Sunteți pe pagina 1din 249

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 2 Economics of non renewable resources


1. Objectives and outline
Oil, gas and coal are considered as non renewable resources. There stock is limited and it is increasingly costly to produce them. In this chapter we explain briefly what the theory of non-renewable resources can offer as insights. The detailed application to the three primary resources is left for later chapters. This chapter also prepares for chapters 3 and 4 where we discuss the climate change problem, environmental externalities and sustainability in the presence of exhaustible energy resources and long term environmental problems. The key questions we want to address in this chapter are: 1. What makes a given resource exhaustible? 2. How to use optimally exhaustible resources? : save them for later or use them now? 3. How is the switch between exhaustible and non-exhaustible resources operated? 4. Would profit maximizing resource owners take the right decisions? 5. How would new information about the resource stock or future demand affect price levels and production profile over time? 6. This is to a large extend knowledge derived from theoretical propositions, has this theory been verified for particular resources? Section 2 classifies resources into exhaustible and non exhaustible resources. Section 3 gives some data on energy reserves. Sections 4, 5 and 6 analyze the optimal allocation of exhaustible resources over time. Section 7 studies how markets allocate resources over time. Section 8 concludes with a brief review of empirical tests of the theory.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

2. Classifying resources
The exhaustibility of a resource can be determined using the simple decision criteria of Table 2.1 Natural Replenishment?

No (= non-renewable resource) Recyclable? Yes (copper, gold) No (oil, gas, coal)

Yes (= renewable resource) Depends on human activity? Yes (water, biomass) No (sun, wind)

Table 2.1: Definition of non renewable resources Within the category of non renewable resources, two dimensions matter for the classification of resources: the cost of producing them (vertical axis in Table 2.2) and the geological probability that they exist (horizontal axis in Table 2.2).

Table 2.2: Classification of resources into reserves 1

Taken from Tietenberg T., Environmental and resource economics, Addison Wesley, 2000, 5the edition, page 127

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost The vertical economic dimension has two categories:, economic: current price is larger than the marginal production cost, subeconomic: current price is below the marginal production cost,

The horizontal geological certainty dimension has many subdivisions: identified: geological location, quality, quantity is known and supported by engineering measurements measured: known from samples with margin of error of 20%, indicated: known partly from samples and partly from geological

undiscovered: unspecified bodies of mineral bearing material surmised to exist on the basis of broad geological knowledge and theory, hypothetical: supposed to exist in a well specified mining district, speculative: undiscovered resources that may exist in favorable geological settings where no discoveries have been made

Often one encounters notions as current reserves: resources that are known and cost effective to produce, resource endowment: estimation of the stock in the earths crust that could be mined without considering the cost. One also uses the static reserve index or R/P ratio = current reserves divided by current consumption, which gives the number of years that the current consumption could be sustained with the current reserves. But this only holds if the current consumption is constant and the current reserves do not change.

3. Some data on energy resources

Estimates on the available resources of oil, gas and coal vary a lot. Some of the resources are controlled by governments and they do not update regularly their resource data. Take Saoudi-Arabia as example: the resource stock of oil is unchanged since 1989 although they have been producing a lot (see BP statistical review). We give her first orders of magnitude relying on mainly 2 sources: the BP statistical review and the IEA Energy

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

Outlook 2008. For oil and gas we will discuss the estimation of reserves more in detail later.

Oil
For oil the BP statistical review gives 1237.9 Billion barrels or Reserves/ production ratio of 41.6 years. These are proved reserves defined as reserves that are known and can with reasonable certainty be recovered profitably at current prices. The recent IEA world energy outlook shows a graph that integrates the cost side and the resource side : :

Figure 2.1 Ultimately recoverable resources of oil (source: IEA 2008) We see that the BP estimate of reserves is only a small subset of the ultimate recoverable reserves and that the conversion of gas and coal to liquid fuels can be considered as a backstop technology. A backstop technology is a technology that produces a substitute at a more or less constant cost. We also notice that OPEC holds the cheap reserves.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

Gas
According to the BP statistical review there are 177.36 Trillion m of gas or an R/P ratio of 60.3 years. The current reserves of gas are more or less equivalent to those of oil 2but because consumption is lower, the R/P ratio is larger.

Table 2.2 Proven reserves and ultimately recoverable reserves (source IEA, 2008) Table 2 relates the 177 Trillion m proved reserves to the total resource base ultimately recoverable conventional resources of 443.3 Trillion m. As in the case of oil one notices a large difference between proved reserves and the ultimate recoverable resources. Table 2 does not contain the non-conventional gas (coalbed methane, tight gas sands, gas shales) that could total 900 Tcm, with 25% in Canada and US and 15% each in China, India and Russia (IEA, 2008).

Coal
For coal, the BP statistical review mentions 847 billion ton of coal current reserves and an R/P ratio of 133 years. This quantity corresponds to 3.3 times the quantity of oil3. The

2 Using the BP statistical review of World Energy (approx conversion factor table), one can convert 1 billion of m of Natural gas into 6.29 million barrels of oil equivalent.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

reserves data for coal have since long not been updated because most producing countries had plenty of coal. So reserves are much larger than reported here (IEA, 2008).

4. Optimal Allocation of resources basic concepts


In order to compare alternative uses of a non renewable resource over time, we need a clear definition of economic optimality. The simplest notion one can use is the sum of the discounted economic surplus. There are many caveats in using this concept, we return to this problem later. First we explain economic surplus in one period and the discounting and summation over time.

Economic surplus
We take a world view here and consider one period (say one year). A world view means that we do not care who in the world has the resource, obviously a strong asumption to which we return later. A resource can be used for many purposes, some uses are easily substitutable, and others are not. Take gasoline for cars as example, I can use a car for 10 000 km/year but also for 20 000 km/ year, the 10 000 km/ year are uses that I could do without. I can also invest in a more fuel efficient but more expensive car etc. For a given state of technology, given income distribution and given prices of other goods (say cars), one can rank the uses of a given resource from very valuable, difficult to substitute and for which people would be prepared to pay a very high price to uses that could be easily substituted. In Figure 3 the Willingness to Pay (WTP (Q) curve reports for every unit of the resource, the highest willingness to pay. In a world where one is not concerned about income distribution, this is also the best use of that resource. The users of te resource can be consumers or firms. The other curve reported in Figure 3 is the marginal production cost function (MC(Q)). This is the cost of producing (extracting) an extra unit of the resource. The first quantity of the resource produced, if allocated to the user with the highest WTP, has a value or benefit A because there is a user prepared

3 Using BP op;cit. one finds that 1 million of coal is equivalent to 1/1.5 million ton of oil equivalent and to 7.33/1.5 million barrels of oil.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

to pay A. This user is prepared to pay A because it either gives him direct benefits (heating the room, driving a km) or allows to avoid more expensive solutions for the same purpose (taking the train, using electric home heating). This first quantity costs at the economy only C, so the net benefit of this first unit is the difference A-C. Continuing the reasoning for larger and larger quantities one maximizes the net benefit or economic surplus by producing a quantity Q*. This quantity maximizes the economic surplus (area ABC, the difference between the value to users and the production cost). Pushing the production level further to a level Q** would reduce the economic surplus as the extra quantity has uses with lower and lower value but costs more to produce. How can one guarantee that this economic surplus is created by producing a quantity Q* Two conditions need to be fulfilled. First the quantity produced has to go to those with the highest WTP. This is guaranteed if one uses the price mechanism to distribute Q*: an auction (selling the good to the highest bidders, where last unit is sold at price D) could do the job. If the price mechanism is not used it is hard to generate the same economic surplus. To see why imagine that the good is given to all users that show an interest. Then all users that have a positive WTP are candidate, but the quantity available is only Q*, this means some rationing and if goods are rationed at random, the average WTP of the receivers of the good is more like E and total economic surplus equals only EFBC, clearly lower than ABC. Second, the good has to be produced by the producers with the lowest costs. If this is not the case, economic surplus is clearly lower. In a market economy with perfect competition (consumers and consumers take the prices as given) the economic surplus would be maximized and the price level would be D. The total economic surplus (here ABC) is then divided between consumers (consumer surplus ADB) and producers (producers surplus DBC).

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

A WTP Price Marginal cost

Willingness to Pay function (WTP (Q) ranking all potential uses

Marginal production cost Function MC(Q) E D


lu rp su c mi no o Ec s

F B

Q*

Q quantity

Figure 2.3 Economic surplus We will use the notion of economic surplus many times in this course. It is useful because it allows us to discuss economic efficiency at the level of one market without having to consider the rest of the economy. This is only valid under rather strict assumptions 4 . Important is first that there are no distortions (important taxes that create wedge between price (or WTP of consumers) and the marginal cost. Second condition is that we are indifferent about the distribution of income. Or equivalently, that there exist perfect redistribution instruments that can be used once the economic surplus has been realized.

Interest rate, discounted sum


When one needs to decide on the allocation of a given resource stock over different years, can we use the simple sum of the economic surpluses used in different years? In principle no. In our analysis we will assume that there is any year always the opportunity to invest money in the capital market and realize a certain return at interest rate r.

Mass Colell, Whinston, Green J., Micro-economic theory, Oxford Univ Press, p325-345

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

In most of the text that follows, we will always work with a real interest rate r, this is equal to the nominal interest rate nr corrected by the expected inflation rate i, so
r nr / 1 i

We also assume that this is a risk free interest rate. In principle the capital market will reward more risky investments with a higher return. The existence of a capital market where a real return of r can be obtained per year has far reaching implications for the allocation of resources over time. Whenever one can generate an economic surplus of 1 Euro this year rather than next year, one will prefer to realize it this year as it allows lending the Euro to the capital market and getting 1+ r Euro next year. The latter option is clearly superior to realizing an economic surplus of 1 Euro next year. The interest rate (and alternative investment and lending opportunities at fixed rate r) allow us to define the discounted sum of economic surpluses in years 1,2,,T ES(T) as: ES(1),

discounted sum =

(1 r )
1

ES (t )
t

Those interested in business economics will recognize the similarity with the discounted cash flow method for selecting investment projects. The three main differences are that, a firm makes an analysis using nominal values (depreciation is in nominal terms), a firm will use its own (nominal) cost of capital and that economic surplus is replaced by net cash flow of the project. We have developed up to now criteria for optimal efficiency from a static point of view (maximize economic surplus within one period) and from a dynamic point of view (allocation of resources over time). period model. We can now start to use these concepts to study the allocation of non renewable resources over time, first in a 2 period model and then in an n

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

10

5. Optimal allocation of non renewable resources in a 2 period model


Introduction
In this section we will use a simple model with a linear demand function and illustrate the results with a numerical example 5 that everybody can check. We start with an example without scarcity and tackle then the case with a scarcity constraint.

Model assumptions
We use the following definitions and assumptions:

p = f(q) , the WTP function and its inverse function q = f(p) that is called the demand function, identical for all the periods we consider
q p

or (WTP:) p a b q

p = price MC = MEC = constant marginal extraction cost, Q = fixed quantity of the non renewable resource, r = real interest rate, all decisions are made by a central authority that maximizes the discounted sum of economic surpluses.

For the numerical illustrations, we use the following values:


p= 8 - 0.4 q MEC = 2 $ r = 0.10 Q > 30

We borrow the simple model and numerical example from Tietenberg (2000)

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

11

No scarcity case
Consider first the problem of allocating the resource when there is no scarcity. For our numerical example, this means maximizing the discounted sum of the economic surpluses realized in the two years: as there is no active resource constraint, it is sufficient to push exploration and production up to the point where WTP=MC in each period. In Figure 4 we see that this implies a consumption of 15 units in each period. The scarcity constraint does not play any role as Q>30.

Figure 2.4: the 2 period model without scarcity constraint

With scarcity
We now introduce the scarcity constraint. The objective function is to maximize the discounted sum of economic surplus in each period: by choosing quantities of production in each period q1 en q2 such that the total quantity of the resource used is lower than the available quantity Q:
q q1 1 2 Max a - bq dq cq1 a - bq dq cq2 1 r q1 , q2 0 0

q1 q2 Q

or

Q q1 q2 0

It is convenient to use Lagranges method 6 for this optimization problem under constraints.

In fact we use here rather the Kuhn-Tucker theorem for optimisation with inequality constraints

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost The Langrangian is defined as:
q q1 1 2 L a - bq dq cq1 a - bq dq cq2 Q q1 q2 1 r 0 0

12

In which is the Lagrange multiplicator. A maximum of the Lagrangian L(q1, q2, ) with respect to the decision variables and the lagrange multiplicator will be a constrained optimum (where the weak inequalities allow for non binding constraints) and satisfy the following (necessary) first order conditions:
L 0 q1 L 0 q2 L 0 a bq1 c 0 1 a bq2 c 0 1 r Q q1 q2 0 q1 q2 L 0 q1 L 0 q2

L 0

If there is no scarcity constraint active, q1 and q2 can be chosen freely and the lagrange multiplier is zero:
q1 q2 Q and

And optimal price and quantities are given by:


pc
* * q1 q2

ac b

The interest rate plays no role in the solution. The best one can do is to choose the best quantity in each period, there is no opportunity cost associated to the use of more resources in one period. When the scarcity constraint is active the solution equals:
* q1

a c
b

r Q 2r 2r

* q2 Q q1

And we can solve for the Lagrange multiplicator:

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost


L 0 q1 a bq1 c 0 q1 L 0 q1

13

a bq1 c p1 c

This is the normal procedure to look for an optimum. The Lagrange method is not the most operational method to find an optimum but economists like to use it because it allows interesting economic interpretations. It allows to structure the economic intuition. The Lagrange multiplier can be shown to equal the shadow cost of relaxing the resource constraint by one unit at the optimum ( uses all existing resources optimally. In our 2 period problem, using the first order conditions, we have: p1 a bq1 c p2 a bq2 c (1 r ) So, if there is a scarce resource, the optimal price in each period equals the marginal production cost c plus the opportunity cost of using the resource this period: . In the first period this is simply , but in the second period, the value generated by the last unit made available (a-bq2-c) only counts for 1/(1+r) because of discounting. So the opportunity cost of using one more unit of the resource in period 2 is actually higher: (1+r). This opportunity cost is given different names in the literature. One uses marginal user cost= opportunity cost. Hotelling proposed this rule in the 1930 ties and it became known as Hotellings rule: when a scarce resource is optimally used, the margin (p-c) has to increase over time at the rate of interest (1+r)t . We return to our numerical example in the next figure. For an available quantity of 20 and a real discount rate of 10% we have that =1.905. We see that the price in the first period equals 3.905= marginal cost of 2 + opportunity cost of using the resource in this period (=1.905). In the second period, the price equals 4.095 = 2 + 1.905 (1+0.10).

d L d Q

): what is the extra economic value that

can be generated when there is one more unit of the resource available, given that one

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

14

Figure 2.5 Optimal allocation of a scarce resource over 2 periods(Q=20, r=10%) If the available quantity is lower, one can look for the optimum solution by progressively increasing until the total demand obtained by using Hotellings rule (letting margins increase by interest rate) satisfies exactly the resource constraint. One will then notice that prices in both periods increase.

6. Optimal allocation of a non-renewable resource over time the N period case

We can generalize the problem in different directions and using different techniques. One can choose between continuous optimal control techniques and discrete optimization techniques. We will use discrete techniques and graphs as these are better to convey intuition. Only in the last section will we use continuous techniques to discuss comparative statics over time. Those who are more interested in a mathematical proof of some of the results can consult the basic articles or an advanced book on natural resources 7 .

Basic N-period model


Generalising to N periods we have:

Pindyck has several interesting papers. Another source is Heal

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost


N qi 1 Max a bq dq cqi i 1 q1 ,.., qN i 1 1 r 0
N i

15

Forming the lagrangian:


L
N qi a bq dq cqi Q qi i 1 i 1 1 r i 0 N

One obtains the first order conditions:


L 0 qi L 0 1 1 r
N i i 1

a bq2 c 0

qi

L 0 qi L 0

Q qi 0

Solving this optimisation problem requires to check in what periods it is optimal to make the resource available and once this is known, to know what quantities are optimal in every period. We know that if periods i and i+1 are part of the optimal extraction period, we have:

pi 1 c 1 r pi c
If all periods i=1 to T are part of the optimal extraction period, we have:
pi c (1 r )i 1 for i=1,...,T If demand is constant over time and the extracting cost is constant, we have for the optimal extraction period (i=1T): 1. The use of the resource decreases continuously over time and stops at T; the intuition for this result is that, given identical demand functions, starting with an identical allocation of resources over time, one can gain by advancing slightly the use of the resource because of the discount rate 2. The whole resource is used; not using the resource would be economically inefficient because using the resource in one of the T periods would generate an economic surplus if one wants to keep some of the resources for later, it is important to include the potential uses in the objective function

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

16

3. The price of the resource increases over time where the margin increases with the interest rate (not the price but the margin!) this is the Hotelling rule that also holds for any path of demand functions (also for growing demand functions) 4. The price in the last period equals the choke price a (the maximum value of the resource in a future year) ; if the price in T would be smaller than a, one could extract for one more period and obtain a price higher than the previous period, and this would be beneficial etc. until one reaches the choke price Returning to the simple numerical example, using the same demand function (WTP in $ = 8-0.4q ), extraction cost = 2 $ , discount rate 10% and a total quantity of the resource= 40 units. One obtains that =2.798 and the optimal extraction period T=9 periods. Graphically, prices and quantities have the following properties:

Figure 2.6 : Numerical example of the optimal price and quantity of a non renewable scarce resource On the left hand panel one sees the decline of the extraction and use, on the right hand pane, we see the margin between price and marginal cost increasing with the interest rate.

Basic N period model with backstop

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

17

A variant that has received a lot of interest is to add a backstop technology. A backstop technology is a technology that can at a fixed (high) cost produce a perfect substitute for the resource in unlimited quantities. Examples for oil would be an oil substitute produced on the basis of coal (Fisher-Tropf process used by Germany during the war and by South Africa during the oil embargo during the Apartheid period) or simply shale oil of which massive quantities are available. Using our discrete periods optimization model and adding the possibility of a backstop production at a fixed production cost of k and using as upper index for the scarce resource t and for the backstop production st we need to solve the following problem:
t st N qi qi 1 a bq dq cqit kqist Max i 1 qt i q st i i 1 1 r 0

q
i 1

t i

Using the first order necessary conditions we find the following characteristics (when the non renewable resource is used for M periods): 1. The maximal price for the resource is limited to the production cost k of the substitute 2. The non renewable is fully used and is exhausted in period M 3. One uses the substitute only when the non renewable resource is full exhausted; the intuition is that, by using the scarce resource first one saves production costs (it costs only c < k to produce the exhaustible resource) and saving production costs in period i<M is important as these savings can be re-invested with a return r. 4. So adding a substitute speeds up the exhaustion of resources When we return to our numerical example and add a substitute that can be produced at a cost of 6$ per unit, we have the following profiles for quantity and prices:

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

18

Figure 2.7 : Price and quantity of the non renewable resource in the presence of a renewable substitute

Increasing marginal cost of extraction


Often the resource base consists of different basins that have different extraction costs. The general rule is that it is always optimal to use the cheaper resource first. In the next figure one finds an example with a resource base consisting of only 2 parts with a different marginal extraction cost.

Figure 2.8 A non renewable resource base with a cheap and an expensive part

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

19

We see that the cheap resource is first fully used and that the margin (p-mec1) increases with the factor (1+r) every period. When it is fully used, the second resource takes over. The total marginal cost is here the mec+opportunity cost. One sees that the price-mec2 follows also the Hotelling rule also but only from T* onwards. The cheapest resource is used first because this allows to save production costs in the first periods and these savings have a higher weight because of the discount rate.

Reserve dependent costs


The extraction cost in any given year can be made an increasing function of the production in a given year and a decreasing function of the remaining reserves R. Making the extraction cost dependent of the remaining reserves could stand for the production costs of an existing well where the pressure in the reservoir drops with each barrel extracted. More production requires increasing the pressure by injecting water or steam etc. and this is more and more costly. When one includes discoveries of always smaller and smaller fields, costs of exploration go up too. The end result will be a continuous version of Figure 2.7 and the price can be seen as the extraction cost plus the opportunity cost of taking the resource out of the ground and this implies increasing the extraction costs for the rest of the reserves.
pt cq ,t
T t

1 (cR ,t n ) where cR ,t n 0 t n n 1 (1 r )

So the price should start above marginal extraction cost and equal the marginal extraction cost in the last period.

Comparative statics of the basic N period case


We now use a model with a more general formulation that allows to study the properties of the optimal solution using a graphical construction.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

20

We will use a continuous time model with a different demand function but still a constant demand function over time and a constant extraction cost 8 :
T

M ax W

U
0

( R ) e rt d t
T

S Rt s u b j to t
w here and U (R )

and

Rtdt S

P ( R )d R c R

P ( R ) K e aR

This problem has an exact solution that allows studying the comparative statics and obtaining unambiguous results. When it the optimal solution is to use the resource (WTP is large enough), one obtains the following analytical solutions:
2aS r
2 ra S

P0 c Ke R r (T t ) a

This solution can be presented graphically:

I use here the version of the model as presented by Perman,Ma,McGilvray, Common, , Natural resource and environmental economics, Pearson, 1999, 2nd edition, Ch7+8

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

21

The N-period Model


Price mec

Demand function

price

mec

Total use of the resource

time

45

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC STUDIES

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Figure 2.9 Optimal use of a scarce resource This figure is constructed as follows. The left upper quadrant represents the demand function that determines quantity for given price in each period. The left lower quadrant is a 1 to 1 mapping from the left horizontal axis to the negative part of the vertical axis. Take now one period, on the positive horizontal axis, going upwards, one finds the (optimal) price in that period; going left one uses the demand function to find the corresponding quantity, using the lower left quadrant one finds the quantity for that period. The total use of the resource is the integral over time and thus the area in the lower right quadrant. We see the properties we know: - resource is fully used - price in last period = maximum price or choke price (K) - price increases over time where margin increases with factor (1+r) every period - use of resource decreases over time We discuss the following parameters one by one: a higher discount rate, an increase in the known resource stock, higher demand growth due to say higher population growth, a

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

22

fall in the price of the backstop technology due to a scientific discovery, changes in the extraction costs.

Higher discount rate

The N-period Model higher discount rate


Price mec

Demand function

price

mec

Total use of the resource

time

45

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC STUDIES

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Figure 2.10 Effect of a higher discount rate The above figure presents what happens when the discount rate increases. The intuitive reasoning goes as follows. When the discount rate increases, we know that the margin (and the price) must increase more strongly over the extraction period. So one must start at a lower initial price and one will reach the choke price more quickly. Total resource is again fully exhausted. A higher discount rate means that it is better to generate benefits in the near future and so it is logical to advance the extraction of the resource.

A decrease in the size of the resource stock

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

23

The N-period Model effect of lower resource base


Price mec

Demand function

price

mec

Total use of the resource

time

45

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC STUDIES

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Figure 2.11 Effect of a lower estimate of the resource base We know that the resource is scarcer, so keeping the initial price path would lead to exhaustion of the resource before T and this at a price smaller than the choke price. This can not be an optimum, so the initial price has to be increased and also the total extraction period will be shortened. To see the latter, imagine one started from the initial T, then going to period T-1, T-2 ..decreasing the margin every year by a factor (1+r) would lead to exhaustion of the resource before the period 0. But then one can as well start the extraction of the resource earlier at a slightly higher price and stop before moment T.

Effect of a lower marginal extraction cost


This can be due to technological progress. The reverse could happen if there is much more attention to environmental problems that went unnoticed.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

24

The N-period Model-effect of lower mec


Price mec

Demand function

price

mec

Total use of the resource

time

45

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC STUDIES

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Figure 2.12 Effect of a lower marginal extraction cost Using the original price path is not optimum because the margin (p-mec) is now larger. So in order to restore the Hotelling rule, one needs to start from a lower initial price. This increases the demand in the early periods and this shortens the extraction period.

Increase in the expected demand

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

25

The N-period Model - increase in demand


Price mec

Demand function

price

mec

Total use of the resource

time

45

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC STUDIES

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Figure 2.12 Increase in demand function An increase in demand can have different meanings. One can increase the number of identical households are economies that all use the same unit demand function: then we have an expansion of the demand function rotating at the same choke price as is shown in this figure. A parallel movement outwards of the demand function means that also the choke price increases and this would produce a different result. Imagine that one kept the old price scheme. Then one would exhaust the resource before T because demand is now higher for every price. Exhausting the resource before reaching T can however not be optimal. So one needs to increase the initial price and this will also lead to a shorter extraction period.

A fall in the cost of the backstop technology

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

26

The N-period Model fall in cost backstop


Price mec price

Demand function

mec

Total use of the resource

time

45

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC STUDIES

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Because the backstop cost falls, the initial price path is no longer optimal: it would imply that one leaves some of the resource in the ground. This implies lowering the price in the final period, in the initial period and using the resource more quickly.

Interpretation of the comparative statics exercise


We have interpreted the previous exercises as follows: given that one has an initial stock of resources, how would the optimal price and quantity profile change if one of the parameters changes. One can also give another more general interpretation to our exercise: imagine one is on one of the optimal profiles and suddenly one of the parameters changes because of extra information that was not anticipated. Then we can see the comparative statics exercise as a new optimization exercice starting at moment t<T. If nothing would have changed in the parameters, one would have continued the old price path. When one changes a parameter, one can by comparing carefully the new and the old price path have a feeling for the change in the price levels. This is a good exercise to check your understanding of the different comparative statics cases.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

27

7. The allocation of non renewable resources in a market economy


Perfect competition case
The theory of non-renewable resources that we surveyed in the previous sections was mainly dealing with the optimal use of a scarce non renewable resource over time. Although we used market prices (auction prices) to make sure the right consumers had access to the resource we assumed that there was an omniscient planner that optimized the extraction over time. In reality, it are firms and governments who decide on extraction and they look for a maximum profit or revenues solution. We start by examining the perfect competition case. This means that all owners of the resource take the market prices as given and choose the quantities to extract that maximize their profits. As each supplier has to decide when and how much to produce, he considers a path of future prices. It is not necessary that the total resource is subdivided among a very large group of owners (say students taking this course). It is sufficient that one has a limited number of suppliers who do not form a cartel and that have each a reasonable share of the market. In this case they will tend to take the prices as given as none of them has an interest to restrict his supply to raise prices because the major beneficiaries will be his competitors who will expand output.. It can be shown that the equilibrium price path has the same properties as the optimal price path we developed in the previous section: the margin (price-mec) must rise every period with a factor (1+r). An equilibrium price path is a path of prices at which none of the suppliers has an interest to supply more, all consumers are at their demand functions (WTP= price) and demand equals supply in all periods. Why does the perfect competition case satisfy the Hotelling rule? Assume it would not be true: then the price in a future year t>t would be such that - either p(t)-c > {p(t)-c}(1+r) (t-t) - or p(t)-c < {p(t)-c}(1+r) (t-t) In the first case every supplier has an interest to sell less in period t and keep that production volume for period t, so this can not be an equilibrium because supply will be less than demand in period t etc.. until equilibrium is restored.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

28

In the second case, the reverse will happen, instead of selling in period t, a supply will prefer to sell more in period t etc. Important assumptions are here that all suppliers use the same discount rate so that they have all access to the same conditions on the capital market. A second important condition is the existence of a full set of futures markets for the commodity.

The monopoly case


For oil we have known several periods where OPEC acted as a monopolist, controlling the quantity in order to increase their revenues. What does this imply for the rate of extraction? The next figure shows that this means higher initial prices and a longer extraction period. Why is this the case? A monopolist knows that by influencing the quantity supplied he can manipulate prices. In any period he will restrict supply until the marginal profit ( marginal revenue marginal cost) increases with a factor (1+r).
The N-period Model monopoly instead of competition

Demand function

Price mec

price

mec

Total use of the resource

time

45

CENTER FOR ECONOMIC STUDIES

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Figure 2.13 Comparing the monopoly solution to the perfect competition case The marginal profit in one period equals the marginal revenue minus the marginal extraction cost:

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

29

p pq mec q q
This is the well known condition for one period, giving rise to a price>mec. Now we also need to take into account that selling one unit this period rather than in a future period has an opportunity cost . So the optimal rule is now to have marginal profit increasing at the discount rate. In order to understand the intuition of the result that monopolists sell less and extend the period of extraction, start at the perfectly competitive solution in the first period. For that price, the monopolist has still an interest to lower the quantity and increase the price because the marginal revenue is higher than the marginal cost plus the opportunity cost. The result is that the price is higher and that he saves one unit for use in future periods. There is a period where both price paths cross as total resource available is identical. In our case there is an exact solution: the total extraction period with a monopoly is more or less 2.5 as long as the extraction period with perfect competition. In the next Figure we illustrate what happens if one has a change in market regime from monopoly (period T1) into perfect competition. This could be the case when a cartel breaks down. We know that the suppliers then lower their prices and want to sell more: prices jump downwards but increase more strongly. If in period T2, the cartel is restored, one returns to a monopoly path with an upward jump. The oil market has seen these jumps but whether the theory of non renewable resources is a good explanation is a different matter.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost Price Choke price

30

ME T1 T2 Time

Figure 2.14 Regime switches between monopoly and perfect competition

Some more issues that arise in a market context


Royalty and revenue tax Most countries charge a royalty tax on their oil and gas production. If the royalty tax is a fixed % of the net margin, this tax does not affect the depletion period and path as the Hotelling condition is unchanged by a tax t: (1 t )( pt c) (1 t )( pt 1 c)(1 r ) A tax on (gross) revenues will discourage production and has the same effect as an increase in the resource extraction cost. Forward markets and expectations In the perfect competition case, the Hotelling rule is the result of arbitrage possibilities of suppliers on forward markets. Forward markets are markets where one can buy the resource in a given future year. Forward markets exist but only for a limited number of years (say 5), so there is no market price for the years 6 and later.

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

31

Extraction under uncertainty


to be completed later

8. How does the model perform in reality?


The Hotelling rule is an exact result that holds if reality confirms to the theoretical set-up. The world is much more complex. An important factor that is still missing in the model is technological progress that lowers extraction costs and tend to increase the resource base. Simple empirical tests of the Hotelling theory are rejected in most cases. In the case of oil this would require that the price path (neglecting the marginal extraction cost) would increase with a factor (1+r). As can be seen in Figure 2.15, this is clearly not the case.1

Figure 2.15 Price of oil and r=5% growth paths (source IEA and Medlock (2009)) This is however insufficient to reject the Hotelling theory. In fact over the years, expectations on future demand, total available reserves, backstop costs and also the

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

32

market regimes have changed. Each of these 4 elements changes the current price level and the fluctuations in the price of oil do therefore not necessarily contradict Hotelling.

9. Conclusions
We have surveyed the theory of non renewable resources. Important questions remain: Is the model useful to understand reality, a point to which we return in our oil and gas chapters Is it acceptable that we use all exhaustible resources now and leave none for the future generations? Is this sustainable development? an issue to which we return in chapter 3
What is the role of environmental considerations in the extraction of exhaustible resources?

10. References
Dasgupta, P., G.Heal, (1979), Economic theory and exhaustible resources, Cambridge University Press Medlock K.B. III, The economics of energy supply, Ch3 in Evans J., Hunt L., (eds.) (2009) International Handbook of the Economics of Energy, Edward Elgar Perman, Ma, McGilvray, Common, , Natural resource and environmental economics, Pearson, 1999, 2nd edition, Ch7+8 Tietenberg (2000)

11. Questions for students


1. Take BP statistical review. Can you explain what happened with Oil reserves in Canada, UK and Saudi-Arabia? 2. Compute ratio present consumption over reserves for oil in 1990, 2000 and 2009, can you explain the evolution? 3. Do you understand what happened to Gas reserves in Canada and the US? 4. Imagine that after the events in Libya, we have a more Western oriented regime that does no longer follow OPEC strategy. What could this imply for the oil prices?

Energy Economics 2011-2012 prof Stef Proost

33

5. Assume there are two suppliers. One has a marginal cost function = 2x, the other has a marginal cost function 4x. Find graphically and algebraically the aggregate marginal cost function. 6. Imagine that scientists found out that from 2025 onwards, it will be possible to have cars running on water at a relatively low cost. What will happen to oil prices now, in 2025 and in 2040? 7. What do the last 400 years of energy supply teach us on resource availability in the future?

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 3 Environment
1. Objectives and outline
Fossil energy use generates different types of negative side effects for society: traditional air pollution but also global warming. As this issue concerns almost all energy use and is the main justification for subsidies to green energy we need to understand this issue in more depth. We do this in three steps. In the first section we survey the the basics of environmental economics with a simple model. This model is used to discuss the use of different types of policy instruments. In the second section we discuss the sustainability concept in abstract terms drawing on a paper by Arrow et al. (2004). In the next chapter we focus on climate change as this is considered at present as the environmental issue with the highest impact on the energy sector.

2. Basic environmental economics


Problem setting
When there is a large number of polluters and victims, every victim and every polluter will take the aggregated pollution level as given. This is the crucial assumption we need to make for our simplified framework to make sense in the real world1. We use a simplified framework with only 2 polluters a, b and 2 victims 1 and 2 to which we add the assumption that they take the actions of the others as given. Our model can be given many different interpretations. The polluters and victims can be different firms, different countries, different generations etc. Initial emission levels are Ea and Eb. The polluters can reduce emissions by quantities Za and Zb at a total cost Ca(Za) and Cb(Zb). This total emission reduction or abatement cost can be interpreted most easily as efforts (equipment, level of care) by the firm (or the household)

1 If we would not make this assumption, all problems between our two agents can be solved by bargaining between the two parties. We know that this can produce efficient solutions.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

to reduce emissions. But in most cases the cost of emission reduction consists also of the lost consumers and producer surplus due to the price increases for goods produced with dirty inputs. We will come back to the measurement of emission abatement costs in later lectures. There are 2 victims I=1,2 with a total environmental damage D1(P) and D2(P). The level of pollution P (has dimension effects rather than emissions) is defined as:

P Ta ( Ea Z a ) Tb ( Eb Z b )
Where the pollution or damage effects are a weighted sum of emissions by the two polluters. The weights T can be interpreted as transfer or transport coefficients translating distance, wind direction, toxicity etc..This is the simplest transfer function one can imagine. In some pollution problems one defines a blame matrix that tells you what share of the pollution of a country or region ends up in all the other regions. This is an important element in EU policies on conventional air pollution. Figure 1 illustrates one of the source receptor relationships used in Gains, a model used to prepare decisions on European policies. Figure 2 illustrates the damage relation, showing the effect of changes in emissions on life expectancy.

Source-receptor relationships for PM2.5


derived from the EMEP Eulerian model for primary and secondary PM

PM 2.5 j
iI

iI

A ij

A * p i ij * s i iI

S S 0.5 * ( ij * a i ij * ni ) iI W 0.5 * min(max(0, c1 * ij * a i c1 * iI iI

14 W W * ij * s i k1 j ), c 2 * ij * ni k 2 j ) 32 iI

PM2.5j Annual mean concentration of PM2.5 at receptor point j I Set of emission sources (countries) J Set of receptors (grid cells) Primary emissions of PM2.5 in country i pi SO2 emissions in country i si NOx emissions in country i ni NH3 emissions in country i ai Linear transfer matrices for reduced and oxidized nitrogen, S,Wij, S,W,Aij, W,Aij, Aij sulfur and primary PM2.5, for winter, summer and annual

Figure 3.1 European air pollution dispersion model (Gains)

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Loss in life expectancy


attributable to fine particles [months]

2000

2020 CAFE baseline Current legislation

2020 Maximum technical emission reductions

Loss in average statistical life expectancy due to identified anthropogenic PM2.5 Calculations for 1997 meteorology

Figure 3.1 Illustration of effect of a policy on damage of emissions (source GAINS model) For the pollution problem we proposed we will analyze three types of solutions: an ideal solution, a centralised solution, and a non-cooperative solution. Ideal solution Look for solution that maximizes the total welfare assuming that there is perfect control of all variables All polluters are only interested in their own damage and take the actions of the others as given (Nash-Cournot equilibrium) Assume that there is a central government that has all the information but has to use given policy instruments (taxes, permits etc.) to control the behaviour of polluters with

Non cooperative solution

centralised government solution

Centralised government imperfect information

solutions

Table 3.1 The different institutional settings considered

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

The ideal (or theoretical optimum) solution


If we use a quasi linear utility function and we have perfect income distribution instruments, we can formulate the optimal pollution problem in a very simple way: PROBLEM 1

choose Z a , Z b and mi such as to Maximise (mi Di ( P ))


1,2

subject to mi Ca ( Z a ) Cb ( Z b ) Ri
1,2 1,2

where P Ta ( Ea Z a ) Tb ( Eb Z b )
If we use all available resources R and substitute m by the resource (or production constraint) of this economy, this problem comes down to minimize overall damage and overall costs (PROBLEM 2-often called the efficiency problem). Implicitly we assume 1) that we are either indifferent about the distribution of costs and benefits to the different individuals or that we have other income distribution instruments operating in the background. 2) The damage of pollution does not depend on the income levels 3) We use a linear production technology except for the production of abatement PROBLEM 2

Minimize D1 ( P) D2 ( P ) Ca ( Z a ) Cb ( Z b ) where P Ta ( Ea Z a ) Tb ( Eb Z b )
By selecting appropriate abatement efforts Z by the two polluters. An interior solution to this optimisation problem is given by the first order conditions:

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost


Ca D1 D2 Z a P P Ta Cb D1 D2 Z b P P Tb
We see 2 properties here:

1) The optimal level of pollution P* is reached when the marginal cost of reducing pollution (Ca/ Za) / Ta equals the total environmental damage expression holds for every polluter 2) Pollution is reduced in a cost minimal way when the marginal cost of pollution reduction is equal between the two sources of emissions: (Ca/ Za) / Ta = Cb/ Zb) / Tb where we see that the transfer coefficients correct the marginal cost of emission reduction to express it in terms of pollution reduction costs this will determine the optimal distribution of emission reductions over the two polluters We can show these properties also in 3 steps and that is what is usely done in the graphical procedure. The first step is then cost efficiency in the reduction of pollution so as to achieve a given level P: PROBLEM 3: (D1/ P) + (D2/ P) this

Minimize Ca ( Z a ) Cb ( Z b ) such that Ta ( Ea Z a ) Tb ( Eb Z b ) P


An interior solution to this problem will satisfy

Cb Ca Z b Z a Tb Ta
This first step allows the construction of a new aggregated total cost function C(P) where, by construction, pollution levels P are achieved at the lowest cost by combining the efforts of the two polluters.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Imagine that one does not systematically combine the abatement efforts of the two polluters in a cost effective way. Then another aggregated cost function CO(P) has to be used that reaches pollution levels at always higher costs. Figure 3 illustrates the marginal cost of reducing emissions of SO2 in a particular zone.

An example cost curve for SO2

3000

Marginal costs (EURO/ton SO2 removed)

0 .0 1 % S d ie s e l o il
2500

2000

FG D s m a ll in d u s t r ia l b o ile r s 0 .6 % S h e a v y fu e l o il

FG D la r g e in d u s tr ia l b o ile r s 0 .2 % S d ie s e l o il FG D o il f ir e d p o w e r p la n ts

1500

FG D b a s e lo a d p o w e r p la n t s

1000

1 % S h e a v y f u e l o il L o w s u lf u r coal

500

R e m a in in g m e a s u re s P r e s e n t le g is la tio n

0 0 50 100 150 200 250 300

R e m a in in g e m is s io n s (k t S O 2)

Figure 3.3 Illustration of a marginal cost function for the reduction of emissions in a given zone The second step is to construct an aggregated environmental damage function D(P). This is easy: Problem 4:

D( P) D1 ( P) D2 ( P )
The third step is to choose the correct level of emission reduction given the aggregated damage and abatement cost functions: Problem 5

Minimize D( P) C ( P)
Where an optimum interior solution satisfies the traditional marginal damage and marginal pollution abatement cost.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

A graphical illustration is particularly easy when the transfer functions are equal for both pollutants. In this case we can use the dimension emissions for all cost and damage functions instead of having to use emissions and pollution. The aggregated damage function is constructed by adding vertically the marginal damage functions of the 2 victims (Fig II and Fig III give rise to MD in Figure I). We use here the public good property of pollution: the pollution generates damages to the two victims so we have to add the marginal damages to obtain total pollution damage. The second aggregated curve, the abatement cost function is constructed combining Fig IV and Fig V into Fig I. Fig IV ranks all emission reduction possibilities for the first polluter in the order of increasing costs (this generates the marginal cost function). We are interested in the reduction of pollution at the lowest cost. The construction of the aggregated marginal cost function uses a given maximum emission reduction cost MAC. Then the total quantity that can be reduced for a marginal cost level lower than the target marginal cost level MAC at the two emission sources is computed. This generates one point on the aggregated marginal cost function. Varying the MAC level allows to construct the complete aggregated marginal abatement cost function. By the way, we use precisely the same procedure to construct an aggregated marginal cost function for the supply of a private good.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

MD MAC

MAC A IV

MAC B V

pollution MD1 II

pollution Optimal abatement for A

pollution Optimal abatement for B

MD2

pollution III

pollution

Figure 3.4 Synthesis figure for simplified environmental problem

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Non cooperative solution


There are situations where there is no central government that can control the polluters. This is typically the case for international pollution problems where there more than a few nations are involved. A typical example is climate change: the emission of each nation will damage all other nations of the world. Here we can not rely upon a central government because there is no world government. Obviously there are international agreements but things are not as simple. Indeed it is dificult to make international agreements that can be enforced. If a country signs an agreement but finds that it is in its interest not to comply with the agreement, there is no international court that can enforce the agreement. We can study this problem with our small model. We assume that there are two countries 1 and 2 and we assume that every country can reduce its emissions. Instead of two firms polluting we have the two countries polluting. Every country solves the following problem: Problem 6

Minimize D1 ( P ) C1 ( Z1 ) where P T1 ( E1 Z1 ) T2 ( E2 Z 2 )
where we see that every country minimizes its abatement costs and its own damage, taking the actions of the other countries as given (Z2 ). The optimal solution for every country is (for an interior solution):

D1 P

Z2

C1 Z 1 T1

This is an equation that expresses the abatement efforts of country 1 as a function of the efforts of country 2:

Z1 R1 ( Z 2 )
This is called a reaction function. When both reaction functions exist and satisfy certain properties (continuity) one can guarantee the existence of a Nash equilibrium :

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost


Nash equilibrium Z1N , Z 2N satisfies Z1N R1 ( Z 2N ) Z 2N R2 ( Z1N )

10

How does this non cooperative solution compare to the ideal (and the centralised solution)? The non-cooperative solution will be less efficient because of two reasons: a) the emission reduction is not produced in the most cost-effective way b) the overall emission reduction effort will be too low as every country takes only into account its own damage and not the damage in the other countries That there are large differences between the non-cooperative solution and the efficient solution can be illustrated for Climate Change. Eyckmans, Proost, Schokkaert (1993) show that for climate change, the non-cooperative solution would produce some 2% of reduction of emissions while the cooperative solution would generate some 16% of emission reductions.

Centralised government solution


Assume the policy maker is interested to achieve the ideal solution that we described earlier. He can however not necessarily control all the actions of the polluters. He is restricted in the type of constraints and incentives he can give to the polluters. These restrictions are sometimes called constitutional in the sense that they are part of a more fundamental contract between citizens that try to preclude the misuse of power by policy makers. We will discuss three types of centralised solutions that are presented in the next table: pollution taxes, standards and tradeable permits: Pollution taxes Tax on all emissions corrected for its effect on pollution - the revenue of the tax is returned to all the citizens as a subsidy per head Standards Tradeable permits Emission limit set for every polluter Every polluter receives emission rights that he can trade freely with other polluters Table 3.2 : main policy instruments discussed

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost


The policy maker has now to solve a problem where his control is more indirect: Problem 6

11

Minimize D( P) Ca ( Z a (control )) Cb ( Z b (control )) where P Ta ( Ea Z a ) Tb ( Eb Z b )


Before analysing the problem faced by the government we need to examine how the polluters react to different types of policy controls by the government.

A tax on emissions
Assume that the polluters are producers that minimize their total production costs. When they are faced with a tax on emissions, corrected for the transfer coefficient (also called ambiant pollution taxes) the polluter faces the following problem: minimize the sum of abatement costs and emission taxes he has to pay. Problem 7

Minimize Ca ( Z a ) t Ta ( Ea Z a )
If we assume that every polluter minimizes indeed this expression, we can derive his reaction function to a change in controls from the first order conditions for an interior minimum solution:

Ca Z a t Ta
this is an implicit equation that gives Za in function of the control t . An interesting property of the ambiant emission taxes is that they always generate emission reductions in a cost-minimizing way. Because all polluters are subject to the same pollution tax t we have indeed (for an interior solution):

Cb Ca Z b Z t a Tb Ta

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

12

This is indeed an interesting property: the policy maker does not need to know the abatement cost functions to achieve a cost minimizing solution , all he needs to do is set the same ambiant pollution tax rate for all polluters.

An emission standard
In the case of an emission standard, the policy maker fixes one emission limit EL for each polluter. The polluter then minimizes total costs subject to this limit on emissions: Problem 8

Minimize Ca ( Z a ) subject to Ea Z a ELa


If the constraint is binding we have that Z is directly controlled by the emission limit. The government has full control but this will only lead to a solution that is cost-efficient if the policy maker has full knowledge of all the abatement cost functions. This is paradoxical: decentralising decisions by using indirect controls as there is an emission tax may improve a solution where the policy maker has full control but not all the information. This is the fundamental reason why economists like to rely on markets to organize production and consumption decisions.

A tradeable emission scheme


The idea in this scheme is that the policy maker allocates emission rights ER to every polluter. Next the polluters can trade emission rights, in the final step every polluter has to limit his ambiant emissions in function of the total number of ambiant emission rights he possesses. We represent the net purchase of ambiant emission rights by ERP and we assume that there is a perfectly competitive market for emission rights where the equilibrium market price is per. A perfectly competitive emission rights market means that all players take the price on that market as given. This will typically be the case if there are a large number of traders on the market and that none of the traders has a dominant position. An equilibrium price per is a price where the sum of the net trades

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost ERPa (per) + ERPb (per) = 0
The problem of every polluter is now: Problem 9

13

Minimize Ca ( Z a ) per . ERP subject to Ta ( Ea Z a ) ERa ERP


And his behaviour (choosing Z and ERP) will be characterised (for an interior solution) by:

Ca Z per a Ta
This equation holds for all polluters, so we achieve again the property that all pollution reduction costs are minimised because all polluters react to the same price signal per:

Cb Ca Z b Z a per Tb Ta
The control variables of the government are now: ER
a and b

but one can show only the

weighted (by transfer coefficients) sum of emission rights matters. This is again an interesting property: the policy maker controls in fact total pollution rights and that is all he needs to achieve a cost effective solution. We can now return to the problem of our policy maker that controls pollution via indirect policy instruments. We can now solve problem 6 with as constraints the behaviour of polluters (problems 7, 8 or 9). We summarize some of the properties of the different instruments in the following table.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

14

Ambiant Pollution taxes

Cost

efficiency

of

pollution

reduction

is

guaranteed reaching the optimal pollution level requires that the ambiant tax is set equal to the Marginal Damage and this requires knowledge of aggregate MC and MD curve

Standards

Cost efficiency of pollution reduction is not guaranteed reaching the optimal pollution level requires that the total quantity of ambiant pollution allowed corresponds to the level where aggreg Marginal Damage = aggreg Marginal cost

Tradeable permits

Cost

efficiency

of

pollution

reduction

is

guaranteed reaching the optimal pollution level requires that the total quantity of ambiant pollution allowed corresponds to the level where aggreg Marginal Damage = aggreg Marginal cost Table 3.3 Properties of some environmental policy instruments

Experience with Emission trading in the energy field: the SO2 trading scheme in the US
See Schmalenzee et al (1998) and ppt. Tradeable emission permitsSO2 in US in TOLEDO

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

15

3. Sustainability
Issue and outline
There are many definitions of sustainability around .We follow a recent paper by Arrow et al (2004) that is a result of a dialogue between economists and ecologists. Ecologists are worried about the future of this planet when you put together some trends. Over the last 100 years, population increased with a factor 4 , industrial output by a facot 35, energy use by a factor 16, fishing output by a factor 35. They consider this as unsustainable. Economists and ecologists tend to use two different views on sustainability. In the most simple economic approach one would define a policy as sustainable when it maximizes the discounted future utility over the rest of the horizon. In the second approach originating from the ecologist tradition and translated into economists language is more policies are sustainable when they guarantee the utility of future generations. We will show that both views are not that different. The sustainability discussion is important for many long term issues and will turn out crucial for the climate change debate.

Sustainability as a maximum of discounted utility


The simplest naive approach is to look for policies that maximize the present value of discounted utility for the rest of the horizon. In its simplest form this comes down to:

Max

(1 )
t 1

U (C (t ))

There are three important assumptions embedded in this formulation. The first is the structure and functional form of the utility function. We have simplified the utility function so that it has only one argument aggregate consumption which is not a strong assumption as long as one can easily produce all goods from a common input (say labour). The utility function is also the same for all individuals and represents an ethical

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

16

judgment on what is the relative value of giving 1 of consumption to one poor individual and one rich individual. In principle one accepts that this function is concave so that 1 taken from the rich and given to the poor increases aggregate utility. The degree of concavity of the utility function will tell us by how much. The second assumption embedded in this formulation is the role of the discount rate. One accepts to weight the utility of consumption now and in the future with one common interest rate. This is acceptable within one generation but doing this over several generations in the very long term is another issue. The third assumption implicit in this formulation is that it is possible to transfer resources over time. To continue our reasoning it is actually easier to transform the sustainability objective into an objective that is only a function of consumption over time. We can do this by using a different discount rate r where is a measure of the concavity of the utility function and where g is the growth rate of consumption over time: r g And use as objective function :
W Ct e rt dt
0 T

This results from the following steps:


T

U (C
0

)e t d t

w ith U ' 0

and

U '' 0

e la s t i c i t y o f m a r g i n a l u t i li t y w r t c o n s u m p t i o n ( c o n c a v i t y o f u t i li t y f u n c t i o n )

=-

C U '' U' c o n s u m p t i o n r a t e o f d i s c o u n t o f c o n s u m p t i o n = r a t e a t w h i c h t h e v a lu e o f d e lt a i n c o n s u m p tio n c h a n g e s w h e n w e m o v e o v e r tim e : M a r g i n a l u t i li t y o f c o n s u m p t i o n = U ' e t T h e d iffe re n tia tio n w r t tim e = U '' C U ' C r C U '' e t U ' e t U ' e t

ta k in g n e g a tiv e o f th is

The intuition behind the transformed discount rate r is simple:

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

17

is the social rate of pure time preference = how one should trade off utility of

somebody now and the utility of somebody in the future, a reasonable ethical choice would be to take a value 0 as there is no reason to value differently the utility of persons living at two different moments in time g is rate of growth of aggregate consumption (1 to 2% in long term) is elasticity of marginal social utility (1 to 4 derived from individual trade offs

under uncertainty) and is a measure of how fast marginal utility decreases when income increases So r, the social rate of discount is of the order of 2% or more We can now see whether current consumption is excessive according to this first sustainability criterion. We need to compare the criterion with the possibilities to carry over resources from one period to another via investments. Assume that any saving of 1 in a given period generates a consumption return of (1+rr) in the next period. rr is the real rate of return on invested capital. In other terms, if one would give up one unit of consumption now, this would generate 1+rr units of consumption the next period. In order to maximize our objective under our constraint to carry over consumption over time, we need to compare r with rr. If r < rr this means that by reducing consumption now and investing 1 more one would generate 1+rr and this would after social discounting (1+rr)/(1+r) be larger than 1, so there is an interest to reduce consumption now and increase investment If r> rr , it is better to decrease investments and consume more now Because it is difficult to claim that rr is much bigger than r, it is difficult to claim that present consumption is excessive. One of the main elements behind a large social discount rate r is the assumption that future generations will be richer (g>0). As future generations get richer it is rather normal that we should not save extra for them.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

18

Sustainability as guarantee for utility of future generations


It has become more common to see sustainability asa guarantee that future generations have the production possibilities to have the same consumption level as we have. Now the main question is what determines future production possibilities? This issue was assumed away in the previous simpler approach where resources could be easily transferred from year to year via a real rate of return rr. We can define future production possibilities via a production function that is function of three inputs: labour (kept constant), man made capital (buildings, technology) and natural capital (depletable resources, biodiversity,...). We can now express the evolution of utility over time as a function of net production over time V(t) that is a function of man made capital Km and natural capital Kn:
V (t ) V

K m (t ), K n (t )
V Km V Kn . . Km t Kn t

d V ( K m (t ), K n (t ))

1 1 p m (t ) p n (t ) K n (t ) Km Kn . . d V ( K m (t ), K n (t )) p m (t ) K m (t ) p m (t ) K m (t ) p m (t ) K m (t ) K n (t ) t t 1 1 K m p n (t ) K n (t ) 1 Kn . d V ( K m (t ), K n (t )) . p m (t ) K m (t ) t p m (t ) K m (t ) K n (t ) t K m (t ) p n (t ) K n (t ) e la s t i c i t y o f K n w i t h r e s p e c t t o K m a lo n g a n i s o q u a n t w h e re p m (t ) K m (t ) o r h o w m a n y u n its o f K n o n e n e e d s to s u b s titu te o n e u n it o f K m p n a n d p m a re p ric e s o f n a tu ra l a n d m a n m a d e c a p ita l

This implies that we can check evolution of production possibilities over time by checking the availability of man made and natural capital over time and confronting this with substitution possibilities. Figure 4.6 gives an idea of the evolution of capital stocks for a given country (here UK)

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

19

2100 Man made Capital stock CURRENT TREND of NATURAL AND MAN MADE CAPITAL OVER TIME measured with current prices

2000

Example: UK (%of GDP)


Physical Investment : Education: CO2: Energy: NET: +3.7 +5.6 -0.3 -2.0 +8.9

Source: Arrow et al. 1750 Natural capital stock

Figure 4.6 Evolution of capital stocks over time in the UK But in order to know what a given evolution of capital stocks means for production possibilities one needs to make assumptions about substitutability of the two capital stocks. In the optimistic view there is easy substitution in the example of Figure 4.7 , there is a decrease of natural capital but overall production possibilities still increase because one ends up on a higher isoquant. In the pessimistic view there is no easy substitution of natural capital. There is a minimum of natural capital required and once this limit is reached, the increase of man made capital is useless. See the example of Figure 4.8.

Man made capital

OVER TIME

Production level curves If substitution perfect

Natural capital

Figure 4.7 Optimistic view on substitutability

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

20

Man made capital B

OVER TIME

Production level curves If no substitution possible

Natural capital

Figure 4.8 Pessimistic view on substitutability There is historical evidence on how mankind has dealt with natural resources and how the economy has grown in a sustainable or non sustainable way. According to Diamond (2005) there have been disasters on Easter Island (island 4h by plane west of Chile) where deforestation has led to internal wars and disappearance of the population. Another case are the Anasazi indians in south west US where population growth and drought has led to mere extinction of certain groups. Another example or the Maya indians. Recent cases of interest or Rwanda and Haiti (very poor but sharing the same island with Dominican republic that is much richer). The next table gives some data on the evolution of capital stocks. Some regions (sub saharan Africa, Middle east decrease their overall capital stock while in most regions the nman made capaital (mainly education) continue to increase. Whether this is sufficient for sustainable development remains an open empirical question.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

21

Table

4. References
K. Arrow, P. Dasgupta, L. Goulder, G.Daily, P. Ehrlich, G.Heal, S.Levin, K-G Maler, S. Schneider, D.Starrett, B.Walker, 2004, Are We Consuming Too Much?, Journal of Economic Perspectives,Volume 18, Number 3,Pages 147172 Diamond J., 2005, Collapse how societies choose to fail or to succeed, Penguin books Schmalensee R., Joskow,P., Ellerman D., Montero J-P, Bailey E., 1998, An interim evaluation of sulfur dioxide emission trading, JEP, vol 12, n3, p53-68

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 4 Economics of Climate Change


1. Objectives
Climate change is considered as one of the major environmental concerns of fossil fuel energy use. Very ambitious emission reduction objectives have been announced for Greenhouse Gas emissions and these will affect strongly the energy markets. In this chapter we study the economics of Climate Change in 4 sections. We start with a problem description at world level. Next we discuss briefly the economics of international negotiations because this is necessary to understand the EU policy and the international negotiation process. In the last section we analyze the implementation of the European climate policy in more detail.

2. Climate change as a problem for the world


We rely heavily on the Stern report (2006, 2008) as this is accessible for non experts. The Stern report has been critically reviewed by several economists. We will mainly integrate comments by Weitzman (2007), Nordhaus (2007) and Heal (2009). In order to understand the climate change problem we work in 5 steps. We first describe briefly the climate change phenomenon, its drivers and its consequences in mostly physical terms. The second step is to look for an objective function by which we can rank different strategies to limit emissions of greenhouse gasses. The third step briefly presents the types of models that are used for an analysis of the climate strategies at world level. In the fourth step we give some idea about the cost of abatement and the damages associated to climate change. In the last step we discuss briefly the policy proposals advanced in the Stern report.

Physics of global warming

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

For dummies climate change is based on the following reasoning: 1. Human behaviour is at origin of extra GHG emissions, mainly under form of CO2 (75% of problem) but also methane, NO and HFCs count. 2. GHG accumulate in the atmosphere and stay active for 100 to 200 years (decay 0.5% / year) 3. The increased concentration of GHG traps heat and generates global warming of the planet 4. Global warming generates climate change this happens with a delay of 30-50 years because of the thermal inertia of the oceans 5. Climate change has several effects, some positive but on average negative Each of these relations are uncertain: what will be the economic growth in the future and to what extent economic growth will be carbon intensive (and emissions will grow rapidly) is not clear but also the effect of the GHG emissions on the climate (the physics of the warming) and the precise effects associated to climate change (the nature of the damage) are uncertain. The global warming effects are often summarized under the form of the expected change in average world temperature compared to the pre-industrial era. At present the concentration of GHG gasses is 430 ppm CO2equivalent and this is rising between 2.5 to 4 ppm per year. Figure 4.1 gives the average global warming associated to different levels of GHG concentrations in the atmosphere. If no policy action is undertaken, one expects that one reaches a Business As Usual concentration in 2050 of the order of 750 ppm CO2eq.. The 90% confidence interval would imply global warming in the range of 2 to more than 6C. In order to illustrate what such a change in temperature implies one needs to put this change in historical perspective. Over the last 3 million years the world has experienced an increase of 2 to 3 C. Humans experienced 10000 years ago 5C cooling (ice sheets up to London ice melted and England became an island). At 5C, most ice and snow would disappear, swampy forests appear everywhere and one could find alligators at the

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

North Pole. There are also major dislocations of population expected in 100 to 200 years as large parts of the world become difficult to live in. Given these expectations it looks reasonable to avoid risks of going beyond 550 ppm and so limit global warming to 3C with still risk of 24% reaching 4C and 9% reaching 5% or 6%

Figure 4.1 Temperature change associated to different concentrations of GHG (source: Stern (2008). The GHG emissions come principally from fossil energy use in different sectors and to a lesser extent from non energy emissions: see Figure 4.2:

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Figure 4.2 Sources of world GHG emissions in 2000 (source Stern (2008)). Avoiding climate change effects requires addressing a stock pollution problem and this is more difficult than a flow pollution problem. Figure 4.3 gives an idea what temporal profile of emissions is necessary to reach a given concentration of GHG in 2050.

Figure 4.3 Emissions profile necessary to reach a given concentration in 2050.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

As can be seen from this figure even a decrease in emissions from now onwards will lead to a strong increase of concentration of GHGs in 2050 because every ton emitted will contribute to the accumulation of the stock in the future.

How to select a climate change strategy for the world?


If there would be one benevolent world government, what emission profile would be optimal when one considers all costs and benefits of abating GHG emissions? This is a central question that has been the source of many discussions among economists and policy makers. As we know from our sustainability chapter this is an ethical discussion in which one needs to trade off the well being of different generations: emissions now will generate damage for the coming generations, the well being of different parts of the world (some will gain with climate change but others may lose heavily. In addition most elements are uncertain. Usually one starts with the following objective function for the world now and in the future:

W U (Ct ) e t dt
0

To make this expression operational one prefers to work with a discounted sum of consumption rather than utility and this requires assumptions on the concavity of the utility function and on the growth rate of consumption. This means one works with: W Ct e rt dt
0 T

And the discount rate is then:

r g

is the social rate of pure time preference = how one should trade off utility of

somebody now and the utility of somebody in the future, a reasonable ethical choice would be to take a value 0 as there is no reason to value differently the utility of persons living at two different moments in time g is rate of growth of aggregate consumption (1 to 2% in long term) this is partly endogeneous as this can be affected by climate change if climate change destroys

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

ecoservices that are a strongly complementary input into production, the production and consumption will be lower (cfr. Ch3) is elasticity of marginal social utility (1 to 4 derived from individual trade offs under uncertainty) and is a measure of how fast marginal utility decreases when income increases the latter measure is used in two types of analysis: in redistribution of income issues and in behaviour under uncertainty those who want to avoid risks, tend to have a very high as high gains become less important than avoiding losses Most discussions center on the choice of these parameters. For a 2% expected growth, one arrives quickly at discount rates r between 1.5 and 5%. This range of discount rates tends to discourage large abatement efforts now. But a full analysis should also take into account the distribution of gains and losses over the world and the risks of extreme events. In the following formulation of the objective function we sum over r=1...R regions in the world and over s=1,...S possible states of the world with probability p(s,t) due to uncertainty in the climate developments. This gives for the welfare in period t:
W (t ) p ( s, t )
r 1 s 1 R S

C1 (t ) 1

When it are particularly the poorest regions in the world (Africa, Bangla-Desh etc.) that would suffer the damages, the concavity of the utility function would give these damages a larger weight. Similarly, when the climate effects tend to be rather extreme, the associated damages generate strong losses of utility (and consumption), risk aversion then calls for a lot of preventive actions and a stronger abatement policy. This holds certainly when some of the effects are irreversible: melting of ice caps, extinction of species...

Integrated assessment models


In order to determine the best emission reduction profile, one needs a long term growth model that tracks the effect of climate change damage and the costs of emission reduction. Such models need a climate module and an economic module that are both reduced forms as shown in Figure 4.4.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

E M IS S I O N S E C O N O M IC M OD EL (r e g io n a l g ro w t h m o d e l) (5 0 t o 2 0 0 dam ages y e a rs ) A b a te m e n t c o s ts C L IM A T E M O D E L L a g + S t o c k a c c u m u la t io n T r a n s l a t e d i n to ( r e g io n a l ) e f fe c t s EFFECTS

Figure 4.4 Structure of an Integrated assessment model One of the best known integrated assessment models is the Nordhaus & Zhang (1996) Rice model. Whose structure is reproduced in Figure 4.5. The most important parameters driving these models are the discount rate (in Fig 4.5 this is ) , the technological progress (A parameter) , the carbon intensity of the future energy use () , the abatement cost (b parameter in ) and the damage of climate change (). Integrated assessment models are necessary to have the argumentation right but given the many uncertainties one should not count on precise results.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

SWF

Production function Net output (after damage and abatement) Net consumption

Capital accumulation

Net emissions (after abatement % ) Stock of GHG T atmospheric temperature

T* deep ocean t F radiative forcing Economic loss factor that accounts for Abatement and damage

For Mini climate model see: http://chooseclimate.org/jcm/jcm8jul03/index.html

Figure 4.5 Structure of the Rice model (Nordhaus & Zhang, 1996)

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Damage of climate change


Estimation of climate change damage is difficult for two reasons. First there is large uncertainty on the precise physical effects of climate change because the translation into a new weather pattern: rainfall, storms, change in sea level and its biological effects are uncertain. Second, the changes that are anticipated are of another magnitude than the ones we experienced in the recent past. A good example of how to measure damages to agriculture is the study by Mendelsohn et al. (1994)). They related the agricultural product in different counties of the USA as a function of average temperature, rainfall, sunshine and soil quality. The effects of a global change in temperature can then be analysed by using the differences observed between counties of the US. They conclude that global warming does not have a negative impact on the agricultural output of the US. Of course this conclusion only holds for the US. There is a large uncertainty on the damages of climate change as can be seen in Figure 4.6 that summarizes several damage estimates:

Figure 4.6 Damage estimates of different sources (Stern (2008)) The damage is primarily a function of the elasticity of marginal utility (risk aversion or aversion to inequality) and a damage parameter that tells us how strongly damages

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

10

increase for an increase in global temperature. The next table gives the loss in permanent consumption possibilities associated to a BAU development (without climate policy). The result depends on the choice of the concavity parameter of the utility function () (higher concavity tends to lower the importance of distant damages but also attaches more weight to catastrophes) and on the choice of the damage function exponent. For instance for =1 and = 2, the uncertainty in the physical effects implies a loss in permanent consumption possibilities in the range 2.2 to 22.8% of permanent consumption.

Table 4.1 Uncertainty on damage costs in the BAU scenario.

Costs of emission abatement


Emissions can be reduced by calling upon two types of actions: by reducing the volume of the polluting activity (smaller annual mileage for cars) and by reducing the emission intensity per unit of activity (production or consumption). A typical ranking of different options to reduce the emission intensity activities is given by the cost curve produced by McKinsey (Figure 4.6). We will later argue that this cost curve contains several errors. One of the errors is the computation of the cost of emission reduction by making cars more fuel efficient. In that computation the high taxes on motorfuels are considered as a real cost, while one should have taken only the production cost of these fuels.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

11

Figure 4.7 Bottom up approach to abatement costs by McKinsey (source, Stern (2008)). One of the important parameters for the cost of GHG emission reduction is the degree of technological progress. Figure 4.8 gives an idea of the cost reductions realized for different electricity generation technologies. These cost reductions are often a function of learning by doing and so a function of cumulative output (cfr. later chapter on renewable energy) .

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

12

Figure 4.8 Average cost of electricity for different technologies as a function of cumulative production Barrett (2009) made a review of alternative long term options to address climate change in the long term: one can invest in avoiding the damage by geo-engineering (addressing the weather on a global scale think about the hail cannon used by the fruit industry in Limburg) but one can also invest in adaptation (lower the damage of the physical effects by building better dikes etc). The other strategy is prevention by either capturing more CO2 or by avoiding the emissions all together. Table 4.2 gives an overview of carbon capture technologies, Table 4.3 gives an idea of the energy supply options without CO2 emissions

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

13

What strategy for emission reduction?


Climate change is a problem of decision under uncertainty. Important questions are the extend of emission reduction as well as the timing of the reductions. One of the ideas is to postpone abatement efforts so that one has a more precise idea about the level of damages and could possibly count on cheaper abatement options. On the basis of decision theory it is not possible to decide in favour or against the postponement strategy. Stern (2008) defends a preventive strategy that would bring down concentration of GHG to 550 ppm and limit global warming to an expected 3C. According to Stern this would cost 1% of GDP in permanence. Delaying action for 30 years would be much more costly. He counts on a global deal between the rich countries that are responsible for a large part of the historic emissions and the developing countries. Figure 4.9 gives the emissions of CO2 per capita for different countries. As can be seen the richer countries emit up to 10 times more GHG per capita than the developing countries. According to Figure 4.3, one needs to reduce overall emissions by 30% compared to current levels. As the economy in 2050 may be three times as large as now, emissions per unit of output would have to decrease by 80 to 85%. Furthermore, in order to allow for a growth in emissions of the developing countries a very strong abatement effort would be necessary in the rich countries. The costs of emission reduction in 2030 would be of the order of 30 /ton of CO2.

Table 4.2Overview of carbon capture technologies (source Barrett 2009)

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

14

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

15

3. Economics of international climate agreements


The international climate negotiations started in Rio de Janeiro (1992) and led to a first agreement in Kyoto (1997). These negotiations are an ongoing process and the last rounds of negotiations took place in Copenhagen in December 2010 and Cancun in dec 2010 and was based on reports like the Stern report. For an outsider, an international agreement is a logical step in an efficient approach to climate change. Up to now the success of the climate negotiations has been rather limited. The Kyoto agreement was not ratified by some of the key emitters (USA) and left out some of the important emitters (China, India). In addition many of the signatories did not comply with their promises. In Copenhagen and Cancun it also proved impossible to have a full agreement on a climate agreement that would more or less limit the expected concentration of GHG to 550 ppm. According to the economic theory reaching a wide agreement on an environmental issue at world scale is very difficult. Contrary to environmental problems at the scale of a country, there is no world authority that can enforce international environmental agreements. One country can take trade sanctions or send fighter jets but this also this enforcement action is costly and will not be easily undertaken.

Figure 4.9 Emissions of CO2 per capita

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

16

Barrett (1994) uses a model with identical countries and finds that the equilibrium number of signatories in an international environmental game that is played only once equals 3 whatever the number of countries in the world. We can illustrate the issue using a simple graph. Figure 4.10 presents a problem where 10 identical problems face an environmental problem that is caused by the sum of the emissions of the 10 countries. Each of them faces a marginal damage function (MB) that is horizontal. Every country can also reduce emissions but at increasing marginal cost: this is the MAC curve.
$/ton Total abatement effort Nash: 1x10 = 10 Int Agreem 3x3 + 7= 16 Full cooperation (FB)= 10x10=100 10 MB

MAC

Int agreement nash 1 3 10

3MB MB abatement

Figure 4.10 Illustration of an international environmental negotiation problem. Consider first what would be the ideal solution for the world. This comes down to reducing emissions in every country up to the point where MC equals the sum of the marginal damages of all the victims, so MC=10 MB and this implies a total abatement effort of 100 units. This can also be called a fully cooperative or first best solution: what could be reached if one could make a binding international agreement where every country would make an effort of 10 units of abatement. Consider now the other extreme where there is no cooperation at all. In that case every country compares its Marginal Cost with the Marginal Damage it avoids in its own country. This is called the Nash non-cooperative solution and the total abatement effort equals 10 times 1=10 (cfr.Ch 3 for an example with only 2 countries). The other solution is an international agreement

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

17

that satisfies the following stability requirement: a country is as well off when it is signing the agreement as when it is not signing the agreement. The group that signs the agreement maximizes its group welfare so it considers the damage of its members. The equilibrium for this game is 3 signatories and the total abatement effort is here 3 countries that make an effort (MC=3MC so 3x3) plus 7 others that work non cooperatively (MC=MB so 3x1) or in total 16 units of abatement. As can be seen the self-enforcing requirement for international agreements is a serious handicap and limits what can be achieved by an international agreement. This is the solution of a one shot game, this is a game that is played over and over again for a few years where players do not take into account past or future behavior. One could argue that this is the right concept given that the political majorities in countries can change and that a new government is not responsible for what the previous government did (think about Obama and Bush). One could also think about behavior of countries as more consistent with more continuity and then one could see the game as a repeated game where each country can start by cooperating and punish those that stop making efforts by also stopping its efforts and doing this forever . When the discount rate is sufficiently low, the sanction consisting of stopping cooperation forever is important and Barrett proves that more performing international agreements become possible. At present the EU plays such a cooperative strategy in the hope that the others will follow.

4. European Climate change policy


The European climate policy has an international and an internal European dimension. We discuss first the international dimension.

International negotiation strategy of the EU


The EU has promised to reduce its emissions of GHG by at least 20% in 2020 compared to the baseline level of 1990. Moreover if there is a comprehensive international climate change agreement, it promises a 30% reduction by 2020. It also promised to increase the

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

18

share of renewables to 20% and have energy savings of 20% by 2020 but these targets have also other objectives than climate change. What are the costs of this strategy and how will the EU achieve the 20 and 30 % objectives? This issue has been studied using the GEM-E3 general equilibrium model. This model studies the economic development in the world by considering 10 or so regions and modelling their emissions of GHG as well as the costs of reducing these emissions.

Table 4.4 Simulation of costs of different EU strategies (source GEM-E3) Table 4.4 presents the economic effects of the cooperative scenario where the rest of the world also agrees to make efforts and the unilateral scenario where only the EU commits to emission reductions. In the cooperative scenario, the assumption is that the USA commits to an identical reduction as the EU (-30% in 2020 and progressively more in 2030)) and that the new industrializing countries commit to monitor their emission/ output ratios so that they cannot sell emission reduction efforts by first increasing their emission levels. A second important assumption is that there is full trade of carbon permits in the world. This means that the emission reduction in the EU and the US are partly bought in China and Brazil. The overall reduction in the world will be 26% and the gross economic cost (before accounting for climate damage) will be 1.2% of GDP in 2020. The price of a permit of CO2 emission will be of the order of 45 $/ton of CO2. The

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

19

cost for the US is lower than for the EU because the US starts from a higher level of emissions per capita and can therefore more easily reduce emissions than the EU. It is also interesting to see what strategy could be followed to realize the 20% if the rest of the world does not sign any agreement. In that case, it would pay for the EU to set up a monitoring system in a country with cheap emission reductions (China) and start trading emission reduction efforts even if this country does not sign an agreement. Important to note is that the demand for permits will be lower and the price of permits will drop to a lower level. Of course there is still some hope that other countries will follow the EU in implementing a strong climate policy but as shown in the previous paragraph good international agreements are very difficult to reach.

European climate policy


It is important to define a climate policy at EU level for three reasons. First, as we know from international negotiation economics, it is better to have transfrontier environmental pollution problems solved at the broadest policy level. Compare the EU 27 with a set of 27 individual countries, the sum of the individual efforts would be much lower. Second, as costs of emission reduction are very different across countries, it makes sense to exchange efforts so that overall costs of reductions can be reduced. Finally, the EU is in fact a common market with a minimum of trade barriers and this is beneficial for the EU as a whole. Individual climate policy initiatives risk to disturb normal trade patterns. Take as example two identical steel factories, one in country A and one in country B that have the same constant variable costs. In country A there is a high carbon tax and in country B, there is a lax emission regulation. Country B will start exporting to country A although this does not make any sense from an economic point of view as they have the same technology and costs. The EU reaches its overall emission reduction objective by using different policy instruments for the big industrial emitters (the Emission Trading System) and for the other polluters (home heating, transport, service sector). In fact the EU has two objectives: the 20% reduction of GHG emissions but also a 20% share for renewables in

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

20

energy supply (mainly electricity production). For the big emitters every country receives emission permits more or less proportional to an average emission rate and the type of industrial sectors it has. The firms can then trade permits nationally and internationally. Initially most permits were grandfathered (distributed for free) but there is a tendency to oblige member states to auction a greater share of the permits. The member states are in favor of this policy because it generates extra tax revenues without having to vote (unanimously) on a carbon tax at EU level which would be virtually impossible. The total emission reduction in the non-ETS sector has been set such that, overall, the marginal costs of emission reduction in the ETS and non-ETS sector are not too different (cfr. Table 4.3). As regards the distribution of efforts over EU countries for the non-ETS sector, the countries with the cheapest options to emission reduction had to promise larger emission reductions. But when this was a poorer and strongly growing country, the effort required from the non-ETS sector in this country was reduced. The instruments used for the non-ETS sector are left to the discretion of the member states but policies that affect the intra EU trade are mostly taken in common. Important policies in the non-ETS sector are fuel efficiency standards for cars, insulation standards for buildings, subsidies for investment in low carbon equipment etc.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

21

Table 4. 5 Results of EU carbon policy.

5. A closer look at the experience with the ETS in the EU


The ETS experience in EU is the first experience with a pollutant at a multi-sectoral scale (the US has experience with sulfur trading in the electricity sector). To start the ETS system one needs first a good record of past emissions. This was taken from a database with all thermal plants large than 20Mw and preferably for 1990, a year in which there was no interest yet in GHG emissions so that it was impossible to increase

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

22

emissions in order to receive more permits. The EC checked that not too many permits were distributed as this would generate a very low price level for emission certificates. Although the member states could auction 5 to 10% of the permits they received, only a few states did this. New entrants received often free emission permits. Those who closed their plant lost their permits. Those not complying (emission in firm > amount of permits it had) had to pay a fine of 40 / ton CO2 in 2005-2007 and 100 / ton CO2 in 20082012. This penaly sets a maximum price for the permits. Firms could bank (save) or borrow emission rights that can be used in later years. Overall the system worked well but there were large fluctuations in the prices (5 to 30 /ton of CO2). The fluctuations were the result of different factors: learning by the market players, changes in the total rights attributed by the Commission, expectations on future economic activity etc.. What was the impact of the ETS system on industry profits? Several sectors had an increase in profits, how can this be explained? A system of tradable permits always increases the marginal cost of production even if the firm receives more permits than it needs. The marginal cost increases because every unit produced requires some permits, and every permit used for its own production reduces the amount of permits that can be sold on the international permit market. The effect of an ETS system on the price and profits of a sector can be analyzed using Figures 4.10 and 4.11. Figure 4.10 represents the possibilities of emission reduction per unit of output. The price of a permit implies that the sector will reduce emissions per unit of output as long as the marginal cost of emission reduction is lower than the price of a permit.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

23

Marginal cost of emission reduction per unit of emission reduction)

Price ETS Euro/ton CO2

Cost increase due to measures to reduce emissions per unit of product(= abatement cost)

Cost increase due to the purchase Of emission rights

Reduction of emissions Initial emission Per unit produced Per unit produced

Figure 4.11 Two sources of abatement costs per unit of output produced

Price
Spermit system A2 J
Price Increase Cost of permits bought or Value of permits received Price of Emission permit
cost

S+Abatement

A3 F D A1 S=Marg Cost

E
H

G C

Demand

O2

O3 O1

Output

Figure 4.12 Effect on profits and prices of an ETS sector.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

24

Figure 4.11 helps to define the upward shift of the marginal cost of production in figure 4.12. The first shift (D to F) from curve S to S+abatement cost represents the extra abatement cost per unit of product (the triangle in Figure 4.11 corresponds to a cost increase per unit of output). The second shift upwards (F to A2) corresponds to the need for permits per unit of output (the rectangle in Fig 4.11 corresponds to an increase in cost per unit of output). The new equilibrium in Fig 4.12 is now A2 and this is the result of the cost increase and the price elasticity of demand. The initial gross profit was H A1 C. The new profit level after imposition of the ETS system is now J A2 F G when all necessary permits J A2 F E have been grandfathered. When no permits are received, the gross profit is reduced to E F H. So whenever the sector receives an important share (40 to 50%) of its previous emissions as emission permits, the profits of the sector will increase. This will also depend on the price-elasticity of demand, if this is low, it is easy to increase prices and maintain profits. This is the case for the electricity sector. The main challenges for the European ETS system are the price formation in an uncertain world environment (cfr. Table 4.2) . The objectives for the EU depend on the cooperation or not of other continents and on the integration or not of the other continents in the ETS system. Indeed, if one opens to other countries with low emission abatement costs, this reduces the equilibrium price of permits. On the other hand, if other continents have also ambitious emission reduction goals, the demand for permits will increase and so may do the price.

6. References
Barrett S.(1994), Self-enforcing environmental agreements, Oxford Economic Papers, 46, p 878-894 Barrett S. (2009), The coming global climate technology revolution, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 23, n2, p53-75

Delbeke J., Klaassen G., van Ierland T., Zpafel P., (2010), The role of environmental poliy making at the European Commission, Review of environmental economics and policy, vol4, 1, p 24-43

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost Mendelsohn R. , W. D. Nordhaus , D Shaw, (1994) The impact of global warming on agriculture: a ricardian analysis. Amer. Econom. Rev. 84 , pp. 753771

25

Stern R. (2008), The economics of Climate Change, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 98, p2-37 Weyman-Jones Thomas, 2006, Current issues in the design of energy policy, Ch 33 in Evans J., Hunt L., (eds.) International Handbook of the Economics of Energy, Edward Elgar

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 5 Coal
1. Outline
This chapter deals with coal. Coal covers 29% of the world energy needs and is the main fuel for power generation in the world. Its future is uncertain: there are abundant reserves but its use generates more air pollution and more GHG emissions than the other fuels. We start the chapter with a small introductory section, dealing with conventions and definitions1. In the third section we survey the main uses, the main consumers and producers as well as the main trade flows. As coal is a scarce resource, it is important to know the total available quantity of coal. This is the topic of section 4. Section 5 presents some basic economic principles of the coal market. Section 6 discusses the history of the natural gas market. Section 7 presents a small model of demand and supply of the coal market.

2. Some conventions and definitions


Different types of coal
For coal one distinguishes traditionally between peat, lignite and coal. Peat and lignite are precursors of coal that have lower energy density. Within the coal category there are many variants. Some coal types are better suited to make metallurgical coal, other types that are ideal for household use (anthracite), all coal can be used as fuel in power stations. The heating capacity of coal varies from less than 28000 kj/kg for lignite to 35000 kj/kg for anthracite.

Units
The heating capacity of 1 tonne of oil is more or less equivalent to the heating capacity of 1.5 tonne of coal.

Sources of data and forecasts


In this chapter we will use often data of IEA outlook 2008. This is not necessarily the outlook we prefer but it helps to put historic trends in perspective. The IEA outlook is based on many

1 For a good review of mainly technical issues in the gas industry see W.Van Herterijck Aardgas , technische, economische en politieke aspecten, ACCO, 2007

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

assumptions. The price of coal is expected to stabilize in real terms at 110$ per tonne or the equivalent of 22.5 $ / bbl2.

3. Main uses, consumers, producers and trade flows


Main uses Coal has long been the dominant fuel replacing wood in the past. Coal is noawadays primarily used for power generation, for industrial heat production and home heating. Use of gas Home heating & cooking Industrial generation Power generation heat Main substitutes Gasoil, natural gas, firewood Fuel oil, natural gas

gas, nuclear, heavy fuel oil

The next graph shows that the consumption of coal is growing strongly in Asia (China, India) over the last years and is more or less stable in the rest of the world.

Main producers
2

Remember that in terms of heating capacity, 1 ton of oil = 7.33 barrels = 1.5 ton of coal

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Production is also more or less stable in most continents but growing strongly in China and India. The main producers are China, the US, India, Australia, South Africa, Russia, Germany..

Trade flows
The major trade flows are from the exporters, Australia, Russia, South Africa,North America and Colombia to the main importers Japan, South Korea, India etc.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

4. How much coal is there?


We know that for any resource, the reserves depend on two factors: the market price and the degree of confidence one has in the estimates. There are ample reserves of coal and these are in addition distributed more equally than oil and gas.

conventional coal
The proved reserves are of the order of 850 billion ton of coal or 565 billion TOE or 3.3 times the proved reserves of oil. In addition, as no one seems worried about the extent of the reserves, much less efforts have been done to estimate the ultimate recoverable reserves.

non conventional coal


There are two types considered. The first is in situ or underground coal gasification. A technique useful for the coal at large depth. Idea is to apply the technique to layers below 1000 m and to coal layers lying offshore. Estimates are 146 Trillion cubic metres. There is one successful plant in Uzbekistan where the gas produced is used to run a 400 MW power plant. Coal mine methane is the second type of non conventional coal resource (one also calls it a gas resource as it produces methane).

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

5. Economics of the coal market


Opening the coal sector to foreign trade
The following two figures illustrate the effects on welfare of an opening of a sector to trade. The first figure shows the situation without trade. The price is high in the potential importing country and low in the potential exporting country.
Equilibrium without free trade POTENTIAL IMPORTER Marginal cost POTENTIAL EXPORTER demand

demand

Pimp

Pexp

Marginal cost Q importing country Q exporting country

How does one protect a sector from too much foreign competition? There are different ways of doing this: outlawing imports, put very excise duties, give very high subsidies to local production, impose regulations on imports that are very costly etc. Obviously, for a given degree of protection, some instruments are more efficient for a country than others: those that generate revenue for the government are better than those that impose extra costs on imports. In the next Figure we allow free trade. There is a small transport cost. In equilibrium, the price in the importing country will equal the price in the exporting country + the transport cost per unit of the product.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

POTENTIAL IMPORTER Marginal cost

POTENTIAL EXPORTER demand

demand

Pimp P*imp C

A B P*exp import Pexp


Transport cost

export D F E

Marginal cost
Q importing country
Q exporting country

Total gains from trade=ABC+DEF = - loss for producers in importing country+gain for consumers in importing country+ gain for producers in exporting country loss for consumers in exporting country

The quantity of imports and exports are equal because there are only 2 countries trading. Both countries gain from free trade but in every country there will be losers and winners. In the importing country, the net gain equals CAB. This is the result of a gain for consumers, who have access to lower prices and have a gain in consumer surplus equal to P A B P*. But there is also a loss for the producers who face lower prices, have to reduce production and see the price for the remaining production decreased. They lose P A CP*. Similarly in the exporting country: there is a net gain of DEF but a loss for consumers P*DFP and a gain for producers equal to P*EFP.

Coal has high transport costs


Coal is costly to transport as it has low energy density. For this reason one prefers to generate electricity near the mine. When one has to export coal, one combines inland waterways, and sea transport. Transport costs are an important determinant of coal trade and will be integrated in the modelling approach that will be presented later.

6. History of the coal market in Western Europe


Second World war - 1970
In this period there is a progressive opening of the European national coal markets to imports of coal. There were very large differences in production costs of coal: some countries had surface coal and thick layers, other countries had very deep mines (1000 m) and thin layers. As the coal industry occupied a large work force in many countries, it was difficult to open the coal sector to competition. This started with the European Union for Coal and Steel.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

In Belgium as in most of Europe, the local coal production was threatened by cheap coal from abroad but also by cheap HFO and natural gas. This lead the government to protect the coal industry using a combination of techniques: subsidies for production, import quotas etc.. Even inside Belgium some regions were protected against the competition of other regions. The older mines in the Walloon region had higher costs than the Limburg region where production started after world war. The Belgian government restricted the output of Limburg coal in order to let the Walloon mines survive longer.

From 1974-2004
In this period there was a renewed interest in the use of coal. Prices of oil and later gas increased strongly and this gave rise to a much higher demand for coal. Power stations initially designed to burn coal, were transformed to use HFO in the 60 ties, switched to cheaper natural gas and were retransformed into coal powered stations. The increased demand for coal was not planned, it was the result of the first and second oil price shock, so there were problems of capacity to meet demand and this led to strong price increases for international coal. There was a strong increase in coal exports (Figure 1). Prices increased strongly in the 70 ties but once capacity of production and transport (train, harbours) were adapted prices dropped (Figure 2). Production expanded mainly in Australia because the South African apartheid regime was still facing a trade embargo. But also the large domestic US market became a net exporter when prices were high enough (Figure 3).

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

In Europe, the domestic coal industry was an important sector in terms of employment and managed to lobby for protection. Main arguments used were employment and security of energy supplies. One had to wait for the late 80 ties to find a political compromise to stop the production of coal in Limburg. In the 80 ties the real value added (measured at world prices without subsidies) of a person employed in the mine was only 20 to 30% of the added value in the rest of the industry. This means that whenever one can transfer a miner to a job in industry and he produces more than 30% of the average worker in industry there is an efficiency gain for the country as a whole. Why did this transfer not happen earlier? The main reasons were first that the miner had a good wage (paid by subsidies) and the prospect to find another job is uncertain. Second there was the idea that the number of jobs is fixed: there is something like a stock of workplaces and it is very difficult that another industrial activity could be developed in that region. The final agreement was based on the following idea: the expected subsidies for the next 10 to 20 years were given to a fund for local development. The fund was used to subsidize the employment of ex miners in other industries. The faster one closed the mines the more funds were available for development. This operation was a success and overall employment in Limburg increased.

From 2004 onwards


We see that coal prices on the international market converge more and more.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

10

Coal prices 1987-2007


100,00 90,00 80,00 70,00 60,00 50,00 40,00 30,00 20,00 10,00 0,00 Nort hwest Europe marker price US cent ral Appallachian Japan coking coal cif japan st eam coal cif

years

Important developments in this period are the high oil (and gas) prices in 2005-2008 and the interest for a limitation of the GHG emissions. In the EU there is a strict limit on GHG emissions implemented via tradable permits. With high gas prices, the use of coal becomes more attractive but users of coal need much more CO2 permits. The GHG emission limit will be the binding constraint on the expansion of coal use in Europe. In the rest of the world, there is not yet a binding GHG emission limit so that coal use will continue to expand in the US, China, India. Also nuclear power can be considered as a strong competitor for coal powered stations but there is a long delay in having new power stations accepted. The competition of nuclear power will also be stronger when there is binding GHG constraint.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

11

7. Modelling the world coal market


Perfect competition model
We propose to model the coal market using a simple optimisation technique initially proposed by Samuelson (1952) and Takayama & Judge (1964)3. This can be used to simulate World trade flows if one assumes perfect competition on the world coal market. Take i=1,...,N producers of coal with a convex continuous total cost function TKi(Xi) where Xi is tota production by I There are j= 1,...,M consumers of coal with a Willingness to Pay function P(Xj) The quantity deliverd by producer i to consumer j is called Xij and there are constant transport costs per unit Tij. Besides perfect competition, we also assume that consumers are not interested in diversifying their supply. The competitive equilibrium can be modelled by maximizing the sum of total consumer surpluses minus the production and transport costs:

M ax


j 0

P(X j) d X j

TK ( X
i

T
i j

ij

X ij


i i

X ij X i

j X j X ij j i first o rd er co n d itio n s P ( X j ) j 0 if X
j

w ith resp ect to X i , X j , X ij , i , j g ive yo u : 0

M K i i 0 if X i 0 T ij i j 0 if X ij 0 su b st itu tin g i an d j in last eq u atio n o n e o b tain s (at o p tim u m ) P ( X j ) M K i T ij fo r all i w h ere X ij 0 an d co m b in in g 2 o f th e latter co n d itio n s o n e h as (at o p tim u m ): P ( X j ) T ij P ( X j ' ) T ij ' fo r all X ij ' , X ij 0
In the optimum, we find a) that the price for each import line that is used by an importer should be identical.

Samuelson P., (1952) Spatial price equilibrium and linear programming, American Economic Review, Vol 42, n3 p 283-303 and Takayma T., Judge G.G., (1964), Equilibrium among spatially separated markets: a reformulation, Econometrica, vol 32, n4 , p 510-524

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost


b) for each producer, the net revenue from all destinations that are used should be equal.

12

Non competitive models


Several non-competitive models have been proposed. One could use a Cournot model where the main exporters (Australia, south Africa, ..) control each their production and there is a competitive fringe. There is some evidence that exporters in Australia and South Africa control their exports via government regulations or private cartels. One of the problems of such a model is that the competitive fringe is very important: the US and China do not export a lot of coal but they have a large national market so their net export and import can react strongly to price fluctuations.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 6 Oil market


1. Introduction
This chapter deals with the most important energy vector: oil. It is still the type of primary energy that has the largest market share. In addition, it is the fuel that can be used for almost any energy need and, given its low transport cost, balances many energy markets in the world. We start the chapter with a small introductory section, dealing with conventions and definitions. In the second section we survey the main uses, the main consumers and producers as well as the main trade flows. As oil is a scarce resource, it is important to survey what we know about the total available quantity of oil and what are the determining parameters for this estimate. This is done in section 3. Section 4 presents a few simple models that can be useful to understand the oil market. In section 5 we try to use different economic models to understand the history of the oil market over the last 50 years. Section 6 deals with policy questions on the oil market: what future can we expect? What can consumers do to keep prices low? An appendix deals with the price formation of oil products.

2. Some conventions and definitions


The different types of oil
We deal in this chapter with crude oil, the raw material that is, after a refinery process transformed into final products like gasoline, diesel, fuel oil, heavy fuel oil, bitumen etc. In a separate chapter we deal briefly with the refining and the price formation for the separate products. For crude oil we distinguish between different types of products because they have a different cost structure and different properties: Concentional Crude Oil: oil produced from conventional wells on land or on sea, at different depth, can have different gravities and sulphur contents. One uses often the API gravity {(141.5/specific gravity)-131.5} where the

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

specific gravity of water is 1 and so the API of water is 10. The higher the API the lighter is the crude and the more light products (gasoline) one can extract out of a ton of crude. Light crudes are Algeria Sahara (44 API), Brent .., heavy crudes are coming from Venezuela, Alaska, etc.. The sulphur content of crude varies from more than 2.5% to less than 0.1%. Sulphur content matters because consumers prefer end products with a low sulphur content for environmental or other reasons. Non conventional oil This represents different types of oil that have lower quality (API<15) but could represent a resource stock larger than that of conventional oil. heavy oil is a dense and viscous oil that requires usually the injection of steam and diluents in the reservoir to produce it. oil sands (tar sand, natural bitumen) are mixtures of sand, clay and crude bitumen, - API is on average 8 oil shales is a hard rock that contains oil Natural Gas Liquids Liquid hydrocarbons produced as a by-product in the production of gas. They represent a small source of oil distillates and are therefore often treated together with oil.

Units
The oil industry uses mostly barrels and million barrels a day. We use the BP statistical yearbook conversion factors: 1 barrel is approx. 1/ 7.33 ton and this allows conversion to Ton oil Equivalent 1 million barrel per day = (1/7.33) (365) = 49.8 million tonnes per year

Sources of data and forecasts

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

In this chapter we will use often data of IEA outlook 2008. This is not necessarily the outlook we prefer but it helps to put historic trends in perspective. The IEA outlook is based on many assumptions. Important assumptions are a real oil price of 100 $/bbl in 2010 and 122$/bbl in 2030 as well as an economic growth in the world of 3.3% per year until 2030.

3. Main uses, consumers, producers and trade flows


Main uses
Oil has non energy uses (lubricant, feedstock for chemicals, bitumen for roads) as well as energy uses. Main energy uses are industrial heat, power generation, home heating and motorfuel. It is relatively easy to substitute in most energy uses except as motorfuel.

Main producers
The next figure gives the production of oil by region. Most important producers are Saudi-Arabia, Russia, US , Iran, Canada, Venezuela , ... The middle east producers together with Venezuela, Nigeria, Indonesia, o and the North African producers form the OPEC group that controls some 44% of total oil supply. So in the next figure OPEC is somewhat larger than Middle East + Africa. OPEC acts often as swing producer, sometimes acting as the dominant supplier that controls prices

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Figure 6.1 Production of oil by region (source: BP statistical review 2008) Some of the main producers are also large consumers. This is the case of the US and Russia. In the next Figure one sees the consumption by region. Important trends are the smaller consumption in Europe and the strongly increasing demand in Asia. The US consumption continues to increase.

Figure 6.2 Consumption of oil by region (source: BP statistical review 2008)

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Trade flows
The cost of oil transport is relatively small because large tankers can be used and the product is easy to ship. Any oil source can in principle be substituted by another oil source but there can be adaptation costs at the refinery.

Figure 6.3 Major Trade flows (source IEA, energy outlook 2006) One sees that some regions are strongly dependent on imported oil. For many OECD regions it is 60% or higher.

4. How much oil resources are there?


We know that the quantity of oil depends on two factors: the market price and the degree of confidence one has in the estimates. We present here briefly three estimates: the IEA (OECD) energy outlook 2008, the EIA (Department of energy of US ) and finally a recent paper by Aguilera et al (2009). We will use million or trillion barrels of oil for estimates of oil resources. These can be compared with a present consumption of some 30 million barrels per year.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

The IEA (OECD) energy outlook 2008


Best is to summarize their view in the following long term cost curve.

Figure 6.4 Long term oil supply curve (IEA, 2008) In this figure the first block represents oil already produced. The next block is cheap oil from Middle East and Northern Africa followed by other conventional sources of oil. Then we have several blocks representing different techniques of enhanced oil recovery and oil produced in very different conditions. The oil recovery factor is very important as a doubling of the oil rovery factor from 30% to 60% doubles the quantity of oil that can be extracted from a given reservoir. For the non conventional oil, the cheapest to develop is the heavy oil (mainly Venezuela), followed by bitumen or oil sands (mainly Canada). The extraction of oil from such resources is difficult and may requires a lot of energy and water as these processes require steam. The next resource category are the oil shales that require even more water and energy if the resources are not near the surface. So the extraction of non-conventional oil has an important CO2 emission drawback. If one really needs liquid fuels one can also transform natural gas and coal into liquid fuels. As there is an extra conversion loss, this will only make sense if the energy need can not be satisfied by coal or gas directly.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

This is a long term cost function and for the production to be available at these marginal costs, several conditions need to be satisfied. First, some of the production needs first exploration (resources are there but statistically). Second, any production needs production capacity and this requires long deadlines if it involves difficult production techniques like in the case of production in deep sea. Investment in production capacity will only happen if the producer believes that future prices are high enough to guarantee a sufficient margin. The higher the risk, the higher the return required. Third some technologies are still under development and will only be available after 2030.

The Energy Information Agency view


The EIA (US department of Energy) is responsible for a regular outlook on the world energy situation. Interesting feature is that they are bound by law to make all the information (and models) publicly available (http://www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/ieo/index.html). The EIA produces estimates of the total resource in place that contains past production (> 1 trillion barrels) and the total resource stock in the reservoirs. Production will be limited by the recovery rate.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Paper of Aguilera et al. 1


These authors produce an estimate on the basis of USGS estimates of 2000 to which they add three new elements. First they estimate the potential of regions previously not assessed. Second they add future reserve growth . Third they add unconventional resources. Details can be found in Aguilera et al. .The methodology is mainly statistical but is well documented in the paper. Unfortunately no confidence intervals are given. Here we concentrate our attention on the long run cumulative availability curve. The long run curve shows a much larger potential of conventional oil than IEA (some 50% more) and this at cost levels less than 50% of the ones mentioned in the IEA study. It is not clear why the cost levels are so different. One possibility is that the IEA adds a large risk premium to the capital costs before certain production potentials are made operational. Also for unconventional oil does one find much more optimistic estimates in the Aguileras study than in IEA. Overall if one believes the Aguileras study, oil would no longer be a very scarce resource as even with a demand growth of 5% per year, oil resources could supply demand for the next 70 years.

1 Aguilera R., Eggert R., Lagos R.,Tilton J. , Depletion and the future availability of petroleum resources, The Energy Journal (2000), Vol 30, N1,

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

Figure 6.5 Cumulative supply curve oil resources

5. Three simple models for the world oil market

In the next sections we will discuss the history and possible futures of the oil market. We will rely on three simple economic models that we review in this section. The first model is a simple demand and supply model for one period with an exogenous OPEC production level. It will mainly serve to illustrate the difference between short and long run responses. The second model is a one period model where a cartel acts as dominant supplier. The third model is a multiperiod model where OPEC sets the prices and quantities to optimize its long term profits.

A simple oil market model with exogenous OPEC supply


The simplest model one can use is a model with linear demand and linear non OPEC supply function that is calibrated to long term equilibrium of the oil market. The data one needs to calibrate the model are limited to the

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

10

equilibrium price and quantity on the world oil market (say for a year), the exogenous supply by OPEC in that equilibrium as well as the short run and long run demand and supply elasticities. The starting point needs to be long term equilibrium. In the first step one calibrates the long run model. The procedure is illustrated graphically in Figure X. One starts with the observation of a long run equilibrium P,Q, substracting the exogenous OPEC production gives the initial equilibrium non-Opec supply (point A). This initial non-OPEC supply, the price P and the elasticity of non-Opec supply allows to find the long run (LR) non Opec supply that passes through point A. The LR demand function can be found by using the observed P,Q and the LR demand elasticity. It is important to use the elasticities in the observed P,Q as the price elasticities of a linear function are not constant.
Price LR demand LR non OPEC supply ADD Assumption on LR elasticity of Supply to have slope

OBSERVED P,Q Market Price P A ADD Assumption On LR elasticity of Demand to have slope Exogenous OPEC supply

Quantity

Figure 6.6 calibration of the long term model We can proceed the same way to find the short run (SR) supply and demand functions. These also have the point P,Q as an equilibrium but the demand and supply functions have a much stronger slope. This time we use the SR elasticities of demand and supply to calibrate the demand and supply functions. These are much smaller as it is much more difficult to react in the

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

11

short term than in the long term because one needs to adapt installations, train personel etc. 2 The calibration is illustrated in Figure XX. We use linear demand and supply functions. There are other functions one could calibrate to a long run equilibrium P,Q. An alternative is a constant elasticity function Q=aPb .
Price SR demand SR non OPEC supply ADD Assumption on SR elasticity of Supply to have slope

LR demand

OBSERVED P,Q Market Price P LR non OPEC supply ADD Assumption On SR elasticity of Demand to have slope

Exogenous OPEC supply

Quantity

Figure 6.7 Calibration of the short run demand and supply functions. Once one has calibrated the short and long run model for the world oil market, one can use the model for comparative statics. An interesting exercise is to analyze the effect of a sudden reduction in the exogenous Opec supply. This is illustrated in Figure 6.8

2 Demand elasticities for durable goods (cars) can be larger in the short run because there is a stock of goods one can use for a longer time.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

12

Price SR demand

SR non OPEC supply New short run equilibrium LR demand New long run equilibrium

Market Price P LR non OPEC supply

INITIAL EQUILIBRIUM OBSERVED P,Q

Exogenous OPEC supply INTERRUPTION

Quantity

Figure 6.8 Effect in short and long run of a sudden interruption in the Opec supply. The sudden reduction of OPEC production shifts the short run supply curve to the left, the intersection with the SR demand function gives a new SR equilibrium with a much higher price and quantity that is only reduced slightly. In Figure 6.8 we can also see that the new long run equilibrium involves much smaller price increase and a larger quantity decrease. Pindyck and Rubinfeld 3 started from the following data for 1997 : World price (18$/bbl), total demand and supply (23 billion bbl/year) and Opec supply of 10 billion bbl/year. Using the following data on price elasticities: PRICE ELASTICITIES Demand Non Opec supply Short run -0.05 +0.10 Long run -0.40 +0.40

Pindyck R., D.Rubinfeld, (2001), Micro-economics, 5the ed., Prentice Hall , p50

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

13

As one can see, demand elasticities are always negative 4 and supply elasticities are always positive. The short run elasticities are much smaller than the long run elasticities. Using this data, one can calibrate the following demand and supply functions: (1) Short run demand (2) Short run non Opec supply (3) Total SR supply And the long run functions: (4) Long run demand (5) Long run non Opec supply (6) Total LR supply D=32.18-0.51P S=7.78+0.29P TS=17.78+0.29P D=24.08-0.06P S=11.74+0.07P TS=21.74+0.07P

We can now compute the possible effects of an interruption of 3 million bbl of OPEC oil using these two systems of equations. For the short run equilibrium we need to solve the system of equations (1) + a new total supply function TS=(21.74-3)+0.07P and this gives a new short run equilibrium where P=41.08 $/bbl and Q=21.62. For the long run equilibrium we need to solve system (4) + new total supply function TS=14.78+0.29P and this gives a new equilibrium price of only 21.75 $/bbl and a quantity of only 21.66 $/bbl. This very simple model already shows an important characteristic of the oil market that is often forgotten: unexpected supply interruptions generate very strong price increases in the short run but after a few years the supply and demand response to a price increase is much larger and the remaining price increase is much smaller. One could also analyse the effect of unforeseen shifts in demand. These could be generated by problems in the supply of a substitute to oil (natural gas). Once one knows the amplitude of the shift one
4 This holds for the oil market but does not need to hold at the level of one private consumer where we only know that the sign of the compensated price effect is negative.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

14

can, using the same procedure, analyse what is the effect of this shift on prices and quantities in the short and long run.

OPEC as dominant firm in a one period model


OPEC can be considered as a cartel where producers agree on the total quantity produced and on the allocation of production among their members such as to minimize costs of production. If this is the case, OPEC can be considered as a dominant supplier because it can supply more than 50% of the market and the other suppliers (called competitive fringe) are all smaller producers that take the market price as given. This is also called Stackelberg equilibrium. The implications for the equilibrium on the oil market can be derived in two steps: Step 1: construct the residual Demand function for OPEC oil by subtracting for each possible price level the competitive supply from the world oil demand Step 2: Derive OPECs optimal production by considering it as a Monopolist confronted with the residual demand function for OPEC oil and a cost function that is the aggregate cost function of the OPEC members. Using linear demand and supply functions, one can derive an algebraic expression for the dominant supplier model. Demand for OPEC oil equals (for any price) the difference between world oil demand and competitive supply:

Dopec Dm Scs 0
Using a linear competitive supply function:

qt

pt d

As well as a linear world demand function:

qt

pt a b

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

15

One obtains the residual OPEC oil demand function (for the prices where the competitive supplier is also active):

Dopec

( da bc) (b d ) * pt bd

Figure 6.9 Demand function for dominant supplier In the second step we derive the optimal production of OPEC. We use for this a constant marginal cost z and look for the optimal price p*:

(da p *(b d )) Max ( p * z) p* bd


p* z ad ad z (b d ) and q* 2bd 2 2(b d )

We see that the price of the supplier is increasing in his own marginal cost (z) and in the choke price (a) . A monopolist will absorb half of the increase in p* 1 the marginal cost and this is what we observe here ( ). z 2 We see that the price p* is also increasing in the slope (d) of the supply function of the competitive fringe supply: a high slope means that the competitive supply has strongly rising marginal cost so that a price increase

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

16

does not generate a strong increase in competitive supplies. This helps the dominant supply to set high prices. In general, the smaller (in absolute value) the price elasticity of world oil demand and the smaller the price-elasticity of the competitive supply, the less elastic will be the residual supply for OPEC oil and the higher will be the price charged by the dominant supplier. The next figure shows the optimum for the dominant supplier. As in the case of a monopolist, the equality MR (MO in Figure 6.10) = MC (MK in figure) determines the optimum quantity and price.

Figure 6.10 Optimal production for a dominant supplier

OPEC as dominant firm in multi-period model


We can elaborate the previous model by adding a reserve constraint for the dominant supplier so that OPEC has to distribute its production over time using the Hotelling rule for a monopolist. We will also add the supply of a backstop technology. De Keyzer 5 constructed a spreadsheet model to test the effects of different parameters on the OPEC strategy if it would follow a Stackelberg (or
T. De Keyzer, Modellering van de oliemarkt met backstoptechnologien, Verhandeling Master Economie, 2008

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

17

dominant supplier) strategy that maximizes discounted profits over time. The parameters used are (initial equilibrium in 2005): World demand price elasticity = -0.5 Exogeneous growth in demand for oil: 1.76% per year World elasticity competitive supply conventional oil = +0.35 Price elasticity backstop supply = + 0.35 Average price in initial year = 42.3 $/bbl Initial quantity world market = 82 Mio bbd Initial competitive supply of conventional oil = 48 Mio bbd Initial Backstop oil supply = 3 Mio bbd Technological progress in backstop = cost reduction of 3% /year Marginal cost of OPEC oil increases with 0.0167 $ per Billion bbl Discount rate = 2.55% Reserves OPEC: 915 billion bbl The model is solved using periods of 5 year. The model is simplified: one looks only at stable long term strategies and no total resource constraint was taken into account for the conventional non-OPEC oil and for backstop oil. The results of this type of model are summarized in the following 2 tables: Price in $/bbl 2005-2010 2011-2015 2016-2020 2020-2025 2026-2030 40 45 50 55 61 Production of OPEC million bbl/day 44.8 50.2 56.1 62.7 70.0

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

18

According to this optimisation, it is in the interest of the long term profits of OPEC to increase its supply of oil gradually, increase its market share and have a price that is gradually increasing. This results in backstop oil supply that remains rather low. Apparently it is not in the interest of OPEC to use all its oil. This could be due to three factors: the limited horizon (25 year), the low elasticity for OPEC oil { approx -0.675 = -0.5 (0.5)(0.35)} that makes price increases less interesting and the increasing marginal cost of OPEC oil.

Market share OPEC 2005-2010 2011-2015 2016-2020 2020-2025 2026-2030 47 49 50 52 53

Market share competitive supply 50 48 46 44 42

Market share backstop 3,42 3,63 3,84 4,05 4,27

Some comparative statics: The growth rate of demand is an important parameter. It increases the market share of OPEC and this allows it to increase its price. Prices increase from the first period onwards because the opportunity cost is higher in the next periods. The resources of OPEC are fully exhausted (they are taken as fixed here and this is an irrealistic simplification).

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

19

different growth rates of demand


180 160 140 120 100 p 80 60 40 20 0 Periode 1 Periode 2 Periode 3 Periode 4 Periode 5 Ref. Scen. 5% groei wereldvraag 0% groei wereldvraag

Figure 6.11 price of oil that max profits of OPEC for different growth rates

6. Understanding the history of the world oil market


Before 1970 History of oil prices is a history of cartels and monopolies even before OPEC became the dominant supplier. As early as 1870 did Rockefeller acquire a monopoly for oil supply in the US with the Standard Oil Company and controlled 90% of total supply. After the breaking up of the monopoly in 1911, Rockefeller was followed by the 7 sisters (Esso, Gulf, Texaco, Mobil, Socal, BP, Shell). Some of the 7 sisters originated from the breaking up of the Standard Oil Company. The origin of the Royal Dutch Shell is the production of oil in Indonesia, for BP, it was the discovery of oil in the Middle East. Both regions are former colonies of the Netherlands and the UK. After the 2nd world war, the 7 sisters controlled total oil output as a cartel. One of the big problems of any cartel is to control each others output. This was done by a system of co-ownership in each others production facilities.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

20

The 7 sisters controlled also sea transport, the refineries and the distribution so that the cartel was very effective. OPEC was created in 1960 in a response to a fall in tax revenues that originated from a recession and the control of prices by the 7 sisters. OPEC nationalised most of the production. But OPEC was not really capable to increase prices as the 7 sisters also controlled the downstream operations.

Figure 6.12 Real oil prices over time (Source: Hamilton (2008)) 1973 This is the first oil shock. This was not a deliberate action by OPEC but rather the result of a response by Arab countries to the Yom Kippur war where Israel tried successfully to conquer some strategically important neighbouring land. The Arab coalition denied oil deliveries to the friends of Israel. This is not really possible as oil, once on a tanker, can be sold to the highest bidder. The result was a restriction of supply and a strong increase in prices. OPEC realised (almost by accident) that it had market power and there was a belief that prices will stay high forever. In this period the economy was growing very quickly, oil was taking over from coal and all this resulted in a strong growth rate for oil (8 to 10% per year before 1973).

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

21

Initially there was a belief that oil demand will simply not react to a higher price. This is correct in the short term but not in the long term. Demand response was to switch to natural gas, coal and nuclear. Converting coal power stations to oil and back to coal or converting oil powered stations to gas does not take much time. Building new nuclear power stations or building new oil platforms in the North Sea takes 5 to 10 years. So the full response to the oil price increase takes time and was hidden by an economy that kept growing. Gately (1995)6 presents the history of the oil market using two diagrams:

Figure 4.13 developments


6

Gatelys

(1995)

interpretation

of

oil

market

Gately D.,Strategies for OPECs Pricing and Output Decisions , The Energy Journal, Vol 16, n3

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

22

In the first diagram the real oil price is related to the output of OPEC and level curves for OPEC revenue (price times OPEC output = level of revenues for OPEC) show what happened to OPEC gross revenues over time. The second diagram shows the OPEC output and the non-OPEC output so that rays from the origin show the market share of OPEC. We know that a dominant producer can only control prices if his market share is large enough: 50% or more. If his market share is too small, any attempt to increase prices by reducing output generates an expansion of the output of the non cartel members so that price increases are costly for the cartel. In the period 1968 to 1973, one sees a strong expansion of demand for oil (at constant price) and it is mainly OPEC that satisfies the increase in demand. This meant its share came close to 2/3 of the market. In these market conditions, the oil production decrease of 1973 worked and allowed to more than double oil revenues of OPEC in the period 1973 to 1979. 1979-1980 With the Iranian revolution at the end of 1978, oil production of Iran decreased and none of the OPEC countries wanted to increase production. This generated the second oil shock, prices doubled again and so did the revenues of OPEC 1980-1985 It is now more than 5 to 10 years after the first oil shock so that demand substitution and non-OPEC production can really react. Moreover the Western economies are in a recession. So total demand for oil and for OPEC oil decreased. In addition Iran and Iraq fought a war and needed oil revenues to finance it. OPEC has to decrease its output in order to maintain the price. OPEC tried to defend the price until 1985-1986. Saudi-Arabia as largest producer cut back its production from 10.3 million bbl/day in 1980 to 3.6 million bbl/day in 1985. But prices decreased strongly and the largest OPEC members decided to regain market share by increasing their production (Saudi-Arabia increased its production in 1986 to 5.2 million bbl/day).

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

23

Figure 4.14 Production of Iran and Iraq (source: Hamilton) With hindsight, OPEC could have done much better by using more prudent price increases. There are different explanations for the cartel behaviour that tried to defend the irrealistic price increase in 1980. A first is that OPEC was not aware of the stronger longer term demand and supply response. One can indeed find official statements that go along that line. A second is that the different cartel members had different interest: some want to maximize revenue in the long term because they have ample reserves and do not want to push the development of substitutes too much but others go for the high revenues in the short term (members with small oil reserve base and large population like Algeria). There was often disagreement between the different groups within OPEC because it is difficult to share the costs of output restriction. 1986 2004 This is a period with strong price fluctuations and different attempts by OPEC to regain control. At a certain moment prices decreased below the 10$/bbl and the expensive oil producers (North Sea) were fearing bankrupty. OPEC tried to control output much better but this was often difficult as the smaller members had an interest to sell oil unofficially (via barter trade etc.). OPEC also tried to made agreements with Russia and Norway (expanded output from 0.8 Million bb/d in 1985 to 3.3 Million bb/d. There was also the

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

24

invasion of Kuwait by Iraq in 1991 but this had only a small effect on the oil price. 2004 2008 There was again a strong price increase. There are several factors. First demand in newly industrialised countries was growing more strongly than expected. Second the last 20 years was a period without any real high and stable prices, so there were less investments in oil supply. In the case of nonOPEC oil, the strong fluctuations in the prices were not very encouraging for investors. In the case of OPEC oil, most production was nationalised and extension of supply was the priority. Third, some sources suspected speculation by the financial markets. Hamiltons statistical analysis of the fundamentals of oil prices Up to now we used an ad hoc explanation using simple demand and supply basics. One can also try to test statistically the real factors driving the oil prices. Hamilton7 (2008) has tried to explain oil prices over the period 19702008. 1. A first model is a pure random walk model without any fundamental factors, prices are a function of the changes in the past with an error term. This model could not be rejected and the result is that oil prices are not predictable in the short term.

Using the estimates, and starting with a price of 115$/bbl, the uncertainty is such that one may end up, after 4 years , with a price as low as 34$/bbl or as high as391 $/bbl. 2. In the following models Hamilton brings in some economic theory. A first bound on price fluctuations comes from the possibility to store oil Denoting the cost of storing oil by C and using an indterest rate I, the expected price of oil should be larger than todays price + storage cost (rental cost of

Hamilton, (2008) Understanding crude oil prices, discussion Paper UCEI, Energy Policy and Economics n23

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

25

facility+interest on cost of oil).If this does not hold all investors would buy oil now and increase their sales net year:

This theory is unable to predict large changes in oil prices. The same holds for the futures markets: arbitrage between spot and future markets guarantees that the current spot price is a good indicator for the foreseeable changes at a horizon of a few years. 3. The next model is a model testing the hotelling scarcity rent. This implies that the margin (Price-Marginal cost) should rise at the rate of interest:

Different empirical tests do not confirm this hypothesis for the period 19702000. In more recent years, there are several statements by OPEC countries that point to a limitation of production to safeguard oil for their descendants. So it is only recently that the scarcity rent may explain price movements. 4. In principle there is a cartel controlling the total output and the price. It is clear that sudden supply interruptions have strongly influenced prices at certain moments (1973, 1979, 2000). But in order to control prices continuously, OPEC needs a system of production quota that is observed by its members. The following figure (Hamilton,2008) shows that the production quota are regularly exceeded by some of the members.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

26

Figure 4.15 Quotas and actual production levels for 5 most important OPEC members

7. And the future?


If we would know the future oil prices and are ready to take a gamble, we would become very rich. The oil market is probably like the stock market: all available information is included in the present price. But there are a few elements that help to explain what is more likely to happen: a) demand and supply take time to react to uncertain events

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

27

b) OPECs market share is likely to increase as they have cheap oil and can extend their production capacity when they want to c) at low prices, oil demand is growing in the world as long as there is no cheap substitute available Putting fundamentals of demand and supply together, most sources expect prices in the 50-70 $/ bbl range according to the IEA, real prices of the order of 125 $ in 2010-2030 could be an equilibrium.

8. Policies to stabilise or decrease oil prices


The Western consuming countries have experienced large fluctuations in oil prices and this has generated large oil rents in the Middle East and in other producing countries. Four types of strategies have been followed to address this problem: emergency and strategic stockpiles, import taxes, lower oil dependency and a strong climate action.. We discuss them one by one. Emergency and strategic stockpiles Most consuming countries have a stock of oil for at least 3 months. This can serve for emergency situations. Some countries have a larger stock and can use this stock when they fear that prices are manipulated and are too high. The use of stockpiles is not so easy. There are two problems. First the simple fact that one country uses its stockpiles can be interpreted by all other consumers that there is a very severe shortage and this may increase the demand and drive up prices. Second, every country that uses its stockpiles increases supply on world market and this benefits all consumers on the oil

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost

28

market. When that country is rather small, the action may not have a large effect. Import taxes In a competitive market it pays for the consuming countries to coordinate their actions and to impose an import tax. This type of action can positively influence the terms of trade (here the import price would decrease). Again all consuming countries can gain by this action but there is a benefit for each country to encourage the other countries to do this but not to do it yourself. The EU has traditionally a higher tax on oil products than the US (think about gasoline). An optimal coordinated import tax for oil would be much higher. Another weakness of this approach is that it assumes non strategic supply behaviour from the side of OPEC. This is somewhat unrealistic as OPEC can, as dominant supplier, also act strategically. Decreasing the oil dependency of the economy This policy has been taken by most consuming countries. They encouraged the switch to nuclear, coal and gas and encouraged a lower oil demand for the transport sector. Climate Change policy and the world oil market One of the possible developments is a strong climate action in the world. This could be implemented by a set of tradable permits or a set of carbon taxes. Some politicians count on a double benefit from a carbon tax as this tax would decrease oil demand and decrease the import price of oil.

Energy Economics 2009-2010 prof Stef Proost


According to

29

Johannson et al (2009) a strong world wide climate change

policy would actually increase the oil rents of Opec if it acts as dominant supplier. The main reason is that the oil substitutes (based on coal or unconventional oil) are also Carbon intensive so that a carbon policy would reduce the threat of cheap substitutes for oil. A world wide carbon policy would reduce the oil rent if one implements a policy based on renewables and on energy efficiency.

9. References
Aguilera R., Eggert R., Lagos R.,Tilton J. , Depletion and the future availability of petroleum resources, The Energy Journal (2009), Vol 30, N1 De Keyzer, T. Modellering van de oliemarkt met backstoptechnologien, Verhandeling Master Economie, 2008 Gately D.,Strategies for OPECs Pricing and Output Decisions , The Energy Journal, Vol 16, n3 Johansson D., Azar C. Lindgren K., Persson T., 2009, OPEC Strategies and Oil Rent in a Climate Conscious World, The Energy Journal, Vol. 30, No. 3 Hamilton, (2008) Understanding crude oil prices, discussion Paper UCEI, Energy Policy and Economics n23 IEA, Energy Outlook 2006, IEA, Energy Outlook 2008

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 7 Natural Gas


1. Outline
This chapter deals with natural gas. As it covers 21% of world energy demand and has been growing strongly over the last 30 years, it merits our attention. We start the chapter with a small introductory section, dealing with conventions and definitions 1 . In the third section we survey the main uses, the main consumers and producers as well as the main trade flows. As gas is a scarce resource, it is important to know the total available quantity of gas.. This is the topic of section 4. Section 5 presents some basic economic principles of the gas market. Section 6 discusses the history of the natural gas market. Section 7 analyses in more detail a model for the European gas market that focuses on the impact of the liberalisation. Section 8 discusses the reliability of Russian gas supply in Europe, one of the main policy concerns in the EU.

2. Some conventions and definitions


Different types of gas
Gas is usually a mix of different types of gasses. Most important for us is the heating capacity of the gas. In European cities one started by using gas manufactured on the basis of coal, so called town gas. This was a gas with a much lower heating capacity (24 Mj/m) than the gas we use nowadays: 36,9 Mj/m for Slochteren (NL), 40,7 Mj/m for North Sea gas and 42,9 Mj/m for Algerian gas. As long as this heating capacity of the gas is not too different, they are considered substitutes in terms of Mj delivered. In Belgium, the Northern part received the Dutch gas (lower heating value), the rest receives Norwegian and other richer gas.

1 For a good review of mainly technical issues in the gas industry see W.Van Herterijck Aardgas , technische, economische en politieke aspecten, ACCO, 2007

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Units
The gas industry has its own units. Volumes are important for transmission so one uses m and cubic feet, for customers it is the heating capacity that counts.We use as much as possible the conventions used by BP statistical review of World energy. Useful for us: 1 billion m natural gas = 0.9 MTOE = 36 Trillion Btu = 38 Trillion kJ

Sources of data and forecasts


In this chapter we will use often data of IEA outlook 2008 and 2009. This is not necessarily the outlook we prefer but it helps to put historic trends in perspective. The IEA outlook is based on many assumptions. Important assumptions are a real oil price of 100 $/bbl in 2010 and 122$/bbl in 2030 as well as an economic growth in the world of 3.3% per year until 2030. The relative price of gas compared to oil products is kept constant in the IEA outlook 2008. This is a working assumption and not a market equilibrium. We will also use the BP statistical review and outlook 2010.

3. Main uses, consumers, producers and trade flows


Main uses
Manufactured gas (on the basis of coal) was initially mainly used for lighting and cooking in cities and in some industrial processes. Gas has not really a captive market. With the arrival of natural gas in the EU (much earlier in the US), gas is used for cooking, home heating, industrial heat, chemical feedstock and power generation. In these different applications, the substitutes differ as shown in table 1. At present natural gas is only rarely used as energy source for transport. In some countries (Italy) there is a small fleet of natural gas cars and in some cities, busses and special purpose vehicles are adapted to use natural gas mainly because of environmental reasons. Gas can be used in gasoline and diesel engines when an appropriate tank for compressed natural gas is build into the vehicle (cfr. LPG vehicles) and when there is a distribution network. In a few countries like Italy there is significant share of vehicles running on natural gas. In several cities

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

busses run on natural gas as this reduces the emission of small particles. Natural gas will probably first enter the transport market via use for busses and trucks. An other option is the conversion to methanol that can be used by gasoline engines (MIT,2010). In Belgium, residential and tertiary use (cooking, home heating) accounts for 1/3 of natural gas consumption, industrial use and power generation each account also for 1/3 of total use. Use of gas Cooking Home heating Chemical feedstock Industrial generation Main substitutes Electricity Gasoil, previously coal furnaces Naphtha

heat Fuel oil, coal in the past

Power generation Transport

Coal, nuclear, heavy fuel oil Oil products

Table 1 Main substitutes for natural gas Figure 1 shows that the consumption of natural gas has been growing continuously in almost the whole world. The transport of gas requires a specific distribution network and is therefore more costly than the transport of oil and coal. For this reason, natural gas consumption is stronger in regions that had early and cheap access to natural gas (US). Most growth is expected in the Middle East and in Asia. In the Middle East producers avoid the costs of gas transportation by producing chemicals at home and using the gas for energy purposes so that more oil can be exported. In Asia, the natural gas is a clean substitute for coal in cities and industries.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Figure 1

Main producers
Figure 2 shows that the US production is relying more and more on unconventional gas. Europe is more and more dependent on pipeline imports (Russia) and LNG imports from North Africa and Middle East. China will rely more and more on unconventional gas (shale gas, Coal Bed Methane) and also syngas produced from coal.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Figure 2 The production of unconventional gas has become interesting by the higher prices and the development of better techniques.

Trade flows
Gas can be transported by pipeline and by LNG tanker. By pipeline for distances of up to 5000km in pipes of up to 1.5 m diameter and at pressure of 70 bar. This means an average speed of 30km/h. Since the 70 ties LNG transport is developing and is becoming more interesting for longer distances. LNG also offers more flexibility to the exporter and to the importer. The exporter can more easily chose other customers and vice versa for the customer who is less dependent on his pipeline 2 . Intercontinental transport requires in general LNG transport (except Algeria to EU). The next Figure gives possible intercontinental trade flows for 2015 and 2030 compared to 2007. As can be seen, most flows increase. The EU is importing much more from Russia and the Middle East (Qatar). Imports by

See Van Herterijck (2007) for a more technical description of gas transport and handling.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

North America are expected to decrease because of the increased (unconventional) gas production in the US and Canada

Figure 3 Intercontinental flows of natural gas (source IEA outlook 2009) The main exporters of natural gas via LNG are Qatar, Algeria and Indonesia. Where Indonesia is mainly delivering to the Asian market. Algeria is mainly delivering to Europe and where Qatar delivers to Europe and Asia. Russia exports most of its gas via pipelines but is also entering the LNG market. The next two figures report on LNG terminal extensions.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

European LNG Terminals


OXFORD INSTITUTE FOR ENERGY STUDIES

22

Source: J.Stern (OIES)

Atlantic Basin LNG Terminals


OXFORD INSTITUTE FOR ENERGY STUDIES

Source: Suez

24

Source: J.Stern (OIES)

4. How much gas is there?


We know that for any resource, the reserves depend on two factors: the market price and the degree of confidence one has in the estimates (Cfr

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 2). It is important to make a distinction between conventional gas and non conventional gas. The next figure (IEA 2009) ranks the different types of gas and their volume for the world. A distinction (IEA WEO 2009) is made between: - conventional gas (estimate of current reserves at present prices and costs) According to the IEA outlook, conventional resources of gas are of the same order of magnitude as those for oil.- tight gas: is a resource that can not be profitable developed with vertical wells due to low flow rates (low permeability of the rocks) ; this resource can be exploited using hydraulically fracturing (or cracking open) in order to release the gas. The fracturing is done by pumping into the well water, chemicals and sand at high pressurethis type of gas is being produced since many years in the US and Canada - shale gas: rock formations that are rich in organic matter and are both source and storage of the gas. The exploitation of this resource requires opening the rock formations and requires more equipment and lots of water to be pumped in the reservoirs. It requires also solutions for the water that is produced together with the gas. - coal bed methane (CBM): is the natural gas contained in coal beds that are too deep or too narrow to be exploited as coal supply the production requires again a lot of equipment and water to extract the gas from the coal beds. The production is growing rapidly in the US 3 . This production can in certain circumstances be combined with the storage of CO2 because fractures in the structure of coal can absorb twice as much CO2 as the methane it initially contained. - sour gas: gas that contains a lot of H2S and needs extra processing before it can be used often associated to oil wells - hydrates: These are crystal-like solids that are formed when methane is mixed with water at low temperature and moderate pressure. They are found offshore and in Arctic regions. The estimates of reserves vary between 2500
3 There have been experiments to produce coalbed methane in the Walloon region and in the Campine region but the productivity was insufficient.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

and 20 000 tcm. These are abundant reserves but they will be costly to produce.

This figure (source IEA 2009) combines quantity of reserves and marginal costs. The right had side of the figure gives an idea of the transport costs that need to be added for pipeline and LNG transport. Aguileras et al (2009) pay more attention to the regions that have in the past not yet explored thoroughly and this results in reserve estimates with an order of magnitude 5 to 10 times higher than the IEA estimates. The EIA (2011) produced recently a new assessment of the non-conventional shale gas reserves for some regions (see table). We see that in the EU, Poland and France have considerable shale gas reserves. The overall shale oil reserves for the regions studied are 6 times as large as the conventional gas reserves. The first problem in the exploitation of the non conventional gas reserves is that one needs a lot of land as one needs to drill a lot of wells and equipment. There is also the environmental problem associated to the use of large quantities of water needed for the exploitation. Finally the use of gas itself produces less carbon per unit of energy but the production of non conventional gas is energy intensive and may compensate this advantage of natural gas.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

10

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

11

5. Economics of the gas market


The gas industry is characterised by high transport costs and a transport and distribution network that is dedicated to a particular production site and or customers. This explains how the industry developed. We focus here mainly on Europe.

High transport costs


Whether one transports gas by pipeline or by LNG tanker, transport operations require always a large upfront investment. One can only start production once the infrastructure is fully in place. Transport by pipeline is also characterised by economies of scale: the volume that can be transported is more than proportional to the diameter while the costs are also less than proportional to the diameter. Increasing capacity by 10% generates a cost increase of only 6% 4 . In the transport by LNG, there are economies of scale in the liquefaction and regasification plant and in the ships used. Ships have a limited capacity per unit (125-170000 m) the number of ships needed depends on the distance.

The hold-up problem for specific transport infrastructure


The pipeline constructed to connect one production site with a customer is often very specific: example of Seapipe that connects a Norwegian Gas field to Zeebrugge. In the past this pipe was only meant to supply the Belgian gas company. It is an investment specific for that link without any other possible use. Costly investments that are specific to serve one customer are at the origin of the so-called hold-up problem. This is the risk that the customer, once the supplier has built the specific transport infrastructure, wants to renegotiate the contract. As the infrastructure can not be used for other purposes, the customer can threaten to pay a much lower price than the price originally agreed. The supplier has no choice but to accept the new deal. One can try to enforce the original contract but the enforcement of international commercial
4

See Van Herterijck, op cit. p64-67

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

12

contracts is weak. The main enforcement mechanism is reputation: a customer that does not comply will have problems to obtain new long term contracts. Another solution that is often used is to ask the customer to participate in the transport investment. This solution was common in Western Europe.

Price discrimination
Whenever there is one importer who controls the transport network, this importer can use different prices for the same good delivered to different customers. In this way the importer can maximize his profits. The following graph shows how an importer facing two different clients (industry and residential) can increase his profits by selling at higher prices to the residential sector (higher willingness to pay and lower elasticity of demand) than to the industrial customers (more substitutes available so higher elasticity of demand). In Belgium Distrigas had the legal monopoly for importing gas and sold at different prices according to the type of industrial sector: sectors that could not easily substitute gas paid a higher price. Nowadays such a practice would no longer be allowed and would no longer be possible because Distrigas has no longer the monopoly of gas trading.
Prijs, MK

Vraag residentiele sector Pres

Prijsdiscriminatie

Pce MK (invoer)

Vraag centrales

q*re

q*cen
MRre

MRce

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

13

Netback pricing of natural gas and take or pay contracts


An importer can only guarantee to sell a given volume of gas if the price is competitive on his market. When the prices of substitutes vary, one needs a system of price indexation to guarantee the sales. In the gas industry, the importer usually also controlled the transmission network so that he can discriminate prices. Many import contracts used the netback technique to specify the import price of gas. The principle is explained in the following figure where gas is sold to two types of uses: industrial consumers whose alternative fuel is HFO and residential heating customers whose alternative is gasoil. The maximal import price of gas for industrial use is then the consumer price of HFO (containing often a specific tax on sulphur content) minus the transmission cost of gas. The maximal import price of gas for residential use is then the consumer price of gasoil (containing often also a specific tax on oil products) minus the transmission cost and minus the distribution cost. The import price of gas is then a weighted average of the two maximal import prices where the weight equals the share of both types of customers. This is only possible if the importer can price discriminate on his internal market. The figure makes clear that gas exporters and sellers were very much in favour of an environmental tax on oil products. With this guarantee on competitiveness of the imported gas, importers could accept take or pay clauses that force an importer to import a given quantity with a take or play clause: even if not imported it has to be paid.
Consumer price Gasoil heating
tax

Price/GJ

Maximum Consumer price Residential heating Maximum Consumer price Gas to industry
Transmission cost+ margin

Consumer price HFO


tax

Distribution Cost+margin

Transmission Cost+margin

Maximal Import Price cif

Maximal Import Price cif

Netback price principle to determine GAS import price = weighted sum of consumer prices of substitutes costs of transmission and distribution

Figure: Netback price principle

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

14

Take or pay clauses were interesting for the exporters because this allows to guarantee a given volume of sales and this helped to use optimally the production and transport capacity..

A Cournot equilibrium
In the European (and Asian) natural gas market there used to be a limited number of suppliers: Norway, Netherlands, Algeria, Russia.for the same product (a GJ of natural gas). How much will each be able to sell? The equilibrium concept that is often used in economics is a Cournot equilibrium. In a Cournot equilibrium every supplier sets the quantity he want to sell, given the quantity that is decided by the other suppliers. He sets this quantity as monopolist on the remaining market. An equilibrium is reached when all quantities produced are mutual best replies: when the quantity sold by him is the best answer to the quantity chosen by the other suppliers and vice versa. This is a non competitive equilibrium. Take an example 5 with two suppliers 1 and 2. In the next figure we determine in a first step the optimal quantity to supply to one given market for supplier 1 for different quantities supplied by firm 2 (0,50,75). For each of the quantities produced by firm 2, firm 1 is a monopolist for the remaining demand and chooses the optimal quantity by equalising marginal revenue and marginal cost. His optimal production will be (50, 25, 12.5). This information can be summarised under the form of a reaction function: what is the optimal production of firm 1 given a production level of firm 2.

Example taken from Pindyck & Rubinfeld

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

15

Cournot equilibrium: step 1


P1
D 1 (0)
If Firm 1 thinks Firm 2 w ill produce nothing, its demand curve, D 1 (0), is the market demand curve. If Firm 1 thinks Firm 2 w ill produce 50 units, its demand curve is shifted to the left by this amount. If Firm 1 thinks Firm 2 w ill produce 75 units, its demand curve is shifted to the left by this amount.

D 1 (75) MR 1 (75)

MR 1 (0)

MC 1 MR 1 (50) 12.5 25
CENTRUM VOOR ECONOMISCHE STUDIEN

D 1 (50) 50

W hat is the output of Firm 1 if Firm 2 produces 100 units?

Q1
KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

Cournot equilibrium step 2


Q1 100
Firm 1s reaction curve shows how much it will produce as a function ofof how much will produce as a function how much it thinks Firm 2 willwill produce. The xs it thinks Firm 2 produce. correspond to the previous model. Firm 2s reaction curve shows how much it will produce as a function of how much it thinks Firm 1 will produce. Firm 2s Reaction Curve Q*2(Q1) In Cournot equilibrium, each firm correctly assumes how much its competitors will produce and thereby maximize its own profits.

75

50 x

Cournot Equilibrium

25

Firm 1s Reaction Curve Q*1(Q2)

25
CENTRUM VOOR ECONOMISCHE STUDIEN

50

75

100

Q2
KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

The second step consists in setting the two reaction functions together and to find a Cournot equilibrium: what are the mutual best reply production levels: here (25,60). The relative production of the two producers will be a function only of their marginal costs because they fact the same total market demand. A lower marginal cost for firm 1 generates a larger market share in equilibrium.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

16

The Cournot equilibrium is often used to study the natural gas market because supply requires important production and transport investment so that suppliers decide on quantities. An alternative equilibrium concept is the Bertrand equilibrium where production can be easily varied and where firms set prices instead of quantities. The best price a firm can set, given the price set by his competitor is to undercut the price by , the equilibrium will be that the price will be equal to the marginal cost of the supplier with the second lowest cost minus . In general the Bertrand equilibrium results in prices much closer to the marginal cost than the Cournot equilibrium. Exercise 6 : assume 2 producers (Norway and Russia) want to supply the German gas market. The inverse demand function of the German gas market is P=100-0.5(q1+q2) where q1, q2 represent the supply by Norway and Russia. The total costs of Norway are 0.5 (q1) and for Russia 5 q2. Find the perfectly competitive equilibrium, the Cournot equilibrium and the Bertrand equilibrium.

6. History of the gas market in Western Europe

Because gas transport is expensive and resource availability differs by continents, market development has been very different in Europe, Japan and the US. Here we focus on Western Europe and more particularly also on Belgium. Before the large gas reserves of Slochteren (NL) were discovered in 1961, natural gas was only used in a few countries (Italy, France and Austria). The discovery of the Dutch gas was the real take off of the natural gas market in Europe. We distinguish 2 periods in this history: before 1973, the period 742004 and after 2004.

Before 1973

Example taken from Dahl, p268 and served as exam question in the past.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

17

There were massive amounts of gas available in the Netherlands. In order to sell the gas one needed large pipeline investments and an extensive distribution network. Once the main import pipelines are constructed one starts by supplying first a few big customers as this allows to sell a large volume without large additional transport investments. Gas substituted oil and coal in power stations. The next step is to connect smaller industrial customers and finally smaller consumers. All European countries opted for an import monopoly with sometimes a partly private ownership (The Belgian Distrigaz was 50% public, and 50% private). The monopoly allowed to benefit from economics of scale in transport and to maximize profits. The profits were important to guarantee a continuous investment in transport networks.
The West-European Gasmarket before liberatisation Consumers
National Transport + strorageg

Importers (countries)
International transport

Exporters (countries)
Netherlands Norway UK.

Power producers. Industry


houeholds Small firms

Frankrijk Duitsland Belgi Andere

Distribution companies

Russia Algeria

CENTRUM VOOR ECONOMISCHE STUDIEN

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

One had double monopolies: each exporter was state controlled, together they form an oligopoly (Cournot) and each of the importers had a monopoly in their own country. This situation lasts until 2000-2004. The national monopolists used their market power to discriminate prices in function of the willingness to pay of the sellers. Power producers that had

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

18

cheap coal or HFO as alternative could bargain a better price than industrial customers that have gasoil as alternative. This is also called Ramsey pricing. Natural gas consumption did grow very rapidly before 1973.

From 1974-2004
The gas demand was growing rapidly because the price of a close substitute (oil products) increased steeply in 73 and 79-80. Initially, prices of gas were not fully indexed on the price of oil products so that demand increased quickly. One needed additional suppliers. They were found in Norway (Ekofisk, Troll, Sleipner fields), in Algeria and in Russia. The high growth in demand led sometimes to unrealistic projected growth rates and bad contracts. The best known example are the first contracts with Algeria. The contracts stipulated sometimes prices for gas fob Algeria that were at the level of the prices of oil substitutes neglecting that the transport and distribution of gas was much more costly than oil. In addition, there was a pay or take clause in the contract. This resulted in financial problems for the importers. In the case of Belgium, Distrigaz was almost bankrupt and went for a long international arbitrage procedure.
Gas price (EU, cif) / Crude oil price (OECD, cif)
1,6 1,4 1,2 1,0 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 0,0 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Ye a r s 19 8 4 - 2 0 0 7

Distrigaz tried to minimize the losses by price discrimination and selling surpluses at discount prices, if necessary abroad.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

19

A large Take-or-Pay Contract with a too high price


Optimal solution: sell x1 on home market and xa-xe abroad
total quantity to import

Price

ca p1 cn

Price Algerian gas

Price Dutch gas

Demand Pe x1 MR
CENTRUM VOOR ECONOMISCHE STUDIEN

Export on spot market


Quantity

Xa

KATHOLIEKE UNIVERSITEIT LEUVEN

This figure illustrates the best solution if there is a very large quantity to be imported at a too large price. If the importer sells at the import price of Algerian gas (ca), his sales will be limited and he has to sell the rest as exports on spot market. The best the importer can do is to charge the monopoly price p1 where the Marginal Revenue equals the Marginal Cost and this is here the price on spot export markets. Most importers were able to discriminate between all types of clients so that they sold xa at prices that approximate the demand function. As most trade was between public exporting and public importing companies, the import contracts were not always economically justified and were used in order to promote other goals: employment, foreign affairs etc.. One of the complicating factors was the strongly fluctuating oil price. As gas prices were indexed on oil prices with a delay of some 6 months, gas was very favourably priced when oil prices were rising and vice versa when oil prices were decreasing.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

20

Another factor that grew in importance was storage. As gas was imported from more and more remote areas, the trade off between storage and transport capacity changed. Importers had the choice between building minimal storage capacity and a transport capacity in function of the winter peak of demand or a larger storage and smaller transport capacity. There was also a continuous attention for environmental regulations and taxes imposed on oil products and coal as these were important for the competitive position of gas. A final important element in terms of demand is the growing use of gas in power plants: in the new combined cycle gas plants their efficiency is 55-60% instead of some 40% in conventional plants. This is coupled in some countries with a nuclear phase out and a concern for CO2 emissions that rules out coal as alternative fuel for power plants.
Gas consumption in Belgium and Luxembourg
18,0 16,0 Gas consumption in bcm per year 14,0 12,0 10,0 8,0 6,0 4,0 2,0 0,0
19 67 19 69 19 71 19 73 19 75 19 77 19 79 19 81 19 83 19 85 19 87 19 89 19 91 19 93 19 95 19 97 19 99 20 01 20 03 20 05 20 07

Years 1967-2007

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

21

From 2004 onwards


From 2000 onwards the EC requires the liberalisation of the gas trade. This means that large consumers can negotiate their own import contract and the transport company has to grant access to parties that want to use the transport network. We will see in the next section what could be the effects of this liberalisation. One of the puzzles in the EU gas market is the continued reliance on oil price indexation in gas contracts. The next table shows that in a mature gas market like the US market, prices are more indexed on gas spot markets.

A second important development is the growing dependence on non-EU sources of supply. Russia, North Africa and Middle East will be responsible for 60% and more of our supplies from 2020 onwards. This raises serious concerns. The IEA expects an increase of gas consumption in the European union from 305 bcm in 2006 to 580 bcm in 2030. Its import dependence will rise from 57% now to 86% in 2030. Most of the increase is met by Russia, Africa and Middle East. We discuss the need for more gas imports and the supply of Russian gas more in detail in section 8.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

22

7. Modelling the European gas market


In this section we use the model of Boots et al (2004) 7 to study how prices are set after the liberalisation and more particularly, what is the effect of the number of traders on consumer prices. We have chosen this model because it is fully documented and describes the European gas market. Many other models of the gas market use a similar approach.

Structure of the model


The model represents the competition at two levels: first between producers (exporters) to one country and second, within one country between different traders for the same consumers. The following figure represents this dual structure.

Structure of the EU gas model


UPSTREAM producer Transport costs DOWNSTREAM Distribution costs Country A Household A Industry A Generation A producer trader Country B trader

Cournot behaviour but each Is Stackelberg leader wrt traders (they take the reaction of traders into account) Gazprom Statoil

Cournot behaviour in end-use Markets and Possible price discrimination (1 and sometimes 3 Traders per country)

Demand Functions Per category and per country

The European consumer countries are numbered n 1,..., N . In each country, there are multiple segments (household, industry, power generation), numbered g 1,..., G . As a result, there are N G different markets, each with its own end-user price.
7

Boots M., Rijkens F., Hobbs B., trading in the downstream European gas market, Energy Journal, vol 25, n3

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

23

In the "upstream part", the producers (indexed i 1,..., I ) play a Cournot game: each takes the sales of the other exporters to a particular market as given and optimizes his profits by selecting a quantity for that market. The producers are only concerned about the border price for each country and each segment the price they receive for the gas at the border where it enters the country and do not get involved in the distribution of gas within the country. Within each country (the "downstream part") there can be 1 or 2 traders, e.g. in Belgium the base case of the model assumes 1 trader, Distrigaz. Traders are numbered r 1,..., R . A key feature of the model is that it allows to increase the number of traders beyond the actual number, to analyze the effects of increasing competition. In each segment, the traders play a Cournot game. If there is only one trader in a given country, then this means a monopoly game. The model assumes that producers have a Stackelberg leadership position vis-vis traders: producers make their decisions before traders do. When making their decisions, producers already anticipate how their decisions will influence the decisions of the traders. Therefore, in this text, we will first study the behaviour of the traders. Using that information, we will then study the behaviour of the producers.

Downstream: behaviour of traders


The model assumes that each market ng has a linear demand curve, i.e.: png ng ng yrng
r

(1)

where yrng is the quantity supplied by trader r to market ng , and png is the resulting market price (end-user price) in market ng . Note that ng 0 . Each trader r sets his quantity yrng to maximize profits:

r max ( png bpng dcng ) yrng


yrng n, g

(2)

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

24

Traders decide after producers have decided, and so they take the border prices bpng for each individual country and segment as given. dcng is the transmission tariff for country n and segment g , and is also taken as given. The first-order conditions for yrng to yield the optimal r , are: 8
r png (bpng dcng ) png yrng 0 yrng
(3)

There are two possible cases: perfect competition and Cournot competition (see section 5 of this chapter). Under perfect competition, a trader cannot influence the market price by his actions, i.e., the market price is taken as given, hence for each individual trader, we have png 0 . Therefore the first-order condition (3) reduces to:

png bpng dcng

(4)

In words: under perfect competition, price equals marginal cost of supply. Combining (4) with the demand curve (1), we find:

bpng ng ng yrng
r

with

ng ng dcng

(5)

from which we can derive the total quantity supplied by all traders as a function of border price (or vice versa). Under Cournot competition, a trader takes into account that his quantity decision influences the market price, and as a result a trader may withhold volumes in order to drive up the market price ( png ng 0 ). In the Cournot equilibrium each trader maximizes his profits while taking the quantities supplied by other traders as given. Assuming that all traders are identical, we find that:

Note that the conditions shown in Boots et al. (2004) are slightly more complicated in order to take into account the

constraint

yrng 0 . In this text we ignore this point for the sake of simplicity.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost


bpng ng ng yrng ng yrng dcng
r

25

ng ng yrng
r

with

ng ng

Rng 1 R ng

(6)

from which, again, we can derive the total quantity supplied by all traders as a function of border price (or vice versa). This expression is similar to equation (5), but has a steeper slope, reflecting the fact that traders take a monopoly/oligopoly margin. The following figure shows how the consumer demand curve (1) is transformed into curves (5) and (6).

Behaviour traders (downstream)


Price (png, bpng) Demand function of consumers ng (equation (1))

Perceived demand function for producers if 1 monopolist trader (equation (6) with R=1)

Perceived demand function for producers if perfect competition in trading (equation (5)) Quantity ( yrng)

Note that equations (5) and (6) are the demand functions perceived by the upstream producers: the curves show which quantities the traders (in total) will buy from producers as a function of border prices charged by producers. Conversely, they show how border prices will change as producers change the quantities exported to different markets.

Upstream: behaviour of producers


Given the perceived demand functions (5) and (6), the producers set quantities (and hence, prices) in each market. The model assumes Cournot

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

26

competition between producers: each producer sets a production quantity (i.e., export quantity) to maximize profits, taking the quantities set by others as given. Practically, for a producer, setting a certain production quantity corresponds to investing in a certain amount of developments of gas fields. The model assumes that producers' marginal production costs are increasing. Furthermore, the long distance transmission costs to transport gas from the gas fields to the borders of the consuming countries are assumed to be constant per km per cubic meter of gas. No transmission capacity limits are assumed. Producers maximize profits:

i max bpng tin qing ci qing


qing

(7)

n, g n, g max ng ng q jng tin qing ci qing qing n, g j n, g

where qing is the quantity supplied by producer i to market ng , and tin is the transmission cost from producer i to country n . The function c() represents the total production cost as a function of the quantity produced. In case the traders are perfectly competitive, ng needs to be replaced by ng . The firstorder condition for maximizing producer i 's profit, is: 9
i ng ng q jng ng qing tin ci 0 qing j
(8)

Equation (8) allows us to compute all quantities set by producers, and hence the resulting border prices. We can extend the previous figure to show the quantity decision by a monopolistic producer graphically.

The same observation as in footnote 8 applies here.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

27

Resulting equilibrium: illustration for 1 producer and 1 or R traders (R, i.e. perfect competition)
Price (png, bpng) If only 1 trader per country: double monopoly margins: margin producer (lower part) + margin importer (upper part) If perfect competition in trade: only monopoly margin for producer

pngdcng>bpng (if 1 trader) pngdcng=bpng (if perfect competition in trade)

c + tin (marginal production & transmission cost)

MR curve for 1 MR curve for 1 producer, if only 1 producer, if perfect trader per country competition in trade

Quantity ( yrng , qing)

If producers are a monopoly/oligopoly and traders are perfectly competitive, consumer prices are higher than marginal costs, due to the margin taken by the producers. However, if traders are a monopoly/oligopoly instead of a perfectly competitive industry, consumer prices are even higher, because in that case both producers and traders take a margin. This phenomenon is called double marginalisation: each non-competitive stage of the production process adds a monopoly margin, thereby disregarding the effect of its margin increase on the profit loss of the next stage. In such circumstances, vertical integration of traders and producers would reduce prices, increase consumer welfare and increase total profits (producers + traders). Jean Tirole launched in 1997 the famous phrase: "What is worse than a monopoly? A chain of monopolies."

Empirical specification
In principle, the equations derived above enable us to compute all quantities, end-user prices and border prices, as soon as the demand curves (parameters ng and ng ), tariffs dcng , transmission costs tin and marginal production costs ci are known. Boots et al. (2004) estimate these parameters based on actual market circumstances.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

28

First of all, the consumer demand curves can be estimated using the actual volumes, prices, and elasticity per segment. The following table shows the data that is used. Note in particular the large price discrimination between different segments in Belgium.

The following table shows assumptions about production costs, which are based on technical estimates. Producers for which i 0 , have a constant marginal cost of production i up to the point where capacity limits are reached.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

29

Scenarios and results


Boots et al. (2004) study 4 scenarios, as shown in the following table.

"No price discrimination" refers to a situation in which producers cannot discriminate between border prices for different segments, i.e., an additional constraint is applied: bpng bpn , g . The following table shows the resulting prices in each of the scenarios. Each cell in the table gives the end-user price and the border price for a given segment in a given country.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

30

The first column ("No discr. Benchmark") represents prices if there is perfect competition among traders and among producers. It is interesting to compare this "benchmark" column with the actual prices in 1995, as shown in Table 1. For example, in Germany, the actual 1995 prices are much higher than the "benchmark" prices: in reality, there is no competition and both traders and producers have high margins. On the other hand, in the UK, the simulated "benchmark" prices are close to the real prices, showing that the market is already quite competitive.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

31

The second column, compared to the first column, shows the effect of oligopolistic behaviour of gas producers. The third column shows the extra effect of allowing border price discrimination: introducing border price discrimination leads to much higher price differences between households and power generators. For most countries, actual 1995 prices from Table 1 are close to the scenarios in the second and third columns: oligopolistic producers and competitive traders. The fourth and fifth column show the effect of oligopolistic behaviour of traders. Profits of traders are zero when they are perfectly competitive, but very large when they have a monopoly/oligopoly. Producer profits are largest when traders are competitive and border price discrimination is possible. The following figure summarizes the welfare effects of the different scenarios.

As mentioned before, the model also enables us to vary the number of traders. The following table shows the prices that result when the number of traders in each market is increased to 3 and then to 9.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

32

The results need to be compared with the fourth column in Table 4. An increase of the number of traders leads to a decrease of traders' profits, an increase of producers' profits, an increase in consumer surplus, and in total an increase of social welfare. If the number of traders were to go to infinity, the results would converge to the second column of Table 4.

8. The security of European gas supply


Introduction
Europes dependence on Russian gas imports has been the subject of increasing political concern after gas conflicts between Russia and Ukraine in 2006 and 2009. We distinguish three issues. A first issue is that some of the countries through which Russian Gas is exported to the EU (Belarus, Ukraine) make use of their monopoly position to get better deals (less expensive gas) with Russia. The second issue is the future supply of natural gas to the EU: where it will come from and at what conditions. The third issue is that Russia itself can threaten to interrupt gas supply to EU or charge higher prices.

Transporting Russian gas to Europe

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

33

The next map shows that most Russian gas is exported to the EU via Belarus and via Ukraine. As former allies of Russia they received Russian gas on better terms than the rest of EU. When Russia wanted to raise their price to EU levels, they both have interrupted the gas supply to EU for some time. This makes both Russia and the EU vulnerable to threats by the transit countries.

Russian Pipelines via Ukraine and Belarus


OXFORD INSTITUTE FOR ENERGY STUDIES

10

Source: Stern J. (2007)

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

34

Blue Stream/South Stream Gas Pipelines


OXFORD INSTITUTE FOR ENERGY STUDIES

12

Source: Stern J. (2007)


Russia and some of the EU countries have reacted to this threat by building bypasses that diminish the bargaining power of the two main transit countries. This is the Nordstream pipeline (connecting Russia and Germany via Baltic sea pipeline) and the project to build a Southstream pipeline (connecting Russia with Bulgaria via Black Sea or via Turkey). The purpose of these 2 pipelines is different from still another project in the South-East of Europe and Turkey, the Nabucco project. In this EU backed project the idea is to connect to an alternative source of supply in the Caspian area. The main problem here will be to have the cooperation of Turkey and of the local producers in the Caspian area.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost


Nabucco: a Caspian/Middle East Pipeline Nabucco:
O F R IN T U EF RE E G S U IE X O D S IT T O N R Y T D S

35

Source: OMV

This is the favourite project of all EU politicians and most media commentators

20

So the purpose of Nabucco is to rely less on Russian gas and not to avoid dependency on some transit countries.

Where could the EU get its gas supply in the future?


The IEA (WEO 2009) looked into the different options to supply natural gas to the EU in the future. The EU has to get its gas from Russia, Middle East (Qatar) of Africa (mainly Algeria). The development of non conventional gas in the US means that these exporters or more interested to export to the EU. The EU is the major customer of Russian gas. The figure is also interesting to show how the margins of exporters become much smaller when they need to supply to remote customers. The nearby suppliers enjoy a rent.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

36

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

37

How to deal with unreliable Russian gas supply?


Introduction Morbee & Proost (2010) assess the potential impact of Russian unreliability on the European gas market, and how it affects European gas import strategy. They study to what extent Europe should invest in strategic gas storage capacity to mitigate the effects of possible Russian unreliability. The European gas import market is described by differentiated competition between Russia and a more reliable competitive fringe of other exporters. The results show that Russian contract volumes and prices decline significantly as a function of unreliability, so that not only Europe but also

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

38

Russia suffers if Russias unreliability increases. For Europe, buying gas from more reliable suppliers at a price premium turns out to be generally more attractive than building strategic gas storage capacity. In recent years, security of gas supply has been high on the political agenda in Europe. Gas import dependence of the European OECD bloc will increase from 45% in 2006 to 69% in 2030, according to the IEA (2008) Reference Scenario. Russia plays a crucial role, given that it already supplies more than half of Europes gas imports and that it has the largest proven natural gas.
Europe needs to import a large share of it gas consumption, especially from Russia Billion cubic meters (bcm), 2005
471 88
UK x

Focus of this paper Share of EU-25 consumption (Percent)

63
Netherlands

200 49
Other 20

EU-25 production

79 Total Exports* EU-25 Norway production production

212 122
Russia (pipeline)

38
Algeria (pipeline)

53
Other**

EU-25 consumption

Total nonEuropean gas imports 19 13 10 42 4 17 45 26

100

11

* Includes exports to countries such as Switzerland, plus other discrepancies between import and consumption ** Mainly LNG from Africa (including Algeria) Source: BP Statistiscal Review of World Energy, 2006

We study long-term gas contracting in a non-cooperative setting, using a partial equilibrium model of the European gas market, with differentiated competition between one potentially unreliable dominant firm (Russia) and a reliable competitive fringe of other non-European import suppliers. Russias potential unreliability is modeled by assuming that there is a probability d that Russia does not comply with the long-term contracts it has

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

39

signed: with probability , Russia defaults and withholds supply to increase its price to monopolistic levels for a duration of four months. The model Europe is modeled as a large number of uncoordinated gas consumers and domestic gas producers, with an overarching government that can decide to invest public funds in gas storage capacity. We assume Europe is a pricetaker with a linear long-run inverse demand curve for gas:

p(q) q
European domestic producers supply an exogenous and fixed quantity qD , and the remaining excess demand q qD needs to be satisfied by nonEuropean imports. Short-run demand is also linear, but with a steeper slope

pSR (q ) p * SR (q q*)
with p*, q* representing the long-run equilibrium. We assume that decisions on long-term gas import contracts and publicly financed strategic storage capacity investments are based on a combination of the interests of importers, end-consumers, domestic producers and taxpayers. We therefore assume that Europe maximizes the expected total European surplus E[S] :
Max E S with S=CS+ D G

where CS is the consumer surplus, D represents the profits of domestic producers, and G is the public expenditure on gas storage capacity investments. _G represents the interests of the recipients of marginal

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

40

expenditures out of general government revenue. Note that this equation assumes risk-neutrality. Excess demand needs to be satisfied by signing long-term import contracts with non-European import suppliers. We assume that the non-European import suppliers have a dominant firm competitive fringe structure. Russia is the dominant firm and the other non-European gas import suppliers are grouped together as the competitive fringe. Russia is modeled as a monolithic entity, i.e. the Russian state is not distinguished from the gas exporter Gazprom. Russia is assumed to be a risk neutral profit maximizer. Russia is modeled to be unreliable: once the long-term contracts have been signed, there is a probability that Russia temporarily does not comply with its supply commitments, i.e. Russia defaults. Conversely, there is a probability (1-) that Russia complies with its long-term contracts during the entire period. All participants know the parameter upfront. Russias long run marginal costs of production are assumed constant at cR . The competitive fringe is a diversified set of current or potential future nonEuropean gas import suppliers, including both pipeline and LNG supplies. Therefore, we assume that as a group the competitive fringe is reliable: even if Russia defaults, the competitive fringe delivers the originally promised contract quantity q0 at the originally promised contract price p0 . This requires two assumptions. First, we assume that the long-term gas import contracts between Europe and the competitive fringe are not indexed on any gas spot market price, which would rise sharply in the event of Russian default. In practice, this condition is fulfilled since most current long-term gas import contracts contain little or no indexation on gas spot market prices. Second, we assume that the competitive fringe players do not deviate from their contracts. This is a major assumption, which can be justified by the difference in scale between Russia and each of the other non-

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

41

European import suppliers. Each of the other non-European import suppliers has much less incentive to be unreliable because the market impact of each of them is much smaller. In addition, a supplier who is perceived as unreliable could face the threat of being replaced by another supplier in the long term. Russia, on the other hand, is hard to replace completely in the long term, even if it behaves unreliably. The interaction between Europe, Russia and the competitive fringe, is modeled as a game in three stages. Figure 1 explains the different stages of the game. In a nutshell: in Stage 1, Europe decides how much to invest in strategic gas storage capacity; Stage 2 is the stage in which Europe signs long-term gas import contracts with Russia and the competitive fringe; Stage 3 consists in the execution of the long-term gas import contracts, in which Russia may or may not comply with the long-term contracts it has signed. We represent the imported gas quantities by qR ,1 (Russia complies with long-term contracts), qR ,2 (Russia defaults) and

q0

(competitive

fringe).

The

corresponding prices are denoted pR ,1 , pR ,2 and p0 .

Before describing each of the stages in detail, it is important to note that the stochastic outcome of Stage 3 influences the strategic interaction in Stage 2, because Europe and Russia factor the expected value of Stage-3 pay-offs into their decisions in Stage 2. In Stage 3, European surplus is either S=S1 or S=S2 depending on whether Russia complies with its long-term contracts or

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost


not.

42

In Stage 2, Europe therefore tries to maximize the expected surplus E[S]. This maximization problem can be translated into demand functions for Russian and other long-term gas import contracts, by finding for given longterm gas contract prices the optimal long-term gas contract quantities that maximize Europes expected surplus E[S] in Stage 3. As for Russia, its expected profits in Stage 3 are either R R ,1 or R R ,2 , depending on whether Russia complies with its long-term contracts or not. Therefore, in the dominant firm competitive fringe game in Stage 2, dominant firm Russia sets the optimal gas contract quantity to maximize its expected profits E R in Stage 3, taking into account the long-term gas import contract supply curve of the competitive fringe and Europes above-mentioned demand functions for Russian and other long-term gas import contracts. European demand for long-term gas import contracts will turn out to be differentiated between gas import contracts from Russia and gas import contracts from the

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

43

competitive fringe, because their effect in Stage 3 is different. The rest of this section describes the three stages in more detail. In Stage 1, Europe decides to foresee a quantity q (in bcm, i.e. billion cubic meters) of strategic gas storage capacity, to be used as a buffer in case of withholding of gas supply by Russia. Given the long lead times involved in the development of storage sites, this decision cannot be postponed until it is known whether Russia will comply with its contracts or not (i.e. it cannot wait until Stage 3). Furthermore, in our model, the storage capacity investment decision takes place before decisions are made regarding the amounts of long-term gas imports that are contracted from Russia and the competitive fringe (i.e. before Stage 2). The reason is that investment in storage capacity is a decision that Europe can make unilaterally. By making the storage capacity investment decision in a separate stage upfront (Stage 1), Europe gives its storage capacity investment decision an advantageous Stackelberg leadership position in the strategic game with its gas import suppliers. In making the decision about storage capacity investment, Europe takes into account the strategic behavior of Stage 2, and it has perfect and complete information to do so. In Stage 2 Europe signs long-term gas import contracts with Russia and with the competitive fringe. Our approach is non-cooperative, with Europe as a price-taker in a dominant firm competitive fringe model of the long-term gas import contract market. Russia, as the dominant firm, puts a quantity

qR ,1 (in bcm per year) on the European market, for which it receives a price pR ,1 (in per tcm). In making its decision, Russia already takes into account
the subsequent decision of the competitive fringe, who put a quantity q0 (in bcm per year) on the market, for which they receive a price p0 (in per tcm). The prices pR ,1 and p 0 are the response of the European inverse demand functions to the quantities qR ,1 and q0 . The quantity-price pairs ( qR ,1 , pR ,1 )

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

44

and ( q0 , p0 ) represent the long-term gas import contracts signed between Europe and Russia, and between Europe and the competitive fringe, respectively. Because of Russian unreliability, the prices pR ,1 and p0 do not need to be the same. Although there are separate inverse demand functions for Russian and other gas resulting from the behavior of importers the end-consumers face a single price for gas and cannot choose their own mix of reliable and non-reliable gas. There is a single end-consumer price in each of the two states of the world in Stage 3. Stage 3, the final stage of the game, is the execution of the long-term gas import contracts signed in Stage 2. Stage 3 is the stage that results in actual pay-offs for the participants to the game. We study one representative year: although the import contracts and storage capacity investment decisions are longterm decisions that will hold for multiple years, all volumes and monetary payoffs in Stage 3 are shown as annual amounts. In a representative year, there is a probability 1- that Russia honors its commitments, and effectively delivers qR ,1 at a price pR ,1 . This is Case 1 (Russia complies with long-term contracts). Figure 2 illustrates Case 1 graphically. qD is the gas supply from European domestic producers, which is assumed to be exogenous and fixed (inelastic). The shaded area, S1 , is the European surplus according to equation (3), but without taking storage capacity investment costs into account. End-consumers pay a single price corresponding to p* pR ,1 , p0 , such that demand at price p* is exactly equal to qD q0 qR ,1 . In a representative year, there is also a probability of default, in which case Russia withholds supply to maximize short-run profits. This is Case 2 (Russia defaults), which is depicted in Figure 3. Assuming that neither qD nor q0 can increase in the short run, Russia can set qR ,2 qR ,1 , for which it can command a price pR ,2 pR ,1 . Note that this price is derived from the short-run

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

45

demand curve. Europe responds by cutting consumption and using the maximum amount of stored gas, which is constrained by the storage capacity qS chosen in Stage 1. The storage capacity investment only covers the cost of the storage facility and the capital cost of the unused gas, but not the purchase price of the stored gas itself. The gas withdrawn from the storage will therefore need to be replaced for future crises, and we assume that this can be done at some point at a price equal to p0 . Effectively, the price of using gas from the storage is therefore p0 (in addition to storage capacity

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

46

costs, which are sunk). The competitive fringe always delivers q0 at price p0, whatever happens in Stage 3. As before, this does not mean that identical end-consumers would pay different prices in the event of Russian default. Since the marginal unit of gas import supply in the short run in case of Russian default has a cost pR ,2 (because only Russia could increase supply), the marginal price for end-consumers should correspond to pR ,2 . While this does create a rent from the fringe supply contracts equal to ( pR ,2 p0 )q0 , the rent is part of the European surplus. In total, the European surplus in case of Russian default is lower than S1 from Figure 2. Figure 3 shows S, the loss in European surplus due to Russian default. This loss is discussed in more detail in equation (8) in the next section. The three stages of the game represent three distinct decisions. We assume that this three-stage game is played once. In practice, the game is obviously repeated after a number of years, but because the lead times for gas projects are very long, we do not consider the repeated game. Finally, if Russia defaults (probability ), the assumption is that this happens only during a fraction s of the year. For the remaining fraction (1-s) of the year, Russia respects

qR ,1

and

pR ,1

In summary, our model describes Russias unreliability as a potential default event, with a probability of default. The model takes into account two ways for Europe to escape from the unreliability of Russian gas supplies: on the one hand, diversification by signing long-term contracts with the competitive fringe, and on the other hand, investments in strategic storage c. The parameters of the model are calibrated on cost data and elasticities from the literature, the 2007 baseline for volume, and the average price 2003 2007.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

47

The results The top half of Figure 4 shows how quantities and prices vary as , the probability of Russian default, goes from 0 to 1. The graph also shows the discount p p0 pR,1 of long-term gas import contracts offered by Russia compared to contracts offered by the competitive fringe. For =0, there is no risk and there is obviously no price difference between the contract with Russia and the contracts with the competitive fringe. The simulation shows that in this case, Europe buys q=135 bcm per year from Russia and q=94 bcm per year from the other suppliers. This is not too far from the actual data in 2007 as cited by BP (2008), which mentions 120 bcm per year from Russia and 95 bcm per year from other non-European import suppliers. Indeed, until recently, Russia was considered a reliable supplier, and so it is not surprising that the currently observed market quantities correspond to the case =0. For >0 Russia becomes unreliable. When Russia defaults, it delivers only an annualized amount qR ,2 instead of qR ,1 , at a higher price pR ,2 instead of the originally agreed long-term gas import contract price pR ,1 . Panel (a) of Figure 4 shows that the quantity withheld would be around 40% and panel (b) shows that the resulting price increase would be around 40% as well. Although substantial, such a price increase is only a two-sigma event over three trading days at gas hubs such as NBP (National Balancing Point, in the UK) when considering a typical daily volatility of 10%. As increases, Europe increases its volume q0 of long-term gas import contracts with the competitive fringe, at a slowly increasing contract price p0 . Meanwhile, Europe procures a smaller volume qR ,1 with long-term contracts from Russia, even though Russia is obliged to give an increasing discount p

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

48

to compensate the risk for Europe. It is obvious why Russia would want to

give the discount: as increases, there is a higher chance that Russia can charge the monopoly price p in Stage 3 (by supplying only a quantity q of gas). By giving a discount p , Russia can induce Europe to sign the long-

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

49

term gas import contracts qR ,1 (despite the unreliability), which puts Europe in a vulnerable situation. For example, for =20%, the Russian contractual discount is 6.3 EUR/tcm or roughly 4.5% of the price. Despite the discount, Russia loses market share as increases and for =57% supply from the competitive fringe outstrips Russian supply. Clearly, Europe tries to make itself less dependent on Russia and therefore less vulnerable in the event of Russian withholding. Panels (c) and (d) of Figure 4 show the effect on European surplus and on suppliers profits, respectively. Recall that S1 is the European surplus in Case 1 (Russia complies with long-term contracts) while S2 is the European surplus in Case 2 (Russia defaults). E[S] is the expected value of the European surplus. For =0 and =1, we obviously find E[S]=S1 and E[S]=S2, respectively. As d increases, E[S] decreases: despite the Russian discount and shifting supply mix, Russian unreliability causes a loss of expected European surplus. Panel (d) shows Russias profits in Case 1 ( R ,1 ), Case 2 ( R ,2 ) and the expected value E[ R ] as well as the profits 0 obtained by the competitive fringe. Clearly, Russias expected profits decrease monotonically with increasing : the negative impact of the Russian contract discount and loss of Russian market share is not sufficiently counterbalanced by Russias increased likelihood of benefiting from a crisis. The only party gaining from increased unreliability is the competitive fringe. The competitive fringe profits 0 increase with increasing , because increased Russian unreliability allows them to sell a larger volume at a higher price. The most important observation is that both Russia and Europe suffer when increases. Although is exogenous in our model, the results show that it would be attractive for both Europe and Russia to invest in a more reliable relationship.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

50

9. References
Boots M., Rijkens F., Hobbs B., 2004, trading in the downstream European gas market, Energy Journal, vol 25, n3 Dahl C., 2004, International Energy Markets, Pennwell EIA, 2011, World sale gas resources: an initial assessment of 14 regions outside the US, April 2011, DOE IEA ,2009, World Energy Outlook MIT, 2010, The future of natural gas an interdisciplinary MIT study, interim report MIT Energy Initiative Morbee, J., Proost S., (2010), "Russian Gas Imports in Europe: How Does Gazprom Reliability Change the Game?", The Energy Journal, vol 31,n4, p79-109 Pindyck , Rubinfeld, Micro-economics, Stern J., 2007, European Gas Security: what does it mean and what are the most important issues? , CESSA presentation, December, Cambridge W.Van Herterijck Aardgas , technische, economische en politieke aspecten, ACCO, 2007

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Chapter 8 Basic electricity economics


1. Introduction
Electricity is the energy vector where the domestic value added and the domestic flexibility is the largest: one can chose the type of primary fuel to use and one can opt for a particular type of organisation of the sector. We start the chapter with a small introductory section, dealing with conventions and definitions. In the second section we survey the main uses, and the way electricity is generated at EU and world level. Sections 3, 4 and 5 present the basic economics of the electricity market. In section 3 we discuss first peak load pricing and investment in a world where demand is certain. In section 4 we discuss optimal pricing and investment with uncertainty. In section 5 we analyse briefly transport of electricity and the location of consumption and production over space. The emphasis in this chapter is on optimal pricing and investment and not on the market institutions that are needed to implement these optimal allocations. Those are discussed in chapter 9. In the rest of this chapter we use the following conventions (based on BP statistical review conventions): 1Kwh=3600kJ=860kcal=3412 Btu 1 MTOE produces approx 4.4 Twh

2. Main uses, consumers, producers and trade flows


Main uses
Electricity as source of power for engines and for lighting has no good substitutes. For some applications natural gas could be an imperfect substitute. For cooking and home heating, gas is a good substitute if it is available. For process heat, except for specific applications, gas is again a good alternative.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost Use of electricity Cooking Lighting, power Home heating Industrial process Transport Main substitutes Gas, coal, firewood Gas Gas, Gasoil, previously coal furnaces Gas, Fuel oil, coal Oil products

Consumption of electricity is mainly concentrated in the richer Western countries and in the former Soviet countries. The consumption per capita per year in OECD is almost 8000 Kwh while consumption per capita in China is less than 2000 Kwh and in India less than 400 Kwh. World consumption in 1980 (6800 Twh/year) was less than half the present consumption (15700 Twh/year). The IEA (Outlook 2008) expects the world consumption to double by 2030. Growth in the OECD area would be rather limited to some 1% per year but growth rates in China would be rather 5% per year.

Production of Electricity by fuel


Before 1960, coal was the dominant fuel for power production. HFO and gas have taken over first, followed by the expansion of nuclear in the seventies and the eighties. Since early nineties there is a nuclear phase out in large parts of the world following the Chernobyl accident. Since then there is also a revival for gas fired units with the appearance of more performing combined cycle gas turbines that have a conversion efficiency of the order of 55 to 60%.. The next table gives shares of generating technologies in the world and expectations of IEA world outlook (2008). For 2030 the share of coal and gas remain large (which means massive investments), the share of nuclear decreases and one expects renewables to grow from 2% to 7% of total power supply in the world.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost 1990 coal oil Gas nuclear hydro biomass Wind Total (TWh) 11811 37% 11% 15% 17% 18% 1% 2006 41% 6% 20% 15% 16% 1% 1% 18921 2030 44% 2% 20% 10% 14% 3% 4% 33265

Source: IEA Outlook 2008 Table 1 Expected electricity generation in the world by type of fuel One of the main uncertainties is the growth of electricity demand in China and India. BP extrapolated the income elasticities observed in other Asian countries, corrected for improvements in electricity efficiency to make its outlook for China.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

3. Trade flows Trading electricity is mainly regional trade and there are two reasons for this. First in many countries (EU, USA), the production and transport of electricity was in public hands or in the hands of a regulated private monopoly. This production was organised at the level of the state or the country and trade between regulated national companies was not a priority even if it could reduce costs. The national control was considered as more important. Second, electricity is costly to transport over large distances. In Europe there are traditionally some net exporters (France) and net importers (Italy, NL, Belgium). Another important issue not dealt with in this chapter is the cost and capacity of electricity transmission.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

3. Optimal pricing and investment when demand is certain


Peak load pricing and investment with only one type of power plants
The demand for electricity is fluctuating strongly within a year: there are daily, weekly and seasonal variations. As electricity demand can not be rationed easily, one has to install capacity in function of the peak demand. This implies that the cost of generating electricity will be different in peak and off peak periods. An efficient electricity market will signal this difference in marginal cost to the consumers. Varying prices over time in function of the marginal cost is called peak load pricing. We develop this idea shortly with a graph, a simple algebraic model and a numerical example. Assume that peak and off peak are periods of equal length within the year and that demand in peak does not depend on prices in off peak and vice versa.
peak load pricing
Euro/K wh Dema nd F unct pea k Exist Cap Optimal Capacity

Dema nd F unct o ff peak P*

P* Op tima l price i n peak fo r give n ca pacity P** Op timal price i n peak w Op tima l capaci ty Variable Cost

Op tima l price o ff peak

Annuity investment cost/length peak

Figure 8.1 Peak load pricing and investment Consider Figure 8.1. First assume there is only one type of plant that can operate and its capacity is given (Exist Cap vertical line in Figure 8.1). Then the optimal price is equal to variable cost in the off peak period (here the marginal cost of one extra Kwh) and in the peak period it is equal to the price P* that is needed to ration demand to existing capacity. This means that in the peak period, prices need to be higher. Peak load pricing

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

means applying marginal cost pricing over time and charge the variable cost except when this would give demand levels that are larger than the existing capacity, at that moment, the peak price has to be raised. We can also consider what happens if we can extend capacity. Assume that this configuration of demand functions continues forever. Then it makes sense to extend capacity up to the point where the marginal benefit of an extra unit of capacity equals the marginal cost of this capacity. The marginal cost is in this case equal to the annuity of the investment (equivalent annual cost of one KW of capacity or rental cost) divided by the number of hours this capacity will be used, here length of the peak period). The marginal benefit is the distance between the demand function and the variable cost. In the presence of optimal investment we obtain that the price in the peak P** will equal the variable cost plus the cost of capacity. In the off peak period the price will still equal the variable cost as no extra capacity needs to be installed to satisfy off peak demand. Peak load pricing can take different forms: day/night tariff; interruptible demand; etc. as there are extra metering cost involved, one leaves the option to the consumer. He will select what is best for him and for the company. Assume that initially customers consume more or less evenly in both periods. One could then offer a choice between a uniform price P, or a differentiated price between peak and off peak. Those who mainly consume in the off peak will opt for the differentiated price and so will do those consumers that can easily reduce their peak consumption. Figure 8.2 illustrates what happens if one implements average cost pricing rather than marginal cost pricing. Average cost pricing would mean charging the same price in peak and off peak. This implies higher prices in off peak period and lower prices in peak period. This creates two types of inefficiencies: charging above the marginal cost in the off peak period and rationing of demand in the peak period. This rationing is very costly as one can not discriminate between high value and low value consumers. When we add investment possibilities, one will tend to invest more as the peak period is charged only part of the investment cost for which it is responsible.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

peak load pricing vs average cost pricing


Euro/Kwh Demand Fct peak Exist Cap Optimal Capacity

Demand Fct off peak

Optimal price peak for given capacity Optimal price peak with Optimal capacity

Average Cost pricing

Variable Cost

Optimal price off peak

Extra capacity needed

Figure 8.2 Average cost pricing and investment To find the optimal price and capacity algebraically (Williamson, 1966), one needs to solve an optimisation problem. Assuming 2 periods of equal length with low demand L and high demand H, the demand in each period does not depend on the price in the other period. Each of these periods generates a net consumer surplus (S-pq) and a producer surplus pq-bq where b stands for the variable cost. We also take into account the capacity costs per unit of capacity. If one considers a representative year, the quantity has dimension Kwh during one representative hour, the variable cost is fuel cost/ Kwh, the capacity cost has dimension annuity per 2KW /8760 h. The following expression is the total economic surplus to be maximised:
qL ,qH ,Q

Max W SL pLqL SH pH qH pLqL bqL ( pH qH bqH ) Q qL Q qH Q

s.t.

L H

And this gives the following first order conditions for the optimal quantities and associated prices: qL Q L 0 and qH Q H 0 and Q 0 L H pL b pH b

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Because the capacity is not fully used in the off peak period, the marginal cost of an extra Kwh is the variable cost. In the peak period, if the capacity is optimally chosen, the price equals the sum of the variable cost and the capacity cost. The optimal capacity level in this context means that the sum of the quasi- rents earned in each period equals the cost of one unit of capacity . In our graphical example (Figure 8.1), there was a large difference between peak and off peak demand functions and the cost of capacity was rather small then there is surplus capacity in the off peak period and the quasi rent earned in the off peak period is zero. If the difference in demand functions is smaller and/ or the cost of capacity larger, there can be quasi-rents in both periods.

Peak load pricing and optimal investment with several types of plants
For the production of electricity one can make use of different plants. They differ in the type of fuel and size. To meet a demand that is not uniform over time it may be more interesting to classify them in function of the cost of capacity C per unit and their variable cost c. The variable cost consists principally in fuel costs. Base load units are units with high cost of capacity and low variable costs. At the other extreme one has peak load units that have low capital cost and high variable cost. The capacity cost is to be understood as the full rental cost to have a given capacity (kW) available during a given year. The rental cost contains the annuity of the plant (so includes the investment cost + interest) plus insurance and other fixed costs (operators) for a year We are interested in two questions: 1) what is the best plant mix to meet a given load profile 2) what does this imply in terms of optimal pricing and capacity? The optimal mix of peak and baseload plants for a given level of demand is a cost minimisation problem that is simple when all the power stations are 100% reliable and one does not need to take into account start up costs. Graphically this can be solved using a load duration curve and total cost functions per type of plant. The total cost function for a plant of 1kW of type i is expressed as a function of the time h it is used: TCi (h) Ci ci h

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

Putting the load curve information (electricity power demand re-arranged in decreasing order) together with the different cost functions one can select the optimal combination of the different types of plants by taking for every yearly utilisation rate the least cost plant.

Peak load plant MW


Load du ra tion

curve

Base load plant

8760 h Euro Total Cost function of peak plant of 1kW Total Cost function base load plant of 1kW

Capacity Cost base load plant Capacity cost peak plant

Peak unit cheaper

8760 h Base load unit cheaper

Figure 8.3 Optimal plant mix for fixed load demand curve When demand is price dependent, we can use an extended version of the algebraic formulation of the peak load pricing problem. We assume that the demands in the peak (High demand H) and off peak period (Low demand L) are independent. The optimal choice of capacities needs now to be solved simultaneously with the pricing problem:

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

10

q L , q H d e m a n d (M W ) in th e L o w p e rio d a n d H ig h p e rio d w h e re p e rio d s h a v e sa m e u n it le n g th q L P , q L B , q H P , q H B p ro d u c tio n s (M W ) in p e rio d s L ,H u s in g p la n ts P (p e a k in g ) ,B (b a s e lo a d ) Q P , Q B c a p a c ity a v a ila b le fo r th e tw o p e rio d s o f e q u a l le n g th (= w h o le ye a r) S L ( q L ), S H ( q H ) g ro ss c o n su m e r su rp lu s in d e m a n d p e rio d s L ,H ("a re a u n d e r W T P fu n c tio n ") c P , c B v a ria b le c o st fo r a p e rio d o f u n it le n g th o f a p e a k p la n t a n d a b a s e p la n t C P , C B c a p a c ity c o s ts fo r a ye a r (2 p e rio d s o f u n it le n g th ) o f p e a k in g a n d b a s e lo a d p la n t P ro b le m : M a x im is e su m o f g ro ss C S - v a ria b le c o sts - c a p a c ity c o sts u n d e r c o n s tra in ts b y c h o sin g p ro d u c tio n q u a n titie s a n d c a p a c ity (p ric e s a re d e te rm in e d im p lic itly b y se le c tin g to ta l p ro d u c tio n in e a c h o f th e p e rio d s) m ax S L (q L ) S H (q H ) c P ( q LP q HP ) c B ( q LB q HB ) C P Q P C B Q B L ( q L q LP q LB ) H ( q H q HP q HB ) LP ( q LP Q P ) LB ( q LB Q B ) HP (q HP Q P ) HB (q HB Q B ) g e n e ra tin g th e fo llo w in g first o rd e r c o n d itio n s (a s su m in g it is o p tim a l to u s e a ll p la n ts in a ll p e rio d s ) SL (1) L 0 pL L qL (2) (3 ) (4) (5 ) (6 )

SH H 0 pH H qH L LP c P LB c B H HP cP HB cB
C P LP HP C B LB HB

The first order conditions tell us what are the properties of the optimal solution. Obviously, in each period, one follows the merit order: use always first the available capacity with the lowest variable cost. Here we also determine simultaneously the capacity of the two plants. Conditions (1) and (2) mean that prices should equal marginal production cost in that period. The marginal cost is given by equations (3) and (4): it is the fuel cost plus a quasi rent (or shadow value). The quasi-rent for a given plant in a given period is the marginal benefit of having one more unit of capacity available during that period (cfr. interpretation of Lagrange multipliers at the optimum). As in each period the two plants are used, every type of plant earns quasi-rents in each period. Optimal capacity is reached when the sum over all periods of the quasi rents (or value) equals the unit cost of capacity. To solve for the optimum we need to solve the system (1) to (6) and do this for all possible combinations of s as there may be corner solutions where the peak plant is not used in the low demand period.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

11

An easier special case is where it is optimal not to use the peak plant in the low demand period:
(0) (1) (2) (3 ) (4) (5 ) (6)

LP 0 SL L 0 pL L qL SH H 0 pH H qH L LB c B H HP cP HB cB
CP CB
HP LB

HB H

( 2 ) (3 ) (5 ) p H ( 4 ) (5 )
HB

C P cP
HB

C P cP cB
L

(1) ( 6 ) p L

cB C B

c B C B [C P c P c B ]

In this case the optimal price (marginal cost) in the High demand period equals the price of fuel plus the full capacity cost of the peak load plant 1 . This is indeed the extra cost to society of satisfying an extra power demand in the peak period. In the Low demand period we obtain that the price equals the fuel cost + the full capacity cost of a baseload unit minus the capacity credit for offering low cost capacity in the peak period. This capacity credit [CP cP cB ] equals the savings in capacity costs in the peak period adjusted for the difference in fuel costs. We illustrate this in Figure 8.4:

Price Per Kwh= fuel cost peak plant /Kwh + annual cost capacity/ length of peak period in h.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

12

cP+CP

Peak

pH

HB

cP

Base load pL LB

cB

8760h

Figure 8.4 Illustration of optimal plant mix with two demand periods We can use a numerical example to illustrate this point. Assume that demand for capacity is given by: qH 125 (200 pH ) qL 125 (100 pL ) with qH , qL in MW and pH , pL in EUR/MWh. Assume, a (base-load) power generation technology with CB c 219000 EUR/MW and B 25 EUR/MWh is available. In

addition, a peak-load power generation technology with CP 50000 EUR/MW and cP 60 EUR/MWh is now also available 2 .Unit conversion yields cP 262800 EUR/MW and cB 109500 EUR/MW. Using the formulas calculated above, we have:
EUR EUR 71 MW MWh EUR EUR pL CB cB [CP cP cB ] 125200 29 MW MWh pH CP cP 312800

2 The parameters of the peak-load technology are taken from the above-mentioned article by Borenstein (2005), assuming USD/EUR parity

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

13

and hence, using the demand curves, qH 16073 MW and qL 8927 MW. A customer who agrees to buy a constant amount of power (i.e., the same rate of consumption during peak and off-peak hours), would pay an average price of 50 EUR/MWh, which is also the average total cost of the base-load power plant. How important is peak load pricing and correct capacity choice? Borenstein (2005) analysed the effects of real time retail pricing with a representative load curve for the US retail customer and used the following costs for power stations:

He computed the effects of real time pricing for different demand elasticities and found that real time pricing can easily pay its higher metering costs for the larger consumers. Figure 8.4 presents the effects on the load duration curve of switching from flat uniform pricing to real time pricing for 1/3rd of the customers. Borenstein found that gains can be large they depend on the elasticity of demand. Time of day pricing (day and night) only captures a small fraction of the benefits of real time pricing. With real time pricing, total consumption of electricity could increase.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost


Effect of switching 1/3 rd of customers from flat to real time pricing

14

Figure 8.4 Effect of switching from uniform flat to real time of day pricing (source: Borenstein (2005)).

Can this type of behaviour be decentralised in a market context?


This is a question we address in Chapter 9. The answer is in principle Yes. If one starts with no initial capacity, a perfectly competitive market would supply the right quantities at the right prices and suppliers would cover their costs. The main assumptions driving this result are the absence of returns to scale in production so that many producers can be active on this market and the absence of reserve capacity requirements. If one would start from the wrong mix of capacity or a too large or too small capacity, the market mechanism can in principle also achieve the right adaptation over time. If capacity is too large, the quasi-rent would be too small to encourage new investments and capacity would gradually be adjusted downwards. Etc.

Cost of power plants


To decide what type of plant is most appropriate for a given number of hours of operation, one can make a simple static comparison of the costs of generating one Mwh. The next table using data from IEA makes such a comparison. In the long term the marginal cost of one Mwh will depend on the availability of the power plant (h/year and technical lifetime), the total

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

15

investment cost, the cost of capital (here a simple interest rate), the efficiency of the power plant, the fuel cost and the cost of the CO2 permits. This table allows to study the importance of each of the parameters. For nuclear, coal and combined cycle gas plant, the availability factor represents the time the machine is not out for planned or unplanned maintenance. For gas turbine, the availability represents the probability the plant is used for peak service. For wind power, the availability factor is a synthesis of wind conditions over the year. The table allows to make a rough first comparison. What is missing is the effective contribution to the guaranteed capacity (could be only 20% of installed capacity). In reality, the effective utilisation of a power plant will depend on the merit order of the available capacities and of the total demand (cfr. Figure 8.4). A private investor will also take into account his cost of capital and will look into the risks associated to his investment. The risk will depend on the price and variability of the price of electricity.

Simple power plant economics: comparing the cost per Mwh for maximum operating hours per year source: IEA Nuclear coal CC gas gas turb Wind o Technical parameters Capacity MW 1400,0 750,0 780,0 150,0 efficiency % 33,0 41,0 57,0 38,0 10 Emission CO2 kg/Gjinput 0,0 93,0 56,0 56,0 Technical life years 60,0 40,0 30,0 30,0 2 Investment cost /kw 2928,0 1523,0 763,0 520,0 434 Fixed cost of O&M /Kw 65,0 15,0 11,0 11,0 Variable cost O&M /Mwh 1,2 2,0 1,5 0,4 3 Market parameters fuel cost Price of CO2 Interest rate Hours of operation Results annuity factor annuity total fixed cost per Mwh total variable fuel cost per hour total variable CO2 permit cost total cost per Mwh

/Mwh /ton %/100 hours/year

3,0 25,0 0,08 7446,0

13,0 25,0 0,08 7446,0

22,0 25,0 0,08 7446,0

22,0 25,0 0,08 1000,0

2 0 376

per Year/ of investm /Kwyear /MW h /Mwh /Mwh /Mwh

0,081 236,576 40,5 10,3 0,0 50,8

0,084 127,719 19,2 33,7 20,4 73,3

0,089 67,775 10,6 40,1 8,8 59,5

0,089 46,190 57,2 58,3 13,3 128,7

0, 442, 11 3

14

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

16

4. Optimal pricing and investment when demand is uncertain and availability of plants is uncertain
Demand is not known with uncertainty and power plants can have unforced outages. This is also known as the reserve capacity requirement. In theory one can expand the neo-classical market framework by defining contingent commodities and trade in these commodities. This would mean that one would buy X MW at price p if there is no unforeseen capacity shortage and buy Z MW at price q if there is no capacity shortage. The problem is that, in case of capacity shortage, it is difficult to suddenly charge higher prices and ration demand in function of the willingness to pay of each customer. This is difficult for two reasons. First the individual WTPs are not known, second one needs special devices to disconnect individual customers. This implies that if there is a shortage, the average consumer is interrupted, not the consumer that could most easily forego the electricity consumption. We illustrate this in Figure 8.5.
A price F DBE=lost consumer surplus when There is efficient rationing and Demand is higher than expected D E AEF= expected loss of consumer surplus when there is random rationing (probability of not safying a customer in the range OqHH =0Q/OqHH =AF/FpHH

pHH pH B

Demand very high (HH) Demand high (H)

0 qH

Q qHH

qHH

Quantity

Figure 8.5 Effect of different types of adapted to peak demand.

rationing when prices can not be

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

17

Take the case of two demand levels: there is the expected demand qH realised with probability and there is the unexceptionally high power demand qHH with probability ( 1 ). Initial existing capacity is fixed at Q. What is an appropriate price and capacity? The problem is that capacity and price in the peak period have to be chosen beforehand. Assume first that the best solution is to always satisfy demand, whatever its level. This requires that the price in the peak period has to be set at an exceptionally high level (pHH) but this would also generate a high loss of efficiency when the peak demand is at a lower, normal level. The other solution is to go for a lower price (pH) but to increase capacity such that demand is always satisfied (QHH). This would be very costly in terms of capacity. Assume now that one will not always satisfy demand in the exceptional peak period. Assume that capacity equals Q and that price equals pH. In that case, the demand in the exceptional peak period has to be rationed. The best option is to use the price mechanism and increase prices up to pHH. The loss of consumer surplus due to insufficient capacity is now limited to area DBE. But it is in general difficult to ration demand efficiently using a higher price. The power cuts are then either at random or proportional. In this case the consumer surplus is much higher and equals AEF: for each consumer in the range 0qHH , a proportion 1-0Q/0qHH will not be satisfied. For each level of capacity, price and probability distribution of demand one can define the Value Of Lost Load (VOLL) ( per expected Mwh lost). The optimal solution is to increase the level of peaking capacity up to the point where the reduction of VOLL equals the marginal cost of capacity (annuity peak capacity/duration of load shedding). One can also increase the price so as to balance the marginal reduction in the VOLL and the higher loss of consumer surplus in the normal demand period. There is a loss of consumer surplus in the normal demand period because the full capacity is not used (we assume that the price>fuel cost) Figure 8.6 shows the different effects at work. Another option is to offer interruptible contracts to those consumers that can easily decrease their demand at short notice. These will be the consumers with the lowest costs of

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

18

being curtailed. An interruptible demand contract acts like an increase in capacity.


A price F pHH pH P B D E Reducing the VOLL by installing More capacity (Q) and raising the price (p) At the cost of increasing the loss of consumer surplus under normal demand conditions

pL PL

Demand very high (HH) Demand high (H)

0 qH

Q q Q HH qHH

Quantity

Figure 8.6 Effects of a price increase and a capacity increase

5. Optimal pricing and investment when demand is uncertain and availability of plants is uncertain
Not only demand can be uncertain, also the availability of plants can be uncertain due to technical failures, unforeseen weather events etc. Assume a load duration curve that is known with certainty.. The probability that demand can not be satisfied fully can be computed by computing all states of the world: this means enumerating all combinations of machines that could have a technical failure. This allows in principle to compute for every production park and a given demand the LOLL. One can again optimize the level of capacity by comparing the cost of extra capacity and the saved LOLL.

Energy Economics 2010-2011 prof Stef Proost

19

6. Production and transport of electricity


For different reasons (cooling, population density, fuel supply) production can be located at some distance of the consumption location. What are good economic principles to invest in transport and what are the optimal locations for production and consumption?

7. References
Borenstein (2005), Long run efficiency of real time Electricity pricing, University of California Energy Institute , CSEM WP 133 r Evans J., Hunt L., (eds.) (2009) International Handbook of the Economics of Energy, Edward Elgar Stoft S.,2002,, Power system economics, IEEE press Williamson, O. E., (1966), Peak-load pricing and optimal capacity under indivisibility constraints, The American Economic Review, p. 810-827

0 2417 135 9
5 92
 1   2  7    7 7
53    1 53

9 38 865  638 5 56 8   5 7 3 3 5  3 933   48 86  8  5  5 366 46 3 3   6  9 38  73 53 6 653 5 3  5 8     3 7  4 56  6  6 3 5  36  5   6 4

01353 246 8 7

0246 843 357 9


6
45 88 6 45 
9 93 
6 66 9  93 
6 66 9  3
3 3 5  4 6 3 353   6    9
4 9    3  93 
66 9 5 89 6 5 !6  5 "4 #$
"4  5 %& "4 5 '
4

9 95 4 9 () 5


3 6 6 9 93 
4

"4 95 4 5 9 0 +   * 3   0 3 5 7  7 79343 0   3 3 6 5


6 0 3 5 ,6
   9

467 9  8 82     8 9 13     89 8     9 9 3 4 9 9 8 88 8 8  9 88  9  9  ! 329 4 9  & 82  8 378 13 " 8 " 32 822" 8 ( 8 & " 9 " 2
 5 
2 2 2  9  
4 1 9 1 4  85 15 1   01 359
2 2 2  9   24 59 1 9 1 4  85 15 1  8 541
393     3 37 5825 15 1 9 8
48
9488 58 48
9835  3 5 5  4 99


4 99
5
1 1  3 4 8 4  ! 4 59 1 5 9 3 575 2 4
4  1 9 85 1 1 " 3
 1 1 4# 5 $ 7
4&8  1 ' 88 5 554 1 
2 $ 3 % 1 1    1( 
8

013 2

4632  " 8 4# 7  9 2 "8 8 7  8 8 8 9  4$ "88 8 32  829  9  8  4% 8 8 &9 927 "38  2   9 38 "  9 9  8   29 '8 8 8  &

01 35785
24 93 8

9 942
-2 148'32 381 84
91515  5 ,1815 12 5'32
5
1+ 32
53
7
4  39 " 1  1  8 8 191 5 11"" 9 49 19 8 1 5  7
493 14 5  ' 1
 $7151
311* 15

2
34 51 1 + 35
+ 1 
+" 9   85 7
44958
8  9 854  7
478'9 82 9 98 31 13 8
21 9947 5 9 94 1
"

 711559

1494
3
$ 7
5 
2 4
1  1+12
&855 )59 # 5,3"1 1 5 9 1
* 5(4 1 1 '4 3  2
5 9 34 35
$ 5    $4)&2454
"
5'1"3531
9 853#
 18 33952#53
588 51895 817
413 4 1 5555 9 -9  9  8 319"9 45195 59 5  81  5  5

                    

0 2417 49
1 1 18 8 2 135 8 5 5 2 9
  33 4 5  1  8  4   33 4 5  1  8  4   5 33 4 5 4  !8 4    5 33 4 5    8  4 4 "1 33 4 5 4 ! 8  4  1 33 4 5   8  4 4  1 33 4 5 4  ! 8  4   1 33 4 5  !  8  4 4  1 # $%%$&%  ! 7

01357
  241 81 4 5 2 6
7 4 2 4   54      3 72    4       3 ! 87 #  %7 &7 %4 " # 8$  
'67(5  "(  

79
2  5460 6 6 16 6 4  5    76 6 6 46 06 3  50 5 5    2     6 7 6 0 6 6  46 4   5  6  7 5 46 6 4254 6  5 5 56 2 

0 25 136 4

 
135289 2 6 6 7

0135289
8 8 8 2 6 6 3 6 9 7

 "883
88 9968 86 8521199 3# 98 1 5 66 9 873
6829 699!  38 3816
6289 8 96
5838888 8 $%2
6 238 3
 6  "8$%
686 962888388865 239
28 99 38 1 5
8 87699  9
# 3 33 6 925 29
 863618 8  8 8 87 61
& 8
5 1 5 6 6 81 9 8 3


  6 19689629 565532
1
35 13923
593 3182838 88
88 92 380368!
3 8
6
8 5
3 5 6 3
6888
182
& 281 9 9 8 86 9
 8 511 86299  6 3 2 1 3  "863
6886897 66
8(
8168262 
1


98 8 5 1
931 '69
8 683 288
6
636  5
 8 36 9 2 5 3 ' 
86 8 58228 2 1'9&81 9
6338 68 916!3 6 3
  )+
3,
6 215 88! 8896 28 9  38 23 28 99 98  8 5  1 8 
5 
 2 *85 1 5 68  
93 3 912 3 618 8 8  3618 8  8 36  $6'
699698 &2
8
 63823 5&3 881 3 8 8 893
879 3 6 8 16918

8 15 8 298 5
5 1 68 83 8211 1 19
 
95 9  3 8  9 6  9 3 818 8 2  & 
8 36 3 6 3 96 8 65 5 8
8 +

 81-! 28 2 8 8 9&8


 6
3 
9  68'1
6182
2 6  
1 8 8 6 9 3 6  929 8 65 2 16
99& ' 6 ' 1 63  .82563  &589 63
8
5 &8

 1 8 9165281 2
8881 3 33
83 33 62 29

8
8
 51536183 6 2

9 52 8 138 97 89 68 98  6


3
9 3 3 9 68 8  8 
3  9 8623
9

5  3 

 68
8 8 9628 28
8 8  8  2 3 6 879 6 3 6 8 23   2   6 8 23 23  528 88 8  98

6 3 2 7  8  6! 3
8 1 2 1

 "8 5 68 8
3939
3 838 & 
98
96
8813 8699
68 1 "288 6 
62821

26618 5 3 6 3 879 9 3 8 99 8 *$/0%226139  


8 3
3 '18 

**,$#.% )%! +& #-(  ! /   01   %  2 % )"2$#576+#"5 ! 7 . !3% 4$4 , %    &   8!  2(:1/:  "  &' %/#94   & '  0 ;+!  2   % ) %"%" ,    3%&"%""%%- "%" 9     #! %.  % # 9<-:6 $ ,$=. #9>,$=( -:6 . ?  "' +1/ %+% / % +    / ) / / '   +# +2/+'+ ,.&! 3  , ) /  &:) '    ) /% +'+%.+'+& +'+ !  +-/ ! ' %"/ "4

01 479 4 8 5 5 235 82
1 7 9 8 2 8#$"! '
#(%!')& 5 !" % 8 25 7 & 9   

   3  71 89

02471

5 1358 9  22 2 2

2 1 7 34 255
 2 45  1 2 7
  39 7 3 5   71
31 1 5934   9
2355

5 8 9 !2
  3 4 4 32  945 8 5  8 9 87 34 4 1 8 3
  1

$
 38 9 23 0%1!2 8  4   71341 $%& 2 9  1  7 024
5  4 9 38 135 22 2 2

#73 $
 38 9 23  71341

1 9 2   79

 
6 7 2 13

01 356 731 3
6 3  24 769 26 1 67 62  56 21
   

      $ %

   ! " 726 76 44 # 5163 1 76    2 66 4 3 # 7 51


4 " 

    & '6 ##"


  #'6 24
2 1 7661 4
2 1 7 1 359 # 1 1 6 6 376 1 1 7 24
2 " 2 7 6 3 2 "
6 1 359 1 (1 13

2 7376 6 6 6 3

 
6 7 2 13

01 356 731 3
6 3 24 769 26 1 227 6 6
2  2 59716562
2  2 3 36 6   
% 1 1 24 7 2  6 1 356
# $    2 737 6 6 6 6 3
1 2631 6 2 &'3
1 7 2  6 & 1 1 ( &3 6 6 2 36 "  6 4 63 2 7 " 9 2  7 91 1
21 561 1 7 1 3 79 7 21 2
6 1 " 1   ! 6 " 726 76    72 66 4 

 6 3 " 5 "76 6 37 6 27 62 6 2 1 2 7 6 3 4 " 6 3 9 7 3 1 6 6


67 62 4 6  2 7

79
2  5460 6 6 16 6 4  5    7   !" # & ! !$% & 7 6 0 6 6  46 4   5  6' ' 7$ 5 46 6 4254 6  5 5 56 2 

0 25 136 4

     "13 36 8 4 14 % 422   !  32# # 44   2 $2# 5 # 5  '7 ( 4 ( 3 3 1 3   83 &42 4 5 4 %4 # 5 3 # 4 71 # 4 ( 1 7 (3  71 4 217 (61 3 37 23 #  8 48 8 # 3  3 )7 ( 35 (   )1 5 2*    ,725 16 2 1    563% +  34  57 5 2 7 1 7 )7 1632 218- 6 4 3 1 5
) 31 18 1 42- 7 2 # )4 2 1 7 53585( 611 .0 36327 ( 4/862 1 8 74 3 3 71 1 57 6
 1 58()4 7 ()4 4 67* 1 5 5 4 8     + 17 7 7 7 5 ( 1 16 2 2 8 !  0  2  1 1 3 571   4 # 4 675# 717 (51( 25 8562
71 4 84 3 4 31 4 22 1 3 7 2 6 24 3 2 ) 311 835* 4
51 4 37 7 ( 865 3 7  6   + 2  3 86) 3 4 848  27 ( 0    7 4 67- 17 ( 7 835 6 57 (5 7 82 7 87 - *

01357
4    241 81 5 2 6  764 5  1 4 53 552 2 4 5 4 26


6 8 22

013 6 292    27   186 24 7 8  6   4 2  013 6 29 24 7 8

0124 674
5  8 5 8 9 68
5 6 8 0124 674
     5 8 9    8

01 35782
9 827
24 3
 2 1   9  
7 8 
   751    9393 3  091 8 2 25  2

0145 79
17    7 77 9  2 6 87 6 77   
75   5 7 55 656 77 9 1 6  25 2 75   5 7
 1 1 7

79
2  5460 6 6 16 6 4  5    76 6 6 46 06 3  50 5 5    2     6 7  !"#$  7% 5 46 6 4254 6  5 5 56 2 

0 25 136 4

01 3619 1 1 0 119 1 257


6  35  8 
6 3 819 8 3 836 1 711  12 
1 99 7259 6

9 61 9  1 0  8    

01534534 2 5 65 5  28 58


  6    69   5 62 6 52 6 88  

0146 4 49 246 4 2 7 8 1
8 1 7 6 1 3 3

82 1 4628 8
 14  8 2 1 2 6  6

0146 4 49 246 4 2 7 8 1
8 1 7 6 1 3 3
8 1
624  1474 4  11 49 1 6 4
92  3 6 218 24 16 4 1 32  44  1 4  14 6 1 3 0146  14 6 1 34   346   1 2 7 6 4 41 4 4  7 4 3 4  144 8 6 14 29

 !  38
6 4   4 4 98 8 "  4 1 8 2 4 6  8 24 3 #6  3 $ 8 244728
%   4 ! ( *" ) 4 4 98 734 3 & 44 8 ' )! ) 2 +6 4  2 4 4 146 4 7  1 6  9  2 7 6 14
3 736 ! 6 64 1 , 1 1

79
2  5460 6 6 16 6 4  5    76 6 6 46 06 3  50 5 5    2     6 7 6 0 6 6  46 4   5  6  7  !"   "

0 25 136 4

79
5 460 6 6 16 4  5    75 51 2506 3 
 6 0 4 
2  6 0 7 5 46 6 46 6 5 5    7 6 0 6 6  46 4   5  6  7  ! !  "5 2$ 6 6#
4

0 25 136 4

 3
01 35 2 24  &%2'81 93


01 2782
 24 81 3 3512 98 5 32 9 




 2 8 
8 2"9 2 4  9 11 83 9 !1 " 8 " 1 
3#8 1 2 2 24 2 1 35 9 $ " 9 2 24 2 2 24 2%  819   2 1 35 9 1 1 35 9 5 3 
283 &" 1931 4  0 1
8

1 2 85 8 8 4 3#8 " 
1 93
8  9
93 2 9 1
92  3 83 23283 39 18 " 4
 2 1 2 9 " #  2 7833881

8 2 9 8

39"  1 2
122
9 "%  2 99 2 83 4 91 " 9  981 81 4 283
1 2 5

 7 81 8 29  3 8 1 381

( # 8   1
1 #
8

4 8
9
 7
*    2 91 2 51 93
1 13 )1 *1  9 2 +3,(#
82 4 83 8292% 9 2 22 2 8 
 5  4   2  ' 1  ( #
82  8281 4 2 19 82 4  5
!   2

3'2 8 9 5  83 82
8
 9 838 82.283  8
9  4  1 93  22  1  921 13  2

01 357817 79 2 283  879 24 12 98 1


921
13 5 2  9 9 2 8
 879  2   9 2
13 2   3 1 2   1 2 7 8
322

0
76494 95 6
4 33
9 678 1246  964 49748445 74
3 7

8
9 
7 9 7 8 4 5 8  
6
  6
6 06
6  13 76 9 9 9 4 6 9  5 8  9 46

4  32 6 26  62 4 4 4 1  6 4 6  23291 29 6 22  6 ! "   6 6 129 4 23#4 3  " 3 9 22  4$ 6   6 4 4
 3 %' 7 9 3 9 12 &(

01146 89 3   23 7 4
  3
2 4 4
6 26 69 6 9 3 1  6

01346 8
959  5795   5 7
85 75  1 7 5  9 87
8   7 8

79
3 454 6  5 3 46 4 2 1 6 6  7 46 56 4 !64  2 6 7 6 4 6 " #$%&' 345 1 4 5 ' (

0136 25 4

 46 42 6   633 64 2 5 3 66  245 2  2 2 4525 6 6 4 2 6 41 4 

025151
1
73
97716 13037748 6 46 3 589 79 23

02 4651
173
46 1351 8 7 7 3 35 79
4
19 8 9 319 
 716 5 78
9  81
3 9723 1 8 9 8 4  77 43 9 3 3 98 
83768
8 2 8 45 
951 9 1 7 3 5 38 
3  9 3 43 12 43 8 2 1631 5
698 1 7 6 3 9 9 3
1 8 41577  6


  81
12
16  9 319 7 3 315 8 


8344339
99638949 63317
53 343
59474 17
5879166 33 4 89
11 31  3 8  3  3  333  ! 9 4
3 83 4"
#4 89 5 $5 
8
!&0  4 4 68 74

 1 9 % " 9 53 3 53 9 9 91 4 68 81

 6 8
3 53 9 319  8

 4 9
917935623536771 945
85735
 91
9 37811 3  8 8 3 64 8 9  3  
' 9 1
533731595 56# 7& 83313 9 (
98 3461)3571 8 53 3  4 7
   43 8
1 77 7 8 9 683 74 9 1 84 8 1 ' * 8
13 77 5 11 %7 98 ' 53 834  1)73 8 #7  1 8
38
7

02 4651
173
46 1351 8 7 7 3 35 79
 721
4 1  48 8331
753  3
1 7  89
9
4 9 53 9  3 86 !  " 9 9 5313 5 9# 8 $9 8 9
% 835#8 9 45 13  43& 537
3 # 37 , 71
18  ) 5 9 4 68
7 3 38 79 53 9  3 51 3 9 9

 *4
1
99174759"7993889
5
333
8937
98 5+8973

979 1
11 4 4 7 4 1 181 83 7 2 3 6
./9989 8982
1591 98844 9 7 1 1 3 6 9  988
54
16

1
#

1 9
39788311%8 975)8

1 5 334 
313391
55 77810 53677 4 1 8 75 

) 

13 1 7  )  1
5 595
8 5  8 7 1  4398 8
6778 3 6 3
1

  016836
8 66
55 76488697
48 68601 76 6  53 476 7 843 3  36563
3  6

56 5358  
54  4
  6  " 8
6585
857544 668357 4 36 6
5 85  06878 6  548 #

 6 6 6  6   6 6 
7   443
 ! 44   5 5  $6
 &85 43
8% 
6 5 %

0135746 6 6 4 8
5 69

 556
76767 64  3   8666
5 585
8
6 84 4734
66  84

 5 5  8 6  7
6 544 7 8 6

 534 65548

754
 644 43
834
86!8  7 844 66844
86   
4856    56 64 684 6 4673 7  66    8 78 8 9 58 8 85 
' &
 7 4

 684 4 83 856  38    
48
4 6  7 4 ' & 86
66
38 8 954 46

 3
3  34586 468 8 7
 5 5 #6  4  5 4   6
 5 
4 6 7 7 ' $656%684  5
3 3  35 6
 5 386666
6 8 667

8  7 8  5 6 !6
48 64 6   4  55 45 #546 ' 47
 46
6%  6  6
  6 6   86  48574 78 4
45  5  5  
53 75( 6 8 68   ' )6848 4  7 5 8 8

4 3
5 4 54  6 58  6 4  8
53 74 *5 4
 * 484 8 7  5   + 3 4!93
3
6 *76 73 8  49
6 8 9  6
84
 54
488
 544  68
 8 

8637
 4   85 75 5 4 4 + , 3
3 8 % 7
6 8 7 84 -5 4 9  6 ! 5  64 8

 65
 484
8  4 6 83 6 6
6 8
  8 5  354 6 8 476846  66 6   5 88
 8 36 3  6 679

 8     84644 56 8  4


7 485

5  4 4
 5 8 4 8  
  685 668 
 9 7

0135746 66844  4 8
75 8 69 7
8   
7  
84 35746 48  48 69 5  6    35746 48
69 6 64  58  "5 4
 

4 #4844
5 8 $         44 85 8
 8 64 635   844 ! 5 8


663 %6 6 " )3   6 8 83 83 &6 483" %6 6 " 86  '4 (6  6 5

' 56 +$  80 754 -8648601*64/  5


8/3 7*
, 8 6848 56 5.5  ! 596 . 5 6
 5 4, 7 0$ 5 41)8 58 0 5 +   464 8 6 4 , 6  5,  2
 

0135746 66844  4 8
75 8 69 7
   1  34   %86
7 (77
 5 " & 46 76
 5 &
 4 ' 6 %5
 56    
3 5  53 "6 -6 "4 .6   8  956 8 8  4 746 
7 5 8   69 6  5      !7 4 7 8 
 58 6 ""4   6

4 746 58
69   # 6"
 58$ 6 ""4 5  8"

4 54
 " 33
5 4  484 8  %& 46$5 56 ! $  + 7  " 5  7
 5 )   ,"3 86
 *  5
  7"6 6 483 5 83 6 "6 /3   6 8 663 -6 "  85 " 84 & 5 8

01 1566 89
4 24 676 1 7 1 4

1 7 7 21 91  1 954 1 7 77   121  ! " 8 7  4  7


27 2  7 7   97 1  !

0121 4 7 93
5 4 1132 5 87 2 7 5

      137  2 12  28  4 2  835 1 4  1 5 2    1 7 1


   1  1 1
  22 4     7 4 
 4    7  3
1 2 2 2

0121 4 7 93
5 4 1132 5 87 2 7 5
52  5 4 1 2 211 4 12

7 
 5

0121 4 7 93
5 4 1132 5 87 2 7 5
52  4 51 2 211 4 12

7 
 5

#$74549 % 71 5 72 72  9



 &  5 4 #4 197524 5
8 &52
4
7 9 #)4 1719 &17
9 2&7 5  89

0135 517
5
4 24 078 5 4 7  7 9

'(24  7 1 '717
5 & 29 9 5
9 & 5 9 4&15  2% 7 2 89 9 9 5
 5 2% 7 1 17 9 

9 24 479 9 72 89 135 9 24 424 4  9  ! "   4 


5 7  24  4  2 4
 9 4 9
 !

79
3 454 6  5 3 46 4 2 1 6 6  7 46 56 4 !64  2 6 7 6 4 6 345 1

0136 25 4

 46 42 6   633 64 2 5 3 66  245 2  2 2 4525 6 6 4 2 6 41 4 

01356 12
6
6 6 2464 6 51 4 37 9 5
    66    4

2 
00  !   %"& 5 53'6(
   ""# $ 2 24'45 )6
6
6 5
-0./0& 4 60 4 5
! 5 1 5 4 4 + 66, * 4
6 4 5& 1' 1+ '46
03 26 32 429 5   3 )2 2  $  456-# 
'6( 764256&22466   %62 5 ' ) 1 & 6 135 4 4 37 2
745226
03 262602 4   ) 4 52 5 3 *2 )   3 00 # 8 2466 12
6
6 65
"& : 24   %0135 4 6 51 4 669 2 ' 37 9 4 +5
4+3 70& 1 12
740 571' 1 261 '
6
45 2
2 52 2( 5
) 3
6 2

79
42 4 16 65662 6 5

0136 25 4

79
    66   76212  4 4 45 !   14 5  2 2 " 5    7#$  644 %2 & 44  !  2 5 6 6 13 " 41  7'6 56 !   76     7'6 56 !(  

7  6  5  4 4 45 36 4 4549 2 42 64 2   2 2 5 4 3 2 5  6     7631 56  1 4 3 6 2 5 26

0131679797 24 4

 8 3

0131679797   24 4

   8 3

78 1
3 197 7 4
9  1
9  6 4
1 197 3 3
9 7 114 3 3 0
9 4 7 3 4 16 77
2 
7 7
1 4 9
3
 7

"  ! 3  3 1 1 ! 69 3 91 177 0 11
 43 991  9
9 17 4 3 # 1 7 49 3 4 
8 914 3 124 4

29 4 4 16 7 3 7
7 7 3 7  1 3 $ 6 471  31
9 9!1 21 18   841


   !3! 9  9 3193 47
6 7  71 1 84!
9 3  ! 78 1
1
%1  841
93 4  !!9& 3
31 28 7  9 3   3 7! 71 24! 77
1
3 3
797 8 3

013 68 9 8     8 98 45 75


7   5  885   

  8  7 4  

013534 9 4 7 787 24657 8 7 3 3 8 8 2

8 8  1  8 3181  9 8 2 63 8 4 4 48  48 221 ! 711 33  "1 #8 5 $7 7 78 %&'73 (9 8 434  4 79 $ 8 4 3 3  8 1 1 2 8 2 8 3 4  1  1 51 1)# $ 43421 7 4! 9 *2719 8 434  38  4)7 ( &+ 25 1 1 2  7 $ )1 3     4 8)7 * &! )1&1 3   9 8 4345  113734, 72 8 4!)7  1 1  8 61 4 64 1 '47 19- 3  6 3  8 61 42 78  &!)118 3 4 71 31 )11 5 33 2 . (  4  $7 3 2  4 2 63 1 1 8 9 311 7753 5 2 1 7 5 !   /73878&4 . & $ $ 2 1 38  7 9 1 2 7 * 5 1 349  7 &4  % $ 8 &%!)112073  1 " 31 49  4 738 )8  * 1 78  4  11377 6 $ 81  64 3  72 0%! 6  78  )1+ )1&1 + *0%+&% $ $ 3  4  4 8  2  8 5 1 2 1)1123 $ "7 2# #3 349 4   5  7 36 41 6

013534 9 4 7 787 24657 8 7 3 3 8 8 2


9 8 434 1177  1 3 2 1 1 2 4 83 7  1 7 9 314 5383 31647    7 4 67   1373   6 4  1 79 !3 5  88  41"
#$7  41685 1265 61314 83 8 9  2 4    2  7 7 2  4 5 7 1 #% 4685 1  3 9  310&' 5   2 4   7  2 3 1 37 7 7( 8  2 12 2 2   1 8 1 685 4 2 65 263142 4)17179 1*   113 7 5 7  4  4 2 1 8 310&838 4243 3 1  25 67 2 1371  17 4  6  3 2 72 24 5788 3 4 2471 48 278 8 737 3 1! 162 


5  7 2  365  1   1
7    4
 
5
5 26 
0 7 2
2  !  545 66  1 3  5  2 3 2 2
 4  7  4  3 34 " 4 52 5#"  36 " 4 62 4  6 2 
6 3 $ 4
2 32     429
1   36  %24 2  &  

932952 '3

4 %2 (  6 5  6 999
4  2 62 4 3  374 2 4 2  & )6 1 6 225
2    42 4 *5

66!4
+56
2 3   36     6 74

2
 $   2 4 2 2
  545   2 2   ,74- 545 32  4 6 4  1 *2 2
5362 3 34 7  53 34  545 22(  6 2 4
 62 7 6  32 1 1.999632 215 (6 2   6 4  9
121!952 '  143 34
1 6 9,9999. 6  6 6 3  7  7  (5 4

 5 7  2 4. 67  42 2 4 2

01356 9
1   2464
  37 

 1
579
 6
26 
4 4 5 3552625 013 4 1  5 357 3  2466 5
3
4  4 52 4 
2 222 3 5
1332 
 9
26256211324 45
246 1!66   5  5 42   1 134  6  7 2113325  5  612
 262 76262 1  4
762 7
6
3! 2  6356 64 2 4 7 33  "
2
5225 421$3222  
24 4 2 2  % 64 
542 #$ 45  5 35
5 46  5534 22 6" 1 7 7 25 3 4 5 6 3 

5  &662 "6
5622$22262
(  
555 624
2 2 #' 2 
% 5 42 52 3 
2) 2 3 1 422 44 2 6 5  4662
54  $
5
2 65
2 4  2 45  3 2 2$2 4 5224 456   5 2

01356 9
1    2464
  37 

 "231$243
342 4   2425 42 635$ 42
52  #
 5 4 2 2  2% 6 141 466
465
2  6  7 2  7  6  5
5324375 1  3  5  0634
432454
2544
47 454!2
4 

4624
6
54
2
554464452
2 .164 23653 4423 22
4626436 .6 4
 

5 2 2
7 3236  2 4
6
 ) 2  45 1    6 6 (  7    %  12412
52 1 %6   %2  2
* ++  
2422$242
2424%4 21544 4    527
25 2! 6  5 
132 6
62  65 4255 446+25673426 5
353 (
24 62 3  3 % 2 3  5 6  3
3 * /6446+4742662 524342$64215 
 5  25 36 5 175622 554 
 
4  22
  6  43 6+ 366 2 22 35 2 2

5 %6 5 ( 7 
 4

* +4
422
62
(42 55217 22 42245 2)  5 
2    7
35  3 !
4 52 34 55$,4 
2  5362 %5 22  (
2  2 * -2 5565
4442!64264
2462163-6
 57 2114 5245654545253 %( 2
42
1  2
$3 2 3
5 2145  4 723 . 6 $2!2 4 4  5 3 (2 2 5 323 2
3$-   2
" 4 13 15 36 264 6   
. 2  6 52 1%5 42 2166 9
1 4  #6  4 14
4  13 4
 0135 4
 
4 2 2  437

 35
2 5 
3 1

01 3531 9
6  24684 8 42 8
 56    2 4
35  2 2 4   01  6  3 3 ! "# 1  % 843 3 5
21 
1  $ 8 1 41  2
43 8 4 4 1    & 331 2 1 3


# '( ' * 155  3 8 64 3 $  ) 6" (  $ + 64

%
86 3
3 6 1 
3
3 4  35 2  1 4 8 4 6" 6      2 3 1 01  %5 33 1 3   5  484 2 4 2 1 436  5 523 4
8 ,
3
01  
3 , 508 3 . 51 2 4 6 1
2 9%
2 434  /
1 3 4  3 42 4 41 6 
&%13 1 62465 62
 " 81 353 4 1 4
  08 1 353 6
1 3 
  ,
 962465 4 2  401 5 ! 1 6
5 1
262461 4 1  3 1 3 1 353 6 1

  311 508 5 3  4 5 5


 84 8 9  5 3 1562466 62 2 43 3 51
84 4 1 353
 5 5
4 48  3 1 5 8401   4 1 1 2 4

01 3531 9
6  24684 8 42 8

156246
56246
6 5 45 4 3 84 4 1 353 1 3532
   1  51 3  5 1 "# $321 
!5 5  4 6 !!5  4 8 2 1 8 51% 3 2 ! 5 4 3 
3 834 3 
5 4 3  3  
2   5 5 4   1 5   6 3

% 4 4  & 6 84 4 624662 2 43 51
1 5 843 15 1 3535 5 48 4 1 1  3  4  

#3 5 
1 "# $
6  3 2 5  8  4 4 8 2 245  2 1 2 6 3 3 84 4 6246 2 43 51
 6 3  4  2  15 1 353 5 48 5   3 62 3 5 5 3 5 5 
35 3 5&3 5    4 3
3 1 4 4  2  4  6 
4 6 #3 5 
1 "# $ 6  3 2 5  8  4 4 8 2 45  2 1 2 6 3 3 84 4 6246 2 43 5  5 3  4  2  15 1 353 5 1  6    3  3 5 5 3 5 5 
35 3 5&3 5 1    4 3
3
 4 4  2  4  6 
4 6

01354180895 8 54235   2 381 381 9


 4 6 5 81454 46 5 4 38  

62 6462 2 43 3 51
1 5 84 124 3
 3 0135 6 5 5
4 48 4 1 1 
15 1543 1 "#5
32
85 %5 53 35 6 4 2 136834256
6 6331154 
%4  48 4!! 5445522$ 61 55 1 
43355 14 3 3
! 36 8 6 1 5  3
4 42 ! 4 
 3
2 & 84 4 624662 2 43 51
1 5 843  4 15 1 3535 5 48 4 1 1   3   08 $2 3 584 4 6246
 9
'
5 31 15 1 353
 ( 3
401.,1234) 143" '508,2*53+ ,  35 2  2 2 51 32 09
6 3

1 3 20 2451 8 514 3
,, - 4 , 63  5
6 /3 35 $4346 5
8 /4+*5 1 14 6 1 5 43*5  '421  , 2 & 5  #1 644 28 3
+- 01 1 5351,1 4 423 2  1&3 1 5 3 08 2  1 3 , *5 1 4  8 35 13 , 9
2 34624604  
1%  3 43 , $  #3 *5  32
14 674 1 
+23 /3 4
8 5 53 1   35 8 ,8 4 , -
16 &32 $4 2014 $41- , ,1231, 65 6  1234 1 
+ , 3 6 4 8 4 ,  1   36 8 24 - 01  5 ) 74, 4" 3 3 084 3 2.01 ,4 3   2%28511233 )
43  91 
+ ,  521 54 ' ./ ,3 3 2451  9 2612 3 3 08 1 35
4
 1  96246 , 1 "56 3  # 3301   
+ 0 , 12384 , *51   2 15 2 4 5 5 7 , , 1 0 , 8 1 4   1 8 42 24523 )
4
2"3 6  ,  5 1 1  
20 5$4*5'346 
5 3534
 01, 4 5
/ 1234 6 $ 3 2 51 21
 02*5 3 
 515 1
53 3 3  6 . , 4

   2465 01  3 515 0 01 353  2 4 1 


1 1 5 3   4!
3 " # 2 1 5"  "81 3 3 2  3 4  5 3 8 4
 42

01 3531 9
6  24684 8 42 8

$5"
26246
5624635 % 3  3 61 3 1 353 1 353 3
 #4 1 & ()),  / , 1 5
23  5"1 3 % 5 5 1 '(*+- 3 ' 3
3 1 # 4 6011  4 8 ) %1 2 35 5 5 4 3 
3 834 3 25 4 "
0 2  3 2 % 
2   5 5 %  4 3  6 43
"
3 4 4 6 5 6 $61 326246621 % 2 43 5"1
1 45 2 5"
1 3535 2# 5 48 4 5 7 1 3
 5 3 3 5 "
1 2
5 1 3 4 "
3 8 3
  4 4 8 2    3
4  2  6 5 6 3 1 326246% 2 43 5"1
5 3  62  3  "
1 353 5 48 6  #4 5 # 1 3 5 5 3 5 5 "
35 3 553 4  4 3
3 1 4 4  2  4 "
 6 6  5 3 3 5 "
1 2
1  4 "
3 8 3
  4 4 8 2  3 3
4  2  6 5 6 3  
2 3 84
3 1 320  
2 3 3 & ()),3  #4  1 6  "

1  1   '(*+ 1 1  ) 5  62  3 5 1 3 5531 5 "
35 3 6 5 #  4 2  4 84 1 4 4  2  6 4 "
3
4 5 6   5 #6   
2 3 5 5  5  
2 4  2 2 5 3 #4  1   1 6  5   3  3 5 5 5% "
35 3 553 4 0 
55 1 #  4 3
 4 4  2  4 "
   # 6 6  5 53 45 2 3 5 3

$2 5 561 326246
55 "1
1 45 284 6 5"
1 353  # 485 4 5 1 1 3 3     3 " #5"  13 4 42   #43 #4 5 1 5 4
3   "81 3 3


43 5
42 "  
 1 225 6 4
 5

01 3531 9
6  24684 8 42 8

 085 35  844656  63553 1 9631


3 96 3 1 5
1 3  1


!2 3 3
1 53325 48408 25 38 1 33 85 248
1 32 826  2 2 532
" !3  25

 1 1 5 1 5 2   3  5 11

# $4 )35 01 4 4 2% ./01& ! 4596


1,1)1 3532   3 2 45  2 434
2 085 5
2 246
  '5 1(*331
43-3 514 1154( ) 33-6'23  626 )5+
22
1,4 6 8
 2 3 ) 1 1  5 33 35 ) 1'28 ) * 6 5 6  3 # $  2433
24  35 25364 3
166./018 84  1 6 01 4 5 2 4 6 3
)1./05 
 1 1% 534&5 4 2 58 ) 33 1 ) ) 3 3   24 1
 5 6 
45 15'2 1 3 6 35 # 53  1 
( ) 5 2 4  3 ) '21  + 1 3 1 7 3 6 4 8 4 ) * 01   - ) 8 1 4 2   3 2 4 1   # 73 4 3*
1./0163 13 4)
3 64 1 
(3 5 8 5 4! 1 8 ) 43 1 4 85 )
, ./01 5)2 012 533644)
! 2  11
3289)./064 6*5 2 1 5 62    3 4( * 31 '2 5 !345 11)6 53 5
234
6(35) 8$
3"2 2
 5 11 2346
2 2 1  1246
3)  01 ( ) 3
   2 + 23 1 )3 3 2 3  5 1 
) *  84  # 73 4 38
1./0163 13 4)
3 684 1 
(3 6 8 5 4! 1(4) ) 3 2  85 )
1) 8'2) * 5 5 8 ) 4 1 4 1
(32  ,./01 4 5 2 6  * 016  5 2 446
5  2 14( ) ./0+ 23 6246
 $
2  3 1 
( )5
53 53313
6
!3 1 32 ) 3 2 3 1 101)8./0 5 2  35: ) )22 
35 3 5  (2  4 ) * ! 1 186  3 8))  1  
4 ( # ;<5 25 13 +

56335
35( ) )45+
65 4!
5 23 111146
3 52( ) 2 53  5 3 1 536
!8 62 1535 301 ./04<+5 3  5 34 ! =23 24 
3 1 

    1
   3 2 13 3 4 21 3 2 4 1 42 3 5 3 5 54   2 38% 516   386011 5 1
1  5! 5 51 2 434&5 2
 5 8  08  4 4 6246;  5 3!
35 01  2 3  41  8 8 - )1 3536 4265  

5 5
1
 5 1+5 )./0 81 3;325  3 2 6 52 2 4 ! 56
1
)5 
+13
64


34 1424 !+3 5 3

 6 2 
 3

4 231   9 43 5  2 3 1 


43 6 4 8 63 6 

2 4 4
1 52 56
52  6

01356 9
1   2464
  37 
563 
22 62  422  6
1  5 2 !"
 5  4 4#
 7
16
%6%2$  545 4 2 5  6 4 
1& 12 2

$
$  421
563%57 & 52 2 % 6
1
2 5 4 '&1 ( 36
6$%  6%32 4 32 5 2
6 & ( &%6 6  %6%2
164  7 32 522466 )

1& 16 4
& &1 135 4 $
37 241!
%6%2&2 5! 2
%6 5 27 
1& 1( 22 & %
1 %21!  &2 4  1 32 5 & 127  (
2 &1 ( 36
6$% 2
6 & ( '
2
$ 3 4
$ !52 4 12 42 4  & 
265
2  1 (  4
*0+4 21 45
44 -7 6 
#
$ 2353 , 2 5 4  6(   2 4 5( 35 4 51(
 $   2 2 (  
&2 426  2  2  446 25 14 % 2  3 34 1  ( &2

 $   6 7   6  (52 3 4 2 .6&2  &1  2 13(
11 2 $ 5 (

013589  2 464
9

 6  7 222  1
  
   34 2 4 5  4 42

! 7 95" "17 # $42%
   &'(9
 64  9  12
!
4 6 5! 32 6266!! 4 " 4 1"2
215! 5 4 6
5   )6 1 3 

01356 9
1   2464
  37 

9 5    246362
152 22  1
 $5 2 4 56 ) 3 5 4 5! 3 4251    4  !
2
2 2  6
! 4 2 76  2 422  54  36
 ! 552  5  2 2 4 5 4 66 22)
3 34  2 
 2:6 4562  6   ! 456  "  7

*0$2+  1  9,42  3 34 7  #  


  6 2 4 7  9,- .$/  1(,/ 3 (4 #  0  2 0 2 *5)56 3 34 7   / 17 7 4 " 2 2  6 2 4   2422 5
2 7 3 5!6 1
4  ) 6  4 )6"2
2
2 4 13
 66  1 1 1
  / 17 7 8 2422 5

013
56 9
1   2464
  37   2
52 45 1

 *
5146
#2$ 
+2634 
"2 22  4  " 3
5 &4 23 

  4 22&2
3525&542  5 35 5  2 # 4 

" 5
 ,#1"2 524&244  2. 526 12  362 4
4
4 
-#$25516 52 4 #55$
6  "4 74 #6 ".222
3"
# 
2
2 
4 1  ( "51342
44 5 12 22 42 64 3" 4 46 222
4#4

 5
4
3
  #
 # 45 2 &. 5 6 + 
 ,# 4451 245
4#$ 345
 2 1#44

6036#34  22  $3  1 .16#


2
3642 2

532
/25

1$6 2623
 3  4  1  20 6   46 1 7 1 422646
54524 & 5  #
#
1 22#41 5  
2 4
 4 5   6$ 2 6 3 04

 99964!92232#64%1
 623#&4 6 "  " 2 5 3

#5& 2 24662764334462 
6 6 65
#" 4
5 1 4 6$

 
5  &4& 4

6 54132
2 46 5  4 &5 " 34
1342 7$4
65 $ 
   '254
&53 34 4 2
3" "  14 4 
4 4
7 
2365 &  6 "  4 5
1 2  2
5 5 5"
 2 
2$  545 4
&54 
"2 2 4  3 2
2 2
 # 4 & 2
5 3 2 
2
2 4 2  (4
$32564#61
23 452
5#$#525  # 54" 
43&54
"63 426 2
252
545 4 4
 4
4
 2
"5 3 #4 5 )999
# 2 4 2  2 " & 6  3

 0+71$143 4 302&56422 62 42


3245621   "3   &224 5
624
$21/3 23145 4/31 "1!# / 4
242315 641" 6#2 43
6 1
1 2 % 6#5
1  4" 6
#1 5 %23 42 
 # 44 
/
 
  & 32 12 2232 &542 3433
1 6 / 4 2 5  4 3 1 46
1"# %
4
6 3"4 &71
56"
1 /  5
 # 5"
445

# 5" 4

 214 + 343  2 2 2 1  
1 "6$ 2   7

79
42 4 16 65662 6 5

0136 25 4

79
    66   76212  4 4 45!  14 5  2 2   5   7"#  644 $2 % 44! 2 5 6 6 13   41 7&6 56     76     7&6 56    '

7  6  5  4 4 45 36 4 45 2 42 64 2   2 2 5 4 3 2  6     7631 56  1 4 3 6 2 5 26

01 34677
2 5  77  2253 9 36 6 3   8 7  8 681 5 28 959 3 43 2  7   47   566 3 496 5877462 1  77  4 7 9 3 7 7 9 8 9596 3 !   47  77 "#$%  7

$21
9 353 28 9595 9 75 4 6 62 78   47 27
9  24 51  2 6 42792 568  4 9 56 6 9 &655 9 1    959 8 5  184  5!%  47 8  76  7  6738'  5 5 $ 77 745 4  5  4686 3 8 775  6 62 8 5 7  959 3 7 46 9 2 4 9 59 64  47 8 6 3 1 47
9  727 8 5'  6  (1 3 76 74) 9652 "#$*2 563 1 668 32676 4 1 5 7 81 7 5
496 5 56 3  5 +  4 31 67   

01 34677
2 5  77  2253 9 36 6 3   8 7 
 776859 
9 353 7
2 566 5 29 3 65
 6 628 89 9 22 4 7  + ,6$443 67 2 576# 3720 56 9  9 3 6 5 4 -$265
 576 36* 3 "2
9  8 86 65 3 .7   /'54  76859 ( 2 01*236  36 6
* ,) 4 7 3 75 2  7326*   3 65
-$ *  6 9 9
 3
5316 5 56 47 6 27 76 253259 6 285328 1     8   3 8 $ 47 4 6    59793  9 '00252 5
8 6 5 6 5 $ 6 2 98 9 2

! "2572 5948#$67656 26$79&1 33 6  41 7 2 48


9 3 47 5  3 % 3 $46 4 56 27  3 8 ! 02 27 7   2 5  45 8 9 '9  9  ! 0'955 )2
6 26 2
9 5*2 2 728 95 4(36
3
5 37248436 556 9 8  83  9 ! 5'287$63683838575  976 7563 5 56493  $ 57
66537683  2 5789 1 7 78 1 6 52  8 79 23 6 4 5 9 18  4 ! 693$*18'2 5$972632293276 2 11
6 6 2 289 4586416 6   4 71 3 957 3  6 69 $ 88 8 2  6

55  5 

3   2 4 
1

01 35 81
  246 9  3

01 35 81
246 9 3

01 34677
2 5  77  2253 9 36 6 3   8 7 
 6772  965256 2 741 56!116 9817986 5 7#"
41 258698 2368$18566 %665 " 9 7656  $682964 $ 769345'4847
5 #7 1  956 4 $7 & 5
 " 7 1 75 6 53 7
9 7  1 3 7  (6743*7517% 3 73$ 3   2 $ &)" 39 " $ 3 9"6 5263+66956 67  % $ 3 766 5 64 8 8
3569 2 !, 4 ' 1 6 61
- .65295!#$6 6 5 "/ 5 -26$7676125318 376 6 3 866 4393 2 8 38 5 2 8 4  
9946""6738$3-"$ "237#63$15#31 92 68638 65$$!68 30 75 
6$4322675 28 9 86 4 7 9
8 2672 3551 3 664"5 89 56!$ "2 5 6 ! 3$ 6 2 5 6 2 81 6 #9772 #823 76 3 5 - 236475 9-$7645 "697 6977
754654 76 93 5234 493 588 59$ 586737 48 9 7  3 62 8  495 $52  6#75 )  6 4 6 "  8 586 4! $7 5 4 $ 5 3 3 4 "8 50 67 5 -  6 8 $6$ " 27 859! 3 4 $ 5 3 4 ,7  3 7 & 727  6 67 8 5 5 -  545 37279 29$  43  274 9 5 ! 7 3 68

001 2 0469 57
8 4 5 
4 6 84 
78  85 

01 34677
2 5  77  2253 9 36 6 3   8 7 
7676 6
8
3 9  3 76
!2
9 "5 2 #2 52 % &9 5 '46 4( 37248
8 9 $5 % 6 6'79 7 !2
9 "5" 9 $5 ) '46 4( 3724842#2 52  &6'79 7 *3
1 8#76 62 6 "626 3 4 +6', 17, -" 2 5" 49359'342 37 2 9 6 ' 36 496 527 " "  9 " #2 5 98 49 86 2
9 , 46 8 1 9++. 6326 6 6 8 378 6326 6 , 46 88
01 35637
3 83 1 79 2  2 8 ++.9 6/8 " 8 3 " 2 51 38 7, -  ' 26 ' 36 826 0"++.9 6/1  $1 ( 2 8 " " " 7, -   /  2 6 9 9 #  36'44 # 579 6 9 7, - 1  365" 67" 2 89 6 6" %  5

79
42 4 16 65662 6 5

0136 25 4

79
    66   76212  4 4 45!  14 5  2 2   5   7"#  644 $2 % 44! 2 5 6 6 13   41 7&6 56     76     7&6 56    '

7  6  5  4 4 45 36 4 45 2 42 64 2   2 2 5 4 3 2  6     7631 56  1 4 3 6 2 5 26

4
7
34 51 85 732 46 1254  4 14 4    2 1

0132 71
2456 8

4 21 1 ! 2 #04$%&(87
 8 1" $ 7 ' 4 )*   +47316"326 4 21 4 $ 5 26 1 8 14 $ 8   4 63 7!671 !   7" 3  ,4$6 "642$46  137 .2 1  7 816 47366 7  381   - 26 2586$ 7   / 60 464+656 1 4 6 4 6 1 2 817 + 7 227 7 8 17 -$7 8 1 1 621  2646 214113831 1  12  -617  27$61-2) 7 34$ 2"(214111"741$) 448  $111 $628$11 $ -251 541 2 7 2  1 4  1  7 171 2-8 7  $4 51) 417 7 4487 2  -251 

   1 34 51 85 732 2 


4 67  254  4 14 4 1  4
  4 617 7  26676  5 2 6  61    7 4 85 7!  1 6 6  2" 4 14 1"1 7 1  #     1  $87 " 2 11"6 7 228# 4  11  2  4 1#2 6 7 $87 7  61151137%  4   4   6 381 8 67 6  &1 4  "! 2  217 '1 1%  87# 2 456( 81# 
 564 51 7 21 68  4 ) "11321   %86!%7 81 2 2 48 4 6*4 # + #6  8554  14 77 38   6 4 6 81 1 4 #4 17 4  7  6 %532 3 85 76 2 1 4 14 161   '1 6 4 2221 %4 7 " 6 6  ", ! # 1 72 3 1 6 7 7 8  41 "623- 414  5  7 346 4 2886 

0132 71
2456 8

79
42 4 16 65662 6 5

0136 25 4

79
    66   76212  4 4 45!  14 5  2 2   5   7"#  644 $2 % 44! 2 5 6 6 13   41 7&6 56     76 '      7&6 56    (

7  6  5  4 4 45 36 4 45 2 42 64 2   2 2 5 4 3 2  6     7631 56  1 4 3 6 2 5 26

 9  6 94  5 2661 646 797 ! 445" 92   1 1 72 57  69 9  6 1   09 # $9 81 44$4$169 61 9  14658 445 211  65  4 1$ 54  14  4 9 779  7 6 5 #5 9
0965 $41 45   41  87 591  9 %579 77  54$41 45 6  4 156 5  5  6 116    4 47 1 9 & 11 798 7' # $ 4(7 1747 6  5 4 5 #591 $5 16   )479 77 9 1 47 5 7 156  8 99  1  *92(724 6   56 1 ( 6 9 715 +6   16 7 75  9 77 $ ' 19   17 1   , 7 1 $7 9 1 8  9171  29  5 7 69 $41 971(78 9 5 9  1    8 1 11 $ 7  

014645451 57  247475
60 57 96 1 78  5 211747  1 

 7 66576 5 8  71$ 4$ 675 7 71,7%$ 7 661 7  4 4 4 198' $ 4 5 9 5 1  4 6949 69  61 19 5 7 6-51 81 1

,)697)8 71 9 $1 9 16 9 7917 $9 8146 445 $ 21 9 58  5 91$617 41 71 1 1 7   6  7   58 1 7 9   9 61  21  5 9# ,,,7,1 41 # 9 $1 9 7917 $9 817989 58 5 7 5 8  61  1 1 1 7 46  6  7   9   9 61 9 1 9    .47112 171 #74  71661 6  7 57   6 +1 947 5  72  $1 4   445719$7949 444  59 11169$1$411 7  71,)9 ,, 91 $ 6  76 6945$4 79515 515 2777116178  7  5 7 6 4 6 $ 61 4517 (7 8   9 7 79/ 4  1 1 7 9  1 29 $  4 8 4 +$1  0
 $61$,)3  ,3 77'41362 62 917 51 ' 1 4   4791 9845 761 917
95 17)541   5 9 77 5 7 516 9  687 9 81 2 5   52569 $ 9 8 9 1 $   %661 41
9 714    ) 7 $ 2 9 679 58 75  70 11# 2   51 5  9   4 9 4 9 6$4 9  01 70  7 $ 9 4  7446 69  1 7 58 75 6 1 61 7  51 2661 ) 69  5 2 5 66  48 1 5 9 9 6$4 5 9 49   1 9 59 4715 2 54661 7 719 7 191
 $   1  5 724  9661   5   7  5791#71 7469  61 79 6  5 70 9 1 6 8 911 59 7 44# 6 0161  94 5 6 48 1 5 1 1964 5  5 5 61 8 176 1 97 1   926 

0 3
4  

013578 9
4 24 1
2
4     

013504 4 24 9

8
7  2 7 1 2  51  76 7   1   82 5 71  2 2  6 672   2 4   7  2761 2 2 1 6 5727772 7 7 1 61 8172 1 72 41   17 3  5 6 7 6 7 1   2   1 312  1  16 5 1 2 2 1 7  7 471 3 3   3 1461 12  7 2 734 72 5 8! 672 5 "1 4 6 663  6 7 6 1   1 16  5 5 7   1  32 72 5 1 1 7 1 32 1 82 5 773 6 #  2   2 4 2  7 2  16 2 6  $  74   1 7  4 2 3

01 3572 2461 6

0133 679
6513  2 453 5  5 9 2 5
 6 7 33 "4517 7 715 #3  15  
9
     3 1 1 15  1 5   45 4   6 7  9  55 5 5  437 3 1 2 1   5 6 15 3 531 1 1 3 31 3 3 !71   5 4   5 6  6 53 17 9
 5 1 3 5 5 3  353 4 1 5  4 9 765 3 5 5 3   3 5 63 1 5  47 9
 5 4 4 1 32 3 3   7 4 9  4 4 $ 15 5  337 23  7 5   3 5 4 %

01346 8
959  5795   5 7
85 75  1 7 5  9 9  87 8
8   7 8

79
3 454 6  5 3 46 4 2 1 6 6  7 46 56 4 !64  2 6 7 6 4 6 "#$%& 345 1 &

0136 25 4

 46 42 6   633 64 2 5 3 66  245 2  2 2 4525 6 6 4 2 6 41 4  ' 6( ,$*   1 )$*+ 6 2 5 5125 1 4  )$* 
 3 226  5  9 5  5 4 5  

01 1566 89
4 24 676 1 7 1 4

1 7 7 21 91  1 954 1 7 77   121  ! " 8 7  4  7


27 2  7 7   97 1  !

#$74549 % 71 5 72 72  9



 &  5 4 #4 197524 5
8 &52
4
7 9 #)4 1719 &17
9 2&7 5  89

0135 517
5
4 24 078 5 4 7  7 9

'(24  7 1 '717
5 & 29 9 5
9 & 5 9 4&15  2% 7 2 89 9 9 5
 5 2% 7 1 17 9 

9 24 479 9 72 89 135 9 24 424 4  9  ! "   4 


5 7  24  4  2 4
 9 4 9
 !

79
3 454 6  5 3 46 4 2 1 6 6  7 46 56 4 !64  2 6 7 6 4 6 345 1

0136 25 4

 46 42 6   633 64 2 5 3 66  245 2  2 2 4525 6 6 4 2 6 41 4 

869
6 66  345 2    869
6  345 25   6 5  33 64 6 2 66  245 2   55 4 6 2    5         2 2 42 166 245 16 5    64 2 ! 145 53 

013686 454 6 25 9
1 4

01313 689 97 991666 243 27


6 3
2 11 9

796
6 66  345 2    796
6  345 25  7 6 5  33 64 6 2 66  245 2   55 4 6 2    5        7 2 2 42 166 245 16 5    64 2 7! 145 53 

0136 25 4

01 35686 5 2 24 7 9 9

0 2 3 679
6 5 1 3 528 5 8 1

01367 2821 4  7 36 4  2 21 9


3  4 9 826  4

024579
93 135 4 4 6

0131269 85 4 189 24358


412 8 1

 

0131269 85 4 189 24358


412 8  1  4 812 9 4  1 949 12 

796
6 66  345 2    796
6  345 25  7 6 5  33 64 6 2 66  245 2   55 4 6 2    5        7 2 2 42 166 245 16 5    64 2 7! 145 53 

0136 25 4

013 373 3 571 74 245 689 6 1 7 2

 5 437 1 5 27 47 7  37 6  3 1 32
1 32  7
2 7  
4
2  762   5 6 4 76 7 
  2  2   1 84 4 1 32  4 2661   3  727 5 1 71 2 47
!6  
#  66 41 778  "  6
5   43 3 $ % 7
5 776 1 31  1 1 2 2 6 4 2
46 1 & %  4
7
72  1 7 4  61

01 35728 6 6 2 1 2461 6
66  3  72 5 1 71 1 47

01230579 5 68
6 1 86 58  9   

 6 
6  9  6  

 66    9 9    9  8 8 6 76 8 98
 5   

796
6 66  345 2    796
6  345 25  7 6 5  33 64 6 2 66  245 2   55 4 6 2    5        7 2 2 42 166 245 16 5    64 2 !"# 2   4 2 6 2 5  2$ 6   5  6  64 6 2 76 1 45 2 45   145
32 54  5 424 2   7% 145 53 
012 21548
8
2
0458 1 235789
 98
833
924  24 4 8 1 4 33 5 4
78 4 !#!"& 4 4 3 5 "$#%3 4 3
58
2
(4 28 8 8  5
3
2
1 5  1
  838
4 413
)  3 8
(83
8 1 )31 8 23
2
8
313 *  5
24  4
4 413 2 8 8 5  ) 
0) 21 8 5  + ,8 23+  5*4 8 24 +4 *)+ 4 13)  4 )*3
44
2 3 - 
1 1
 1 4 5 44 33 1 1 1 24 34 1 34 + 4 2 2 4 2
4  2 8 5   1
3
.+
4 + 5  344 33 *8 4  4 4 8 2 1 8 ) +5 2 21 4  5 2304) 4 92 531 5
5) 44 ) 3
3.+
4 1 43
838 8 / 4 0 4 3 41
8 4
4 + 23 *+ 4 8 2

0136 25 4

13+ 4 8 ,2313 13


2) +11 8  4 24 *4 
4 2 +8   25 *  8 45 1
+ )  + 3
71- 2(3 2- 3(49575691 72
358  - 3
5 1 5 53
975 8 
4 
2 92  8  2 8 8 4 1 48 4 2699

012 2 789
2 041 23 5 3
4 9235 84
2 24 4 3
1!4  24   4 3 4 3  2  4
"#4  8 1013  1 25453& )9*+, 5 $ 2 8 % ,-
4 +9/ %514 52412
'( 7.09/
8
4 28  42
011 
34 
3 2 5 
 "2  1 5
%  2# % 8 ! 534 4 3
4 1  4 8

8414 2 5   1 8 23
2
$24 34 !1 5 3# % 24  !4
4 413 85 2 58 2 5 8
8  011 
25 
3 %4  - 8 2 144 5 # 
31 5&4 # $22  245 2 384 8 11 
 24 54 484

- 28
8   1 45%# 24 3
4
4 2 1 13  8 8 253 4 3 (  8 4
$3 2 8 15 3$2
1 $441 3 3
45 $ 458
813 4 8 52 %
346
/52835 8 3 6 2 54 %4 2$47 8   92#/ 4 11 382512434 % 4$3$2 33 6 % 83 '% 4 4 3  5& 4
1
15 55832
82 4 83 21548

4  558 4 2 44413
51
% 35  4 3   1 8  8 5  2 5 %
84 33% 8 4 1
 494 34 2 $$2
2
5 8 4 834  # 5:2 $ 1  84 33% 8 4 1   2 2 $$2
2
5 8 4 4 3 5 $ 5

012 2 789
2 041 23 5 3
4 9233 1 4 32 24 12245          
4 !18 "#43 %4
1 1"3  232   2 8 $ 54 5  12 ' & 4
7(8)8 2 
%4 411 &28 1) 445 *4 !13 *& 2
4 3
44' 8 7+ 2 (44&* 2
54 & 8 41313
 4 ,
45 44 2 344 # 4 5 *3 2 4(4
1 & 2*  58 .1
11 &02545%4 81  232  3
!5 "# 22 12 ' 8 4 4 !18 ! 21
  2
4 3 /  8 44!34# (4 8 42  2 1 * $ 8 2 *+ 4 !185 ) 083433
"131 & 4! 21
31& 58 
& 58 +
4 3 33 2 5*1& 58 1 4 413
#  4 5
54 14 3 433
8 2

2 1 13 3
4
8  1! #32 14! 21
1 8 + 72
"358 233 3!3
2* #  5 2
4 3  ! 4 1 5 53
52 135 4 8 * 1 (31 # +  #  45 06 74 &* 3)533*1 ! 2  !48 8 # 5
2 33! 8
4

252!4 41 5 * # 838 * 3 8# 838


( 1 5 53
4 1 & # (4 513
# 5
8 4 2
"358 3 5
8 8 2 5 3
8


13  7 13
6
6 12 1  33     3
36  !
  36 13  2  "
 7 7   

013 56 83 73 12 1 7 93
1
"  3 % 6 6  23& 13 
13
 3 3# $ 7 9
  7   7  '   6
2 1  "  3 (
1
13
71 2
6 3 3# $  3  6

 2  " 
2  (3 )61 "    
63 6 23193   )   * 3 3 7  2  
 1   
    %, -& 13
3 + ,  
 .  3  3 6 6  9 1 6  ' 3 3
 
  3

   / 0%  6&.13  3 3 6 6 
32 139  3  ,  2 ' 3 3
 
6 
9    7 " 331 6  
139  6 3 3
3 3 3
 
6  6 6  / 43 
 !5& 6' %92   23
32 6 % 3   .   ) 1  "
7 6 
9&   43 

3 9 6 (
 26   
27 1 6 1       7 
 
" 7 1       " 9339  3  
 3
   
%, 7 33(33 1 1+ , -  9 1" 1(
6  6 , &   6  32 ,   3
 2 
1    6 7 6 33  3

3

6 333

6 
63  6    
   ! 6 63 3
9" 6  6 %"  9
  ' 62 3  3 3 3 3&

3 3
3936  3 1 7 6663
1 3 3   6 3 7 9
3
6

013 56 83 73 12 1 7 93
1
#3 3 73 6 231 3  3 3 11

3  3 7  1  
  6 9
 $%#&
7 1  3
1

6 6 2 6!5'(3 939 8*3 3
7  3 36 2 93 3 633167  3  ) 3  33 2 
+ 

3
6936
 6723  36393  636 36
 1 3    6   
 0   61 3 
3
!32 9   6    3  7 76 
9  193
 3 1 2 6723 9 
6 2  2 " 3 23  3
 9 6 9 1 3 6 1    $66  7
3  79 6
7
 
3   1
6 3 913

9
3 36 7,2 5 7$
613
 3
 3   1
 6 1

796
6 66  345 2    796
6  345 25  7 6 5  33 64 6 2 66  245 2   55 4 6 2    5        7 2 2 42 166 245 16 5    64 2 !"# 2   4 2 6 2 5  2$ 6   5  6  64 6 2 76 1 45 2 45   145
32 54  5 424 2   7% 145 53 

0136 25 4

 4  2

317 9  
  4 8
2 238 27
2 1 1 3 9 9
1 48
2
61
4 27
8 9 "  4
4 4 93  1
9 ! 1 32 ! # 3 19 4  1
3827 2#4 17
 3 1 2 3
1

2 "    648 
41
42
 2 3 92 4  34  1 2 " 4 $ %
$ %   1 ' ) 44 % $ % & 4 14  ( 4 * "4 4 4
9

01464 8
2 1 2 2 7 9 
 2 3

 911 11 61 2 566 535795 71 6 5 9  5  7 88 1 4  1 98  9  63  5675  8 28 6 9 8 7 4 8 6 

01 3579 767379 2 46 6 86 8 8

 #6 6 1766 867379 8 1 33 2 559189 98 0 4 ( 7  8 6  4 1164 1'  6  56173168 " 578  81 7 9 56 61886 98 9 9 54 1 7 6 )9 $ ) 5  #1574 5681 1517661 16 9 67 65 31 1 )54 " 51618 739 67379  918 6 7 79 9 3 98 51 41 $8$7  1 6$1  1 64 8 " 6 " 3 6 1" 818 5 1 4  # 1  8 461$  " 6 6 7 5 61 6 51 "    518 1 157 4 5 51 8 3 61 86 9  7 57 181   0136 59 6 1 518  3796 7 8 1* + 47 1  1  767 6 5  8 ( 8   )95 $50 5 61,125 8  9 6 11 $5 61 879842 456  479 36 8 8 9  57 1 6 11  61 4 4 5 6 $ 6 3 6

 4 ! 8 6757673795295 635 6 54618 17 5 16 6 78!1 9 8  16 1 8  52 886819 " 6 7 1  8 4  9 6  # 9468767 814"656867169  %6&81 381 1 77  1 6 1 4  5 3  7 69 9 55" $2616737 1 78 4 88768116 1 46 971 7798  9929 7$1541176 6 76739  16 16 3 37685196 5 752659 1 87537 "49 675 51$3 185 76251 731  8 1 7 1   4 41$ 7 6 87 9 991 68 5 115   

9
77 77 3 7272   262 43  1 71 6 1  6 3  9  5 31 1 5 47 21 7  1 4  63766  177 51 254 7 1 1 2  264 22  7 2 6 7  2 2    1   72   1 

01 3572 2461 6

9 %24 1 1 6672 #775721 61 176 6 ( ( 571 3 47 7 2 363722  4   2 164 1711 1 1 1 2 2 6 2 6 5 1  9
2 7 2 7 76 7  4 2 1  2 2  1 3 1  2 65 66  1   55   7 3
9 %  ( 2 23 37  26 4 2  4   7 7 4 7  4 1  4 9 54  1  2  3  6 5 1 1) 9 * 3 21 76 4 2  61 3    2 24  1 442)

 6  7 6 4 2 1 7 1 2 3723 3 7  5 1   232  7  1   2 45 3722 1  !" #$  42 7  72 4     1   7 6271 2 4  1 6  77  51  3  0%&' 6(  ( 1  2 2  6 ( 6  1 2 2 11 2 7

75  5 5 7
49 24 6 5  9 5   1357 4 794 4
 75   
 5  4 7 6 75 4! 34  5   45
9 75  !  !4 
4 764  5  4 4
 79  !19

0135774

5 4 24 64 7 7 9 7 
94 4

01 41 5689 2  52 2 1 7
15 9
051 29 1  6 #$% 15  52 9 816  595 " 1 16  99 79  !1 9 2   5 2  61 15  9 1 1 9  52 76 1
979 1 25 1 99 91      2 5 92   
% 15 7  9

2  61 
5  5  9 1 1 9

01 41 5689 2  52 2 1 7
15 9
051 29 1  6 %7
52  7 2 15 9 68 8 5  2 7 2 5 2 95 2 
 67   9 2 7
7 9 1 1 9 816 595 ! " $5
19  1 1 162   99 79 15  1 9 2   5 2  61 15  9 1 1 9 !"# 15  52 9

     2  4 2 95 2  2  2 15

! $% #

011
9256169 
7 22
5 5
2 2451 6892 88 6282 26 72 2 86 72  6 2 829 5 5
7 458   2 5 7   72 62 2
5
 ' 82 8
5   16 762 62 ( $ $ ) *+ $ ) ! $ $ '  5# '

&  "7 8
5 8862 62
"222
4587/86261,5
98625 5 25
12 6 02 9  8 2 7 5
2  2 3"" 
07 1 8 
02  17 8
"222 745
24567 5

2 6 4 079 2 51  58/ 96216 2 9 29 21 7 5


818  82 1*97 7 $ 1  $ *225 5 58
$ # 1 5 $  

 458   5 7  

 ' 8 8862 62   16 7 8


5 , 2 761 5266 72 -592 1 587
7 2   $ '. & + (   $ $ )% $  , ,(

"207 2
51122 /6561626
107  7276 25
/5
986218687 86 2
6 5 2 745
2202215 182 2 6622 2  1 8 5 2 2
2 6 / 9 4 9 29   2 9 2 

6288 1 6  86 9 6  2 72  8 2 72  9 8 8 2   1  797 1 9  1 2 21  6 81 2 22 8  4  6 1 72 91 5 69 57 2 6 5 1 82 11  72 862   7  ! 818 7 6 7  27  4 8 2 9"67 9 92 97 7 22 2 22 6 2 68 4 6 1  2   9 2  1 2 1 9 262

01 4 572
2 2689


2  2 9

01 326 482 22 4279

7 
2 2
1   1 474 71 9 2 3 2  78 4 2 8
9  2 2
1 22

7 7 7 31 ! 9 


4   2

1  2 1 2 6 22  2 1 2#
486$1 2  81  
2 1  " 2 972  
 9 2 2 9 6 7 8!  %2#2 01 322  22 4 2 &6429 2 9 

4 6 8 1   22 6 1 6 

01 4 579
2 2 682

62 22 242 1

68 22 2 6 2  882 6222 6 22
74 2 25 6
7 4 579 1 6 5 4184  2 68 2 1 2 2 6

 22
2   84  84
86 8
 

2 2 929
6 684 24 28284
8 8 6 6
26 2
 8 
2

120 67 7 7 4 8 9

   7 
0

8
73753 236 6  45 4  6 5 7 7 7 6  35777355  75 4 3 73 3  8 $ 4 5  8% 5546 7 4 6   
7 5 7 4526 4 65  6 7 746   ! 6
 ! " # 60"

1247 36 5

582535 5 8 65   2 
 5    255522 3 2 88  52 6  56  
  4 658

 69  3 8   9 255 5  93   4   6833


 69  23 8 5 8 5 353 255  25   8 8  86
29 5 329 4 5
 5   23 3    5 55522 3
4 6  56  !4 528 53 5  5 6 6 62 4 2  5  2365  9 93   688335  52 353 9 
0

124 68
5   6 9 35 9 58 5 5 2

7  432 45 3  27 34  3 7

123579 643 346 247

 4 47
7 77 3 3 2
6    9 646
67
2 4 66 5 375 7   24
6 44  
4 77 2 7       7   9!"74339 6 #63 464 # 3 6 5!"44 5 34  4!"942 74 4 7  47 
2 7 7 944 27  
 4  2 7 4# 947  7
7 469 65
7 7743 434   2 5 2 57 24 73 3 2

2
7  477 2 7
 # 77 34 7 4 4 23 4 3    7 
32 7 2 4  $37364#9 643 6  
4 2 %&'7 34 33 26 247  7  2 7   432 3 2
2  (  67 34  32 7 34 32 %&'  7 57 432 4   432 7 #  )432 34 4 3     5   6 34 7 3      7  57   12242 3  577 7# 7 3 5 44 *2 6 
43 
94 ,6  7  2 7  2  6 + 237 72 2 2   92    1
4 354  67 7# 2   3 2 7 7 57  2  - 37  !" 54432
0


 42  2  58 2 5
8  2 4  8  7   7 4 4

25 583
8  742 4  4 4 444 2 4 !  5 5
8 83
8
"5  3322  ! 74
4 8 ! 8 83
 3 2   8 3 4  2 # 44 32 !  8 2 4  ! 538 7  4 8 44 ! 5  2 3 $2 4 ! 5 842 344
72 4  8 $2 4   %4  832!54  44 ! 53 4 4 8
2 8 4! 2  ! 42 &
  8 4  8 3 3 ' 2 ! 7
2 44 ! 4 !  2
0

12 47844 
2  3 52 5
8 4 8

  5 
 42 3 2 5   4 72 3   8 4 2 5  !  

25 58  744

12 47844 
2  3 52 5
8 4 8

    /, 2 0--, 3 0. .,     " $" !" # # %&!!  .*%'()-*  '()     1 %+ + $"   & %&! 4 , 

5 6  25 5

4   2 4  47 74 4  2 8 83


8   25 52 8

12 47844 
2  3 52 5
8 4 8

84 
37 8   8 2 44 4
7
0

2
 4  4 5 4 4 
 2 5 3   8    8 2 5 2  4
82 4   2
4  5 4 5    2   2 5 
84  
2  85  282 3 2 7    !  "88 # 54 8 4 # 83
4 4 44 4 4 4 4$ 54 4  5 2  2
 3  #44    83
72 5  2 83 5  2 % & 4 2 4   # 83
44  8   2  54 4   8 5 2

 24
82  4 72 5 2 5 8  4 " & 4 2 7 74# 83
442  8  25 5 54 4   8 7 5
 3 2   2 5  83
2
0

12 47844 
2  3 52 5
8 4 8

12572
8  8

22 2  3 8 2 98   9 9  2


7 28
    8 2 
2  9
 "8
2 9 $
   #  92 9  3   "
9 8
 7
 %2  2
   7    7 92 ! 1  8# 2
7

"8#9 

"8#3  

236 83 9  9 33 3 0 4 9 3 


9  

  33494 4 83  9 
 9    9 39 9 9 8 3839 3    0 3      
 %9 3
'     
3 ! 3  !9      %
9  8  (3 !  9" 

# 8  8  
3 $ & 8 9

%9 3  

%99   

0 1

1248422484 
2  34 748458
8 4 8 55 7 +
12 45" 4 3 5 

 4 4 444 
2  2     5 5
8 4 8 
  233

 & 4 "4 # 2 4 83
 58"
   !

 43
2#$   242%2 3 8  83 "$ 2 2 2  5  '
2 %284 44 5  ( , 53 2 " * 327 5 4,+-%4%453 472 8 " 4 3
 *
+ 74 2 3 4) 8+ # 524 "  -) 
2
85 5 "4 " 4  2%  7  2 #   2 ( . 8 4 2% 4)/0 01 0  3*/ *01 0 44   5
 8 )   0  (
4 "+"38 2 3 2%54" 08 44 48 54 2,8-2 344 8 $4 
7
38 "0 432  84
 2 8  4 ( )*2 38+48 34 8 44 4  3 )*2  &4
4 5  $4
8     7 3 4 7 +4 4
4  4 8 (  4 " 52 "5 34 45 4
+  2 23 4
+44 34 +2 5 7 8 58 37 5 73  8""557 8 8" 5 + 8   4 6 3 47 2 
 +
2 2  4

2 4 4 +   4 4 "   2 8 2  
0 0

 95 58   9  83 6  2  95  55  5 3 9    3   8 9    3 3  59  5 5 5  5 5 4 4 3 3 5 5 9!5   5 5   64 35  "3 95  6 9  6 5 5    3 5 5 5 5  9  49 #   4 $%&     4    4 5  9 35  3855'3 $%& 55 !95 8  9 8  (9889 59  65 5 8 5 3 3  5 5 5  9 9# 9
0 1

23 58955  3  4 63 6 9 5 9 

 5 3 9 8 3   0   5    9  9    5  3 53 59 93 5   5  9 8 5 85    8  3 9 !   89 5"  3 93   9 5 3 5  3  5   8 9  9 # 68 4 9 95 3 5 3 ! 5 5 "5  5 58   5 9 86# 0 95 893   0  $ 4 36  34 9 43 94   4  3 3  9 4 4895  9  & 5  3 %5 4 5  3 

23 58955  3  4 63 6 9 5 9 

0 1

 50 95 893   0   4 9 4  34 9 43 94   4  5 3 3  4895  9  6  3 5 4 5  6  5


23 3 8 9 43   5 !  8 9 8 94 5  9  4 5 9 3 94  4 5 6 ! 4 " 3 5    35 9 "  3 3 23 3    9 43   5 !  8 94 53 4 5  9  4 3 #$%5  52 9!  3 9 4 5    8  4  9 5 6 5  9 9 5 &'()  * + 0 8% $ 8 5 5 5  5 , - 58   3 9 $ 5 " " 6 ! 4 "3 5  9-853   55 9 "  3 9 5 4 5 9 8   350 + %  5 ! !  6$9 .  3 5  4   4 3  6 5  9! %53 6 5 4 5 53   %

23 58955  3  4 63 6 9 5 9 

0 1

23 58955  3  4 63 6 9 5 9 
3 5 4  4 4  996  9 5    3 5 

0 1

23 58955  3 0 4 63 6 9 5 9  
3  5   9  
   96 58 3 549 5 9 4 58  5 5 8     5 6 5 5 3   4 49 58 3 5   35   8  64 5 69  5 5 6  4 9 4  5 3  953 55 8 6 9 
! 5  8 853 " # 4 5   # 9  36" 6"     3  $5 8"5% 5 9 &  '59  (  3 9  65 5 5  5 "  85 5 )5  9 5  963 49 ) 3 )  95  5" 8 " 45 9 " 45 3 5 *+'$5 , "55  9 &

0 1

23683 9  9 33 3  4 9 3 


9  

  3 

9       
 "9 3
$    # 
3 
  & ' "9#
  "9#4   4   "
 9  8  %3  3    8    8
3 ! 2  9# 3 8

0 1

236 9



3 0 3 4 7 3 3  33     
3
9
4 34 939
  43  3


0  
    3      
&
3 (      3  " 3    "
     &

     & !
 9  )3 "  
#    $ 9  9   3 %  '9 
 !

&
 3   

0 1

 63  95 955 9 5  6 39 5 5 6  

23 58955  3 0 4 63 6 9 5 9 0 
65 5 50$  3 3  63 6   3  9 499 "% 4 9 9  3  399539 !4# 3 &  '853( 35 959   5 9 45 6)( 39 55     3 4 63 4 4  5344 5 93 '8 9 59  5  9 5 9356 9 5   53 9  5  3 5 3  9 49 5 *53 69 6 955 4  5    5 55'+39 5    3 9635 9  4  ,    ' 6

0 1

37
6578
74
88574 74    4 3 7 7 3 4 7  35 6  

68683
 48 67 8 37 ! 7! 4

"7 7 57 7 7 7 7 7 5  37 5#  ! 7  8433 65



"358 44 %4
7#8 ! 378
644! !7 $ 4 74

767368 ! 3 7 3  # 7% 757 5  3 $ 7 3 3
5 7 6!33 58$7 " ! 
! # % #7 '!  7 6  5#!  4#7 &
& 
3  3 7 6
7
3  (5 78535 67$ !)%#33 58!"7
! 7"585
)*"5
86583  
3 8 3 58 3 45 6 7 65
 ! 36 7!
 3 7 # 7! 5 7 ! 
3 65 3
4 7 )7
4 3 3 ! (3 577755)+67
)8 8 737! ! 883 6 !!5  77384
483 ! 84744! ! 767 8
857! !6 567 8
 7 4 ,7 7 7 7 3 ! 858
 4 3  ! 8 ,/08  5
 47 7# !6
4#  8 3 7 7 7
7 33 
0 1

235586
577 4 7 3 8 6

-.37
!5
87735! 38443*46 5 "! 57 5688  3 8584 7!5! 7 7 784 !8 8! 67 8 78 6
7  7 7 8 6

557 458  357 6 6 7 8  458  7 357 6

235586
577 0 4 7 3 8 6

7 7 77 7  4 8 
 4
 3 5 
 33


873 4 65
 8 
 43 57  33   3 7 7 7 7 3 7 4
4
7 8"#
 4  77 57  7 7 !1 $7 7 7 7%5 3   8 85&'(3  7 #5876
567 8 37  384 6 8  
7  5 %7 )8  7657*3 853   85 5 68 8
  
384 
 8 7 8
 48 6 75%+  4 %, 7 7 3 7 7 7 7 8
7 7 55 
 5 8 58 
 8 55  87

- 1/ 2/ 3 .41 / 0/

0 1

6 7
 347  6 246 5

1244759466 3 6 2 7

5

 6 6 66 6  3 7
 9  3 9  2 4 9 
22

9762 3
549 7  9  32 46  22   2 6 6 6 6 2 6 393 9 6 7 !  9  3  6674  46  6 6
 " #6 6 6 6$4 2  273  7 %&'2 6 "47659456 7 26 
5
7   9 6  4 $6 (7  6546)2 742  
74 4 57 7 9    9 273  9  7
2 6 9  37 6 6 6 *266657     6

 ( 45$9
652  2  )2 746 
74 667 2 46    9   9 273 3 9  7
6  9  374 9 2  3456 79 # 52 59 2 6 6 6  6  9 46  9 2 7$6  6 46 5  6649 45946 765  7  7 296  2  74 2 3     +2 97
 645946657
56 7 26  46 9 
, 96    6 6  4  6 $6  56646 2 9  3734 -2 6  5$49 7 6 7  7 6 6 6 3  9 3
6 5 3 ,2 5  2 67
 7 456 7 26   -6 6657599  9 
 29 6  4 2 6     2 7  $6 6

0 0

<'*#5(3#'= *.'+,+6,= = 44 ' >)1.#*#5(3#' &'45, !5,)!935!)!&%#) ##*4.'+,+6,14# #%& #3&((!3*+"' *' C@ *3'8#3&((!3F A '.& 5,)!935!GC + D'&9#5(3#'###)& 4&'.&8'"8()!*#(58(!# (' 34,+6,,6& * %5&!3' *!#+ ("E! *9," 4 E 6 + I 34 & C @ # '&).41!#%&&)')*+'!#35!*&*!*8#*EJ GK %& ('# "# '( !+,H("(!3! '6 4)0!#O A ' ( ' * L34,%5, !,#'#, )+.!#E,4# '&)6)!&! 2&.& #%&5& &+!%&# 8"(#* %& ( ('* J &3 6 # 4 ' ,) 0 1 @? @M @N?M ? P M Q :PP ;

583 8 3 6 8 85
7
7 
 5 7 77 85
5
5   3 7    583 8
7 8 7 6  !#%&&)')*+&@ "# '( !+, ' ' * -!",.* ,#&# '&),"' & #34,%5& A #!### %*/!)%& ( &!1! 2&.& ,#C ' 0 " &3 6 7*.'+5(3#' &.8#%&5,)!935!(!0A@B ; (4*# ,+6,1435, ! #3&((!36') C ? @ 4 ' &:

235586
577 4 7 3 8 6

583 8 3 6 8 85
7
7 


235586
577 4 7 3 8 6

5 7 77 85
5
5      583 8
7 8 7  3 7 6 !373 768 
 " 7

 63 7755 57 6 


3  4567 8 5  
46 
75# $ $
7
7 6 6 57 6 %3 7   7 85
77 85
5$ 5 7  3
583 8# 583 8 4 7  4 $ 677758$577
5
 5   7 8 8  8 47 
3 
3  3  3 77 85
  583 8 &8
 43 
$ 67 67  37  # 7 7 7 $7 65 73 8  7  5  3 7 573  5 67 8  756
57763 7  75 4 7 7

7     6 8 4  7  45 67 8 35 4 7 7 6 4
0 1

2396 937933488973
 45 73  5 898
 8 68
9 3   5 8  3 3 38 

0 1

23 683 3 5 890 45 7
38 9 
  8  38 3 8 6 5    
 6 5 89  38   % 9! "889
 5
87 " 3

  !   74   &  "53 98
6  7! 7 8 9  23 9498"
43  8! 46 !886
 7   8 987 
9
98     '4893 6 !7
6 5 7  96 ! 79 98

  " 3 8 
6! 33 3
 3 3

7
   
74   9   5388 9 77
6 53 9  7
76 3   " 7! 7  ' 3 (39 7! 7  76

98 53 9
8  ' 3 
 7  76

3 949
8   7
 7 3

  93 74  95 "6!89#
998894793
3"78!6 !3 5 8 537 63  85
53
 !
796 6! 989 ! 7
64
63 78 3946
7    5!7$8 3 7  6  " 7 

0 1

VU4U5 U6 4U7/64 U7 /60 W X YW W T/ X X T V/Y/ X/Y/ TYT Y1/ / 0 23 8 ;=?ABC8D E;B88FH/ T Y1I 9:<>8;8= C C C<GTZ 0 2 ; J BK?FD:DKNC4<>;PD 8F Q6 >O=OO?E8L /R471236 D DL; M<B=; DLO= CE?B8 98C DN D <G 1 /0/ C D BK?FD:DKNCSC LO=PD 8F 98C =OOD <G0R[712321236 DL; M<B=; B >; CE?B8 >ODN?E8L 1 /4 / 0/ \ C D 0 a E^<a_2 0 / 8 // 1 SA<F =ODLO=PD 8F ; ;=8OC5D>=O;H ^6 a` 8 0 8>8DNM>; CE?B8O C<>;FNN?DNO]4/ Y 1/

 35
8
73 3 3 7
3 4 3 78 98 5 9 9 4 
  6  9   6
8
5579 98
49
3 4 98 5 
4 7 75 38 9 9 9   9
4  8 236
58
5 9 3 ! 0#83 9   79
 8 9 4 " ! 8 3  
4 84 5
3 6 9    9   3 5
8
3 5
4  98 3 9 $
7855 ! 385 "%' 3  9 47 8 3 458 &0   (80   7 9 +)& 3,9
78"( -. )
* 5 0 *  7 5 83 & 9

23578
9 9 8  4 35  49 6 9 855 9 47 8 87 

235669 
!97" 798
67 8 8 6 8 8
   9       0    

0 1

  44  4 7  683 73 6 53    53 8 5 7 0 438 747 8  
57 57  ! 347 4 5  8 3 7 

 8  "
4  6  8  87  33 3 3 7 8 4   53
 5   7 5 457   
8 3583 # 8  7 3347 3 7  3 8  47  8 #44  $88
 7  % 7
  &(* , / 21,3435 44 33 3 ')+ - 012+ ( 8  5   # 5 5 4  4 
7 5  4 43 8 $ 4 $3 $  7 7  8   7  5  3( / *// 21, 7 )+0( ' 2( 5 )  5 44 )5 ( 6 012+ 2 /8) ,/ 3, (5   33 3 4  4 
7 5  4 43 5   #$3 $  7 7  8   5 5 5   8 $ 4 7  8+ 39 34+ 821: , )3,35 44 33 97 3( , +26/ /(1 8  5  + 5 3  5 447  4 8 8 5 8 8  #    3  8 7  3 5 7 7   4  437  83  5! 43 4  56  4  4  8 7  8   6 438 $ 4    
0 1

2354387 6 4647


4 4

  44  4 7  683 73 6 53    53 8 5 7  438 747 8  
57 57  ! 347 4 5  8 3 7 

 8  "$ %& (* "-( /& 0 "  00 733 8   # # '# +, . ,$ &0
7 12 123 3 ++ 7 4  53 8    5 4443 33 8 7 123 3 !     5  7  5 3  5 44435 8 8 4  7  6    7  3 8 7 7   5  7  4 8 8  35 448 7 443  3 6 8 8    7  "$ %& (/*+ 8,$/'.: 5 44 33 # # '# "0 9. 8 /0   5  + 5  3  5 44435 7 4
 4  6    7 8  7 7  5  8 8 8 7 7 68343  3 6   53 4   7 7 6 "$ %& (/"/&9 /' .:
<  5 44 # # '# ## "; 8 /0 7 < 2!   33 3  47 7
53
4    4 5   6   48
8 3 3 8  5 5  7 
543 458    4 5  46 3
 8  7  3 = 4 7 8 6 5 4 7 7 8 7 4  
0 1

2354387 6 4647


4 4

23 3 27 9 4 6 8
3  6

0 1

8 88    8!8! " 881#$8 %$  88 2345 3 4 7 3 89  
  

0 1

12 465 4
54  3576 6 2 6 2 58

0 0

36753 4 39 57 4 73 7   6335 376  7      4363  563    35647437333 564 5 4 7    3  6   3 5 85 3 5 6 7 4 656 3  7 3 73 63    3 6    5 4 3   

23 576 5 65 4687 7 3 69

7336 734869 5 356 &59 84 73 69  7    6 3  3  6 6  36 5#$%5 3955563455354473 '7 773 7 743 536 345 5 79 3 3 9 7 35 38 3   5 7 4      (

! "44  6 5694   74 54  543 6 9 4  5  3 3 3  6   35 3 ! "76773 9 7 44 6 85734    57 75 3 63  3 3 3 38#$% 3 6

0 1

 64 6 6 5 
9 9 
 4 9 9 

99  5    6 7    3    49 5    5   5      99 7  5 "   #9 9 4
  45 
 955 5!   3 55       59   3  6  76 9  5
4 5 3 6 9 35756 5    3 9 6 9 6 7 6

 6 9    6 7 
7   $4 9 #%65    4 &  5 9 3  6  9 1 (!  7
66 5  ' 3  9    245   6    7 6 5  9 3 3  9

23 6 9
 6  4457
 

0 1

9 84864 347 7  56 5  7 6 8 8 8 7  46888466  86 5 4 84 4  9!& 5 6  9' 6657 8 5 7   
8 6 8 56  !76  7 8 857 37 5  " !7  " $ % 7#$

2358 47 6

0 1

6   ! 0 " # $% 8 $ '( )$23 9 8 9   &7  9  8     *$ 8   ,&- 98 6 98+   $  6  ,  .8
8 + $   ,  
.9 9 56    8  / 7      
#0781 66 78 8 $$ 8 $   $ 8 $ . 8  6 .     9 $

  6 
#2 6 7$9 5 5 7$   8 6$  6 8 + 6 # ,6 6.  9 $ 86  .  8 7 
6 58
 8  6 968 6 78$ 6$  56  7
$88 6 7  8. 5  $  
87 79 $  9
56  8 / 7  9    #3  9 $8996 8 $$   6   6 5 $   98   $ 
0 1

235  
68
9 222  7 9  6 8668    97 

23 5 4 96
 6 9
5 46 8
5 4   8  4

0 1

23 3 73
98 7 9 6 5 4 56 89    69 4 4 

0 1

2375746 475   7 7 46 693446454 5357 5 7 75  6   7    3

 9 7  557479657 64 75 4  577 6  3  69  4  9 7 4  5  5   4796 57   7 7 7 7  55  4 9  !577 6 9 7" 9
#$757 %7 55  & 4554   5    7  9 7   4   7  6 9 4 7 4 4 7   6
 '  6 7 77   5& 47 65  ( 9 4 75 3  & 57 9     7 %5 4  ' 6 )    7  57  6 * 9 75" 4  7  7  75 4 4%5  6 5 #+73 44 7564 6    6  69 73 44 7  5  , 69 55 6  5  5 6 7 756  7 73 44  7  73 44 5 5  6   5757     3  4  4 4     45 7 4   9 6 4 5 55 55  7   6 7  7   3  47   4 4  73 44 5   )  7 74    4    7  #$4 4 55 4 55 55 97  3   5 4 4  -4 55 64 7547 6 5547679657    4   4    4 9  4 4 7 7  .5 4 7 5/53606 5 77   455 5    5 3 4 4  9 5  7 3 4 7 4 6 47 7 45 91 4 5 474   4 63 5 9 6-5  65 9 5 6  3 4 4 4 7  6

0 1

'&( '*

231389 8 8  4  7   4 7    3    ! 3  #$34  !%  "    !3 3    
&4 4 #'4() 4     

2 #33   7 7

+! ,-4  .  

     01  

 

23178
 84 3  98 4 3  3
3  
3 9    4  839
3 9
9   34 4 3   3 "  3 8!
      4  83 

3    8  



3 8  9
9  3 3   8
34 3 9 3 8!
   4  "    8
#   3 78 93    8  



0 1

0 1

4349 5 6644 3 4 5    6 4 1 3 6 49 69   34  6  5 3 5  55 95 9 96   


6 3 3 6 2  95 46 26   6   4 4 9 69 49  5 3 5  8 84 4 !69 49  4 5  35  9  55 3 5 "6  1 25  9 5
39  5  #   9 4 4 4 5  4 389
269 4
4 3 63  9 4   5 3 9 4  $4 4
4 5 89
0 0

1235 35 89  34 64 4
4 4 

0 1

23 38
6 9 9  49 4679
8 7 9 3  9 733 8
93
9499  6  7 38!938 39"9   9  8 3 6 6 3  9  8  3 
 9  8 9 
" 86   9  89 9  7   9 9! 33     9 


( 
9 6  4 78 3 ) 9 3  ! 9 8 3
86  9# 99 9  9  &3 ') ) 9! 33 7$!   %9 6 9  (  * 9 6  )  +9  ) )) ( 3# ) 1, 3  -) .   (

0 1

23 38
6 9 9  49 4679
8 7 9 3  9 733 8
93
9499  6  7 38!938 39"9   9  8 3 6 6 3  9  8  3 
 03 679
6 9
129 7  6 '3 &3# 4 8 ) ( 838
8 3 9  73 9 8
 1 ( 3 ( ( 3 5$3 3 12 ,
*  09 3 9 8
6797  8   9
8   9   69 3 7 9
677 !69  8 ! 396 6
 
8# 6 !  9 3 9  3  8 9 
9 3 8 " 6    6 7 7   3
86  9# 99 9  9  &3 '( ( 9! 33 7$!   %9 6 9   ) * 9 6  () ) ,9  ( ((  3# ( +- 3 ) .( / )  

0 1

9 84864 347 7  56 5  7 6 8 8 8 7  46888466  86 5 4 84 4  9!% 5 6  9& 6657 8 5 7   
8 6 8 56  !76  7 8 857 37 5  " !7  " $ 1 7#$

2358 47 6

0 1

2357
4 3 468


0 1

2353 8
5
9 
94 44 79 9 9 9 33 4
 8

3 89 8 83 8
4   9 35
9 9 9 3 

0 1

23568
4  67 4 7 4 464  7667  74

4 4     4 7  0 
0 1

0 1

0 1

23568
4 464 4 7 4 67 

0 1

124 789
2 3 3 5 289   3 4 21 3 !  "  2  4  5    2  4   4 3   2 #  4 # #  2$" %   3  &  4#    3       &  4 2 ' 3  3 00   "  2 3    22  3  #( 3  3   3    4 3 2   2# 

0 1

   698 4  6 39 5

23 5794  4683 8 4  6

    4 8   6 9 

!3 3 4858" 59    9 3   6

689 7 6 3867 68   33  3   54 6 6 4

0 1

S-ar putea să vă placă și