees. Sqrtempli Figure 4 Effects of Size and Size Interactive Terms On the Prediction of Big 5 and Non-Big 5 Audit Fees (Lfee)
4

3.5

2.5

Big 5 Non Big 5

1.5

0.5

0 Rank of Size (5 Groups)

Auditor Big 5 Non-Big 5

Variable Size n= Size n=

Rank of Size 1 2 3 2.869 576 1.347 91 4.271 577 2.236 92 5.217 577 2.874 92

4 6.234 577 3.706 92

5 7.987 576 5.296 91

Sizei

= Logarithm of end of year total assets;

45

S-ar putea să vă placă și