Sunteți pe pagina 1din 46

Lecture 4.

1: Chapter 8

Monopoly Markets

Learning Objectives
1. Define monopoly.
2. Explain three reasons why monopolies arise.
3. Explain how a monopoly determines price and
output.
4. Use a graph to illustrate how a monopoly affects
economic efficiency.
5. Discuss government policies towards monopolies.
6. Monopoly and Price discrimination
2

Is any firm ever really a monopoly?

Narrow definition of monopoly: A firm is the only


seller of a good or service which does not have a close
substitute. This implies that a monopoly can ignore the
actions of all other firms.
For example, the government water authority can ignore the
price of bottled water.

Broad definition of monopoly: This means that


other firms in the market are not close enough
substitutes to compete away economic profits in the
long run.
For example, the only pizza shop may have a monopoly,
although burgers may be a substitute.
3

Where do monopolies come from?


Monopolies emerge due to a lack of competition
created by barriers to entry.
Three reasons for high barriers to entry are:
1. Government blocks the entry of more than one firm into
a market.
2. One firm has control of a key raw material necessary to
produce a good.
3. Economies of scale are so large that one firm has a
natural monopoly.

Where do monopolies come from?


1. Government blocks entry in three main ways:
i.

By
License
Association);

(e.g.

Taxis;

Australian

Medical

ii. By granting a patent or copyright to an individual


or firm, which gives the exclusive right to produce a
product or service for a period of time.
iii. By granting a firm a public franchise, which makes
it the exclusive legal provider of a good or service.
Example, Australia Post
5

Where do monopolies come from?


2. Another way for a firm to become a monopoly is by
controlling a key resource.

Example

During the last century, De Beers owner 90 percent


of the worlds diamonds.

China owns 95 per cent of the worlds rare earth


metals which it has nationalised.
Firms use rare earth metals to produce 17 chemicals that
are used in the production of many goods including
mobile phones and laptops.

How does a monopoly choose price


and output?
Like every other firm, a monopoly maximises profit at
the output when marginal revenue equals marginal
cost (MR = MC).
However, the difference is that a monopolys demand
curve is the same as the demand curve for the product
(downward sloping).

How does a monopoly choose price


and output?
Monopoly is a price maker. It does not face a
horizontal demand curve.
In fact, both its demand curve and marginal
revenue curve are downward-sloping; and
Its marginal revenue curve is positioned below its
demand curve.

(dollars per subscription)

Price & marginal revenue

Demand and Marginal


Revenue
60

To sell more, the price


must be lowered. The
marginal revenue curve
will be below the demand
curve.

Total revenue
loss $4

c
50

48

Total revenue gain $48


Marginal revenue $ 44

44

MR

Quantity (subscriptions)
9

Profit-maximising quantity and price for a monopoly: Figure 8.3a


Price and cost
MC

$60

Profitmaximising
price

42

27

A
Demand

Profit-maximising quantity
10

MR

Quantity

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Profits for a monopoly: Figure 8.3b


Price and cost
MC

$60
Profit

ATC
Profitmaximising
price

42

30

A
Demand

Profit-maximising quantity
11

MR

Quantity

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Does monopoly reduce economic


efficiency?
We know that equilibrium in a perfectly competitive
market results in the greatest amount of economic
surplus, or total benefit to society, from the
production of a good or service.
However, a monopoly will produce less and
charge a higher price than would a perfectly
competitive industry producing the same good.

12

What happens if a perfectly competitive industry


becomes a monopoly?: Figure 8.4
Price and
cost per
unit

If the industry is perfectly competitive, the


intersection of the demand and supply
curves determines equilibrium price and
quantity.

Price and
cost per
unit

Supply
3. and
charges a
higher price.

PC

1. If the industry
becomes a monopoly,
the supply curve
becomes the
monopolists marginal
cost curve.

2. The
monopolist
reduces
output to the
level where
MR = MC,

PM
PC

MR

Demand
0

QC

Quantity

(a) Perfect competition


13

MC

QM

QC

(b) Monopoly

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Demand
Quantity

Does monopoly reduce economic


efficiency?
The effects of monopoly can be summarised as
follows:
1. Monopoly causes a reduction in consumer surplus.
2. Monopoly causes an increase in producer surplus.
3. Monopoly causes a deadweight loss, which
represents a reduction in economic efficiency;
allocative inefficiency occurs.
14

The inefficiency of a monopoly: Figure 8.5


Price and cost
Transfer of
consumer surplus to
monopoly

PM
PC

MC

Deadweight loss from a


monopoly (B + C)

B
C

MCM
Marginal cost of
the last unit
produced by the
monopoly
15

Demand

MR
0

QM

QC

Quantity

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Gains from Monopoly


Market power and technological change

16

Market power: The ability of a firm to charge a


price greater than marginal cost.

The introduction of new products requires firms


to spend funds on research and development.

Because firms with market power are more likely


to earn economic profits, they are also more
likely to introduce new products.

Government Policy
Toward
Monopoly

17

Government policy toward monopoly


Collusion: An agreement among firms to charge
the same price, or to otherwise not compete.
In Australia, trade practices laws are used to deal
with monopolies, collusion and other forms of anticompetitive behaviour.
The laws usually make it illegal for large firms with
market power to collude, and firms wishing to
merge or take over another firm must apply for
permission to do so.
18

Government policy toward monopoly


In Australia, competitive behaviour is monitored by
the Australian Competition and Consumer
Commission (ACCC).
The major regulatory law regarding trade practices
is the Competition and Consumer Act 2010. It
covers the following seven key areas:
Anti-competitive agreements, such as price fixing.
Exclusive dealing, such as: (i) market sharing
arrangements; and (ii) third line forcing.
19

Government policy toward monopoly

20

Misuse of market power, such as predatory pricing.

Boycotts, such as an agreement between some


suppliers and purchasers not to supply to, or
purchase from, a particular firm or competitor.

Resale price maintenance.

Unconscionable and misleading conduct, such as


deceiving people into signing contracts that they do
not understand.

Product safety and reliability.

Monopoly
&
Price Discrimination
21

Monopoly & Price Discrimination


Price
discrimination:
Charging
different
customers different prices for the same product
when the price differences are not due to
differences in production costs.

22

Price discrimination
There are three requirements for successful
price discrimination:
1.A firm must possess market power.
2.The firm must know what different consumers are
willing to pay.
3.The firm must be able to divide (segment) the
market for the product, and prevent resale between
these segments.
23

Price discrimination by a cinema: Figure 8A.1

24

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Airlines: The kings of price discrimination

Business travellersmore price inelastic

Holiday travellersmore price elastic

Day and time

Season

Price
Discrimination
Economy,
business and first class

25

Yield management: Continually adjusting prices to


take into account fluctuations in demand.

Perfect price discrimination: This occurs when


each consumer has to pay a price equal to the
consumers maximum willingness to pay (no
consumer surplus).

Price Discrimination

Two key outcomes of price discrimination are:

26

Firm profits increase

Consumer surplus decreases

Perfect price discrimination: Figure 8A.2

27

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Lecture 4.2: Chapter


9

Monopolistic
Competition

PowerPoint to accompany:

Learning Objectives
1. Explain why a monopolistically competitive firm has
downward-sloping demand and marginal revenue
curves.
2. Explain how a monopolistically competitive firm
maximises profit in the short run.
3. Analyse the situation of a monopolistically
competitive firm in the long run.
4. Compare the efficiency of monopolistic competition
and perfect competition.
29

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Monopolistic competition: A market structure in


which barriers to entry are low, and many firms
compete by selling similar, but not identical,
products.
Differentiated products
Positive economic profit in the short run

30

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Starbucks: Growth through product


differentiationdecline through
competition
Starbucks has been competing
in a highly contested market for
over three decades, but was
able to maintain profits and
expand its operation across the
globe thanks to successful
differentiation strategy. It is
only recently that Starbucks ran
into trouble, with its strategy no
longer successful in all markets.

31

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Demand and revenue at a Starbucks coffee house: Table 9.1

32

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

The demand and marginal revenue curves for a


monopolistically competitive firm: Figure 9.3
Price

Demand
0
33

MR

Quantity

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Demand and marginal revenue for a


firm in a monopolistically competitive
market
Marginal revenue for a firm with a downwardsloping demand curve
Every firm that has the ability to affect the price of
the good or service it sells will have a marginal
revenue curve that is below its demand curve.

34

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

How a monopolistically competitive firm


maximises profits in the short run
Another way to calculate profit is using the following
formula:
Profit = (P - ATC) x Q
where P is price, ATC is average total cost and Q is
quantity traded.
Note: P - ATC provides profit per unit.
Remember: Profit is maximised or loss is minimised
when MR = MC.
35

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

How a monopolistically competitive firm


maximises profits in the short run

To maximise profit, the Starbucks coffee house wants to


sell caffe lattes up to the point where the marginal
revenue from selling the last caffe latte is just equal to
the marginal cost.

As the information in the table in the textbook shows,


this happens with the fifth caffe latte A which adds
$1.50 to the firms costs and $1.50 to its revenues. The
firm then uses the demand curve to find the price that
will lead consumers to buy this quantity of caffe lattes
(point B).

36

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Maximising profit in a monopolistically competitive market:


Price (dollars per
cup)

$6.00

Starbucks Short-run
profit equals $1 5 =
$5.00. (i.e. (P-ATC) x
Q)

MC
ATC

3.50
Profit
2.50

A
Demand

0
37

MR

Quantity (cups per week)

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

What happens to profits in the long


run?
How does entry of new firms affect the profits of
existing firms?
Entry of new firms will shift the existing firms
demand curve to the left.
The firm will sell fewer products at every price.
The demand curve will also become more price
elastic.

38

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

A monopolistic competitor may earn a short-run


profit: Figure 9.5a
Price (dollars
per cup)

MC
Short-run profit

P(Short run)

0
39

ATC

MR(Short run)
Q (Short run)

Demand(Short run)
Quantity (cups per week)

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

A monopolistic competitors profits are


eliminated in the long run: Figure 9.5b
Price (dollars
per cup)

MC
ATC
A

P(Short run)
P(Long run)

0
40

B
MR(Short run)
MR(Long run)

Q(Long run) Q(Short run)

Demand(Short run)
Demand(Long run)
Quantity (cups per week)

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

What happens to profits in the long


run?
Is zero economic profit inevitable in the long run?
Relatively easy entry into the market causes the
disappearance of economic profits in the long run.
Exception: If a firm finds new ways of differentiating
its product or finds new ways of lowering the cost of
producing its product, it can maintain economic profits,
even in the long run.

41

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Comparing perfect competition and


monopolistic competition
There are two important differences between long-run
equilibrium in the two markets.
1. Monopolistically competitive firms charge a price
greater than marginal cost.
2. Monopolistically competitive firms do not
produce at minimum average total cost.

42

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Comparing perfect competition and


monopolistic competition
Excess capacity under monopolistic competition
As a monopolistically competitive firm produces at P
> minimum ATC, the firm has excess capacity; if it
increased its output it could produce at a lower
average cost.

43

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Comparing long-run equilibrium under perfect competition


and monopolistic competition: Figure 9.6
Price
and cost

MC
ATC

P = MC

D=MR

Quantity
QPC
(Productively efficient)

(a) Perfect competition


44

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Comparing long-run equilibrium under perfect competition


and monopolistic competition: Figure 9.6
Price
and cost

Price
and cost

MC

MC

ATC

ATC
P
P = MC

D=MR
MC
D

MR
0

Quantity
QPC
(Productively efficient)

(a) Perfect competition


45

QMC

QPC

Quantity

Excess capacity

(b) Monopolistic competition

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

Comparing perfect competition and


monopolistic competition
Is monopolistic competition inefficient?

Monopolistic competition is inefficient in terms of


allocative and productive efficiency.
However, it is likely to be more efficient in terms of
dynamic efficiency.
How consumers benefit from monopolistic competition.

From being able to purchase a product that is


differentiated and more closely suited to their tastes.
That is, consumers enjoy product variety.
46

Copyright 2013 Pearson Australia (a division of Pearson Australia Group Pty Ltd) 9781442558069/Hubbard and O'Brien/Essentials of Economics/2e

S-ar putea să vă placă și